Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 16

MODULE 2

TEN AXIOMS THAT FORM THE BASICS OF FINANCIAL MANAGEMENT

Axiom 1: The Risk-Return Tradeoff - We Wont Take on Additional Risk Unless We


Expect to Be Compensated with Additional Return

At some point we have all saved some money. Why have we done this? The answer is
simple: to expand our future consumption opportunities. We are able to invest those savings and
earn a return on our dollars because some people would rather forgo future consumption
opportunities to consume more now. Assuming there are a lot of different people that would like
to use our savings, how do we decide where to put our money?

First, investors demand a minimum return for delaying consumption that must be greater
than the anticipated rate of inflation. If they didnt receive enough to compensate for anticipated
inflation investors would purchase whatever goods they desired ahead of time or invest in assets
that were subject to inflation and earn the rate of inflation on those assets. There isnt much
incentive to postpone consumption if your savings are going to decline in terms of purchasing
power.

Investment alternatives have different amounts of risk and expected returns. Investors
sometimes choose to put their money in risky investments because these investment offer higher
expected returns the more risk an investment has, the higher will be its expected return. This
relationship between risk and expected return is shown in figure 1-1.

Notice that we keep referring to expected return than actual return. We may have
expectations of what the returns from investing will be, but we cant peer into the future and see
what those returns are actually going to be. If investors could see into the future no one would
have invested money in the dressmaker Leslie Fay, whose stock dropped 43 percent on April 5,
1993, when it announced it was filing for bankruptcy. Until after the fact, you are never sure
what the return on an investment will be. That is why General Motors bonds pay more interest

than U.S. treasury bonds of the sam


samee maturity. The additional interest convinces some investors
to take on the added risk of purchasing a General Motors bonds.

This risk-return
return relationship will be a key concept as we value stocks, bonds, and
proposed new projects throughout this text. We will also spend time determining how to measure
risk. Interestingly, much of the work for which the 1990 Nobel Prize for Economics was
awarded centered on the graph in Figure 3 and how to measure risk. Both the graph and the riskrisk
return relationship it depicts
picts will reappear often in this text.

Figure 2. The Risk-Return


Return Relationship

Axiom 2: The Time Value of Money A Dollar Received Today is Worth More
Than a Dollar Received in the Future

A fundamental concept in finance is that money has a time value associated with it: A
dollar received today is worth more than a dollar received a year from now. Because we can earn
interest on money received today, it is better to receive money earlier ra
rather
ther than later. In your
economics courses, this concept of the time value of money is referred to as the opportunity cost
of passing up the earning potential of a peso today.

In this text we focus on the creation and measurement of wealth. To measure wealth or
value we will use the concept of the time value of money to bring future benefits and costs of a
project back to present. Then, if the benefits outweigh the costs the project creates wealth and
should be accepted; if the costs outweigh the benefits the project does not create wealth and
should be rejected. Without recognizing the existence of the time value of money, it is
impossible to evaluate projects with future benefits and costs in a meaningful way.

To bring future benefits and costs of a project back to the present, we must assume a
specific opportunity cost of money, or interest rate. Exactly what interest rate to use is
determined by Axiom 1, The Risk Return Tradeoff, which states investors demand higher
returns for taking on more projects. Thus, when we determine the present value of future benefits
and costs, we take into account that investors demand a higher return for taking on added risk.

Axiom 3: Cash Not Profits Is King

In measuring wealth or value we will use cash flows, not accounting profits, as our
measurement tool. Cash flows are received by the firm and can be reinvested. Accounting
profits, on the other hand, are shown when they are earned rather than when the money is
actually in hand. A firms cash flows and accounting profits may not occur together. For
example, capital expenses, such as the purchase of new equipment or a building, are depreciated
over several years, with the annual depreciation subtracted from profits. However, the cash flow
associated with this expense generally occurs immediately. Therefore cash outflows involving
paying money out and cash inflows that can be reinvested correctly reflect the timing for the
benefits and costs.
At this point, the first three axioms we have presented can be used to determine the value
of any asset, be it a business, a new project, or a financial asset like a share of stock or a bond. In
future chapters we will provide the techniques for determining the value of an asset based on
these axioms.

Axiom 4: Incremental Cash Flows Its Only What Changes That Counts

In making business decisions, we are concerned with the results of decisions: What
happens if we say yes versus what happens if we say no? Axiom 3

states that we should use

cash flows to measure the benefits that accrue from taking on a new project. We are now fine
tuning our evaluation process so that we only consider incremental cash flows. The incremental
cash flow is the difference between the cash flows if the project is taken on versus what they will
be if the project is not taken on.

Not all cash flows are incremental. For example, when Leaf Inc., a manufacturer of sports
card, introduced Donruss Triple Play Baseball Cards in 1992, the product competed directly with
the companys Leaf and Dunuss Baseball cards. There is no doubt that some of the sales dollar
that are ended up with Donruss triple Play Cards would have been spent on Donruss or Leaf
Cards if Triple Play Cards had not been available. Although the Leaf Corporation meant to target
the low-cost end of the base cards market held by tops, there was no question that Triple Play
sales bit into actually cannibalized sales from the companys existing product lines. The
difference between revenues generated by introducing the new cards versus maintaining the
original series are the incremental cash flows. This difference reflects the true impact of the
decision.
What is important is that we think incrementally. Our guiding rule in deciding whether a
cash flow is incremental is to look at the company with and without the new product. In fact, we
will take this incremental concept beyond cash flows and look at all consequences from all
decisions on an incremental basis.

Axiom 5: The Curse of Competitive Markets Why Its Hard to Find Exceptionally
Profitable Projects

Our job as financial manager is to create wealth. Therefore, we will look closely at the
mechanics of valuation and decision making. We will focus on estimating cash flows,
determining what the investment earns and valuing assets and new projects. But it will be easy to
get caught up in the mechanics of valuation and lose sight of the process of creating wealth. Why

is it so hard to find projects and investments that are exceptionally profitable? Where do
profitable projects come from? The answers to these questions tell us a lot about how
competitive markets operate and where to look for profitable projects.

In reality, it is much easier evaluating profitable projects than finding them. If an industry
is generating large profits, new entrants are attracted. The additional competition and added
capacity can result in profits being driven down to the required rate of return. Conversely, if an
industry is returning profits below the required rate of return, then some participants in the
market drop out, reducing capacity and competition. In turn, prices are driven back up. This is
precisely what happened in the VCR video rental market in the mid-1980s. this market
developed suddenly with the opportunity for extremely large profits. Because there were no
barriers to entry, the market quickly was flooded with new entries. By 1987 the competition and
price cutting produced losses for many firms moving out of the video rental industry, profits
again rose to the point where the required rate of return could be earned on invested capital.

In competitive markets, extremely large profits simply cannot exist for very long. Given
that somewhat bleak scenario, how can we find good projects that is, projects that return more
than the required rate of return? Although competition makes them difficult to find, we have to
invest in markets that are not perfectly competitive. The two most common ways of making
markets less competitive are to differentiate the product in some key way to achieve a cost
advantage over competitors.

Product differentiation insulates a product from competition, thereby allowing prices to


stay sufficiently high to support large profits. If products are differentiated, consumer choice is
no longer made by price alone. For example, in the pharmaceutical industry, patents create
competitive barriers. Smith Kline Beckmans Tagamet, used in the treatment of ulcers, and
Hoffman-La Roches Valium, a tranquilizer, are protected from direct competition by patents.

Service and quality are also used to differentiate products. For example, Caterpillar
Tractor has long prided itself on the quality of its construction and earth-moving machinery. As a
result, it has been able to maintain its market share. Similarly, much of Toyota and Hondas

brand loyalty is based on quality. Service can also create product differentiation, as shown by
McDonalds fast service, cleanliness and consistency of product that brings costumers back.

Whether product differentiation occurs because of advertising, patents, service, or


quality, the more the product is differentiate from competing products, the less competition it
will face and the greater the responsibility of large profits.

Economies of scale and the ability to produce at a cost below competition can effectively
deter new entrants to the market and thereby reduce competition. The retail hardware industry is
one such case. In the hardware industry there are fixed cost that are independent of the stores
size. For example, inventory costs, advertising expenses, and managerial salaries are essentially
the same regardless of annual sales, therefore, the more sales that can be used to full potential.

Regardless of how the cost advantage is created by economies of scale, proprietary


technology, or monopolistic control of raw materials the cost advantage deters new market
entrants while allowing production at below industry cost. This cost advantage has the potential
of creating large profits.

The key to locating profitable investment projects is to first understand how and where
they exist in competitive markets. Then the corporate philosophy must be aimed at creating or
taking advantage of some imperfection in these markets, either through product differentiation or
creation of a cost advantage, rather than looking to new markets or industries that appear to
provide large profits. Any perfectly competitive industry that looks too good to be true wont be
for long.

Axiom 6: Efficient Capital Markets The Markets are Quick and the
Prices Are Right

Our goal as financial managers is the maximization of shareholder wealth. Decisions that
maximize shareholder wealth lead to an increase in the market price the existing common stock.
To understand this relationship, as well as how securities such as bonds and stocks are valued or

priced in the financial markets, it is necessary to have an understanding of the concept of


efficient markets.

Whether a market is efficient has to do with the speed with which information is
impounded into security prices. An efficient market is characterized by a large number of profitdriven individuals who act independently. In addition, new information regarding securities
arrives in the market in a random manner. Given this setting, investors adjust to new information
immediately and buy and sell the security until they feel the price correctly reflects the new
information. Under the efficient market hypothesis, information is reflected in security prices
with such speed that there are no opportunities for investors from publicly available information.
Investors competing for profits ensure that security prices appropriately reflect the expected
earnings and risks involved and thus the true value of the firm.

What are the implications of efficient markets for us? First, the price is right. Stock prices
reflect all publicly available information regarding the value of the company. This means we can
implement our goal of maximization of shareholder wealth by focusing on the effect each
decision should have on the stock price if everything else were held constant. Second, earnings
manipulations through accounting changes will not result in price changes. Stock splits and other
changes in accounting methods that do not affect cash flows are not reflected in prices. Market
prices reflect expected cash flows available to shareholders. Thus, our pre-occupation with cash
flows to measure the timing of the benefits is justified.

As we will see, it is indeed reassuring that prices reflect value. It allows us to look at
prices and see value reflected in them. While it may make investing a bit less exciting, it makes
corporate finance much less uncertain.

Axiom 7: The Agency Problem Managers Wont Work for the Owners Unless Its
in Their Best Interest

Although the goal of the firm is the maximization of shareholder wealth, in reality the
agency problem may interfere with the implementation of this goal. The agency problem results

from the separation of management and the ownership of the firm. For example, a large firm may
be run by professional managers who have little or no ownership in the firm. Because of this
separation of the decision makers and owners, managers may make decisions that are not in line
with the goal of maximization of shareholder wealth. They may approach work less energetically
and attempt to benefit themselves in terms of salary and perquisites at the expense of
shareholders.

The costs associated with the agency problem are difficult to measure, but occasionally
we see the problems effect in the marketplace. For example, if the market feels management of
a firm is damaging shareholder wealth, we might see a positive reaction in stock price to the
removal of that management. In 1989, on the day following the death of John Dorrance, Jr.,
chairman of Campbell Soup, Campbells stock price rose about 15 percent. Some investors felt
that Campbells relatively small growth in earnings might be improved with the departure of
Dorrance. There was also speculation that Dorrance was the major obstacle to a possible positive
reorganization.

If the management of the firm works for the owners, who are actually the shareholders,
why doesnt the management get tired if they dont act in the shareholders best interest? In
theory, the shareholders pick the corporate board of directors and the board of directors in turn
picks the management. Unfortunately, in reality the system frequently works the other way
around. Management selects the board of director nominees and then distributes the ballots. In
effect, shareholders are offered a slate of nominees selected by the management. The end result
is management effectively selects the directors, who then may have more allegiance to managers
than to shareholders. This is turn sets up the potential for agency problems with the board of
directors not monitoring managers on behalf of the shareholders as they should.

We will spend considerable time monitoring managers and trying to align their interests
with shareholders. Managers can be monitored by auditing financial statements and mangers
compensation packages. The interests of managers and shareholders can be aligned by
establishing management stock options, bonuses and perquisites that are directly tied to how
closely their decisions coincide with the interest of shareholders. This agency problem will

persist unless an incentive structure is set up that aligns the interests of managers and
shareholders. In other words, whats good for shareholders must also be good for managers. If
that is not the case, managers will make decisions in their best interest rather than maximizing
shareholder wealth.

Axiom 8: Taxes Bias Business Decisions

Hardly any decision is made by the financial manger without considering the impact of
taxes. When we introduced Axiom 4, we said that only incremental cash flows should be
considered in the evaluation process. More specifically, the cash flows will consider will be
after-tax incremental cash flows to the firm as whole.

When we evaluate new projects, we will see income taxes playing a significant role.
When the company is analyzing the possible acquisition of a plant or equipment, the returns from
the investment should be measured on an after-tax basis. Otherwise the company will not truly
be evaluating the true incremental cash flows generated by the project.

The government also realizes taxes can bias business decisions and uses taxes to
encourage spending in certain ways. If the government wanted to encourage spending on
research and development projects it might offer an investment tax credit for such investments.
This would have the effect of reducing taxes on research and development projects, which would
in turn increase the after-tax cash flows from those projects. The increased cash flow would turn
some otherwise unprofitable research and development projects into profitable projects. In effect,
the government can use taxes as a tool to direct business investment to research and development
projects, to the inner cities, and to projects that create jobs.

Taxes also play a role in determining a firms financial structure, or mix of debt and
stock. Although this subject has been the focus of intense controversy for over three decades, one
aspect remains constant: The tax laws give debt financing a definite cost advantage over stock.
As we noted when we examined how taxes are computed, interest payments are a tax-deductible
expense, whereas dividend payments to stockholders may not be used as deductions in computing

a corporations taxable profits. Interest pa


payments
yments lower profits, which are not a cash flow item,
and this in turn lowers taxes due, which are a cash flow item. In effect, paying interest as
opposed to dividends reduces taxes.

Axiom 9: All Risk Are Not Equal Some risk Can Be Diversified Away,
and Some Cannot

Much of finance centers on Axiom 1, The Risk


Risk-Return
Return Tradeoff. But before we can fully
use Axiom 1 we must decide how to measure risk. As we will see, risk is difficult to measure.
Axiom 9 introduces you to the process of diversification and demonstrates how it can reduce
risk. We will also provide you with an understanding of how diversification makes it difficult to
measure a project or an assets risk.

Figure 3. Reducing risk through diversification.

You are probably


bably already familiar with the concept of diversification. There is an old
saying dont put all your eggs in one basket. Diversification allows good and bad events or
observations to cancel each other out, preferably reducing total variability without affecting
a
expected return.

To see how diversification complicates the measurement of risk, let us look at the
difficulty Louisiana Gas has in determining the level of risk associated with a new natural gas
well drilling project. Each year Louisiana Gas mi
might
ght drill several hundred wells, with each well

having only a 1 in 10 chance of success. If the well produces, the profits are quite large, but if it
comes up dry the investment is lost. Thus, with a 90 percent chance of losing everything, we
would view the project as being extremely risky. However, if Louisiana Gas each year drills
2000 wells all with a 10 percent, independent chance of success, then they would typically have
200 successful wells. Moreover, a bad year may result in only 190 successful wells, while a good
year may result in 210 successful wells. If we look at all the wells together the extreme good and
the bad results tend to cancel each other out and the well drilling projects taken together do not
appear to have much risk or variability of possible outcome.

The amount of risk in a gas well project depends upon our perspective. Looking at the
well standing alone, it looks like a lot; however, if we consider the risk that

each well

contributes to the overall firm risk, it is quite small. This occurs because much of the risk
associated with each individual well is diversified away within the firm. From the point of view
of a diversified shareholder, much of the risk that a project contributes to the firm is further
diversified away as the shareholder adds the Louisiana Gas stock to other stocks in his or her
portfolio. The risk of an investment varies depending upon the perspective of the individual
considering the risk.

Perhaps the easiest way to understand the concept of diversification is to look at it


graphically. Consider what happens when we combine two projects as depicted in Figure 4. In
this case, the cash flows from these projects move in opposite directions, and when they are
combined, the variability of their combination is totally eliminated. Notice that the return has not
changed-both the individual projects and their combinations return averages 10 percent. In this
case the extreme good and bad observations cancel each other out. The degree to which the total
risk is reduced is a function of how the two sets of cash flows or returns move together.

As we will see for most projects and assets, some risk can be eliminated through
diversification, while some risk cannot. This will become an important distinction later in our
studies. For now, we should realize that the process of diversification can reduce risk, and as a
result, measuring a project or an assets risk is very difficult. A projects risk changes depending

on whether you measure: (1) the projects risk when it is standing alone, (2) the amount of risk a
project contributes to the stockholders portfolio.

Axiom 10: Ethical Behavior Is Doing the Right Thing, and Ethical Dilemmas Are
Everywhere in Finance

Ethics, or rather a lack of ethics in finance, is a recurring theme in the news. During the
late 1980s and early 1990s the fall of Ivan Boesky and Drexel, Burnham, Lambert, and the near
collapse of Salomon Brothers seemed to make continuous headlines. Meanwhile, the movie Wall
Street was a hit at the box office and the book Liars Poker, by Michael Lewis, chronicling
unethical behavior in the bond markets, became a best seller. As the lessons of Salomon Brothers
and Drexel, Burnham, Lambert illustrate, ethical errors are not forgiven in the business world.
Not only is acting an ethical manner morally correct, it is congruent with our goal of
maximization of shareholder wealth.

Ethical behavior means doing the right thing. A difficulty arises, however, in
attempting to define doing the right thing. The problem is that each of us has his own set of
values, which forms the basis for our personal judgments about what is the right thing to do.
However, every society adopts a set of rules or laws that prescribe what it believes to be doing
the right thing. In a sense, we can think of laws as a set of rules that reflect the values of the
society as a whole as they have evolved. For purposes of this text, we recognize that individuals
have right to disagree about what constitutes doing the right thing, and we will seldom venture
beyond the basic notion that ethical conduct involves abiding by societys rules. However, we
will point out some of the ethical dilemmas that have arisen in recent years with regard to the
practice of financial management. These dilemmas generally arise when some individual
behavior is found to be at odds with the wishes of a large portion of the population even though
that behavior is not prohibited by law. Ethical dilemmas can therefore provide a catalyst for
debate and discussion, which may eventually lead to a revision in the body of the law. So as we
embark on our study of finance and encounter ethical dilemmas, we encourage you to consider
the issues and form your own opinion.

Many students as, Is ethics really relevant? This is a good question and deserves an
answer. First, although business errors can be forgiven, ethical errors tend to end careers and
terminate future opportunities. Why? Because unethical behavior eliminates trust, and without
trust business cannot interact. Second, the most damaging event a business can experience is a
loss of the publics confidence in its ethical standards. In finance we have seen several recent
examples of such events. It was the ethical scandals involving insider trading at Drexel,
Burnham, Lambert that brought down that firm. In 1991 the ethical scandals involving attempts
by Salomon Brothers to corner the Treasury bill market led to the removal of its top executives
and nearly put the company out of business.

Beyond the question of ethics is the question of social responsibility. In general,


corporate social responsibility means that a corporation has responsibilities to society beyond the
maximization of shareholder wealth. It asserts that a corporation answers to a broader
constituency than shareholders alone. As with most debates that center on ethical and moral
questions, there is no definitive answer. One opinion is that because financial managers are
employees of the corporation, and the corporation is owned by the shareholders, the financial
managers should run the corporation in such a way that shareholder wealth is maximized and
then allow the shareholders to decide if they would
like to fulfill a sense of social responsibility by passing on any of the profits to deserving causes.
Very few corporations consistently act in this way. For example, in 1992 Bristol-Myers Squibb
Co. announced it would start an ambitious program to give away heart medication to those who
cannot pay for them. This announcement came in the wake of an American Heart Association
report showing that many of the nations working poor face severe health risks because they
cannot afford heart drugs. Clearly, Bristol-Myers Squibb felt it had a social responsibility to
provide this medicine to the poor at no cost.

How do you feel about this decision?

A Final Note on the Axioms

Hopefully, these axioms are as much statements of common sense as they are theoretical
statements. These axioms provide the logic behind what is to follow. We will build on them and
attempt to draw out their implications for decision making. As we continue, try to keep in mind
that while the topics being treated may change from chapter to chapter, the logic driving our
treatment of them is constant and is rooted in these ten axioms.

Activity 2

Make sure that you have read the previous chapter before answering this activity. DONE? If yes,
you may answer the following questions briefly.
1. Enumerate the 10 Axioms that form the basics of Financial Management.
a.
b.
c.
d.
e.
f.
g.
h.
i.
j.

2. Among the 10 Axioms / Principles in Financial Management, which one has been applied
to your life recently? Is it Axiom 1, Axiom 2, Axiom 9 or other Axioms? Try to share
your experience and what actions did you make by posting it in our egroup.

You might also like