Goldscheider 25 Percent Rule

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 11

Use Of The 25 Per Cent

Rule In Valuing IP
BY ROBERT GOLDSCHEIDER, JOHN JAROSZ AND CARLA MULHERN*

Introduction in copyright, trademark, trade se- ents, the Swiss subsidiary of a large
cret and know-how contexts as well. American company, with 18 licens-

A
s the importance of intellec-
tual property (“IP”) protec- Since the Rule came into fairly com- ees around the world, each having
tion has grown, so has the mon usage decades ago, times, of an exclusive territory. The term of
sophistication of tools used to value course, have changed. Questions each of these licenses was for three
it. Discounted cash flow,1 capitali- have been raised on whether the years, with the expectation of re-
zation of earnings,2 return on in- factual underpinnings for the Rule newals if things continued to go
vestment,3 Monte Carlo simulation4 still exist (i.e., whether the Rule has well. Thus, if any licensee “turned
and modified Black-Scholes op- much positive strength) such that sour,” it could promptly be re-
tion valuation methods 5 have it can and should continue to be placed. In fact, however, even
been of great value. Nonetheless, used as a valid pricing tool (i.e., though all of them faced strong
the fairly simple “25 Per Cent whether the Rule has much nor- competition, they were either first
Rule” (“Rule”) is over 40 years old mative strength). or second in sales volume, and
and its use continues. Richard In this paper, we describe the probably profitability, in their re-
Razgaitis has called it the “most fa- Rule, address some of the miscon- spective markets. These licenses
mous heuristic, or rule of thumb, ceptions about it and test its factual therefore constituted the proverbial
for licensing valuation.”6 underpinnings. To undertake the “win-win” situation. In those li-
The Rule suggests that the lic- latter, we have examined the rela- censes, the intellectual property
ensee pay a royalty rate equivalent tionship between real-world royalty rights transferred included: a port-
to 25 per cent of its expected prof- rates and real-world industry and folio of valuable patents; a continual
its for the product that incorporates company profit data. In general, we flow of know-how; trademarks de-
the IP at issue. The Rule has been have found that the Rule is a valu- veloped by the licensor; and copy-
primarily used in valuing patents, able tool (rough as it is), particularly righted marketing and product
but has been useful (and applied) when more complete data on incre- description materials. For those li-
mental IP benefits are unavailable. censes, the licensees tended to gen-
The Rule continues to have a fair erate profits of approximately 20
degree of both “positive” and “nor- per cent of sales on which they paid
mative” strength. royalties of 5 per cent of sales. Thus,
1. D.J. Neil, Realistic Valuation of Your IP, the royalty rates were found to be
32 les Nouvelles 182 (December 1997); History of the Rule
25 per cent of the licensee’s profits
Stephen A. Degnan, Using Financial Models One of the authors — Robert
to Get Royalty Rates, 33 les Nouvelles 59 on products embodying the pat-
(June 1998); Daniel Burns, DCF Analyses in Goldscheider7 — did, in fact, under- ented technology.9
Determining Royalty, 30 les Nouvelles 165 take an empirical study of a series
(September 1995); Russell L. Parr & Patrick of commercial licenses in the late
H. Sullivan, Technology Licensing: Corporate 1950s.8 This involved one of his cli-
Strategies For Maximizing Value 233-46
(1996); Richard Razgaitis, Early-Stage
Technologies: Valuation and Pricing 121- *Robert Goldscheider, Chairman, Interna-
58 (1999). tional Licensing Network.
2. Robert Reilly & Robert Schweihs, Valuing John Jarosz and Carla Mulhern, Princi-
Intangible Assets 159-66 (1999).
7. See, e.g., Richard S. Toikka, In Patent pals, Analysis Group/Economics.
3. Parr and Sullivan, pp. 223-33.
Infringement Cases, the 25 Per Cent Rule We would like to thank the following in-
4. V. Walt Bratic et al., Monte Carlo Analyses Offers a Simpler Way to Calculate Reason-
Aid Negotiation, 33 les Nouvelles 47 (June able Royalties. After Kumho Tire, Chances dividuals for their hard work and useful
1998); Razgaitis, pp. 160-77. are the Rule Faces Challenges to its comments on earlier drafts of this paper:
5. Dr. Nir Kossovsky & Dr. Alex Arrow, Daubert Reliability, Legal Times 34 (August Jaime Baim, Laura Boothman, Jeff Kinrich,
TRRU™ Metrics: Measuring The Value and 16, 1999). Jennifer Price, Chris Vellturo and Robert
Risk of Intangible Assets, 35 les Nouvelles 139 8. Robert Goldscheider, Litigation Back-
(September 2000); F. Peter Boer, The Valuation Vigil. The views expressed here are ours
grounder for Licensing 29 les Nouvelles 20, 25
of Technology: Business and Financial Issues In (March 1994); Robert Goldscheider, Royalties and do not necessarily represent those of
R&D, 302-06 (1999). as Measure of Damages 31 les Nouvelles 115, others at the International Licensing Net-
6. Razgaitis, p. 96. 119 (September 1996). work or Analysis Group/Economics.

les Nouvelles December 2002 123


Mr. Goldscheider first wrote is then multiplied by 25 per cent to pendent upon factors specific to the
about the Rule in 1971.10 He noted, arrive at a running royalty rate. In user (e.g., organizational infrastruc-
however, that in some form it had this example, the resulting royalty ture).15 IP, like any other asset, de-
been utilized by valuation experts rate would be 4 per cent. Going for- rives its value from the use to which
prior to that. 11 For example, in ward (or calculating backwards, in it will be put.16
1958, Albert S. Davis, the General the case of litigation), the 4 per cent Focus also is placed on expected
Counsel of Research Corporation, royalty rate is applied to net sales profits because the license negotia-
the pioneer company in licensing to arrive at royalty payments due to tion is meant to cover forthcoming
university-generated technology, the IP owner. The licensee/user re- and on-going use of the IP.17 It is the
wrote: ceives access to the IP, yet the price expected benefits from use of the IP
If the patents protect the Licensee (i.e., royalty) it pays will still allow it that will form the basis for the
from competition and appear to be valid to generate positive product returns. licensee’s payment of an access fee.
the royalty should represent about 25% The theory underlying this rule Past, or sunk costs, typically should
of the anticipated profit for the use of of thumb is that the licensor and lic- be ignored because a decision is be-
the patents.12 ensee should share in the profit- ing made about the future.18 That is,
A form of the Rule, however, ex- ability of products embodying the what going-forward price results in
isted even decades before that. In patented technology. The a priori the product being a sound invest-
1938, the 6th Circuit Court of Ap- assumption is that the licensee ment? Any product in which the
peals, in struggling with the prob- should retain a majority (i.e., 75 projected marginal benefits exceed
lem of determining a reasonable per cent) of the profits because it the projected marginal costs should
royalty, heard expert testimony to has undertaken substantial devel- be undertaken.
the affect that: opment, operational and commer- Focus is placed on long-run profits
cialization risks, contributed other because access to IP often will afford
… ordinarily royalty rights to the
inventor should bear a certain propor- technology/IP and/or brought to the user more than just immediate
tion to the profits made by the manu- bear its own development, op- benefits. 19 Focusing on a single
erational and commercialization month or single year typically will
facturer and that the inventor was
contributions. not properly represent the forth-
entitled to a ‘proportion ranging from
probably ten per cent of the net profits Focus of the Rule is placed on the coming and on-going benefits of the
to as high as thirty per cent,’ which licensee’s profits because it is the lic- IP. In many occasions, it takes some
should be graduated by the competitive ensee who will be using the IP.14 The period of time for a new company
situation.13 value of IP is, for the most part, de- or new product to obtain its opera-
tional efficiencies and a steady state.
Regardless of its origins and
Furthermore, up-front investments
author(s), the concept has aided IP
often need to be amortized over the
valuators for many years.
economic life of a product (not just
Explanation of the Rule its starting years) in order to evalu-
14. In the reasonable royalty determination
In its pure form, the Rule is as fol- in Standard Manufacturing Co., Inc. and ate properly the economic returns
lows. An estimate is made of the DBP, Ltd. v. United States, both sides’ to the product.
licensee’s expected profits for the experts focused on the patent holder’s
profit rate. The Court took exception
product that embodies the IP at is- noting that defendant’s profits were a
sue. Those profits are divided by the “more realistic and reliable estimation of
expected net sales over that same profits which were to [the plaintiff] by the
period to arrive at a profit rate. That infringement since they are derived from 15. Baruch Lev, “Rethinking Accounting,”
the actual sale of [the infringing product].” Financial Executive Online Edition, March/
resulting profit rate, say 16 per cent, Standard Manufacturing Co., Inc. and DBP, April 2002 Cover Story, http://www.fei.org/
Ltd. v. United States, 42 Fed. C1. 748, 767 maggable/articles/3-4-2002.coverstory.cfm.
(1999). The Court noted that a variety of
16. In some circumstances, the licensor’s
federal courts held the same, citing Mahurkar profits may provide some guidance. That is,
v. C.R. Bard, Inc., Davol Inc. and Bard Access those profits may, in part, reflect his/her
System, Inc. 79 F.3d 1572, 1580 (Fed. Cir. 1996) appetite for a license and those profits may
9. Robert Goldscheider, Technology Manage- (district court did not err in calculating serve as a surrogate for missing or unknown
ment: Law/Tactics/Forms § 10.04 (1991). portion of award when it initially used licensee profits.
10. Robert Goldscheider & James T. Marshall, infringer’s profit rate); TWM Manufacturing
Co., Inc. v. Dura Corp. and Kidde, Inc. 789 F.2d 17. Razgaitis, p. 108. Fonar Corporation and
The Art of Licensing – From the Consultant’s Dr. Raymone V. Damadian v. General Electric
Point of View, 2 The Law and Business of 895, 899 (Fed. Cir. 1986) (affirming district
court’s computation of damages based on Company and Drucker & Genuth, MDS, P.C.
Licensing 645 (1980). d/b/a South Shore Imaging Associates,
infringer’s profits); Trans-World Manu-
11. Robert Goldscheider, Technology Manage- facturing Corp. v. Al Nyman & Sons, Inc. and 107 F. 3d 1543 (Fed. Cir. 1997). Hanson v.
ment: Law/Tactics/Forms §10.04 (1991). Al-Site Corporation, 750 F.2d 1552, 1568 Alpine Valley Ski Area, Inc., 718 F.2d 1075
12. Albert S. Davis, Jr., Basic Factors to be (among factors considered in determining (Fed. Cir. 1983).
Considered in Fixing Royalties, Patent reasonable royalty was the infringer’s 18. Richard Brealey & Stewart C. Myers,
Licensing, Practicing Law Institute, 1958. anticipated profit from invention’s use, and Principles of Corporate Finance, 123 (6th
13. Horvath v. McCord Radiator and Mfg. Co. et evidence of infringer’s actual profits probative Ed. 2000).
al., 100 F.2d 326, 335 (6th Cir. 1938). of anticipated profit.) 19. Razgaitis, p. 108.

124 December 2002 les Nouvelles


Finally, the Rule places focus on Figure 1
fully-loaded profits because they 25 Per Cent Rule Illustration - Revenue Side
measure the (accounting) returns on
a product. Gross profits represent No Patent Revenue 25 Per Cent Rule
the difference between revenues Enhancing Patent
and manufacturing costs. Gross
profits, however, do not account for Revenues $100 $110
all of the operating expenses asso-
ciated with product activity. Those Cost of Sales $40 $40
costs include marketing and selling
(“M&S”), general and administra- Gross Margin $60 $70
tive (“G&A”) and research and de-
velopment (“R&D”) expenses. Some Operating Expenses $30 $30
of those costs are directly associated
with product activity, others are ($40*25%)/
Operating Profits $30 $40 $110=9.1%
common across product lines.
“Fully-loaded” profits account for Some environments are competitive and turing overhead. Not subtracted out
the fact that a variety of non-manu- require a lot of support costs which re- is other income and expenses. In
facturing overhead expenses are duce net profits. Intellectual property many cases, these two measures of
undertaken to support the product that is used in this type of environment profit are quite similar; in other
activity, even though they may not is not as valuable as intellectual prop- cases, they are not. Given that the
be directly linked to certain volume erty in a high-profit environment where value of intellectual property is in-
or activity levels. And such costs are fewer support costs are required. A dependent of the way in which a
often driven by product activity. proper royalty must reflect this aspect firm (or project) is financed,23 from
Failure to take into account these of the economic environment in which a theoretical point of view, the op-
operating expenses may lead to an it is to be used. A royalty based on gross erating profit margin is the correct
overstatement of the returns asso- profits alone cannot reflect this reality.21 measure to use.
ciated with the sales of a product.
Fully-loaded profits may refer to Suppose that firm A and firm B
According to Smith and Parr: either pretax profits or operating each have one piece of identical in-
Omission of any of these [overhead] profits. Pretax profits are calculated tellectual property and each manu-
expenses overstates the amount of eco- as revenues minus: 1) cost of goods, factures and sells one product that
nomic benefits that can be allocated to 2) non-manufacturing overhead ex- embodies that intellectual property.
the intellectual property. In a compari- penses and 3) other income and ex- The only difference between the
son of two items of intellectual prop- penses. The historical relationships firms is that firm A is heavily fi-
erty, the property that generates sales, underlying the 25 Per Cent Rule, nanced by debt and firm B is not.
captures market share, and grows, while however, have in fact been between Firm A would then have significant
using less selling and/or support efforts, royalty rates and operating profits.22
is more valuable than the one that re- The latter is revenues minus: 1) cost
quires extensive advertising, sales per- of goods sold and 2) non-manufac-
sonnel, and administrative support. 22. Robert Goldscheider, Technology Manage-
ment: Law/Tactics/Forms § 10.04 (1991),
The economic benefits generated by the Razgaitis, p. 103.
property are most accurately measured 21. Parr, pp. 170-71. 23. Brealey & Myers, Chapters 2 & 6.
after considering these expenses.20
According to Parr: Figure 2
The operating profit level, after con- 25 Per Cent Rule Illustration - Cost Side
sideration of the nonmanufacturing op-
No Patent Cost Reducing 25 Per Cent Rule
erating expenses, is a far more accurate Patent
determinant of the contribution of the
intellectual property. The royalty for Revenues $100 $100
specific intellectual property must re-
flect the industry and economic envi-
Cost of Sales $40 $30
ronment in which the property is used.
Gross Margin $60 $70

Operating Expenses $30 $30


20. Gordon V. Smith & Russell L. Parr,
Valuation of Intellectual Property and Intangible ($40*25%)/
Operating Profits $30 $40 $100=10%
Assets, 362 (2nd Ed. 1994).

les Nouvelles December 2002 125


interest expenses to deduct from its costs that it generates versus the applying the 25 Per Cent Rule to
operating profits resulting in pretax next best alternative.25 The extent of such expected operating profits re-
profit levels below operating profit that excess (or incremental value), sults in a royalty rate of 10 per cent.
levels. Firm B does not have any in- holding all else constant, may form Valuators (and courts) who use
terest expense to deduct. Thus, on the upper bound for the appropri- the 25 Per Cent Rule occasionally
an operating profits basis, firm A ate price.26 split the expected or actual cost (i.e.,
and firm B would have equivalent The 25 Per Cent Rule can be (and incremental) savings associated
profit margins; but, on a pretax ba- is) applied when the licensee re- with the IP at issue.28 According to
sis, firm B would be considerably ports product line revenue and op- Degnan and Horton’s survey of li-
more profitable. Application of the erating profit data for the product censing organizations who base a
25 Per Cent Rule to operating prof- encompassing the IP. It need not be royalty payment on projected cost
its would result in the same royalty the case that the IP at issue be the savings, almost all of them pro-
rate in the case of firm A and firm only feature driving product value. vide for the licensee paying 50 per
B; whereas, application of the Rule (In fact, underlying the Rule is the cent or less of the projected sav-
to pretax profits would result in a understanding that a variety of fac- ings.29 The apparent reasoning is
lower royalty rate for firm A. Since tors drive such value.) That is why that such incremental benefits
the underlying intellectual property only a portion of the profits — 25 should be shared.
and the products embodying it are per cent — is paid in a license fee. Splitting the cost savings by 75/
identical for both firms, one would And that is why the appropriate 25, however, may not be consistent
expect to obtain the same resulting profit split may be much less than with the 25 Per Cent Rule. In Fig-
royalty rate. Thus, application of the 25 per cent of product profit. ure 2, the incremental (or addi-
Rule to operating profits would
The Rule also can be (and is) ap- tional) cost savings are $10. Splitting
yield the appropriate results.
plied when the licensee does not re- that amount ($10) by 25 per cent,
Illustration of the Rule port profits at the operating profit results in a running royalty rate of
IP, like any asset, can be (and is) level. (In fact, there are very few in- 2.5 per cent ($10 x 25%/$100), which
valued using three sets of tools. stances in which firms report prod- is 1/16 of the new “product” prof-
They are often referred to as the In- uct profits at such a level.) As long its, rather than 1/4. Applying the
come Approach, the Market Ap- as product revenues and costs of Rule to incremental savings (or ben-
proach and the Cost Approach.24 goods sold are reported (i.e., gross efits) results in a running royalty
The Income Approach focuses on margins are available), the accoun- that is lower than that dictated by
the returns generated by the user tant or economist can (and does) the 25 Per Cent Rule. It may under
owing to the asset at issue. The Mar- allocate common (or non-manu- compensate the IP owner. The 25
ket Approach focuses on the terms facturing overhead) costs to the Per Cent Rule, in its pure sense,
of technology transfers covering product line in order to derive op- should be applied to fully loaded
comparable assets. The Cost Ap- erating profits. operating profits, not to already
proach focuses on the ability (and The illustration in Figure 1 shows computed incremental benefits.
cost) to develop an alternative as- how the Rule is applied. Several courts have (implicitly)
set that generates the same benefits. A patent may enhance or im- recognized the problem of splitting
The 25 Per Cent Rule is a form of prove product revenues through incremental benefits. In Ajinomoto,
the Income Approach. It is particu- increased prices (though that may the district court wrote:
larly useful when: 1) the IP at issue occur with a reduction in volume27) Although the ‘licensing rule of
comprises a significant portion of or through increased volume. The
product value and/or 2) the incre- second column in Figure 1 illus-
mental benefits of the IP are other- trates the impact of a revenue-en-
wise difficult to measure. hancing patent. Applying the 25 Per
IP is often priced based on the en- Cent Rule to the expected operat- 27. Paul A. Samuelson & William D. Nordhaus,
hanced revenues and/or reduced ing profits results in a royalty rate Economics 47 (17th ed. 2001). Crystal Semi-
of 9.1 per cent. conductor v. Tritech Microelectronics International,
Inc., 246 F. 3d 1336 (Fed. Cir. 2001).
A patent may also reduce prod-
28. Standard Manufacturing Co., Inc. and DBP,
uct costs. Figure 2 illustrates that by Ltd. v. United States, 42 Fed. C1 748, 764-765
(1999). Ajinomoto Inc. v. Archer-Daniels-
24. Shannon P. Pratt et al., Valuing a Business:
Midland Co., No. 95-218-SLR, 1998 U.S. Dist.
The Analysis and Appraisal of Closely Held
LEXIS 3833, (D. Del. March 13, 1998). Tights,
Companies, 149-285 (3rd Ed. 1996); Shannon
P. Pratt et al., Valuing Small Businesses and Inc. v. Kayser-Roth Corp. 442 F. Supp. 159
Professional Practices, 507-524 (2nd Ed. 1993); (M.D.N.C. 1977). Dow Chemical Co. v. United
Gordon V. Smith & Russell L. Parr, Valuation 25. Paul E. Schaafsma, An Economic Over- States, 226 F. 3d 1334 (Fed. Cir. 2000) Razgaitis,
of Intellectual Property and Intangible Assets, view of Patients, 79 Journal of the Patent pp. 117-18.
127-136 (2nd Ed. 1994); Robert Reilly & Trademark Office Society 251, 253 (April 1997). 29. Stephen A. Degnan & Corwin Horton, A
Robert Schweihs, Valuing Intangible Assets 26. Jon Paulsen, Determining Damages for Survey of Licensed Royalties,
118-203 (1999). Infringements, 32 les Nouvelles 64 (June 1997). 32 les Nouvelles 91, 95 (June 1997).

126 December 2002 les Nouvelles


thumb’ dictates that only one-quarter the 25 Per Cent Rule is a variant) in ferent grades of X. P-2 did not in-
to one-third of the benefit should go to determining royalties.35 volve the need to purchase Y from
the owner of the technology … given A dramatic employment of the B. Rather than simply abandon P-1,
[defendant’s] relatively low production Rule occurred in the early 1990’s in however, A decided to offer B the
costs and its belief that the sale of [the the course of negotiations between opportunity to become the exclu-
product] would increase [convoyed two major petrochemical compa- sive worldwide licensee of P-1. The
sales], the court concludes that [defen- nies, respectively referred to as “A” argument was that such a license
dant] would have been willing to share and “B”. A was a leading manufac- could be profitable to B because it
all of the benefit with [plaintiff] and that turer of a basic polymer product was a basic producer of Y (which A
[plaintiff] would have settled for noth- (“X”), with annual sales of over $1 had been purchasing at a price con-
ing less.30 billion. Its process (“P-1”) required taining a profit to B), and B could
Furthermore, in Odetics, the Fed- the purchase from B of an interme- thus manufacture X on a cost-effec-
eral Circuit wrote that “one expects diate compound (“Y”) in annual tive basis. Another attraction of
[an infringer] would pay as much as volumes of over $400 million. A such a license would be that it could
it would cost to shift to a non-infring- owned a patent on its P-1 process compensate B for the loss of its sales
ing product.”31 And in Grain Process- to manufacture X, which would ex- of Y to A.
ing, the Federal Circuit adopted the pire in 7 years. B was interested to take such a li-
lower court’s reasoning that an in- A developed a new process to cense to P-1, and offered to pay a 5
fringer “would not have paid more make X (“P-2”) to which it decided per cent running royalty on its sales
than a 3% royalty rate. The court to switch all its production of the of polymer made in accordance
reasoned that this rate would reflect polymer concerned, essentially for with P-1. A decided to test the rea-
the cost difference between (infringe- cost reasons, but also because P-2 sonableness of this offer by apply-
ment and non-infringement).”32 was more flexible in producing dif- ing the 25 Per Cent Rule, a good
To the extent that incremental portion of which analysis could
benefits (i.e., cost savings) have al- employ 20-20 hindsight. A under-
ready been calculated, any profit stood the market for X, past and
split applied to those may not be present, and had what it considered
consistent with the 25 Per Cent 33. Robert E. Bayes, Pricing the Technology, in to be realistic projections for the fu-
Rule. In theory, the licensee should Current Trends In Domestic and International ture. A had made such a study be-
Licensing 369, 381 (1977). Marcus B. Finnegan cause it intended to remain in the
be willing to accept a royalty that is & Herbert H. Mintz, Determination of a
close to 100 per cent (not 25 per cent) Reasonable Royalty in Negotiating a License
market for X, utilizing P-2. A was
of the cost savings. Agreement: Practical pricing for Successful also able to calculate pro-forma
Technology Transfer, 1 Licensing Law and profitability to B by subtracting B’s
Application of the Rule Business Report 1, 19 (June-July 1978). margin on its sales of Y to A for use
The 25 Per Cent Rule is used in Lawrence Gilbert, Establishing a University
Program, 1 The Law and Business of Licensing in P-1.
actual licensing settings and litiga- 506.267 (1980). Robert Goldscheider & James This analysis revealed that B
tion settings. Over the past three de- T. Marshall, The Art of Licensing-From the should be able to operate as a lic-
cades, a variety of commentators Consultants Point of View, 2 The Law and Business
of Licensing 645 (1980). H.A. Hashbarger, ensee under A’s P-1 patent at an op-
have noted its widespread use.33 In
Maximizing Profits as a Licensee, 2 The Law erating profit of 44 per cent. A
their survey of licensing execu- and Business of Licensing 637 (1980). Alan C. shared its fully documented analy-
tives, which was published in 1997, Rose, Licensing a “Package” Lawfully in the
sis with B and asked “please tell us
Degnan and Horton found that Antitrust Climate of 1972, 1 The Law and
Business of Licensing 267 (1980). Yoshio if we are wrong.” If not, A would
roughly 25 per cent (as a sheer co-
Matsunaga, Determining Reasonable Royalty expect to receive an 11 per cent roy-
incidence) of licensing organiza- Rates, — les Nouvelles 216, 218 (December alty based on B’s sales of X using
tions used the 25 Per Cent Rule as a 1983). The Basics of Licensing: Including
International License Negotiating Thesaurus, A’s patented P-1 process, based on
starting point in negotiations. 34
les 13 (1988). Edward P White, Licensing: A the 25 Per Cent Rule, rather than the
They also found that roughly 50 per Strategy For Profits, 104 (1990). Martin S. 5 per cent that was offered.
cent of the organizations used a Landis, Pricing and Presenting Licensed
“profit sharing analysis” (of which Technology, 3 The Journal of Proprietary Rights Following study of A’s work
18, 20-21 (August 1991). Wm. Marshall Lee, product, B (somewhat surprised
Determining Reasonable Royalty, les Nouvelles and reluctantly) agreed with A’s
124 (September 1992). David C. Munson,
Licensing Technology: A Financial Look at the conclusion. B accepted these terms
Negotiational Process, 78 J.P.T.O.S. 31, 42 n.21 because B would still make a 33 per
30. Ajinomoto Inc. v. Archer-Daniels-Midland (January 1996). Schaafsma, p. 251. Munson, cent operating profit under the li-
Co., No. 95-218-SLR, 1998 U.S. Dist. LEXIS Figuring the Dollars in Negotiations, 33 les cense, which was higher than B’s
3833, at 44 n.46 (D. Del. March 13, 1998). Nouvelles 88 (June 1998). Robert Reilly &
Robert Schweihs, Valuing Intangible Assets normal corporate operating profit
31. Odetics, Inc. v. Storage Technology Corp. 185
F. 3d 1259, 1261 (Fed. Cir. 1999). 193-94, 503 (1999). rate. Over the remaining life of its
32. Grain Processing Corp. v. American Maize- 34. Degnan and Horton, p. 92. P-1 patent, this additional 6 per cent
Products Co., 185 F. 3d 1341, 1345 (Fed. Cir. 1999). 35. Degnan and Horton, p. 92. royalty amounted to added profit,

les Nouvelles December 2002 127


in fact, of several hundred million
dollars to A.
In Standard Manufacturing Co., Inc. Figure 3
and DBP, Ltd. v. United States,36 the Licensed Royalty Rates (Late 1980’s - 2000)
U.S. Court of Claims employed a
Minimum Maximum Median
two-step approach to determining Industry No. of Royalty Royalty Royalty
a litigated reasonable royalty. The Licenses Rate Rate Rate
first step involved an estimation of Automotive 35 1.0% 15.0% 4.0%
an initial or “baseline” rate. The sec-
ond step entailed an adjustment up- Chemicals 72 0.5% 25.0% 3.6%
ward or downward depending on Computers 68 0.2% 15.0% 4.0%
the relative bargaining strengths of Consumer Goods 90 0.0% 17.0% 5.0%
the two parties with respect to each
Electronics 132 0.5% 15.0% 4.0%
of the (15) factors described in Geor-
gia-Pacific Corp. v. United States Ply- Energy & Environment 86 0.5% 20.0% 5.0%
wood Corporation.37 Food 32 0.3% 7.0% 2.8%
The Standard Manufacturing Court Healthcare Products 280 0.1% 77.0% 4.8%
found the application of the 25 Per Cent Internet 47 0.3% 40.0% 7.5%
Rule to be an appropriate method for
Machine/Tools 84 0.5% 25.0% 4.5%
determining the “baseline” royalty
rate. And in support of its use of the Media & Entertainment 19 2.0% 50.0% 8.0%
25 Per Cent Rule, it cited defendant’s Pharma & Biotech 328 0.1% 40.0% 5.1%
expert’s (Robert Goldscheider’s) Semiconductors 78 0.0% 30.0% 3.2%
considerable practical experience
with the Rule. 38 The Court also Software 119 0.0% 70.0% 6.8%
noted that a number of other fed- Telecom 63 0.4% 25.0% 4.7%
eral courts had recognized that the
Total 1,533 0.0% 77.0%
25 Per Cent Rule is a “rule of thumb”
typical in the licensing field.39 For
example, the 25 Per Cent Rule has
been useful in situations where a
party analyzes its own IP for man- Figure 4
agement or tax reasons, or as part Industry Profit Rates (1990 - 2000)
of a merger, acquisition or divesti-
ture. The Rule has been employed Industry No. of Companies Wtd. Avg. Operating Margin

Automotive 100 5.0%


Chemicals 126 11.1%
Computers 459 6.9%
36. Standard Manufacturing Co., Inc. and DBP, Consumer Goods
Ltd. v. United States, 42 Fed. C1. 748 (1999 U.S.
544 11.0%
Claims LEXIS 11). Electronics 425 8.8%
37. Georgia-Pacific Corp. v. United States Energy & Environment
Plywood Corporation, 318 F. Supp. 1116
767 12.2%
(S.D.N.Y. 1970) modified and aff’d, 446 F.2d Food 240 7.3%
295 (2d Cir. 1971).
Healthcare Products 433 14.8%
38. Standard Manufacturing Co., Inc. and DBP,
Ltd. v. United States, 42 Fed. Cl. 748, 763-64 Internet 781 -13.5%
(1999 U.S. claims LEXIS 11).
Machine/Tools 174 7.9%
39. Ajinomoto Co., Inc. v. Archer-Daniels-
Midland Co., No. 95-218-SLR, 1998 U.S. Media & Entertainment 360 10.6%
Dist. LEXIS 3833, at 052 n.46 (D. Del.
March 13, 1998); W.L. Gore & Associates, Inc. v.
Pharma & Biotech 534 16.4%
International Medical Prosthetics Research Semiconductors 207 17.4%
Associates, Inc., 16 USPQ 2d. 1241 (D. Ariz.
1990); Fonar Corporation and Dr. Raymond V. Software 534 18.8%
Damadian v. General Electric Company and Telecom
Drucker & Genuth MDS, P.C. d/b/a/ South Shore
627 14.2%
Imaging Associates, 107 F.3d 1543 (Fed. Cir. Total 6,309 10.4%
1997). See also, Donald S. Chisum, Chisum
On Patents, 7 § 20-03[3] [iv], 20-188, 20-189
(1993 and Supp. 1997). Fromson v. Western
Litho Plate & Supply Co., 853 F. 2d 1568 (Fed.
Cir. 1988).

128 December 2002 les Nouvelles


as follows:
• the remaining economic life of
the property being valued, which Figure 5
may be shorter than the remaining Licensee Profits (1990 - 2000)
legal life of any patents that may be Licensee Wtd. Avg.
part of the analysis, is estimated; Industry No. of Companies
Operating Margin
• the operating profit rate ex- Automotive 4 6.3%
pected during each of such years is
Chemicals 6 11.6%
projected and 25 per cent (or an-
other rate considered appropriate in Computers 20 8.0%
accordance with the Rule) is applied Consumer Goods 23 16.2%
to each of the annual figures; Electronics 30 8.8%
• a discounted cash flow analysis Energy & Environment 14 6.6%
is performed, using an appropri-
Food 6 7.9%
ate discount rate to convert future
flows into a current year lump Healthcare Products 80 17.8%
sum amount. Internet 14 1.0%
The rationale for this appraisal Machine/Tools 8 9.4%
methodology is that the plus or mi- Media & Entertainment 3 -304.5%
nus 25 per cent apportionment is the
price of a reasonable royalty that the Pharma & Biotech 76 25.4%
appraising party would be willing Semiconductors 16 29.3%
to pay for a license for this property, Software 19 33.2%
at that point in time, assuming that Telecom 28 14.1%
it did not own it.
The Rule, whether used in litiga- Total 347 15.9%
tion or non-litigation settings, pro-
vides a fairly rough tool to be
augmented by a more complete roy-
alty analysis. The precise “split” of Figure 6
profits should be adjusted up or Royalty Rates and Licensee Profits
down depending on the circum-
stances of each case and relative Median Average Royalty
Industry Royalty Operating as % of
bargaining positions of the two Rate Profits Profit Rate
parties.40 If a licensor comes to the
bargaining table armed with a rela- Automotive 5.0% 6.3%* 79.7%
tively strong arsenal of assets, it Chemicals 3.0% 11.6% 25.9%
may be entitled to 25 per cent, or Computers 2.8% 8.0% 34.4%
perhaps more, of the pie. Corre- Consumer Goods 5.0% 16.2% 30.8%
spondingly, a weak arsenal of as-
sets supports a lower split. In Electronics 4.5% 8.8% 51.3%
determining the appropriate split Energy & Environment 3.5% 6.6% 52.9%
of profits, the factors established in Food 2.3% 7.9% 28.7%
the Georgia-Pacific case are quite
Healthcare Products 4.0% 17.8% 22.4%
helpful.41 In fact, many of the courts
that have used the Rule in litigation Internet 5.0% 1.0% 492.6%
Machine/Tools 3.4% 9.4% 35.8%
Media & Entertainment 9.0% -304.5%* -3.0%
Pharma & Biotech 4.5% 24.5% 17.7%
40. Robert Goldscheider, Litigation Back- Semiconductors 2.5% 29.3% 8.5%
grounder for Licensing, 29 les Nouvelles 20, 25
(March 1994). Software 7.5% 33.2% 22.6%
41. Georgia Pacific v. United States Plywood Telecom 5.0% 14.1% 35.5%
Corp., 318 F. Supp. 1116 (S.D.N.Y. 1970)
modified and aff’d, 446 F.2d (2d Cir. 1971), Total 4.3% 15.9% 26.7%
the court set forth 15 factors that should be
considered in determining a reasonable * Fewer than 5 observations in data set.
royalty. See also, Stephen A. Degnan, Using
Financial Models to Get Royalty Rates, 33 les
Nouvelles 59, 60 (June 1998).

les Nouvelles December 2002 129


have done so in the context of evalu- Figure 7
ating Georgia-Pacific factor #13 — Distribution of Profit Splits - Licensee Profits
“the portion of the realizable profit
that should be credited to the inven- 10
tion as distinguished from non-pat- 9

Number of Industries
ented elements, the manufacturing 8
process, business risks, or significant 7
features or improvement added by 6
the infringer.” 5
4
Justification for the Rule
3
The Rule, based on historical ob- 2
servations, provides useful guid- 1
ance for how a licensor and licensee 0
should consider apportioning the <0% 0%-20% 21%-40% 41%-60% 61%-80% >80%
benefits flowing from use of the IP.
Somewhat untenable (and unreal-
istic) is guidance that either the li- Figure 8
censor or licensee is entitled to all Royalty Rates and Successful Licensee Profits
of the returns. No bargain would Median Average Royalty
be reached. Though a 50:50 start- Industry Royalty Operating as % of
ing split has a ring of a “win-win” Rate Profits Profit Rate
situation, in fact, the evidence sug- Automotive 5.0% 11.3%* 44.1%
gests otherwise.
Chemicals 3.0% 12.0% 25.0%
Richard Razgaitis has identified 6
Computers 2.8% 8.3% 33.3%
reasons for why a 25/75 (starting)
split makes sense.42 First, “that’s the Consumer Goods 5.0% 18.4% 27.1%
way it is.” Numerous licensors and Electronics 4.5% 13.1% 34.3%
licensees have agreed to a 25/75 Energy & Environment 3.5% 9.2% 38.1%
split. It is, according to him, the in-
Food 2.3% 14.2% 15.8%
dustry norm. Second, typically 75
per cent of the work needed to de- Healthcare Products 4.0% 18.5% 21.6%
velop and commercialize a product Internet 5.0% 10.4% 48.0%
must be done by the licensee. Third, Machine/Tools 3.4% 9.6% 35.0%
“he who has the gold makes the
rules.” Licensees have considerable Media & Entertainment 9.0% -13.5%* -66.7%
leverage because of the numerous Pharma & Biotech 4.5% 25.8% 17.4%
investment alternatives open to Semiconductors 2.5% 31.9% 7.8%
them. Fourth, a 3-times payback ra-
Software 7.5% 25.1% 21.4%
tio is common. Such is obtained by
a licensee retaining 75 per cent of Telecom 5.0% 14.5% 34.5%
the return by investing 25 per cent. Total 4.3% 18.8% 26.6%
Fifth, technology is the first of the 4
required steps of commercializa- * Fewer than 5 observations in data set.
tion. The others are making the
product manufacturable, actually Figure 9
manufacturing it and selling it. Fi- Distribution of Profit Split - Successful Licensee Profits
nally, the ratio of R&D to profits is
10
often in the range of 25 to 33 per cent.
9
Number of Industries

Criticisms of the Rule 8


Despite (or perhaps because of) its 7
widespread use, the 25 Per Cent 6
Rule has been criticized in several 5
ways. First, it has been characterized 4
as a “crude tool” and as “arbitrary.” 3
According to Paul Schaafsma: 2
1
0
<0% 0%-20% 21%-40% 41%-60% 61%-80%
42. Razgaitis, pp. 99-102.

130 December 2002 les Nouvelles


A typical ‘rule of thumb’ … is for the again). Moreover, the Rule is not in- plication because gross margin ig-
licensor to command 25% of the profit. tended to be used in isolation. There nores a host of other relevant costs.
While this … attempts to link the value are a variety of other tools that Such analysts have concluded that
of the patent to the profitability of com- should be employed in any valua- while the 25 Per Cent Rule is “simple”,
mercial exploitation, because it does not tion assignment. “popular” and “easy to understand”, it
relate to the value and degree to which A second criticism is that the Rule “should be avoided.”51 Focusing on
the patent can exclude substitute prod- is “indefinite”. That is, should 25 per gross profits ignores “too many im-
ucts and therefore command a patent cent be applied to gross profits, oper- portant factors.”52
profit, it is little better than [an] ‘in- ating profits, or some other measure This criticism is specious, however,
dustry norm.’ … Patented products add of profits? According to William Lee: because the 25 Per Cent Rule is an al-
to [ ] economic profit the patent profit location (or splitting) of operating prof-
The ‘25% rule’ is sometimes a little
tied into the ability of the patent to fur- its. Explicit consideration is given to
indeterminate as to whether it refers to
ther exclude substitutes. … the portion all of the costs, including non-manu-
25% of net profit or 25% of gross profit
of the total profit can vary greatly even facturing overhead, that are needed
(if you represent the prospective licen-
within a given industry. Adding these to support a product or are driven by
sor, then of course you apply the 25%
values together, and multiplying by an the product. The Rule is not a split of
against anticipated gross profit; if you
arbitrary fraction to derive the value of gross profits.
represent the prospective licensee, you
a patent is an exercise in arbitrary busi-
contend that the 25% applies to net Furthermore, in their survey of li-
ness analysis.43 profit!). Note that the indefiniteness as censing executives, Degnan and
According to Mark Berkman: to whether the ‘25% rule’ speaks to net Horton found that royalty rates
[The 25 Per Cent Rule does] not take profit or gross profit brings it somewhat tend to be 10 to 15 per cent of gross
into account specific circumstances that in line with the rule of thumb of 1/3 to profits. 53 In other words, royalty
will determine the actual value of the 1/4 of profit as a reasonable royalty as rates divided by gross margin is
patent at issue. No consideration is expressed in [some publications].48 substantially lower than 25 per cent.
given to the number or value of eco- In fact, there is no indefiniteness. In P&G Co. v. Paragon Trade Brands,54
nomic alternatives or the incremental The Rule is based on historical ob- the court cited testimony that the
value of using the patented technology servations of the relationships be- Rule “is not really even useful as a
over other viable alternatives.44 tween royalty rates and operating general guide for deriving an ap-
And Richard Toikka has ques- margins.49 That is, rates often are 25 propriate royalty rate.”55 In part be-
tioned whether, in litigation contexts, per cent of operating margins. And cause of that, the court wrote that it
the Rule is reliable under Daubert v. it is anticipated operating margins, “will consider the [25%] Rule-of-
Merrill Dow Pharmaceuticals45 and according to the Rule, against which Thumb analysis in determining the
Kumho Tire Co. v. Carmichael.46 the profit split figure should be ap- royalty rate, [but] this approach will
The Rule, however, is one of many plied. Applying it to another level not receive substantial weight.” 56
tools. Ultimate royalty rates often of profits may be valid and useful Nonetheless, in its final royalty
are higher or lower than 25 per cent in certain contexts, but such an ap- analysis, the court did write that
of fully-loaded product profits, de- plication is not grounded in the con- “the [25%] ‘Rule-of-Thumb’ analy-
pending upon a host of quantitative cepts and facts surrounding the 25 sis provides an additional confirma-
and qualitative factors that can and Per Cent Rule. tion of the reasonableness of a
should affect a negotiation (or liti- Third, some analysts believe that royalty rate of 2.0%.”57
gation). Even critics of the Rule have there is no indefiniteness and that,
conceded that, despite its “crude- in fact, 25 per cent is meant to be
ness”, it retains “widespread en- applied to a licensee’s gross profits.50
dorsement and use”.47 Part of that (Gross profits, again, represents the
is due to its simplicity and part of difference between revenues and 51. Parr, p. 169.
that is due to self-fulfilling proph- cost of goods sold. No deduction for 52. Parr, pp. 169-171.
ecy (because of its simplicity, it has non-manufacturing overhead costs 53. Degnan and Horton, p. 95.
become a norm and, because it is a is included.) They criticize that ap- 54. The Procter & Gamble Company v.
norm, it is used over and over Paragon Trade Brands, 989 F. Supp. 547 (D.
Del. 1997).
55. The Procter & Gamble Company v.
Paragon Trade Brands, 989 F. Supp. 547, 595
48. Russell L. Parr, Intellectual Property (D. Del. 1997).
Infringement Damages: A Litigation Support 56. The Procter & Gamble Company v.
43. Schaafsma, pp. 251-52. Handbook 171 (1993). Paragon Trade Brands, 989 F. Supp. 547, 595
44. Mark Berkman, Valuing Intellectual 49. Robert Goldscheider, Litigation Back- (D. Del. 1997).
Property Assets for Licensing Transactions, grounder for Licensing, 29 les Nouvelles 20, 25 57. The Procter & Gamble Company v.
22 The Licensing Journal 16 (April 2002). (March 1994). Paragon Trade Brands, 989 F. Supp. 547, 596
45. 509 U.S. 579 (1993).
50. Parr, p. 169. Berkman, p. 16. Gregory J. (D. Del. 1997). The expert’s “Rule-of-
46. 526 U.S. 137 (1999). Battersby & Charles W. Grimes, Licensing Thumb” analysis obtained a range of 1.975
47. Schaafsma, p. 252. Royalty Rates: 2002 Edition 4-5 (2002). Per cent to 2.6 Per cent.

les Nouvelles December 2002 131


Fourth, it has been asserted that from thousands of actual licensing information provided by Royalty-
the Rule is inappropriate to use in transactions.59 Because of the confi- Source.com, a searchable database
those instances in which the IP at dentiality of these licenses, along of intellectual property sale and li-
issue represents a small fraction of with a lack of access to expected (or censing transactions, containing in-
the value residing in a product. The actual) product profit rates, we were formation spanning the late 1980s
authors are sympathetic to the criti- unable to undertake a direct com- to the present. From RoyaltySource,
cism. However, both the concepts parison of product profit and roy- we obtained summaries of all avail-
underlying the Rule as well as the alty rates. We, therefore, examined able licensing transactions involv-
empirics supporting it recognize the profit data for two surrogates — lic- ing the following fifteen industries:
flexibility of the Rule. The precise ensee profits and “successful” lic- • Automotive
split should be adjusted up or down ensee profits. • Chemicals
depending on a host of factors, in- With the first proxy, we examined • Computers
cluding the relative contribution of the profits for those firms in each • Consumer Goods
the IP at issue. Relatively minor IP industry that were involved in li- • Electronics
often should (and does) command censing transactions. We used those • Energy and Environment
a split of profits lower than rela- profit rates as a proxy for expected • Food
tively important IP. long-run product profits. • Healthcare Products
A final criticism of the Rule is that With the second proxy, we exam- • Internet
it provides a rough or imprecise ined “successful” licensee profits. • Machines/Tools
measure of incremental benefits. A We defined as “successful” those lic- • Media and Entertainment;
complete (and accurate) incremen- ensees in the top quartile in their re- • Pharmaceuticals and Biotech-
tal analysis is preferred. None of the spective industries in terms of nology
authors disagree. The Rule often is profitability. Presumably, these may • Semiconductors
an adjunct to other valuation meth- more accurately reflect the kind of • Software and
ods. And it is particularly useful profit rates that are generated by • Telecom60
when helpful data on incremental products that embody valuable IP. These licenses involved a variety
value are unavailable or limited. of payment terms — lump-sum, fee
For both proxies, we compared
The 25 Per Cent Rule is a starting per unit and running royalties on
median (or middle of the range) in-
point to apportioning the profits. sales. For ease of comparison, we
dustry royalty rates to weighted av-
William Lee, both a critic and pro- confined our analysis to the 1,533
erage profit rates. Although we
ponent of the Rule, has noted: licenses that involved running roy-
considered comparing median
…in most instances the rule-of- alties on sales.61
royalty rates to median profit rates,
thumb of approximately 1/4 to 1/3 of for some industries, median profit Figure 3 shows on an industry-by-
the licensee’s anticipated profit to go rates differed substantially from industry basis, the information we
to the licensor is a good starting place weighted average profit rates due, obtained from RoyaltySource. We
for negotiations. Whether or not an- at least in part, to the presence of a have reported minimum, maximum
ticipated profit is expressed during significant number of small, start- and median royalty rates. The me-
negotiations, the effect of royalty on up firms earning negative profit dian royalty rate across all indus-
profitability should certainly be in the margins. Given that the negative tries was 4.5 per cent, though
minds of the negotiators on both sides. margins earned by start-ups may median rates ranged from a low of
My experience, and apparently the ex- not be indicative of expected long- 2.8 per cent to a high of 8.0 per cent.
perience of others, tends to show that run profits, we examined weighted Industry Profits
most successful licensing arrangements average profit margins (which gives We obtained financial informa-
end with royalty levels in this range. these negative profit margins rela- tion for the fifteen industries included
However, like all rules-of-thumb, cir- tively less weight).
cumstances alter cases.58
Royalty Rates
Empirical Test of the Rule To obtain information regarding
To test the validity of the 25 Per royalty rates observed in actual 60. RoyaltySource database tracks licensing
Cent Rule, we attempted to com- licensing transactions, we used transactions for other industries as well. The
pare royalty rates from actual licens- industry categories used here were developed
ing transactions with the expected by the authors and are somewhat different
than the internal classification system used
long-run profit margins of the prod- by RoyaltySource.
ucts that embody the subject IP. We 61. Data available to us from RoyaltySource.com
were able to gather royalty rate data 59. We were unable to gather (or evaluate) did not allow us to easily convert lump-sum
information from proposed transactions that or the per unit royalties into royalties per
were never consummated. Presumably, in dollar, which terms were needed for testing
those instances, IP sellers were asking for our hypothesis. As a result, we excluded
more than IP buyers were willing to pay. We those observations from our analysis. We
have no a priori reason to think, however, that have no a priori reason to think, however, that
58. Lee, p. 2073. exclusion of such “data” biases our results. exclusion of such data biases our results.

132 December 2002 les Nouvelles


in our analysis from Bloomberg. The among the remaining industries ductor industry to a high of 48.0 per
Bloomberg database provided fi- varies from 8.5 per cent for semicon- cent for the internet industry.
nancial data for the period 1990 ductors to 79.7 per cent for the au- Figure 9 reports the ratio distri-
through 2000 for 6,309 companies tomotive industry. bution across industries and shows
included in the fifteen industries un- In spite of the variation across in- that, again, the majority of indus-
der consideration. Figure 4 reports dustries, the majority of industries tries have ratios of royalty rates to
both the average operating profit had ratios of royalty rates to licensee successful licensee profit margins in
margin for each of the industries. profit margins of 21 to 40 per cent. the 21 to 40 per cent range.
Licensee Profits Figure 7 shows a distribution of the
Conclusions
Because total industry profits are ratios across industries.
An apportionment of 25 per cent
not a particularly close match to Successful Licensee Profits
of a licensee’s expected profits has
royalty rates covering a limited We also examined profitability become one, of many, useful pric-
number of companies, for our first data for “successful licensees.” We ing tools in IP contexts.62 And our
analysis, we examined profitability defined those to be licensees with empirical analysis provides some
data for only those companies that profit rates in the top quartile for
were identified as licensees in the support for its use.
each industry. We used these profit
licensing transactions database. Fig- rates as a further-refined surrogate A comparison of royalty rates
ure 5 reports weighted average op- for projected product profit rates. with two proxies for expected
erating profit margins for each of long-run product profits (namely,
Royalty Rates and Successful licensee profits and “successful”
the industries.
Licensee Profits licensee profits) yields royalty to
Royalty Rates and Licensee A comparison of royalty rates and
Profits profit ratios of 27 per cent and 23
successful licensee profits appears per cent, respectively.
A comparison of royalty rates and to, again, provide some support for
licensee profits provides some sup- Although the data support the
use of the 25 Per Cent Rule. As
port for use of the 25 Per Cent Rule shown in Figure 8, across all indus- Rule generally, there is quite a varia-
as a tool of analysis. Across all (15) tries, the median royalty rate as a tion in results for specific industries.
industries, the median royalty rate percentage of average operating As this variation makes clear, the
as a percentage of average licensee profits was 22.6 per cent. Excluding Rule is best used as one pricing tool
operating profit margins, as shown the media and entertainment indus- and should be considered in con-
in Figure 6, was 26.7 per cent. Ex- try, for which only limited data were junction with other (quantitative
cluding the media & entertainment available, the ratios range from a and qualitative) factors that can and
and internet industries, the range low of 7.8 per cent for the semicon- do affect royalty rates.

62. Razgaitis, p. 118.

les Nouvelles December 2002 133

You might also like