Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 6

Pricing Strategies for Monopolist Price discrimination

• We have assumed so far that the • Price discrimination:


monopolist charges the same price to different buyers are charged different unit
every buyer prices for similar goods, and the prices are
• If the monopolist can set different prices in different ratios to marginal costs.
for different customers, it can be shown
that this enables her to increase her profit.

Conditions for Successful Price


Examples
Discrimination
• Pricing of cinema hall tickets by time of • The firm must have some degree of
day market power, i.e., the ability to set
• Pricing of transport services by age prices.
• Pricing of professional services by income • The firm must be able to separate
categories customers into two or more groups.
• Pricing of goods by different degrees of • The firm must be able to prevent arbitrage
recognition or frequency of purchase
by buyers, i.e., resale by buyers
• Pricing of books by different editions
• Pricing by region

When resale is not possible Three degrees of price discrimination

• Services • First-degree or perfect price discrimination


• Warranties – The firm can void a warranty
if the object is resold • Second-degree or nonlinear pricing
• Transaction cost
• Contractual remedies • Third-degree price discrimination
• Vertical integration
• Government intervention

1
First-degree or perfect price
Why three degrees? discrimination
• How much information does the seller • The seller has perfect information about
have about buyers? the demand curves of buyers.
1. Perfect information – seller knows the • For each unit sold, the seller charges the
type of each and every buyer buyer an amount equal to the maximum
2. Seller knows the distribution of buyer willingness to pay for that unit.
types, not individual buyers
3. Seller can identify buyer types by
categories

Example First-degree or perfect price


discrimination
Buyer Maximum price Total market
• Next, suppose that each consumer wants one
buyer is willing demand unit of a product, but consumers are willing to
to pay pay different amounts.
• By ranking the consumers according to their
A 10 1 maximum willingness to pay and plotting the
B 9 2 aggregate demands, we get a downward sloping
aggregate demand curve.
C 8 3 • The firm then charges each consumer the
D 7 4 maximum that the person is willing to pay and
sells to any customer whose maximum
E 6 5 willingness to pay exceeds or is equal to the
MC = 8 marginal cost.

First-degree or perfect price


discrimination p, $ per unit
p1

Results: A es
MC

1. From the efficiency standpoint, perfect


ps
B C ec
price discrimination gives the same result
pc =MC c
E

as perfect competition – no deadweight


D MCs

loss MC1
Demand, MR d

2. Distributional implications are totally MR s


Q s Qc=Q d Q, Units per day
different: CS = 0 and Seller captures all
consumer surplus

2
Two-part tariff Examples of two-part tariffs
• Use of two-part tariffs to achieve perfect 1. Membership fees for clubs plus the price
price discrimination of drinks and meals
• A two-part tariff consists of: 2. The entrance fee to the zoo together
- a fixed fee that buyers have to pay to be with separate fees for entering the
allowed to purchase the commodity reptile house and other exhibits
(sometimes called the access fee)
3. Monthly rentals for telephones plus
- and a fixed per unit charge thereafter
payment for calls. etc.
Two-part tariffs fall under the category of
non-linear pricing

Two-Part Tariff with a Single Consumer Second-degree price discrimination


or nonlinear pricing
$/Q
Usage price P* is set where • We assume that the monopolist will not be
T*
MC = D. Entry price T*
is equal to the entire able to identify the type of a particular
consumer surplus.
buyer, though she may have a good idea
about the distribution of buyer types
MC
P*

D • The monopolist then constructs a price


schedule in such a way that buyers reveal
their types by choosing points on the
schedule – “self-selection”
Quantity

Second-degree price discrimination Getting customers to identify


or nonlinear pricing themselves
• Customers may be identified by their Coupons
willingness to spend time to buy a good at - People who use coupons are more price-
a lower price or to order goods and sensitive on average than those who don’t
services in advance of delivery clip coupons
Airline tickets
• Firms use differences in the value - Choice between high-price tickets with no
customers place on their time to strings attached and low-price fares with
discriminate by using queues various kinds of restrictions

3
Non-linear pricing Quantity discounts
• Buyers face nonlinear price schedules, i.e., • Most customers are willing to pay more for
the price paid depends on the quantity or the first units than for the successive units
quality bought • Firm can price-discriminate by letting the
price each customer pays vary with the
• Sometimes differences in quality, too, get number of units the customer buys
reflected in a nonlinear manner in prices - • Use of a price-schedule
The price difference between a high • Implies quantity discounts
quality and a low quality good is more
than that can be explained by differences
in quality alone.

Non-linear pricing Non-linear pricing


• Uniform price to all customers: • Incentive compatibility constraint
Total revenue = pQ - The seller must make sure that the offer
• Non-linear pricing via a price-schedule: aimed at a type A is not found attractive by
p = 10 – Q a type B, say.
Q p
1 9 • Individual rationality constraint
2 8 - Each buyer of a certain type must find the
3 7 etc. appropriate price sufficiently attractive to
buy the product.

Third-degree price discrimination Third-degree price discrimination


Different groups of buyers are charged different • The first order conditions are
prices.
dΠ/dQ1 = dΠ/dQ2 = 0.
• Suppose that the buyers can be separated • These yield the conditions
into two groups, with inverse demand curves MRi(Qi) – MC(Q1 + Q2) = 0, i = 1,2.
P1(Q1) and P2(Q2), respectively.
• The monopolist’s cost function is C(Q1 + Q2).
The conditions can be written alternatively as
• The monopolist tries to maximize the joint
profit from the two groups of buyers : MR1(Q1) = MR2(Q2) = MC(Q1 + Q2)
Π = [P1(Q1)] (Q1) + [P2(Q2)](Q2) - C(Q1 + Q2)

4
Third-degree price discrimination Durable Goods Monopolies
• Also, MRi = Pi(1 – 1/ei) • Durable goods do not perish even after
• Then MR1(Q1) = MR2(Q2) => repeated usage.
P1/P2 = (1 – 1/e2)/(1 – 1/e1) • Monopolist is then tempted to charge a
= (e1e2 - e1)/ (e1e2 – e2). lower price in the future – temporal price
discrimination
1. Prices charged to the two groups of
• But buyers should be able to anticipate
buyers are equal if the price elasticities
this and postpone their purchase
are equal.
2. Otherwise, P1 > or < P2 according as
e1 < or > e2.

Durable Goods Monopolies Durable Goods Monopolies


Coase (1972) had conjectured that Solutions:
1. Rent/lease rather than sell. Why might this not
• if the time periods are short enough be feasible?
• and the consumers can rationally 2. Produce less durable goods
anticipate buyer’s actions, 3. Ensure that future production is prohibitively
costly
4. Guarantee to buy back the good in the future
from any consumer at the price they paid for it.
then the price might immediately drop down This is sometimes not possible because
to the level of marginal cost and the consumer usage can change the nature of the
monopolist forfeit all market power. good or lower its value.
5. Acquire a reputation for never lowering its
prices

Bundling Bundling
• Two or more commodities are sold only in • Pure Bundling
fixed proportions. • 100 buyers of each type
• Pure vs. mixed bundling • Zero costs
Pencil Box Sharpener Total
Type 1 24 2 26
Type 2 22 3 25
No bundling Bundling
Total revenue 4400+400 25x200

5
Bundling
• Reservation prices are positively correlated

Pencil Box Sharpener Total


Type 1 24 3 27
Type 2 22 2 24
No bundling Bundling
Total revenue 4400+400 = 24x200

You might also like