Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 0

JOIM

www.joim.com
JOURNAL OF INVESTMENT MANAGEMENT, Vol. 1, No. 2, (2003), pp. 6072
JOIM 2003
THE TREYNOR CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL
CraigW. French
a,
Historygenerallyaccordsthedevelopment of thesingle-period, discrete-timeCapital Asset
PricingModel (CAPM) totheworksof Sharpe(1964), Lintner (1965a,b) andMossin
(1966). Weexploretheearlyworkof another notablenancial economist, JackL. Treynor,
whoalsodeservescredit for theoriginal Capital Asset PricingModel becauseof hisrevolu-
tionarymanuscriptsMarketValue, Time, andRisk, Treynor (1961), andTowarda
Theoryof Market Valueof RiskyAssets, Treynor (1962)whichwerecirculatedduring
the1960sin mimeographeddraft formbut havenever been publishedin an academic
or practitioner journal. Mr. Treynorsearlywork appearstohavepredatedandantici-
patedSharpe(1964), Lintner (1965a,b) andMossin(1966). However, whilenancial
economistsinitiallycreditedMr. Treynor for hisinnovation, theTreynor CAPM hasnot
enjoyedabroadpublicreach. This, apparently, isthereasonMr. Treynor isnotconsistently
recognizedasoneof theprimaryarchitectsof theCAPM.
1 Introduction
In 1981 Fischer Black wrotean open letter to Jack
Treynor, whose13-year tenureastheeditor of the
Financial Analysts Journal was then coming to a
close; in his letter, Dr. Black stated, You devel-
oped thecapital asset pricingmodel beforeanyone
a
Quantitative Analyst, Dubin & Swieca Capital Manage-
ment, LLC, 9 West 57th Street, 27th oor, New York,
NY10019, USA.
Tel.: 212.287.4967; Fax: 212.751.0751; E-mail:
craigf@hcmny.com, crgfrench@aol.com

Theopinionsexpressed herein aresolely thepersonal views


of the author and do not necessarily represent the views or
opinionsof thermor itsprincipals.
else.
1
Thepresent paper investigatesthisassertion
and concludesthat, likeso many of Fischer Blacks
other beliefs, it seemsto beaccurate.
Popular history generally accordstheinitial devel-
opment of theCapital Asset PricingModel (CAPM)
to theworksof Sharpe(1964), Lintner (1965a,b),
and Mossin (1966).
2
After a decade of academic
attempts, the most frequently cited likely being
Black etal. (1972) and Famaand MacBeth (1973),
to substantiateor refutethevalidity of theCAPM
asapositiveeconomicmodel, Roll (1977) demon-
strated that, sincethemarket portfolio specied
by the model is immeasurable, the CAPM can
never beempirically tested conclusively. Neverthe-
less, theCAPM continuestoinspiretheoretical and
SECOND QUARTER 2003 60
THETREYNOR CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL 61
empirical research. As Dr. Black recognized, Jack
Treynor also deservescredit for theoriginal CAPM
becauseof hisrevolutionary manuscripts, Market
Value, Time, and Risk and Toward aTheory of
Market Value of Risky Assets, which were circu-
latedduringthe1960sinmimeographeddraft form
but have never been published in an academic or
practitioner journal.
3
The reference dates cited in the literature usually
refer to Mr. Treynors CAPM asTreynor (1961)
4
and Dr. Sharpes CAPM as Sharpe (1964). How-
ever, it would beamistaketodatetheformer work
withthedateit isgenerallycreditedwithbeingwrit-
ten andthelatter paper withitsdateof publication.
Mr. Treynor andDr. Sharpedevelopedtheir original
modelsindependentlyandalmost concurrently. It is
well knownthat bytheendof 1961, Dr. Sharpehad
extended thenal chapter of thedoctoral disserta-
tion hehad begun in 1960intoapaper that herst
presented in January 1962totheQuadrangleClub
in Chicago. He submitted this paper to the Jour-
nal of Financein 1962, and it wasrejected. Upon
resubmission, it waspublished asSharpe(1964).
In 1958, Jack Treynor wasemployed by Arthur D.
Little. That summer hetook athree-week vacation
toEvergreen, Colorado, duringwhich heproduced
forty-four pages of mathematical notes on capital
asset pricing and capital budgeting. Over thenext
two years, Mr. Treynor rened hisnotesinto what
is in all likelihood the rst CAPM. Mr. Treynor
gave a copy of this early model to John Lintner
at Harvard in 1960. While in business school at
Harvard from 1953 through 1955, Mr. Treynor
had taken nearly every nancecourseoffered, and
though he signed up for Dr. Lintners economics
coursehewasforcedtocancel duetoaschedulecon-
ict. In 1960, Dr. Lintner wastheonly economist
hekneweven slightly.
Mr. Treynor rened his 1960 model into the 45-
page Market Value, Time, and Risk (Treynor,
1961). Treynor (1961) developed theCAPM using
theconcept of experiment spacetoquantifyriskand
risk relations.
5
Without hisknowledgeor encour-
agement, oneof Mr. Treynorscolleaguessent the
draft toMertonMiller in1961, after Dr. Miller had
moved totheUniversity of ChicagofromCarnegie
Instituteof Technology. Dr. Miller sent thepaper
toFrancoModigliani at MIT inthespringof 1962,
and Dr. Modigliani invited Mr. Treynor to embark
on aprogram of graduatework at MIT under his
supervision. Mr. Treynor did so during the1962
1963academicyear; inadditiontoDr. Modiglianis
course, hetook Bob Bishopspricetheory and Ed
Kuhseconometricscourses, amongothers.
By thefall of 1962, Mr. Treynor had consolidated
therst part of Treynor (1961), onthesingle-period
model, into Toward aTheory of Market Valueof
Risky Assets, and presented it to theMIT nance
faculty. Although this famous paper has generally
been cited in theliteratureasTreynor (1961), it
waswrittenasanindependent piecein1962, andwe
refer toit herein asTreynor (1962). Treynor (1962)
usestherst-order conditionsfor exposition, which
providesgreater clarity than theexperiment space
method employed in its parent. By the spring of
1963, Mr. Treynor hadconsolidatedthesecondpart
of Treynor (1961), andpresentedit totheMIT fac-
ulty. Thisthird paper, Implicationsfor theTheory
of Finance, Treynor (1963), appearsto havebeen
the rst development of an intertemporal, multi-
period CAPM. It was later radically rethought
and rewritten by Fischer Black, and appeared as
Treynor and Black (1976). In thesummer of 1963,
Mr. Treynor returnedtoArthur D. Littleandbegan
to work on applicationsof histheory to theprob-
lemof portfolioanalysis.
6
Mr. Treynor subsequently
published more than fty papers in the Harvard
Business Review, Financial Analysts Journal, Jour-
nal of Portfolio Management, Journal of Finance,
Journal of Business and the Journal of Accounting
Research, including Treynor (1965)on measur-
ingselectionandTreynor andMazuy(1966)on
SECOND QUARTER 2003 JOURNAL OF INVESTMENT MANAGEMENT
62 CRAIG W. FRENCH
measuring timingas well as Treynor and Black
(1973)on the appraisal problem referred to in
Treynor (1962).
7
Thusit appearsthat, whilebothmodelsweredevel-
oped nearly simultaneously, the conception and
initial drafting of Mr. Treynors CAPM pre-dated
that of Dr. Sharpes. Treynor (1961, 1962) was
arguably therst CAPM to derivethelinear rela-
tionship between expected return and covariance
with themarket portfolioand alsotoconcludethat
inequilibrium, themarket itself isthesingleoptimal
meanvarianceefcient portfolio.
In spiteof itslack of publication, Treynor (1962)
has received some credit; it is possibly the most
frequently cited unpublished work in thenancial
economicsliterature. Treynor (1962) isoneof the
very fewunpublished paperslisted [entry 5419] in
theauthoritativenancial research bibliography of
Brealey and Edwards(1991).
Several preeminent nancial economists, including
Sharpe(1964), havecited Treynor (1962). Jensen
(1972b) describestwoprimarylinesof inquiryinto
positive applications of the normative Markowitz
portfolio selection framework: (1) Tobins(1958)
work utilizing thefoundationsof portfolio theory
todrawimplicationsregardingthedemandfor cash
balancesand (2) thegeneral equilibriummodelsof
asset pricesderived by Treynor (1961[sic]), Sharpe
(1964), Lintner (1965a,b), Mossin (1966), and
Fama (1968).
8
Jensen (1972b) further describes
empirical testsof theCAPM using evidencefrom
mutual fund returns, and asserts that the rst
ever portfolio evaluation model wasalso aTreynor
modelDr. Jensen lists this line of research in
chronological order, as Treynor (1965), Sharpe
(1966), and Jensen (1968, 1969). It seems that
Dr. Jensen viewed Mr. Treynor as the pioneer
of both the theoretical development and practi-
cal useof theCAPM. Black, Jensen, and Scholes,
in their famous 1972 empirical tests, state in
their introduction that the best known [gen-
eral equilibrium model of the pricing of capital
assets] is the meanvariance formulation origi-
nally developed by Sharpe (1964) and Treynor
(1961[sic]), and extended and claried by Lintner
(1965a,b), Mossin (1966), Fama (1968), and
Long(1972).
9
Fischer Black, in hisother paper
of 1972, states, The rst writers to deal ade-
quatelywithuncertaintyareSharpe(1964), Treynor
(1961[sic]), Lintner (1965[a]), Mossin (1966), and
Fama (1968).
10
Clearly Dr. Black viewed Mr.
Treynor ashavingdeveloped oneof therst capital
asset pricing models; in fact, Black (1981) indi-
catesplainly that hebelieved Mr. Treynor wasthe
rst ever todevelop theCAPM asweunderstand it
today.
Two of themost important worksin nancial eco-
nomics cite Treynor (1962). Black and Scholes
(1973) introduce their elegant options pricing
model (which hasbeen called themost successful
theory not only in nance, but in all of economics
by Professor Ross
11
) by informingusTheinspira-
tion for thiswork wasprovided by Jack L. Treynor
[in hisunpublished memorandums, Implications
for the Theory of Finance and Toward a The-
ory of Market Value of Risky Assets]. Black and
Scholes (1973) provide a derivation of their dif-
ferential equation using the CAPM, which they
attributetoTreynor (1962), Sharpe(1964), Lintner
(1965a) and Mossin (1966). Ross (1976, 1977),
in his magnicent Arbitrage Pricing Theory, also
referencesTreynor (1962).
2 Mr. Treynors development of the CAPM
The published version of Treynor (1962), in
Korajczyk (1999), is nearly identical to the orig-
inal 1962 mimeo. Edits consist primarily of
minor typographical corrections. Note that Mr.
Treynors notation is economical: Double sum-
mations, typically denoted with two summation
JOURNAL OF INVESTMENT MANAGEMENT SECOND QUARTER 2003
THETREYNOR CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL 63
signs, e.g.,

N
i=1

N
j=1
X
i
X
j

ij
, which is the
customary representation of a sum of sums

N
i=1
(

N
j=1
X
i
X
j

ij
), sometimes expressed less
formally as

X
i
X
j

ij
, when the nature of the
summation is clear from context, are denoted
in Treynor (1962) as follows:
12

ij
X
i
X
j

ij
, and
occasionally simply as

X
i
X
j

ij
.
In this section we review the development of
Treynor (1962). Wenotethemathematical equiv-
alence of Treynors risk premium measure a
i
for
capital assets, and that of itslinear relationship in
equilibriumwith thesingleperiod expected return,
to thoseof Sharpe(1964) and Lintner (1965a,b).
Thereinterpretation of Sharpe(1964) provided by
Fama(1968) asserted theequivalenceof thelatter
twomodels, whiletheproofsgiven in Stone(1970)
formally established theequivalenceof theSharpe
Fama, Lintner, and Mossin models. It seemsclear
that themodel of Treynor (1962) isequivalent to
the three later models. Treynor (1962) can cer-
tainly be considered to reside neatly within the
two-parameter functional representation of Stone
(1970), asa special caseof Stonesgeneral model,
alongsideeach of thelater models.
Theintroduction of Treynor (1962) (therst two
paragraphsof p. 15)
13
liststheaimsof thishighly
idealized capital market model as being: (1) to
demonstrate that optimal behavior of the agents
leads to Proposition I of Modigliani and Miller
(1958); (2) to investigate the relation between
risk and investment value; and (3) to distin-
guish between insurableand uninsurablerisk. Mr.
Treynor approached capital asset pricing from the
perspective of corporate cost-of-capital decision-
making. Whilestill in businessschool, Mr. Treynor
resolved to try to understand therelation between
risk and the discount rate [for making long-
term plant investment decisions.]
14
Thisexplains
the focus of Treynor (1962) on Proposition I of
Modigliani and Miller (1958), which assertsthat,
in equilibrium, the market value of any rm is
independent of its capital structure and is given
by capitalizing its expected return at the rate
k
appropriateto itsclass.
15
Treynor (1962), at the bottom of p. 15 and all
of p. 16, discusses the seven primary assump-
tionsof Treynorsmarket model: (1) no taxes; (2)
no market frictions; (3) trading does not affect
prices; (4) agents maximize utility in the sense of
Markowitz; (5) agentsarerisk-averse; (6) aperfect
lendingmarket exists; and (7) agentshaveidentical
knowledge of the market and agree in their fore-
castsof futurevalues. Theseassumptionsarelisted
inTable1of thepresent paper, wheretheyarecom-
paredwiththoseof Sharpe(1964), Lintner (1965a),
and Mossin (1966).
Mossin (1966) notesthat theassumption of identi-
cal perceptionsamongagentsabout theprobability
distributions of the yields of risky assets is not
crucial, andalsothat specication of quadraticutil-
ity functions (through the assumption of agents
focus on the rst two moments of the probabil-
ity distribution, which hedoesinvoke, along with
acceptanceof thevon-NeumannMorgensternutil-
ity axioms) is unnecessary.
16
While Dr. Sharpe
explicitly allowsthecovariancematrix of therisky
assets to be singular, Dr. Lintner and Dr. Mossin
explicitly require it to be positive denite and
therefore non-singularLintner (1965a), p. 21,
and Mossin (1966), p. 771and Treynor (1962)
implicitly requiresnon-singularity.
Treynor (1962) developstheCAPM inthelast para-
graphonp. 16throughp. 20. Theexpositionbegins
bydecomposingexpectedreturn into(1) arisk-free
component and(2) arisk-premiumcomponent. By
denition, Treynorsrisk-freecomponent isequiv-
alent to that of Lintner: Dr. Lintner denes the
risk-freecomponent r

astheinterest rateon risk-


less assets or borrowing (Lintner, 1965a, p. 16),
whileMr. Treynor denestherisk-freecomponent r
SECOND QUARTER 2003 JOURNAL OF INVESTMENT MANAGEMENT
64 CRAIG W. FRENCH
Table 1 Assumptionsof themodels.
Assumption Treynor
(1962)
Sharpe
(1964)
Linter
(1965)
Mossin
(1966)
No taxes Explicit Implicit Explicit Implicit
No frictions(transactionscosts) Explicit Implicit Explicit Implicit
Agentsarepricetakerswho all faceidentical prices Explicit Implicit Explicit Implicit
Agentsmaximizeexpected utility of futurewealth Explicit Explicit Explicit Explicit
Utility represented asafunction of return and risk Explicit Explicit Explicit Explicit
All agents agree that variance (or standard deviation) is the
measureof security risk
Explicit Explicit Explicit Explicit
Agentsprefer morereturn to lessand display risk aversion Explicit Explicit Explicit Explicit
Arisklessasset (payingan exogenouslydeterminedpositiverate
of interest) exists, and all investorsagreethat it isriskless
Explicit Explicit Explicit Explicit
All agentssharethesamesubjectiveprobability distribution of
expected futureprices
Explicit Explicit Explicit Explicit
Fractional sharesmay beheld Implicit Implicit Explicit Explicit
Short salesareallowed Explicitly
allowed
Explicitly
disallowed
Explicitly
allowed
Explicitly
allowed
Leverageisallowed Explicitly
allowed
Explicitly
disallowed
Explicitly
allowed
Implicity
allowed
Thenumber of sharesof each security isconstant Implicit Implicit Implicit Implicit
Agentssharethesamesingleperiod timehorizon Explicit Explicit Implicit Implicit
asthe[perfect] lendingrate, whichisacomponent
of hisone-period discount factor b. SinceTreynor
(1962), p. 17, denesb= 1/(1+r), thisisequiv-
alent to deningr asthegrowth factor. Therefore,
expectedperformanceisgiven byrC [thereturn on
capital at therisk-freerate] plus(1+r)

x
i
a
i
[the
expected return dueexclusively totherisk premia].
Likewise, by denition, Treynorsrisk premium, a
i
,
isequivalent to Lintnersrisk premium x
i
.
17
Treynor (1962) denestheexpected portfolio risk
premium as the present value of the portfolio
risk premium, and he derives the linear relation
between risk and expected return on pp. 18 and
19. Mr. Treynor denesthecovariancematrixusing
Dr. Markowitz formula.
18
Healsodenesportfolio
varianceusingtheMarkowitzformulation.
19
Next, as in Tobin (1958), p. 83, Mr. Treynor
sets out to nd the linear relation: rst, Treynor
denes expected performance in terms of Tobins
non-negativescalar k, and proceedsto minimize
portfoliovariancesubject toexpectedperformance.
HeformstheLagrangianandinvertsthecovariance
matrix, arrivingafter somesubstitution andalgebra
at thereward per risk equality
2
/
2
= 2k/, and
given thedenition of ,
20
demonstratesthat kisa
linear function of . Thisisso becausethereward
per risk ratio
2
/
2
isequivalent to theweighted
sum of sumson thecovariancematrix inverse, the
equality shown as
2
/
2
=

ij
a
j
B
ji
a
i
on p. 19.
Thisisequivalent to Eq. (3.25), thelinear oppor-
tunity locus, on p. 84 of Tobin (1958): Squaring
both sidesof Tobins(3.25),
21
weobtain

2
R
=
2
R

j
r
i
r
j
V
ij
,
which (sinceTobin sets[V
ij
] = [V
ij
]
1
, and there-
fore V
ij
in expression (3.25) is the analogue of
JOURNAL OF INVESTMENT MANAGEMENT SECOND QUARTER 2003
THETREYNOR CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL 65
TreynorsB
ji
, theinverseof thecovariancematrix,
andalsosinceTobinsr
i
correspondstoTreynorsa
i
)
isequivalent to

2
=
2
N

i=1
N

j=1
a
j
B
ji
a
i
.
Sincetheexpression
N

i=1
N

j=1
a
j
B
ji
a
i
isexpressed byTreynor as

ij
a
j
B
ji
a
i
,
and thisisshown tobeequal to
2
/
2
inTreynors
equation, it is clear that Mr. Treynors formula
equalsDr. Tobins(3.25). Likewise, Mr. Treynors
discussion at the bottom of p. 19 is analogous to
that given by Dr. Tobin at the bottom of p. 83
and thetop of p. 84. Mr. Treynorsdevelopment to
thispoint is, therefore, indeed equivalent tothat of
Tobin (1958).
Dr. Lintner, too, presents proofs of Tobins sep-
aration theorem, following Fisher (1930). Dr.
Lintner refers to an environment in which agents
haveidentical probability beliefs, or homogeneous
expectations, as idealized uncertainty, and it is
under these conditions that Dr. Lintner arrives
at the following conclusions: In equilibrium, (1)
thesamecombination of risky assetswill beopti-
mal for every investor, (2) theinvestment amounts
invested in each risky asset will beequivalent tothe
ratio of theaggregatemarket valueof theith risky
asset to thetotal aggregatevalueof all risky assets,
and (3) each investment amount in theindividual
risky assetsmust thereforebeapositiveamount.
22
Mr. Treynor reachestherst conclusion in hisdis-
cussionat thebottomof p. 19(Theholdingsof any
twoinvestorsarethusidentical, uptoafactor of pro-
portionality,) and thelatter twoconclusionsin his
discussion at thetop of p. 21 (ideally theinvestor
will hold sharesin each equity in proportion tothe
total number of sharesinthemarketandthelatter
sharequantitiesarealwayspositive.)
3 Comparison of models
The CAPM was built upon the single-period
discrete-time foundation of Markowitz (1952,
1959) and Tobin (1958). Although Dr. Sharpe
himself did not conclude in Sharpe (1964) that
the market itself is the single optimal portfolio,
Fama (1968) offered an interpretation that did,
andalsoreconciledtheSharpeandLintner models.
Lintner (1965a) reached exactly the same conclu-
sions as Treynor (1961, 1962). Mossin (1966)
claried Sharpe(1964) by providingamoreprecise
specication of theequilibriumconditions.
Eachof themodelsmakesgenerallysimilar assump-
tions. Asummaryof theassumptionsof themodels
isgiven in Table1.
Later work showed that most of the assump-
tions in these early models could be relaxed:
Lintner (1969) incorporatedheterogeneousbeliefs.
Brennan(1970) incorporatedtheeffectsof taxation.
Mayers (1972) allowed for concentrated portfo-
lios through trading restrictions on risky assets,
transactions costs, and information asymmetries.
Black (1972a) utilized the two-funds separation
theorem
23
to construct the zero-beta CAPM, by
using a portfolio that isorthogonal to themarket
portfolio in place of a risk-free asset. Rubinstein
(1973) extended the model to higher moments,
andalsoderivedtheCAPM without arisklessasset.
Ingersoll (1975) andKrausandLitzenberger (1976)
also incorporated thehigher moments.
The models of Treynor (1962), Sharpe (1964),
Lintner (1965a), and Mossin (1966) have much
in common. Table 2 summarizes the models
SECOND QUARTER 2003 JOURNAL OF INVESTMENT MANAGEMENT
66 CRAIG W. FRENCH
Table 2 Characteristicsof themodels.
Model type
Single-
period/multi-
period
Discrete
time/continuoustime
Market/consumption
oriented
Meanvarianceobjective
function
Treynor (1962) Single Discrete Market Yes
a
Sharpe(1964) Single Discrete Market Yes
b
Lintner (1965) Single Discrete Market Yes
b
Mossin (1966) Single Discrete Market Yes
a
Requirements
Requires
market clearing
Requiresnonsingular
covariancematrix
Allowsshort sales Allowsleverage
Treynor (1962) Implicit Implicit Yes Yes
Sharpe(1964) No No No No
Lintner (1965) Implicit Yes Yes Yes
Mossin (1966) Explicit Yes Yes Not addressed
Conclusions
Market itself is
efcient
In equilibrium, the
samecombination of
risky assetswill be
optimal for every
investor
Amount invested in each
risky asset will equal the
ratio of market valueof the
asset to thetotal market
valueof all assets
Amount invested in each
risky asset will beapositive
amount
Treynor (1962) Yes Yes Yes Yes
Sharpe(1964) No No No Yes
Lintner (1965) Yes Yes Yes Yes
Mossin (1966) Yes Yes Yes Yes
Exposition method
Employsrst-order conditions
Treynor (1962) Yes
Sharpe(1964) No
Lintner (1965) Yes
Mossin (1966) Yes
a
Objectivefunction stated in termsof terminal wealth and variance.
b
Objectivefunction stated in termsof percent return and standard deviation.
characteristics. All are single-period, discrete-time
models,
24
and all are market-focused as opposed
to consumption-focused. The most fundamental
similaritiesarethat each rest on thefoundationsof
Markowitz(1952, 1959) andTobin (1958), which
bothbuildupontheutility-of-wealthliteraturethat
assumesthat agentsarerisk-averterswith convex
25
loci of constant expected utility of wealth, repre-
sented asindifferencecurvesin themeanvariance
plane.
Utility-of-wealth notions are based, primarily,
on the works of Friedman and Savage (1948),
Marschak (1950), von Neumann and Morgenstern
JOURNAL OF INVESTMENT MANAGEMENT SECOND QUARTER 2003
THETREYNOR CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL 67
(1953), and Savage (1954). Sharpe (1964) notes
that Hirshleifer (1963) suggests that this model
of investor behavior should be regarded as a
special case of the more general constructs of
Arrow(1953).
26
WhileMarkowitz(1952) did not
addresstheissueof probability beliefs, Markowitz
(1959) did.
27
The critical departure of Mr.
Treynor (and later, of Professors Sharpe, Lint-
ner, and Mossin) from Dr. Tobin, aside from
the purpose of the paper,
28
was the invocation
of two key additional assumptions: The existence
of a perfect lending market, and homogeneous
expectations.
29
It wastheutilization of thesetwoextremely restric-
tive and unrealistic assumptions that allowed Mr.
Treynor toanswer thecompelling, yet unasked and
unanswered, question in Tobin (1958): In equi-
librium, what is the composition of E?
30
Tobin
described investors as considering the universe of
risky assetsasif therewereasinglenon-cash asset,
acompositeformedbycombiningthemultitudeof
actual non-cash assetsin xed proportions.
31
One
of Mr. Treynorsprimaryaccomplishmentsindevel-
opingtheCAPM wastoask thequestion, what are
thosexed proportions?, and answer: ideally,
theinvestor will hold sharesin each equity in pro-
portion to the total number of shares available in
the market.
32
Both Dr. Lintner and Dr. Mossin
also reached such aconclusion.
33
Dr. Famas 1968 discussion of the Sharpe model
agrees exactly with Dr. Sharpes own discussion
only up to the bottom of Fama (1968) p. 32, at
which point Dr. Famabeginsto deviatefrom Dr.
Sharpesdiscussion and to offer hisown clarifying
interpretation:
optimumportfoliosfor all investorswill involvesomecom-
bination of therisklessasset F andtheportfolioof riskyassets
M. Therewill beno incentiveto hold risky assetsnot in M.
If M doesnot contain all therisky assetsin themarket, or if
it doesnot contain themin exactly theproportionsin which
they areoutstanding, then therewill besomeassetsthat no
onewill hold. Thisisinconsistent with equilibrium, sincein
equilibrium all assetsmust beheld. Thus M must bethe
market portfolio; that is, M consistsof all risky assetsin the
market, each weighted by theratio of itstotal market value
to the total market value of all risky assets The market
portfolio M istheonly efcient portfolio of risky assets.
34
Thisisavalid conclusion if werequirethat markets
clear, but it isonethat Dr. Sharpehimself did not
make, whereasMr. Treynor, Dr. Lintner, and Dr.
Mossin did.
WhileTobin (1958) restrictsholdingsof consols,
or risky assets, to longholdingsonly (p. 82, all x
i
are non-negative, where x
i
represents the weight
in theportfolio of theith non-cash asset), Treynor
(1962) doesnot (p. 16explicitlyallowsfor short sell-
ing, thoughinhisequilibriumresult therewouldbe
none, asnoted on p. 21). Sharpe(1964), in con-
trast, explicitly disallowsshort salesin themodel.
35
Weinterpret Dr. Sharpesobservationonp. 437that
acombination [of asset i plusan efcient combi-
nation of assetsg] in which asset i doesnot appear
at all must berepresentedbysomenegativevalueof
not expresslyasallowingtheovert negativehold-
ing of asset i, but rather as a device which allows
us to interpret point g

in such a fashion, with-


out any actual short salehavingoccurredthat is,
sinceg

istheportfolio gexcludingany holdingin


asset i, we can consider g

to be the combination
[]i +(1 [])g. Both Lintner (1965a, p. 19)
and Mossin (1966, p. 776) allowfor short sales.
Tobin (1958) does not cover the case of
borrowingheexplicitly disallowsleverage(p. 82,

x
i
= 1);
36
the portfolio is restricted to lend-
ing only, extending the opportunity locus only
to point E (p. 83, Figure 3.6) where

x
i
=
1, whereas Treynor (1962) extends the efcient
set beyond

x
i
= 1 (p. 16, Another aspect
of the present paper which diverges from the
Tobin paper istheabsenceof positivity constraints.
The individual investor is free to borrow or lend,
to buy longor sell shortas he chooses ).
SECOND QUARTER 2003 JOURNAL OF INVESTMENT MANAGEMENT
68 CRAIG W. FRENCH
WhileSharpe(1964) disallowsleverageviahisnon-
negativity constraint on all assets (including the
risk-freeasset), hediscussesthepossibility (p. 433,
If theinvestor can borrow thisisequivalent to
disinvesting in [the risk-free asset]. The effect of
borrowingcan befoundsimplybyletting [the
proportionof wealthinvestedinP, therisklessasset]
takeon negativevalues). Lintner (1965a) also
allowsfor borrowing(p. 15), whileMossin (1966)
issilent on thisissue.
All of the theorists express optimal portfolios
using the vector of (expected mean) returns and
the covariance/variance matrix; as Dr. Markowitz
examines risky assets only, his E, V efcient set
is therefore nonlinear, whereas Dr. Tobin, Mr.
Treynor, Dr. Sharpe, Dr. Lintner, and Dr. Mossin
employ a riskless asset in order to derive a lin-
ear opportunity locus/efcient set/capital market
line/market opportunity line/market line. In order
toderivetheopportunitylocus, or rayof dominant
sets, Tobin (1958) makesuseof Lagrangemulti-
pliers in order to minimize variance per expected
mean return (p. 83). Dr. Markowitz critical line
algorithm makes use of the same technique in
thecomputation of efcient sets(1959, Appendix
A). Treynor (1962), Lintner (1965a), and Mossin
(1966) all usethesametechnique.
4 Conclusion
Bernstein (1992) quotesFranco Modigliani, refer-
ring to his mentoring of Mr. Treynor, as saying
I madeamistakewith Treynor. Hewastrying to
bite off so big a bullet that I did not give suf-
cient stress to the one part that was right. That
one part was Treynor (1962). Dr. Modigliani
was not the only one to initially miss the power
and eleganceof theCAPM; when Dr. Sharperst
submitted hismanuscript for Sharpe(1964) to the
Journal of Financein 1962, arefereerecommended
to the editor that, due to its extremely restrictive
assumptions (primarily Dr. Sharpes second equi-
librium assumptionthat all investors hold the
sameviewsregarding futureexpected values, stan-
dard deviations, and correlation coefcientsa
restriction that was subsequently dubbed homo-
geneity of investor expectations by one of the
referees
37
), the paper not be published, as it was
uninteresting.
38
Current researchers almost never cite Treynor
(1962). Research citation tends to evolve in
Darwinian fashion. Later researchers have little
incentivetoreferenceapaper that isnot citedbyear-
lier ones. Theearlyimportant worksof Dr. Lintner,
Dr. Mossin, Dr. Fama, and Dr. Merton all ignore
Mr. Treynors early contributions, and later theo-
reticians who refer to and extend these works are
unlikely to citeTreynor (1962), simply becauseof
path dependence.
Theexisting copiesof Treynor (1962) in itsorigi-
nal Rough Draft formarenot publicly available,
though fortunatelycopiesdoexist in privatecollec-
tions. It appears that, because it was unpublished
until recently, Mr. Treynorsearlywork hasnot been
widely distributed, and is therefore cited less fre-
quently. Perhapsthepublication of Treynor (1962)
as chapter 2 of Korajczyk (1999) will mitigate
this issue. It seems that, as Fischer Black stated,
Mr. Treynor developedtherst CAPM, andthat he
should bemorewidely credited with itsinvention.
Acknowledgments
Theauthor wishestothank: Jack andBetsyTreynor,
for clarication of numerous facts, as well as for
generously providing original copies of Treynor
(1961, 1963); William Sharpe, who graciously
sent relevant portions of Sharpe (1961) and pro-
vided important feedback; Mark Rubinstein, for
inspiringthistopicwhen hepresented hisremarks,
TheSurprising History of Financial Economics,
JOURNAL OF INVESTMENT MANAGEMENT SECOND QUARTER 2003
THETREYNOR CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL 69
at theIAFE2002annual meeting, andwhooffered
many useful suggestions for the improvement of
this paper; Eugene Fama, who kindly provided
helpful critical comments; Andrew Lo and Mark
Carhart, who reviewed and circulated early drafts;
ElroyDimson, whoprovidedafacsimileof hisorigi-
nal mimeographof Treynor (1962); PerryMehrling,
Emanuel Derman, Karim-Patrick Khiar, and Kent
Osband, who gavehelpful feedback; Robert Kora-
jczyk, who offered a copy of his wonderful book;
Jonathan Green, Associate Archivist at The Ford
Foundation, for hishelpful research assistance; an
anonymousreferee, for commentsthat resulted in
enhanced clarity; Glenn Dubin, Henry Swieca,
AnnaTaam, Craig Bergstrom, Rusty Holzer, Greg
Martinsen, and Stephanie Carter, for providing a
stimulatingand enjoyablework environment; and,
not least of all, Shirley French, Kiely French, and
Connor French, for givingmeinspiration and joy.
All opinions, errors and omissions herein, are, of
course, my own.
Notes
1
Black (1981), p. 14.
2
SeeSharpeandAlexander (1978), p. 194; Merton (1990),
p. 475; Bodieet al. (1993), p. 242; Reilly (1994), p. 270;
and Cochrane(2001), p. 152.
3
Pleaserefer to thenal version of Treynor (1962), which
waspublished aschapter 2 of Korajczyk (1999). All page
and paragraph referencesherein regardingTreynor (1962)
specify those in the Korajczyk (1999) version. Treynor
(1961) remainsunpublished.
4
Although Mr. Treynors 1962 paper, Toward aTheory
of Market Value of Risky Assets is correctly referred to
asTreynor (1962) in Korajczyk (1999); it isalso occa-
sionally referred to asTreynor (1963), e.g., Harrington
and Korajczyk (1993), p. 123. Some references append
an s to the Toward, e.g., Luenberger (1998), while
most donot; however, thepublished version in Korajczyk
(1999) includes the s in its title. The authors copy of
the 1962 mimeograph does not. We have yet to nd
a reference to Market Value, Time, and Risk in the
literature.
5
In experiment space, thereisonedimension, or axis, for
each experiment. For example, thecorrelation coefcient
of two timeseriesisthecosineof theanglebetween two
vectors, andstatisticallyindependent randomvariablesare
orthogonal in experiment space.
6
This paragraph relies on personal correspondence with
Jack Treynor, and parallels the discussion in Bernstein
(1992), pp. 183202. Notethat Bernstein (1992) reports
theyear of Mr. Treynorsvacation as1959, but thecorrect
year is1958.
7
Refer to Korajczyk (1999), p. 20.
8
Jensen (1972b), p. 4.
9
Black et al. (1972), p. 79.
10
Black (1972b), p. 249.
11
Ross(1987), p. 24.
12
Mr. Treynor wasnot alonein employingthisconvention;
Dr. Lintner also used thisnotationseeLintner (1965a),
p. 20, Eqs. (6b) and(8). Pleasenotethat all notationinthe
present paper isasdened in theoriginal models; wedo
not introduceanynewnotation, nor doweredeneanyof
theoriginal conventions. Thereadersunderstandingwill
beenhanced by direct referenceto theoriginal papersin
thisdiscussion.
13
Pageandparagraphlocationsrefer tothepublishedversion
of Treynor (1962) in Korajczyk (1999).
14
Personal communication of Mr. Treynor to theauthor.
15
Modigliani and Miller (1958), p. 268, formula(3): V
j

(S
j
+D
j
) = X
j
/
k
.
16
Another interesting aspect of Mossin (1966) is that
Mossins discussion of structural diversication indiffer-
ence on pages 779781 is the rst formal proof of the
homemadediversication argument. Thiswasnoted in
Rubinstein (1973).
17
Lintner notes, Positive(negative) riskpremiumsareneither
asufcientnoranecessaryconditionforastocktobeheldlong
(short) [original emphasis.] Lintner (1965a, p. 23).
18
Markowitz (1952), p. 80:
ij
= E{[R
i
E(R
i
)][R
j

E(R
j
)]}.
19
Markowitz(1952), p. 81: V(R) =

ij
.
20
TheLagrangemultiplier isthemarginal utilityof wealth,
given constant prices.
21
Tobin (1958), p. 84:
R
=
R

i

j
r
i
r
j
V
ij

1/2
.
22
Lintner (1965a), p. 25.
23
Markowitz (2000) distinguishes between the Tobin sep-
aration theorem and the two-funds separation theorem:
First, Tobin (1958) showed that the choice of propor-
tions among risky assets is a separate decision from the
choiceof leverageevery efcient portfolioisof theform
x= x

+(1)x
c
, wherex
c
istherisk-freeasset, x

isa
SECOND QUARTER 2003 JOURNAL OF INVESTMENT MANAGEMENT
70 CRAIG W. FRENCH
portfolioof riskyassetsand isanon-negativescalar. This
result is known as theTobin separation theorem. Later,
Sharpe(1970) andMerton (1972) showedthat if theonly
constraint is

x
i
= 1, theneveryefcient portfolioisthe
combination x= x

+(1)xwith 0, wherexis
theminimum-varianceefcient portfolio, withor without
the existence of a risk-free asset. This result is the two-
fundsseparationtheorem[Markowitz(2000), pp. 3839].
Merton (1990) providesthegeneralized three-fund sep-
arationtheorem, which assertsindifferenceamong agents
between portfolios selected from the original n assets or
portfolioscomposed of (1) themarket portfolio, (2) the
risklessasset, and(3) aportfoliothat isinstantaneouslyper-
fectly correlated with changesin theinterest rate[Merton
(1990), pp. 382386 and 490492.]
24
Treynor (1961, 1963) also address multi-period and
continuous-timeenvironments.
25
Although Tobin terms this concave upwards, we refer
here to the currently accepted denition of concav-
ity/convexity of functionsin Euclidean space.
26
Sharpe(1964), p. 427, footnote6.
27
See, in particular, Markowitz (1952), p. 81, footnote7:
Thispaper doesnot consider thedifcult questionof how
investors do (or should) form their probability beliefs,
and Markowitz (1959), chapter 10, which outlinesthree
axiomsof rational behavior, aswell aschapter 13, which
addresses what Markowitz calls the second chief limi-
tation of Markowitz (1952), the assumption of static
probability beliefs.
28
Tobin sought to explain the demand for cash and its
inverse relationship with the differential in the yields of
default-free xed income instruments, thus maintaining
the implications of the liquidity preference component
of Keynes theory of underemployment equilibrium. The
risk aversion theory of liquidity preference in Tobin
(1958) wasdeveloped to avoid theobjectionableproper-
tiesof Keynes (1936) assumption of stickinessin interest
rate expectations, which had been criticized in Fellner
(1946) and Leontief (1947). Therisk in Tobinsconsols
isuncertainty about futureinterest ratesonly. In contrast,
Mr. Treynor and subsequent nancial economistssought
to develop a general equilibrium model of capital asset
pricebehavior, andwereprimarilyconcernedwiththerisk
of equity price uctuations; in doing so, they implicitly
assumed away theonly risk Tobin considered (seeTreynor
(1962), p. 16).
29
See Treynor (1962), p. 15, assumptions 6 and 7;
also see Sharpe (1964), p. 433, two assumptions for
equilibrium. Mr. Treynors terms for these assumptions
are a perfect lending market and perfect [investor]
knowledge; Sharpes terms are a common pure rate of
interest and homogeneity of investor expectations.
30
HereE isthepoint where

x
i
= 1ontherayof dominant
sets, illustrated in Tobin (1958), p. 83, Figure3.6.
31
Tobin (1958), p. 84. Thiscompositeisrepresentedgraph-
ically in Tobin by E (p. 83, Figure3.6), in Sharpeby
(p. 432, Figure4), andinLintner byM (p. 19, Figure1); it
isnot graphicallyillustratedeither inTreynor or inMossin.
32
Treynor (1962), p. 21.
33
Lintner (1965a), p. 25, andMossin (1966), pp. 775776.
34
Fama (1968), pp. 3233. Fama emphasizes, in footnote
11 on p. 33, that Sharpesversion of equilibriumdoesnot
imply that the market portfolio M is the only efcient
portfolio of risky assets.
35
Sharpe(1964), p. 433, footnote15: Thediscussioninthis
paper isbasedonMarkowitz formulation, whichincludes
non-negativity constraints on the holdings of all assets.
Markowitz assumptionsof no short sales(X
j
0 for all
j) and no leverage(

X
j
= 1) can befound on p. 171 of
Markowitz(1959).
36
However, Sharpe(1964) interpretsotherwise; seep. 433,
footnote 15 for Sharpes relaxation of the no-leverage
restriction of Tobin (1958).
37
Sharpe(1964), p. 433, footnote16.
38
Bernstein (1992), pp. 194195.
References
Arrow, K. J. (1953). LeRledesValuersBoursirespour la
Rpartition laMeilleuredesRisques. conometrie, Collo-
ques Internationaux du Centre National de la Recherche
Scientique, vol. 11, Paris, pp. 4147.
Bernstein, P. L. (1992). Capital Ideas: TheImprobableOrigins
of ModernWall Street. NewYork: TheFreePress.
Black, F. (1972a). Capital Market Equilibrium with
Restricted Borrowing. TheJournal of Business45(3), 444
455.
Black, F. (1972b). Equilibrium in the Creation of Invest-
ment GoodsUnder Uncertainty. In StudiesintheTheory
of Capital Markets. Michael C. Jensen (editor) New York:
Praeger, pp. 249265.
Black, F. (1981). AnOpenLetter toJackTreynor. TheFinan-
cial AnalystsJournal July/August. LetterstotheEditor, p. 14.
Black, F., Jensen, M. C. andScholes, M. (1972). TheCapital
Asset Pricing Model: SomeEmpirical Tests. In Studiesin
theTheoryof Capital Markets. Michael C. Jensen (editor)
NewYork: Praeger, pp. 79121.
JOURNAL OF INVESTMENT MANAGEMENT SECOND QUARTER 2003
THETREYNOR CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL 71
Black, F. and Scholes, M. (1973). The Pricing of Options
and CorporateLiabilities. TheJournal of Political Economy
81(3), 637659.
Bodie, Z., Kane, A. and Marcus, A. J. (1993). Investments.
2nd edn. Burr Ridge: Irwin. (special edition for CFA
candidates).
Brealey, R. A. and Edwards, H. (1991). A Bibliographyof
Finance. Cambridge: MIT Press.
Brennan, M. J. (1970). Taxes, Market Valuation, and Cor-
porateFinancial Policy. National TaxJournal 4, 417427.
Cochrane, J. H. (2001). Asset Pricing, Princeton: Princeton
University Press.
Fama, E. F. (1968). Risk, Return, and Equilibrium: Some
Clarifying Comments. The Journal of Finance 23(1),
2940.
Fama, E. F. and MacBeth, J. (1973). Risk, Return and Equi-
librium: Empirical Tests. TheJournal of Political Economy
81(3), 607636.
Fellner, W. J. (1946). MonetaryPoliciesandFull Employment.
Berkeley: University of CaliforniaPress.
Fisher, I. (1930). TheTheoryofInterest. NewYork: MacMillan.
Friedman, M. and Savage, L. J. (1948). TheUtility Analysis
of ChoicesInvolvingRisk. TheJournal ofPolitical Economy
56(4), 279304.
Harrington, D. R. and Korajczyk, R. A. (editors) (1993).
The CAPM Controversy: Policy and Strategy Implications
for Investment Management. Charlottesville: Association for
Investment Management and Research; ICFA Continuing
Education.
Hirshleifer, J. (1963). Investment Decision Under Uncer-
tainty, PapersandProceedingsof theSeventy-SixthAnnual
Meeting of the American Economic Association, Decem-
ber. Subsequently extended and published as Invest-
ment Decision Under Uncertainty: Choice-Theoretic
Approaches. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 79(5),
509536. Also, see Investment Decision Under Uncer-
tainty: Applications of the State-Preference Approach.
The Quarterly Journal of Economics 80(2), 252
277.
Ingersoll, J. E., Jr. (1975). Multidimensional Security Pric-
ing. TheJournal of Financial andQuantitativeAnalysis10,
785798.
Jensen, M. C. (1968). The Performance of Mutual Funds
in the Period 194564. The Journal of Finance 23(2),
389416.
Jensen, M. C. (1969). Risk, the Pricing of Capital Assets,
and theEvaluation of Investment Portfolios. TheJournal
of Business42(2), 167247.
Jensen, M. C. (editor) (1972a). StudiesintheTheoryofCapital
Markets. NewYork: Praeger.
Jensen, M. C. (1972b). TheFoundationsand Current State
of Capital Market Theory. InStudiesintheTheoryofCapital
Markets. Michael C. Jensen (editor) New York: Praeger,
pp. 343.
Keynes, J. M. (1936). TheGeneral Theory of Employment,
Interest, andMoney. NewYork: Harcourt Brace.
Korajczyk, R. A. (1999). Asset Pricingand PortfolioPerfor-
mance: Models, StrategyandPerformanceMetrics. London:
Risk Books.
Kraus, A. and Litzenberger, R. H. (1976). Skewness Pref-
erence and the Valuation of Risk Assets. TheJournal of
Finance31, 10851100.
Leontief, W. (1947). Postulates: Keynes General Theoryand
theClassicists. In TheNewEconomics: Keynes Inuenceon
Theoryand PublicPolicy, chapter 19. Seymour E. Harris
(editor) NewYork: Knopf, pp. 232242.
Lintner, J. (1965a). The Valuation of Risk Assets and the
Selection of Risky Investments in Stock Portfolios and
Capital Budgets. TheReviewof EconomicsandStatistics47,
1337.
Lintner, J. (1965b). Securities Prices, Risk, and Maximal
Gainsfrom Diversication. TheJournal of Finance20(4),
587615.
Lintner, J. (1969). The Aggregation of Investors Diverse
Judgement andPreferencesinPurelyCompetitiveSecurities
Markets. TheJournal ofFinancial andQuantitativeAnalysis
4, 347400.
Lintner, J. (1972). FinanceandCapital Markets. New York:
National Bureau of Economic Research.
Long, J. B. Jr. (1972). Consumption-Investment Decisions
andEquilibriumintheSecuritiesMarkets. InStudiesinthe
Theoryof Capital Markets. Michael C. Jensen (editor) New
York: Praeger, pp. 146222.
Luenberger, D. G. (1998). InvestmentScience. Oxford: Oxford
University Press.
Markowitz, H. M. (1952). Portfolio Selection. TheJournal
of Finance7(1), 7791.
Markowitz, H. M. (1959). PortfolioSelection: Efcient Diver-
sication of Investments, Cowles Foundation for Research
in Economics at Yale University, Monograph #6. New
York: John Wiley & Sons, Inc. (Second edition, 1991,
Cambridge: Basil Blackwell, Inc.).
Markowitz, H. M. (2000). MeanVarianceAnalysisinPortfolio
ChoiceandCapital Markets. New Hope: Frank J. Fabozzi
Associates.
Marschak, J. (1950). Rational Behavior, Uncertain
Prospects, and Measurable Utility. Econometrica 18(2),
111141.
Mayers, D. (1972). NonmarketableAssetsandCapital Mar-
ket EquilibriumUnder Uncertainty. InStudiesintheTheory
SECOND QUARTER 2003 JOURNAL OF INVESTMENT MANAGEMENT
72 CRAIG W. FRENCH
of Capital Markets. Michael C. Jensen (editor) New York:
Praeger, pp. 223248.
Merton, R. C. (1972). An Analytic Derivation of theEf-
cient Portfolio Frontier. The Journal of Financial and
QuantitativeAnalysis7, 18511872.
Merton, R. C. (1990). Continuous-TimeFinance. Cambridge:
Blackwell (revised paperback edition, 1999 reprint).
Modigliani, F. and Miller, M. H. (1958). TheCost of Cap-
ital, Corporation Finance, and theTheory of Investment.
TheAmericanEconomicReview48, 261297.
Mossin, J. (1966). Equilibrium in aCapital Asset Market.
Econometrica34(4), 768783.
Mossin, J. (1973). Theoryof Financial Markets. Englewood
Cliffs: Prentice-Hall.
Mossin, J. (1977). The Economic Efciency of Financial
Markets. Lanham: Lexington.
Reilly, F. K. (1994). InvestmentAnalysisandPortfolioManage-
ment, 4th edn. Fort Worth: Dryden.
Roll, R. (1977). ACritiqueof theAsset PricingTheorysTests
Part I: On Past andPotential Testabilityof theTheory. The
Journal of Financial Economics4(2), 129-176.
Ross, S. A. (1976). The Arbitrage Theory of Capital
Asset Pricing. The Journal of Economic Theory 13(3),
341360.
Ross, S. A. (1977). Return, Risk and Arbitrage. In Riskand
ReturninFinance, Section 9. Irwin Friend and J. Bicksler
(editors) Cambridge: Ballinger, pp. 189219.
Ross, S. A. (1987). Finance. In TheNewPalgraveFinance.
John Eatwell, Murray Milgateand Peter Newman (editors)
NewYork: W.W. Norton, pp. 134.
Rubinstein, M. (1973). The Fundamental Theorem of
Parameter-Preference Security Valuation. TheJournal of
Financial andQuantitativeAnalysis8, 6169.
Savage, L. J. (1954). TheFoundationsof Statistics. NewYork:
John Wiley & Sons.
Sharpe, W. F. (1961). Portfolio Analysis Based on a Sim-
plied Model of the Relationships Among Securities.
Unpublished doctoral dissertation. LosAngeles: University
of Californiaat LosAngeles.
Sharpe, W. F. (1963). A Simplied Model for Portfolio
Analysis. Management Science9(2), 277293.
Sharpe, W. F. (1964). Capital Asset Prices: A Theory
of Market Equilibrium Under Conditions of Risk. The
Journal of Finance19(3), 425442.
Sharpe, W. F. (1966). Mutual Fund Performance. The
Journal of Business39, 119138.
Sharpe, W. F. (1970). PortfolioTheoryandCapital Markets.
NewYork: McGraw-Hill.
Sharpe, W. F. (1990). Autobiography. In Les Prix
Nobel 1990. Tore Frngsmyr (editor) Stockholm: Nobel
Foundation.
Sharpe, W. F. and Alexander, G. J. (1978). Investments, 4th
edn. (1990). Englewood Cliffs: Prentice-Hall.
Stone, B. K. (1970). Risk, Return, andEquilibrium; AGeneral
Single-PeriodTheoryof Asset Selection and Capital-Market
Equilibrium. Cambridge: MIT Press.
Tobin, J. (1958). Liquidity PreferenceasBehavior Towards
Risk. TheReviewof EconomicStudies, No. 67, February,
6586. Reprinted asCowlesFoundation Paper 118.
Treynor, J. L. (1961). Market Value, Time, and Risk.
Unpublished manuscript. Rough Draft dated 8/8/61,
#95209.
Treynor, J. L. (1962). Toward a Theory of Market Value
of Risky Assets. Unpublished manuscript. Rough Draft
dated by Mr. Treynor to the fall of 1962. A nal ver-
sion was published in 1999, in Asset PricingandPortfolio
Performance. Robert A. Korajczyk (editor) London: Risk
Books, pp. 1522.
Treynor, J. L. (1963). Implications for the Theory of
Finance. Unpublished manuscript. Rough Draft dated
by Mr. Treynor to thespringof 1963.
Treynor, J. L. (1965). How to RateManagement of Invest-
ment Funds. HarvardBusinessReview43, 6375.
Treynor, J. L. and Mazuy, K. (1966). Can Mutual Funds
OutguesstheMarket? HarvardBusinessReview44, 131
136.
Treynor, J. L. andBlack, F. (1973). HowtoUseSecurityAnal-
ysisto ImprovePortfolio Selection. TheJournal of Business
46(1), 6688.
Treynor, J. L. and Black, F. (1976). Corporate Investment
Decisions. In ModernDevelopmentsinFinancial Manage-
ment. Stewart C. Myers (editor) Hinsdale: The Dryden
Press, pp. 310327.
von Neumann, J. L. and Morgenstern, O. (1953). The-
oryof GamesandEconomicBehavior, 3rd edn. Princeton:
Princeton University Press.
JOURNAL OF INVESTMENT MANAGEMENT SECOND QUARTER 2003

You might also like