MLV2 Toy

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 87

Credit Risk, II.

T.R. Bielecki, M. Jeanblanc and M. Rutkowski


MLV, November 2006 2006
1
II. Hazard Process Approach: A Toy Model
1. The Model
2. Toy Model and Martingales
3. Valuation and Trading Defaultable Claims
2
The Model
3
The Market
We begin with the case where a riskless asset, with deterministic
interest rate (r(s); s 0) is the only asset available in the default-free
market.
R(t) = exp
_

_
t
0
r(s)ds
_
4
The Market
We begin with the case where a riskless asset, with deterministic
interest rate (r(s); s 0) is the only asset available in the default-free
market.
R(t) = exp
_

_
t
0
r(s)ds
_
The time-t price B(t, T) of a risk-free zero-coupon bond with maturity
T is
B(t, T)
def
= exp
_

_
T
t
r(s)ds
_
.
5
Default occurs at time , where is assumed to be a positive random
variable with density f, constructed on a probability space (, G, P).
F(t) = P( t) =
_
t
0
f(s)ds .
We assume that F(t) < 1, t
6
Defaultable Zero-coupon with Payment at Maturity
A defaultable zero-coupon bond (DZC in short)- or a corporate
bond- with maturity T and rebate paid at maturity, consists of
The payment of one monetary unit at time T if default has not
occurred before time T,
A payment of monetary units, made at maturity, if < T, where
0 < 1.
7
Value of the defaultable zero-coupon bond
The value of the defaultable zero-coupon bond is dened as
D
(,T)
(0, T) = E
_
B(0, T) (11
{T<}
+11
{T}
)
_
= B(0, T) (1 (1 )F(T)) .
8
Value of the defaultable zero-coupon bond
The value of the defaultable zero-coupon bond is dened as
D
(,T)
(0, T) = E
_
B(0, T) (11
{T<}
+11
{T}
)
_
= B(0, T) (1 (1 )F(T)) .
The value D
(,T)
(t, T) of the DZC is the conditional expectation of the
discounted payo B(t, T) [11
{T<}
+11
{T}
] given the information:
D
(,T)
(t, T) = 11
{t}
B(t, T) + 11
{t<}

D
(,T)
(t, T)
9
Value of the defaultable zero-coupon bond
The value of the defaultable zero-coupon bond is dened as
D
(,T)
(0, T) = E
_
B(0, T) (11
{T<}
+11
{T}
)
_
= B(0, T) (1 (1 )F(T)) .
The value D
(,T)
(t, T) of the DZC is the conditional expectation of the
discounted payo B(t, T) [11
{T<}
+11
{T}
] given the information:
D
(,T)
(t, T) = 11
{t}
B(t, T) + 11
{t<}

D
(,T)
(t, T)
where the predefault value

D
(,T)
(t, T) is dened as

D
(,T)
(t, T) = E
_
B(t, T) (11
{T<}
+11
{T}
)

t <
_
10

D
(,T)
(t, T) = E
_
B(t, T) (11
{T<}
+11
{T}
)

t <
_
11

D
(,T)
(t, T) = E
_
B(t, T) (11
{T<}
+11
{T}
)

t <
_
= B(t, T)
_
1 (1 )P( T

t < )
_
12

D
(,T)
(t, T) = E
_
B(t, T) (11
{T<}
+11
{T}
)

t <
_
= B(t, T)
_
1 (1 )P( T

t < )
_
= B(t, T)
_
1 (1 )
P(t < T)
P(t < )
_
13

D
()
(t, T) = E
_
B(t, T) (11
{T<}
+11
{T}
)

t <
_
= B(t, T)
_
1 (1 )P( T

t < )
_
= B(t, T)
_
1 (1 )
P(t < T)
P(t < )
_
= B(t, T)
_
1 (1 )
F(T) F(t)
1 F(t)
_
14
The formula

D
(,T)
(t, T) = B(t, T) B(t, T)(1 )
P(t < T)
P(t < )
can be read as

D
(,T)
(t, T) = B(t, T) EDLGD DP
15
The formula

D
(,T)
(t, T) = B(t, T) B(t, T)(1 )
P(t < T)
P(t < )
can be read as

D
(,T)
(t, T) = B(t, T) EDLGD DP
where the Expected Discounted Loss Given Default (EDLGD) is
dened as B(t, T)(1 ) and the Default Probability (DP) is
DP =
P(t < T)
P(t < )
= P( T|t < ) .
16
In case the payment is a function of the default time, say (), the
value of this defaultable zero-coupon is
D
(,T)
(0, T) = E
_
B(0, T) 11
{T<}
+B(0, T)()11
{T}
_
= B(0, T)
_
P(T < ) +
_
T
0
(s)f(s)ds
_
.
17
In case the payment is a function of the default time, say (), the
value of this defaultable zero-coupon is
D
(,T)
(0, T) = E
_
B(0, T) 11
{T<}
+B(0, T)()11
{T}
_
= B(0, T)
_
P(T < ) +
_
T
0
(s)f(s)ds
_
.
The predefault price

D
(,T)
(t, T) is

D
(,T)
(t, T) = B(t, T)E( 11
{T<}
+()11
{T}

t < )
= B(t, T)
_
P(T < )
P(t < )
+
1
P(t < )
_
T
t
(s)f(s)ds
_
.
18
We introduce the increasing hazard function dened by
(t) = ln(1 F(t))
and its derivative (t) =
f(t)
1 F(t)
where f(t) = F

(t), i.e.,
1 F(t) = e
(t)
= exp
_

_
t
0
(s)ds
_
= P( > t) .
19
We introduce the increasing hazard function dened by
(t) = ln(1 F(t))
and its derivative (t) =
f(t)
1 F(t)
where f(t) = F

(t), i.e.,
1 F(t) = e
(t)
= exp
_

_
t
0
(s)ds
_
= P( > t) .
The quantity (t) called the hazard rate is the probability that the
default occurs in a small interval dt given that the default has not
occured before time t
(t) = lim
h0
1
h
P( t +h| > t) .
20
For = 0,

D(t, T) = exp
_

_
T
t
(r +)(s)ds
_
in other terms, the spot rate has to be adjusted by means of a spread
() in order to evaluate DZCs.
21
Defaultable Zero-coupon with Payment at Hit
Here, a defaultable zero-coupon bond with maturity T consists of
The payment of one monetary unit at time T if default has not yet
occurred,
A payment of () monetary units, where is a deterministic
function, made at time if < T.
Here, we do not assume that F is dierentiable.
22
Value of the defaultable zero-coupon
The value of this defaultable zero-coupon bond is
D
()
(0, T) = E(B(0, T) 11
{T<}
+B(0, )()11
{T}
)
= G(T)B(0, T)
_
T
0
B(0, s)(s)dG(s) ,
where G(t) = 1 F(t) = P(t < ) is the survival probability.
23
For t < T,
D
()
(t, T) = 11
t<

D
()
(t, T)
where

D
()
(t, T) is called the predefault price dened by
B(0, t)

D
()
(t, T) = E(B(0, T) 11
{T<}
+B(0, )()11
{T}
|t < )
=
P(T < )
P(t < )
B(0, T) +
1
P(t < )
_
T
t
B(0, s)(s)dF(s) .
Hence,
B(0, t)G(t)

D
()
(t, T) = G(T)B(0, T)
_
T
t
B(0, s)(s)dG(s) .
24
In terms of the hazard function, the time-t value

D
()
(t, T) satises:
B(0, t)e
(t)

D
()
(t, T) = e
(T)
B(0, T) +
_
T
t
B(0, s)e
(s)
(s)d(s) .
25
A particular case If F is dierentiable, the function =

satises
f(t) = (t)e
(t)
. Then,
R
d
(t)

D
()
(t, T) = R
d
(T) +
_
T
t
R
d
(s)(s)(s)ds
with
R
d
(t) = exp
_

_
t
0
(r(s) +(s)) ds
_
The defaultable interest rate is r + and is, as expected, greater than r
(the value of a DZC with = 0 is smaller than the value of a
default-free zero-coupon).
26
The dynamics of

D
()
(t, T) are
d

D
()
(t, T) = (r(t) +(t))

D
()
(t, T)dt (t)(t)dt .
The dynamics of D
()
includes a jump at time .
27
Spreads
A term structure of credit spreads associated with the zero-coupon
bonds S(t, T) is dened as
S(t, T) =
1
T t
ln
D(t, T)
B(t, T)
.
In our setting, on the set { > t}
S(t, T) =
1
T t
ln Q

( > T| > t) ,
whereas S(t, T) = on the set { t}.
28
Toy Model and Martingales
We denote by (H
t
, t 0) the right-continuous increasing process
H
t
= 11
{t}
and by (H
t
) its natural ltration. Any integrable
H
t
-measurable r.v. H is of the form
H = h( t) = h()11
{t}
+h(t)11
{t<}
where h is a Borel function.
29
Key Lemma
If X is any integrable, G-measurable r.v.
E(X|H
t
)11
{t<}
= 11
{t<}
E(X11
{t<}
)
P(t < )
.
30
Key Lemma
If X is any integrable, G-measurable r.v.
E(X|H
t
)11
{t<}
= 11
{t<}
E(X11
{t<}
)
P(t < )
.
Let Y = h() be a H-measurable random variable. Then
E(Y |H
t
) = 11
{t}
h() + 11
{t<}
_

t
h(u)e
(t)(u)
d(u)
31
An important Martingale
The process (M
t
, t 0) dened as
M
t
= H
t

_
t
0
dF(s)
1 F(s)
= H
t

_
t
0
(1 H
s
)
dF(s)
1 F(s)
is a H-martingale.
32
Hazard Function
The hazard function is
(t) = ln(1 F(t)) =
_
t
0
dF(s)
1 F(s)
In particular, if F is dierentiable, the process
M
t
= H
t

_
t
0
(s)ds = H
t

_
t
0
(s)(1 H
s
)ds
is a martingale, where (s) =
f(s)
1 F(s)
is a deterministic non-negative
function, called the intensity of .
33
The Doob-Meyer decomposition of the submartingale H
t
is
H
t
= M
t
+ (t )
The predictable process A
t
=
t
is called the compensator of H.
34
The process
L
t
def
= 11
{>t}
exp
_
_
t
0
(s)ds
_
is a H-martingale.
35
Proof: We shall give 3 dierent arguments, each of which constitutes a
proof.
a) Since the function is deterministic, for t > s
E(L
t
|H
s
) = exp
_
_
t
0
(u)du
_
E(11
{t<}
|H
s
) .
From the Key Lemma
E(11
{t<}
|H
s
) = 11
{>s}
1 F(t)
1 F(s)
= 11
{>s}
exp ((t) + (s)) .
Hence,
E(L
t
|H
s
) = 11
{>s}
exp
_
_
s
0
(u)du
_
= L
s
.
36
b) Another method is to apply integration by parts formula to the
process L
t
= (1 H
t
) exp
_
_
t
0
(s)ds
_
If U and V are two nite
variation processes, Stieltjes integration by parts formula can be
written as follows
U(t)V (t) = U(0)V (0) +
_
]0,t]
V (s)dU(s) +
_
]0,t]
U(s)dV (s)
+

st
U(s) V (s) .
dL
t
= dH
t
exp
_
_
t
0
(s)ds
_
+(t) exp
_
_
t
0
(s)ds
_
(1 H
t
)dt
= exp
_
_
t
0
(s)ds
_
dM
t
.
37
c) A third (sophisticated) method is to note that L is the exponential
martingale of M, i.e., the solution of the SDE
dL
t
= L
t
dM
t
, L
0
= 1.

38
In the case where N is an inhomogeneous Poisson process with
deterministic intensity and is the rst time when N jumps, let
H
t
= N
t
. It is well known that N
t

_
t
0
(s)ds is a martingale (see
Appendix). Therefore, the process stopped at time is also a
martingale, i.e., H
t

_
t
0
(s)ds is a martingale.
39
Change of probability
Let P

be a probability equivalent to P on the space (, H) where


H = H

is the -algebra generated by . Then,


dP

= h() dP
where h is a strictly positive fonction, such that E
P
(h()) = 1. Let
g(t) = e
(t)
E
P
(11
t<
h()) .
If is continuous,

is continuous and
d

(t) =
h(t)
g(t)
d(t)
40
Proof:
P

( t) = E
P
(11
t<
h()) =
_

t
h(u)dF(u) = e

(t)
Hence
e

(t)
d

(t) = h(t)dF(t) = h(t)e


(t)
d(t)
Therefore
E
P
(11
t<
h())d

(t) = h(t)e
(t)
d(t)
It follows that
d

(t) =
h(t)
e
(t)
E
P
(11
t<
h())
d(t) =
h(t)
g(t)
d(t)
41
Exercices: Let
t
= E
P
(h()|H
t
). Prove that

t
=
_
t
0
h(s)dH
s
+ (1 H
t
)g(t)
Prove that the martingale admits a representation in terms of M as

t
= 1 +
_
t
0
(h(u)
u
)dM
u
and that an explicit representation is

t
= (1 + 11
t
k()) exp
_

_
t
0
k(u)d(u)
_
where k(t) =
h(t)
g(t)
1
42
Incompleteness of the Toy model
If the market consists only of the risk-free zero-coupon bond, there
exists innitely many e.m.ms. The discounted asset prices are
constant, hence the set Q of equivalent martingale measures is the set
of probabilities equivalent to the historical one. For any Q Q, we
denote by F
Q
the cumulative function of under Q, i.e.,
F
Q
(t) = Q( t) .
43
The range of prices is dened as the set of prices which do not induce
arbitrage opportunities. For a DZC with a constant rebate paid at
maturity, the range of prices is equal to the set
{E
Q
(B(0, T)(11
{T<}
+11
{<T}
)), Q Q} .
This set is exactly the interval ]R
T
, R
T
[.
44
Risk Neutral Probability Measures
It is usual to interpret the absence of arbitrage opportunities as the
existence of an e.m.m. . If DZCs are traded, their prices are given by
the market, and the equivalent martingale measure Q, chosen by the
market, is such that, on the set {t < },
D(t, T) = B(t, T)E
Q
_
[11
T<
+11
t<T
]

t <
_
.
Therefore, we can characterize the cumulative function of under Q
from the market prices of the DZC as follows.
45
Zero Recovery If a DZC with zero recovery of maturity T is traded at
a price D(t, T) which belongs to the interval ]0, R
t
T
[ , then, under any
risk-neutral probability Q, the process R(t)D(t, T) is a martingale, the
following equality holds
D(t, T)B(0, t) = E
Q
(B(0, T)11
{T<}
|H
t
) = B(0, T)11
{t<}
exp
_

_
T
t

Q
(s)ds
_
where
Q
(s) =
dF
Q
(s)/ds
1 F
Q
(s)
. The process
Q
is the Q-intensity of .
Therefore the unique risk-neutral intensity can be obtained from the
prices of DZCs as
r(t) +
Q
(t) =
T
ln D(t, T)|
T=t
46
Fixed Payment at maturity If the prices of DZCs with dierent
maturities are known, then )
B(0, T) D(0, T)
B(0, T)(1 )
= F
Q
(T)
where F
Q
(t) = Q( t), so that the law of is known under the
e.m.m..
47
Payment at hit In this case, denoting by
T
D the derivative of the
value of the DZC at time 0 with respect to the maturity, we obtain

T
D(0, T) = g(T)B(0, T) G(T)B(0, T)r(T) (T)g(T)B(0, T) ,
where g(t) = G

(t). Therefore, solving this equation leads to


Q( > t) = G(t) = (t)
_
1 +
_
t
0

T
D(0, s)
1
B(0, s)(1 (s))
((s))
1
ds
_
,
where (t) = exp
_
_
t
0
r(u)
1 (u)
du
_
.
48
Representation Theorem
Let h be a (bounded) Borel function. Then, the martingale
M
h
t
= E(h()|H
t
) admits the representation
E(h()|H
t
) = E(h())
_
t
0
(

h(s) h(s)) dM
s
,
where M
t
= H
t
(t ) and

h(s) =
_

t
h(u)dG(u)
G(t)
.
49
Representation Theorem
Let h be a (bounded) Borel function. Then, the martingale
M
h
t
= E(h()|H
t
) admits the representation
E(h()|H
t
) = E(h())
_
t
0
(

h(s) h(s)) dM
s
,
where M
t
= H
t
(t ) and

h(s) =
_

t
h(u)dG(u)
G(t)
.
Note that

h(s) = M
h
s
on s < .
50
Representation Theorem
Let h be a (bounded) Borel function. Then, the martingale
M
h
t
= E(h()|H
t
) admits the representation
E(h()|H
t
) = E(h())
_
t
0
(

h(s) h(s)) dM
s
,
where M
t
= H
t
(t ) and

h(s) =
_

t
h(u)dG(u)
G(t)
.
Note that

h(s) = M
h
s
on s < .
In particular, any square integrable H-martingale (X, t 0) can be
written as X
t
= X
0
+
_
t
0
x
s
dM
s
where (x
t
, t 0) is a predictable process.
51
Proof: A proof consists in computing the conditional expectation
E(h()|H
t
) = h()H
t
+ (1 H
t
)e
(t)
_

t
h(s)dF(s)
and to use integration by parts formula.
52
Partial information: Due and Landos model
Due and Lando study the case where = inf{t : V
t
m} where V
satises
dV
t
= (t, V
t
)dt +(t, V
t
)dW
t
.
53
Partial information: Due and Landos model
Due and Lando study the case where = inf{t : V
t
m} where V
satises
dV
t
= (t, V
t
)dt +(t, V
t
)dW
t
.
Here the process W is a Brownian motion. If the information is the
Brownian ltration, the time is a stopping time w.r.t. a Brownian
ltration, therefore is predictable and admits no intensity.
54
Partial information: Due and Landos model
Due and Lando study the case where = inf{t : V
t
m} where V
satises
dV
t
= (t, V
t
)dt +(t, V
t
)dW
t
.
Here the process W is a Brownian motion. If the information is the
Brownian ltration, the time is a stopping time w.r.t. a Brownian
ltration, therefore is predictable and admits no intensity. If the agent
does not know the behavior of V , but only the minimal information H
t
,
i.e. he knows when the default appears, the price of a zero-coupon is, in
the case where the default is not yet occurred, exp
_

_
T
t
(s)ds
_
where (s) =
f(s)
G(s)
and G(s) = P( > s), f = G

, as soon as the
cumulative function of is dierentiable.
55
Valuation and Trading Defaultable Claims
56
We assume that the market has chosen a riskneutral probability Q and
that M and are computed w.r.t. Q. We assume here that the interest
rate r is constant.
57
We assume that the market has chosen a riskneutral probability Q and
that M and are computed w.r.t. Q. We assume here that the interest
rate r is constant.
Price dynamics of a survival claim (X, 0, ).
Let (X, 0, ) be a survival claim. The price of the payo 11
{T<}
X that
settles at time T is
Y
t
= e
rt
E
Q
(11
{T<}
e
rT
X| H
t
).
58
We assume that the market has chosen a riskneutral probability Q and
that M and are computed w.r.t. Q. We assume here that the interest
rate r is constant.
Price dynamics of a survival claim (X, 0, ).
Let (X, 0, ) be a survival claim. The price of the payo 11
{T<}
X that
settles at time T is
Y
t
= e
rt
E
Q
(11
{T<}
e
rT
X| H
t
).
The dynamics of the price process is
dY
t
= rY
t
dt Y
t
dM
t
=
_
r + 11
{t<}
(t)
_
Y
t
dt Y
t
dH
t
.
59
Price dynamics of a recovery claim (0, Z, ).
The recovery Z is paid at the time of default. The cum-dividend price
process Y of (0, Z, ) is
Y
t
= e
rt
E
Q
(11
{T}
e
r
Z() | H
t
) ,
60
Price dynamics of a recovery claim (0, Z, ).
The recovery Z is paid at the time of default. The cum-dividend price
process Y of (0, Z, ) is
Y
t
= e
rt
E
Q
(11
{T}
e
r
Z() | H
t
) ,
and
dY
t
= rY
t
dt + (Z(t) Y
t
) dM
t
=
_
r + 11
{t<}
(t)
_
Y
t
dt 11
{t<}
Z(t)(t) dt + (Z(t) Y
t
) dH
t
.
61
Price dynamics of a recovery claim (0, Z, ).
The recovery Z is paid at the time of default. The cum-dividend price
process Y of (0, Z, ) is
Y
t
= e
rt
E
Q
(11
{T}
e
r
Z() | H
t
) ,
and
dY
t
= rY
t
dt + (Z(t) Y
t
) dM
t
=
_
r + 11
{t<}
(t)
_
Y
t
dt 11
{t<}
Z(t)(t) dt + (Z(t) Y
t
) dH
t
.
The ex-dividend price is
S
t
= e
rt
E
Q
(11
{T>t}
e
r
Z() | H
t
) = Y
t
e
rt
Z()e
r
11
{t}
.
62
Price dynamics of a recovery claim (0, Z, ).
The recovery Z is paid at the time of default. The cum-dividend price
process Y of (0, Z, ) is
Y
t
= e
rt
E
Q
(11
{T}
e
r
Z() | H
t
) ,
and
dY
t
= rY
t
dt + (Z(t) Y
t
) dM
t
=
_
r + 11
{t<}
(t)
_
Y
t
dt 11
{t<}
Z(t)(t) dt + (Z(t) Y
t
) dH
t
.
The ex-dividend price is
S
t
= e
rt
E
Q
(11
{T>t}
e
r
Z() | H
t
) = Y
t
e
rt
Z()e
r
11
{t}
. Hence
dS
t
= (rS
t
Z(t)(t))dt (S
t
Z(t))dM
t
.
63
Valuation of a Credit Default Swap
A credit default swap (CDS) is a contract between two counterparties.
B agrees to pay a default payment Z to A if a default of the obligor C
occurs. If there is no default until the maturity of the default swap, B
pays nothing. A pays a fee for the default protection. The fee can be
either a fee paid till the maturity or till the default event.
64
A can not cancelled the contract. He can at any time before the default
transfer the contract to D: D will pay the fee and receive the default
payment if any. As we shall see, it can happen that D will require an
amount of cash to accept to receive the contract. Usually, the fee
consists of C
i
paid at time T
i
(this is the xed leg). However, here we
shall consider a continuous payment. The default payment is called the
default leg.
65
A stylized credit default swap is formally introduced through the
following denition.
A credit default swap with a constant spread and recovery at
default is a defaultable claim (0, C, Z, ), where Z
t
(t) and
C
t
= t for every t [0, T]. An RCLL function : [0, T] IR
represents the protection payment and a constant IR is termed
the spread (or the premium) of a CDS.
66
For simplicity, we assume that the interest rate r = 0, so that the price
of a savings account B
t
= 1 for every t. Our results can be easily
extended to the case of a constant r.
67
Ex-dividend Price of a CDS
The ex-dividend price of a CDS maturing at T with spread is given
by the formula
S
t
() = E
Q

_
()11
{t<T}
11
{t<}

_
( T) t
_

H
t
_
.
68
Ex-dividend Price of a CDS
The ex-dividend price of a CDS maturing at T with spread is given
by the formula
S
t
() = E
Q

_
()11
{t<T}
11
{t<}

_
( T) t
_

H
t
_
.
The ex-dividend price at time t [s, T] of a credit default swap with
spread and recovery at default equals
S
t
() = 11
{t<}
1
G(t)
_

_
T
t
(u) dG(u)
_
T
t
G(u) du
_
.
69
Proof: We have, on the set {t < },
S
t
() =
_
T
t
(u) dG(u)
G(t)

_

_
T
t
udG(u) +TG(T)
G(t)
t
_
=
1
G(t))
_

_
T
t
(u) dG(u)
_
TG(T) tG(t)
_
T
t
udG(u)
_
_
.
It remains to note that
_
T
t
G(u) du = TG(T) tG(t)
_
T
t
udG(u),

70
The ex-dividend price of a CDS can also be represented as follows
S
t
() = 11
{t<}

S
t
(), t [0, T],
where

S
t
() stands for the ex-dividend pre-default price of a CDS.
71
Market CDS Spreads
Assume now that a CDS was initiated at some date s t and its initial
price was equal to zero. A market CDS started at s is a CDS initiated
at time s whose initial value is equal to zero. A T-maturity CDS market
spread at time s is the level of the spread = (s, T) that makes a
T-maturity CDS started at s worthless at its inception. A CDS market
spread at time s is thus determined by the equation S
s
((s, T)) = 0.
72
The T-maturity market spread (s, T) is a solution to the equation
_
T
s
(u) dG(u) +(s, T)
_
T
s
G(u) du = 0,
and thus for every s [0, T],
(s, T) =
_
T
s
(u) dG(u)
_
T
s
G(u) du
.
73
Standing assumptions. We x the maturity date T, and we write
briey (s) instead of (s, T). In addition, we assume that all credit
default swaps have a common recovery function .
Note that the ex-dividend pre-default value at time t [0, T] We have
the following result, in which the quantity (t, s) = (t) (s)
represents the calendar CDS market spread (for a given maturity T).
74
The ex-dividend price of a market CDS started at s with recovery at
default and maturity T equals, for every t [s, T],
S
t
((s)) = 11
{t<}
((t) (s))
_
T
t
G(u) du
G(t)
= 11
{t<}
(t, s)
_
T
t
G(u) du
G(t)
,
or more explicitly,
S
t
((s)) = 11
{t<}
_
T
t
G(u) du
G(t)
_
_
T
s
(u) dG(u)
_
T
s
G(u) du

_
T
t
(u) dG(u)
_
T
t
G(u) du
_
.
75
Price Dynamics of a CDS
In what follows, we assume that
G(t) = Q( > t) = exp
_

_
t
0
(u) du
_
where the default intensity (t) under Q is deterministic. We rst focus
on the dynamics of the ex-dividend price of a CDS with spread
started at some date s < T.
76
The dynamics of the ex-dividend price S
t
() on [s, T] are
dS
t
() = S
t
() dM
t
+ (1 H
t
)( (t)(t)) dt,
where the H-martingale M under Q is given by the formula
M
t
= H
t

_
t
0
(1 H
u
)(u) du, t IR
+
.
77
Proof: It suces to recall that
S
t
() = 11
{t<}

S
t
() = (1 H
t
)

S
t
()
so that
dS
t
() = (1 H
t
) d

S
t
()

S
t
() dH
t
.
Using the explicit expression of

S
t
, we nd easily that we have
d

S
t
() = (t)

S
t
() dt + ((s) (t)(t)) dt.
The SDE for S follows.
78
Trading Strategies with a CDS
A strategy
t
= (
0
t
,
1
t
), t [0, T], is self-nancing if the wealth process
U(), dened as
U
t
() =
0
t
+
1
t
S
t
(),
satises
dU
t
() =
1
t
dS
t
() +
1
t
dD
t
,
where S() is the ex-dividend price of a CDS with the dividend stream
D. A strategy replicates a contingent claim Y if U
T
() = Y .
79
Hedging of a Contingent Claim in the CDS Market
Our aim is to nd a replicating strategy for the defaultable claim
(X, 0, Z, ), where X is a constant and Z
t
= z(t).
80
Hedging of a Contingent Claim in the CDS Market
Our aim is to nd a replicating strategy for the defaultable claim
(X, 0, Z, ), where X is a constant and Z
t
= z(t).
Let y and
1
be dened as
y(t) =
1
G(t)
_
_
t
0
z(s)dG(s) +XG(T)
_

1
(t) =
z(t) y(t)
(t)

S
t
()
,
81
Hedging of a Contingent Claim in the CDS Market
Our aim is to nd a replicating strategy for the defaultable claim
(X, 0, Z, ), where X is a constant and Z
t
= z(t).
Let y and
1
be dened as
y(t) =
1
G(t)
_
_
t
0
z(s)dG(s) +XG(T)
_

1
(t) =
z(t) y(t)
(t)

S
t
()
,
Let
0
t
= V
t
()
1
(t)S
t
(), where V
t
() = E
Q
(Y |H
t
) and
Y = 11
{T}
z() + 11
{T<}
X
82
Hedging of a Contingent Claim in the CDS Market
Our aim is to nd a replicating strategy for the defaultable claim
(X, 0, Z, ), where X is a constant and Z
t
= z(t).
Let y and
1
be dened as
y(t) =
1
G(t)
_
_
t
0
z(s)dG(s) +XG(T)
_

1
(t) =
z(t) y(t)
(t)

S
t
()
,
Let
0
t
= V
t
()
1
(t)S
t
(), where V
t
() = E
Q
(Y |H
t
) and
Y = 11
{T}
z() + 11
{T<}
X
Then the self-nancing strategy = (
0
,
1
) based on the savings
account and the CDS is a replicating strategy.
83
Proof: The terminal value of the wealth is
Y = z()11
{<T}
+X11
{T<}
84
Proof: The terminal value of the wealth is
Y = z()11
{<T}
+X11
{T<}
On the one hand
E(Y |H
t
) = Y
t
= z()11
{t}
+ 11
{<t}
1
G(t)
_
XG(T) +
_
t
0
z(s)dG(s)
_
=
_
t
0
z(s)dH
s
+ (1 H
t
)
1
G(t)
_
XG(T) +
_
t
0
z(s)dG(s)
_
85
Proof: The terminal value of the wealth is
Y = z()11
{<T}
+X11
{T<}
On the one hand
E(Y |H
t
) = Y
t
= z()11
{t}
+ 11
{<t}
1
G(t)
_
XG(T) +
_
t
0
z(s)dG(s)
_
=
_
t
0
z(s)dH
s
+ (1 H
t
)
1
G(t)
_
XG(T) +
_
t
0
z(s)dG(s)
_
hence dY
t
= (z(t) y(t)) dM
t
with y(t) =
1
G(t)
(
_
t
0
z(s)dG(s) +XG(T)).
86
Proof: The terminal value of the wealth is
Y = z()11
{<T}
+X11
{T<}
On the one hand
E(Y |H
t
) = Y
t
= z()11
{t}
+ 11
{<t}
1
G(t)
_
XG(T) +
_
t
0
z(s)dG(s)
_
=
_
t
0
z(s)dH
s
+ (1 H
t
)
1
G(t)
_
XG(T) +
_
t
0
z(s)dG(s)
_
hence dY
t
= (z(t) y(t)) dM
t
with y(t) =
1
G(t)
(
_
t
0
z(s)dG(s) +XG(T)).
On the other hand,
dY
t
=
1
t
(dS
t
() (1 H
t
)dt +(t)dH
t
) =
1
t
((t) S
t
()) dM
t
.
87

You might also like