Need To Rephrase

You might also like

Download as docx, pdf, or txt
Download as docx, pdf, or txt
You are on page 1of 7

Need to Rephrase

In particular, modern financial theory is founded on three central assumptions: markets are
highly efficient, investors exploit potential arbitrage opportunities, and investors are rational
(Dimson & Mussavian, 1999).
Bernoulli (1937) explored different issues that are the core of modern finance and assets pricing
theory. He rejected the proposition of measuring risk by mathematicians that Expected values
are computed by multiplying each possible gain by the number of ways in which it can occur,
and then dividing the sum of these products by the total number of possible cases.
Proper examination of the numerous demonstrations of this proposition that have come forth
indicates that they all rest upon one hypothesis: since there is no reason to assume that of two
persons encountering identical risks, either should expect to have his desires more closely
fulfilled, the risks anticipated by each must be deemed equal in value. No characteristic of the
persons themselves ought to be taken into consideration; only those matters should be weighed
carefully that pertain to the terms of the risk. Rules would be set up whereby anyone could
estimate his prospects from any risky undertaking in light of one's specific financial
circumstances.
Example: To make this clear it is perhaps advisable to consider the following example:
Somehow a very poor fellow obtains a lottery ticket that will yield with equal probability either
nothing or twenty thousand ducats. Will this man evaluate his chance of winning at ten thousand
ducats? Would he not be ill-advised to sell this lottery ticket for nine thousand ducats? To me it
seems that the answer is in the negative. On the other hand I am inclined to believe that a rich
man would be ill-advised to refuse to buy the lottery ticket for nine thou-sand ducats. If I am not
wrong then it seems clear that all men cannot use the same rule to evaluate the gamble. The rule
established in Proposition 1 must, therefore, be discarded. But anyone who considers the
problem with perspicacity and interest will ascertain that the concept of value which we have
used in this rule may be defined in a way which renders the entire procedure universally
acceptable without reservation. To do this the determination of the value of an item must not be
based on its price, but rather on the utility it yields. The price of the item is dependent only on
the thing itself and is equal for everyone; the utility, however, is dependent on the particular
circumstances of the person making the estimate. Thus there is no doubt that a gain of one
thousand ducats is more significant to a pauper than to a rich man though both gain the same
amount.
The determination of the value of an item must not be based on its price but rather on the utility
it yields. Price of the item is dependent only on the thing itself and is equal for everyone but
utility on the other hand is dependent on the particular state of the person making the estimate.
If the utility of each possible profit expectation is multiplied by the number of ways in which
it can occur, and we then divide the sum of these products by the total number of possible
cases, a mean utility [moral expectation] will be obtained, and the profit which corresponds to
this utility will equal the value of the risk in question.

The capital asset pricing model (CAPM) is the standard risk-return model used by most
academicians and practitioners. The underlying concept of CAPM is that investors are rewarded
for only that portion of risk which is not diversifiable. This non-diversifiable risk is termed as
beta, to which expected returns are linked. The risk is variability in return and the total risk consists
of both systematic risk and unsystematic risk.
The assumptions underlying the CAPM
1. All investors focus on a single holding period, and they seek to maximize the expected
utility of their terminal wealth by choosing among alternative portfolios on the basis of
each portfolio's expected return and standard deviation.
2. All investors can borrow or lend an unlimited amount at a given risk-free rate of interest
and there are no restrictions on short sales of any assets.
3. All investors have identical estimated of the expected returns, variances, and co variances
among all assets (that is, investors have homogeneous expectations).
4. All assets are perfectly divisible and perfectly liquid (that is, marketable at the going
price).
5. There are no transaction costs.
6. There are no taxes.
7. All investors are price takers (that is, all investors assume that their own buying and
selling activity will not affect stock prices).
8. The quantities of all assets are given and fixed.

The yield on short-term Government debt, which is used as a substitute for the
risk-free rate of return, is not fixed but changes on a daily basis according to
economic circumstances. A short-term average value can be used in order to
smooth out this volatility. WHAT ABOUT THIS?
(Deepa, 2013)

But empirical work, old and new, tells us that the relation between beta and average return is
flatter than predicted by the Sharpe-Lintner version of the CAPM. As a result, CAPM estimates
of the cost of equity for high beta stocks are too high (relative to historical average returns) and
estimates for low beta stocks are too low (Friend and Blume, 1970).
The foundations for the development of asset pricing models were laid by Markowitz
(1952) and Tobin (1958).
When a portfolio of risky assets is formed, the standard deviation risk of the portfolio is
less than the sum of standard deviations of its constituents (Markowitz, 1952). The
Markowitz model generates the efficient frontier of portfolios and the investors are
expected to select a portfolio, which is most appropriate for them, from the efficient set of
portfolios available to them. But he could not find the formula to measure the risk and
return relationship. Sharpe (1964) developed a computationally efficient method, the
single index model, where return on an individual security is related to the return on a
common index. The common index may be any variable thought to be the dominant
influence on stock returns and need not be a stock index (Jones, 1991). The single index model
can be extended to portfolios as well. This is possible because the expected return on a portfolio is a
weighted average of the expected returns on individual securities. When analysing the risk of an
individual security, however, the individual security risk must be considered in relation to other securities
in the portfolio. In particular, the risk of an individual security must be measured in terms of the extent to
which it adds risk to the investors portfolio. Thus, a securitys contribution to portfolio risk is different
from the risk of the individual security.
Investors face two kinds of risks, namely, diversifiable (unsystematic) and non-
diversifiable (systematic). Unsystematic risk is the component of the portfolio risk that can
be eliminated by increasing the portfolio size, the reason being that risks that are specific
to an individual security such as business or financial risk can be eliminated by
constructing a well-diversified portfolio. Systematic risk is associated with overall
movements in the general market or economy and therefore is often referred to as the
market risk. The market risk is the component of the total risk that cannot be eliminated
through portfolio diversification.
The CAPM conveys the notion that securities are priced so that the expected returns will compensate
investors for the expected risks. There are two fundamental relationships: the capital market line and the
security market line. These two models are the building blocks for deriving the CAPM. The capital
market line (CML) specifies the return an individual investor expects to receive on a portfolio. This is a
linear relationship between risk and return on efficient portfolios. The security market line (SML)
expresses the return an individual investor can expect in terms of a risk-free rate and the relative risk of a
security.
Asset pricing models
1. Single-factor CAPM
In order to test the validity of the CAPM researchers always test the SML. The CAPM is a single-period
ex-ante (before the event or forecasted) model. However, since the ex ante returns are unobservable,
researchers rely on realized returns. So the empirical question arises: Do the past security returns conform
to the CAPM?
Early studies (Lintner, 1965; Douglas, 1969) on CAPM were primarily based on individual security
returns. Miller and Scholes (1972) highlighted some statistical problems encountered when using
individual securities in testing the validity of the CAPM.
Black, Jensen and Scholes (1972), in their study of all the stocks of the New York Stock Exchange over
the period 1931-1965, formed portfolios and reported a linear relationship between the average excess
portfolio return and the beta, and for beta >1 (<1) the intercept tends to be negative (positive).
Therefore, they developed a zero-beta version of the CAPM model where the intercept term is allowed
to change in each period. Extending the Black, Jensen and Scholes (1972) study, Fama and MacBeth
(1973) provided evidence (i) of a larger intercept term than the risk-free rate, (ii) that the linear
relationship between the average return and the beta holds and (iii) that the linear relationship holds
well when the data covers a long time period. Subsequent studies, however, provide weak empirical
evidence on these relationships. See, for example, Fama and French (1992), He and Ng (1994), Davis
(1994) and Miles and Timmermann (1996). (See their seminal papers what they said).The
single-factor CAPM is rejected when the portfolio used as a market proxy is inefficient. Roll (1977) and
Ross (1977)
Beta is unstable over time. Bos and Newbold (1984), Faff, Lee and Fry (1992), Brooks, Faff and Lee
(1994) and Faff and Brooks (1998)
2. Multifactor models
A growing number of studies found that the cross-sectional variation in average security returns cannot
be explained by the market beta alone and showed that fundamental variables such as size (Banz, 1981),
ratio of book-to-market value (Rosenberg, Reid and Lanstein, 1985; Chan, Hamao and Lakonishok,
1991), macroeconomic variables and the price to earnings ratio (Basu, 1983) account for a sizeable
portion of the cross-sectional variation in expected returns.
Fama and French (1995) observed that the two non-market risk factors SMB (the difference between
the return on a portfolio of small stocks and the return on a portfolio of large stocks) and HML (the
difference between the return on a portfolio of high-book-to-market stocks and the return on a
portfolio of low-book-to-market stocks) are useful factors when explaining a cross-section of equity
returns. Chung, Johnson and Schill (2001) observed that as higher-order systematic co-moments are
included in the cross-sectional regressions for portfolio returns, the SMB and HML generally become
insignificant. Therefore, they argued that SMB and HML are good proxies for higher-order co-moments.
Ferson and Harvey (1999) claimed that many multifactor model specifications are rejected because they
ignore conditioning information.
Multifactor arbitrage pricing theory (APT) models introduced by Ross (1976) APT models allow for priced
factors that are orthogonal to the market return and do not require that all investors are mean-variance
optimisers, as in the CAPM. Groenewold and Fraser (1997) examined the validity of these models for
Australian data and compared the performance of the empirical version of APT and the CAPM. They
concluded that APT outperforms the CAPM in terms of within-sample explanatory power.
3. Conditional asset pricing models

You might also like