Download as doc, pdf, or txt
Download as doc, pdf, or txt
You are on page 1of 16

Erin Fitzpatrick

The Globalization of Democracy Building: A Polyarchic Dilemma


December 10, 2003
When we look at the Middle East and democratization, we must realize that
democracy in its current form is largely a Western concept. Democracy building on the
part of the US outwards is a classic example of globalization.
This paper will examine two theories of globalization: the interdependency theory
of Waltz and Robinsons view of globalization as one of power politics. It will then move
on to examine globalization theory in regards to democracy building. Finally, this paper
will seek to examine democracy building initiatives in two countries, Iraq and Lebanon.
Theories of Globalization
Waltz contends that we view globalization at interdependence, and that
interdependence [is] again associated with peace and peace increasingly with
democracy.1 People, firms, markets matter more; states matter less, because it is the
economy that drives states to make decisions.

As the world becomes more

interdependent on one another, decisions are made as a collective whole in the economic
field, not the independent political state.
In many ways, Waltz suggests that Globalism is really Americanism spread
around the globe. As the Cold War ended, it become clearer that the ideology that won
out, a capitalist democracy, was the winner and dominant ideology. The theology behind
it was that if a country is not transparent, with a flexible free market, then it will crumble.
What if a country is looking to open its economy? Waltz argues that a country
wishing to join the world market must wear a golden straightjacket, a package of
1

Waltz, Kenneth. Globalization and Governance. PS: Political Science and Politics, Vol. 32, No.4, (Dec.
1999), 693.
2
ibid, 694

policies including balanced budgets, economic deregulation, openness to investment and


trade, and a stable currency. 3 Because it is economies that globalism is most concerned
with, it is not a political decision by any one state or person, rather an economic herd of
investors and lenders that decide when a country will receive investments and become a
world economic player. Because it is a herd that decides the success of a state, they do
not care about who is in government, rather whether a state has stability, predictability,
transparency, and the ability to transfer and protect its private property.4
To Waltz, globalization also means homogeneity: of prices, products, rates of
interests, etc. But could this not also translate into a homogeny of culture? A strong
economy under globalization requires transparency, but then that transparency might
transfer ideologically to the social and political realms as well. Waltz argues that this is
exemplified in that latecomers imitate the practices and adopt the institution of the
countries who have shown the way.5
States are differentiated from one another not by function but primarily by
capability.6 Capacity to change, adopt, keep power, trade, adapt. If they cannot adapt,
then Waltz argues that their failure to be welcomed into the global community will lead to
a larger poverty gap, less investment, less technology: a stagnant economy.

What

globalism has brought the world, Waltz ultimately argues, is not an increasing
interdependence, but growing inequality amongst Northern and Southern states.
Robinson focuses on economics as well, but further argues that globalization is
the spread of capitalism throughout the world. Before globalization was relevant, power
3

Waltz, Kenneth. Globalization and Governance. PS: Political Science and Politics, Vol. 32, No.4, (Dec.
1999), 694
4
ibid
5
ibid, 695.
6
ibid, 698

was battled through militaries and physical strength, through conflicts. The US picked up
where colonialism left off, intervening both politically and militarily in Latin America,
the Middle East and elsewhere. After WWII, this left the U.S. with the responsibility of
stability, and they often chose authoritarian regimes, whether purposely or not.7
However, these authoritarian regimes were often challenged as in Egypt and Iran,
by nationalist-oriented elites to secure greater autonomy and local control. 8 They were
then were responded to by the U.S. , with support for the authoritarian regimes in order to
maintain stability.
This changed in the 1970s and 80s, as popular movements demanding change
became more frequent. The fall of the Shaw and the support for Nasr and subsequent
Nasrist rebellions in the Middle East are perfect examples of this. There was a crisis with
the ruling elite that the US had supported, and the authoritarian regimes became destabilized. As the movements were gaining momentum, the US could no longer ensure
economic stability in the region and backing authoritarian regimes was therefore not a
way to ensure the stability that was needed. Therefore, in the 1980s, the US changed its
foreign policy to one of democracy promotion.9
As the global economy became more relevant and defined, a new elite emerged
based on capitalist strength; an elite fluent in money markets and free capital exchange.
Robinson points out that this happened in the mid-1980s before the end of the Cold War.
This is an important point, because it shows that the US was concerned with globalization
of political and economic factors before the supposed end of the bi-polar hegemonic
system.
7

Robinson Globalization, the World System, and Democracy Promotion in US Foreign Policy. Theory
and Society, Vol. 25, No.5 (Oct., 1996), 615-665.619.
8
Ibid.
9
ibid, 621

What resulted from the switch away from supporting authoritarian regimes was an
endorsement of polyarchy. Polyarchy refers to a system in which a small group actually
rules and mass participation in decision-making is confined to leadership choice in
elections carefully managed by competing elites. 10 The assumption in polyarchy is that
the elite will respond to the will of the majority.
In the Middle East, populace movements are seeking fundamental social change,
not just simply a change in the electoral process.

The difference between popular

democracy and polyarchy are important to note. Popular democracy means that the
majority of voters decides policy and representative outcomes, while polyarchy implies
that an elite will decide what is best for the majority.

Transitions away from

authoritarianism towards polyarchy does not involve eliminating a coercive apparatus


but subordinating that apparatus to civilian elites.11 In other words, whomever is elected
does not have to represent all the people, simply the ruling economic elite. The economic
elite make globalization work.
The term globalization implies two processes: capitalist production and trade
replacing protectionist economies through specialization and globalization of the process
of production and an integrated market.12 This has led to an integration of national
economies, where uniformity results across boarders, not just economically, but socially
as well. The rule of the economies is based in the US, along with Europe and other ruling
elites.
This elite gives sway to neo-liberalism, a model that seeks to achieve the
conditions for the total mobility of capital. [It] includes the elimination of state
10

Robinson, Globalization, the World System, and Democracy Promotion in US Foreign Policy. Theory
and Society, Vol. 25, No.5 (Oct., 1996), 615-665. p624.
11
ibid, p.628
12
ibid, p632

intervention in the economy and the regulation by individual nation states over the
activity of capital in their territories. 13 In the Middle East, the elite is seeking stability in
the economic policies of the state, so that the structures of the global economy can
operate. This requires price and exchange rate stability, etc. for markets and capital to
flow freely.
Polyarchy is basically defined as:
Nothing more than the holding of elections. Equality of conditions for electoral
participation is not relevant, and these conditions are decided unequal under
capitalism owing to the unequal distribution of material and cultural resources
among classes and groups, and the use of economic power to determine political
outcomes. Political rights are most importantly the judicial right, not the material
ability to become a candidate and participate in elections. The outcome is
unimportant.14
The transnational practices of globalization are on three levels: economic,
political and cultural. Economically it is transnational capital that is most important to
the globalized elite. Politically, it is the success of the economic elite, and culturally,
globalism is a system of consumerism.
According to Robinson, US aid programs target the stability now of polyarchic
systems. These systems must respond to dissent. The change cannot be from above,
but must be from below, changing civil society, organizations at the grassroots level.
Therefore, US aid programs target women and student groups, as well as labor unions
and political parties in democracy building programs.15

13

Robinson, Globalization, the World System, and Democracy Promotion in US Foreign Policy. Theory
and Society, Vol. 25, No.5 (Oct., 1996), 615-665.p634.
14
ibid, p636
15
ibid, p643.

Democracy Building
Kriesberg was right when he said, When parties do not agree about the system
they constitute, the conflicts are particularly contentious and difficult to settle. 16 This is
particularly true when controversies over institutionalized systems are created in the
political and social sphere. But people have to be largely discontent with the party in
charge. That discontent within the political arena, democracy advocates claim, can be
solved with more democratization.
It is important to understand however that regimes will only become democratic when
they are significantly challenged from within. Unfortunately, those that are most able to
form a collective majority are the Islamic parties and such opposition does exist.
Since the Kennedy administration, the US has been sending aid to countries around
the world under the guise of democracy building. As part of his Cold War strategy,
Kennedy linked democracies to peace, arguing that democracies lead to more economic
stability and friendly relations to the United States. Otherwise known as the Democratic
Peace Thesis, the idea that democracies dont fight other democracies was fundamental to
the Kennedy Administration.
However, aid until the early 1990s went primarily to Latin America and Asia.
After the Gulf War, Bush started to increase aid to the Middle East to around $250
million over the decade with the majority of those funds going to Egypt and the Occupied
Territories in Israel (West Bank/Gaza). The US did not challenge other countries. The
money that went to the Middle East was primarily for institutional reform in Egypt: to
court efficiency, tort reform and decentralization of government. The U.S. defined its

16

Kriesberg, Louis. Constructive Conflicts: From Escalation to Resolution. 1998. Rowman & Littlefield,
p16

role in the Middle East as that of helping to prepare the countries for the day when
political change would become possible, rather than making change happen.17
The Middle East Policy Initiative, launched at the end of 2002, harolled the Bush
administration as stepping up its funding to democracy building in the Middle East. In
reality, the funds allocated for this goal was $29 million for 2003, an insignificant
increase from the 1990s.18
Market Linkage
There are many that agree with Robinson, who argue that the institutionalization
of US aid towards democracy is not whole-hearted, with democracy as its only goal.
Vitalis contends that, beneath the latest fashionable rhetoric, democracy in the hands
of AID serves as an instrument for the pursuit of other ends specifically, more marketfriendly economies.19
These market- friendly economies are important for US exports, price controls
and stable currencys that will allow foreign direct investment (FDI). As a country
becomes more open to trade and reforms the government sector, the private sector
becomes more open for firms to operate on a more level playing field with state owned
banks and institutions. This means that the US and other market-economies can have a
slice of the pie, in any country that becomes more capitalistic.
Countries may allow democracy building companies such as the National
Democratic Institute, or USAID into their countries, because of what Vitalis terms rentseeking. Rent-seeking is when a country seeks aid of any kind that can bring in

17

Ottaway, Marina. Thinking Big: Democratizing the Middle East. Boston Globe. Jan. 5, 2003. p1
ibid, p2
19
Vitalis, Robert. The Democratization Industry and the Limits of the New Interventionism. Middle East
Report, No. 187/188. Intervention and North-South Politics in the 90s. (Mar. Jun., 1994), 46
18

additional income to the state, including money from licenses or permits. These activities
require employment of citizens in the home country as well.
What USAID then accomplishes is dominance by both the US- in domestic
markets, and the home country who is rent-seeking, not looking to employ democracy
building for democracys sake. What AID [then] exemplifies the parasitic relationship
Springborg describes between a self interested and embattled public authority and the
array of clients it serves.20
USAID argues alternatively that AIDs democracy project would operationalize a
strategy for supporting processes of democratic institutional reform that will further
economic liberalization objectives.

21

Institutional reform does not simply imply

legislative or judicial branch reform, but economic-market reform as well.

If

transparency is a bi-product of market reform that seeps into the private sector, then that
is a worthy bi-product.
What market reform accomplishes in the democracy building front is a
justifi[cation] sociologically and politically as the best way to reduce the impact of
nepotistic networks. The wider the scope of market forces, the less room there will be for
rent-seeking by elites with privileged access to state power and resources.22

20

Vitalis, Robert. The Democratization Industry and the Limits of the New Interventionism. Middle East
Report, No. 187/188. Intervention and North-South Politics in the 90s. (Mar. Jun., 1994), 48.
21
ibid, 49.
22
Lipset, Seymour Martin. The Social Requisites of Democracy Revisited: 1993 Presidential Address.
American Sociological Review, Vol. 59, No. 1 (Feb., 1994), 3

Case Studies: Iraq and Lebanon


There is an assumption in the Middle East is that democracies cannot successfully
take form in Arab countries that are Islamic. Democracy building dissenters sometimes
argue that a stable democracy is virtually impossible in any Arab/Muslim country. These
beliefs are held by the same people who believe that there is a Huntington-like clash of
civilizations, where ideologies of the West cannot be merged with those of the East.
Their argument is said to be based in history, as Freedom House President Adrian
Karatnycky represents, when he argued that:
Since the early 1970s.the Islamic world, in particular its Arabic core, have
seen little significant evidence of improvements in political openness, respect for
human rights, and transparency.23
Other groups, like CATO and World Values, join the Freedom house in this course of
ideology, when they contend that they calculated that a non-Islamic country is three
times more likely than an Islamic country to be democratic.24
Alternately, scholars argue that there is a homogeneity that exists in most
countries that would lend itself to solely Muslim rule, with each countrys Muslim
majority. This is because of the simple assumption that in a representative government,
majority rules.
However, there are two countries that stand out of this norm, even to those
scholars who agree with Huntington: Iraq and Lebanon. Both countries have mixed
societys comprised of different religious and ethnic backgrounds that serve to balance
each other out, with no one party holding a clear majority. Indeed, before the Lebanese
23

Basham, Patrick. Gambling with History: Bringing Democracy to the Middle East. CATO Institute. Aug.
26, 2003. www.cato.org/cgi-bin/scripts/printtech.cgi/dailys/08-26-03.html p1
24
ibd.

civil war that began in the 1970s, Lebanon represented to the Arab world a society that
was free, open, pluralist and stable.25 Lebanization emulating a country that had
worked to perfect political compromise, create a system of careful consensus politics,
while creating a working proportional representational system.
The system of governance in Lebanon would be proportional based on the
confessional system: a representative structure on the basis of religious and ethnic
heritage. It would not be by ideological beliefs, etc., but by representation of all people
along these divisional lines. Once established, the National Pact limited the actions that
the political infrastructure of Lebanon could take. The majority of seats were given to the
Christian populace (six) and five to the Muslim populace, therefore creating a system
where each populace would have ensured representation.
In July of 2003, the Governing Council of Iraq was created as an interim
government, charged with the task of assembling the beginnings of a government in both
the legislative and judicial areas of government, under the US-led Coalition Provisional
Authority (CPA). It is composed based on a confessional system, comprised of thirteen
Arab Shiites, five Arab Sunnis, five Kurdish Sunnis, a Christian and a Sunni Turk. In
September, the Council also created a cabinet that was comprised of a similar make-up.
Some opponents to the CPA and Governing Council argue that the confessional
system would engrain and legitimize particularistic identities, creating notions of
exclusiveness that inevitably would exacerbate dislocations among the countrys various
communities.26 These same opponents point to Lebanon as a reaffirmation to this claim,

25

Hawthorne, Amy., ed. Arab Reform Bulletin. Carnegie Endowment for International Peace. November
2003, Vol. 1, Issue 5. p6
26
ibid, p7

arguing that it was the confessional system that led to the civil war and its own political
demise.
Kora Mehta, a program officer who works with democracy building projects in
Lebanon, discussed why the confessional system in Lebanon has failed:
I see the confessional system as involving 2 parts:
1: the confessional system itself as an institution
2: the circumstances that keeps it in place and maintains the power it
has, feeding into itself. There is a lot of Syrian involvement, and they continue to
take advantage of the system and manipulate those aspects of the confessional
system that help them. Because of the manipulation and the support, the
confessional system on the national level dictates the political environment in
Lebanon. The reasons that it is powerful is because of that manipulation I
differentiate then between the system itself and manipulation of that system.
What Lebanon shows about the challenges of the confessional system is
that manipulation is easier, because youre not violating the tenants of the system.
By increasing manipulation, youre buying into the system itself, but weakening
the system as a whole. This is because your therere representing your sect or
religion. Youre not advocating democracy in the pluralistic sense It doesnt
require systems to become pluralistic.27
Other scholars would like to suggest that the major conflict in Lebanon is that of
identity, where lines are drawn according to religion. This is a fair position; however, the
divisions by religion are artificial. Those lines were established by the French when they
created Greater Lebanon in order to be able to use the Maronites to administer the
country. The French felt that they had a common bond with the Christians in the area, and
thus gave them more favors and opportunity than the rest of the community. 28
Chrigton and Iver, in their case-study of Lebanon, viewed protracted conflicts as
identity driven, the result of an underlying fear of extinction that grows out of the
experience of being a vulnerable ethnic group living with memories of persecution and
massacre.29 What is successful about Lebanon, was that for 30 years, there was no
27

Mehta, Kora. Personal Interview. December 9, 2003.


Maktabi, Rania. The Lebanese 1932 Census Revisited. Who Are the Lebanese? British Journal of Middle
East Studies.Vol. 26, No. 2 (Nov. 1999), 224.
29
Crighton, Elizabeth. Martha Abele Mac Iver. The Evolution of Protracted Ethnic Conflict: Group
Dominance and Political Underdevelopment in Northern Ireland and Lebanon. Comparative Politics,
28

significant internal conflict. The civil war that started in the 1970s was largely instigated
by outside states, using Lebanon as their battlefield: not fundamental problems with
Lebanon itself. As my previous paper argued, the continued problems in Lebanon are due
to lack of economic stability, which has tied the hands of those responsible for the
political climate.
Iraq is not identical to Lebanon in make-up; it has a large Shii majority, with
large constituencies of Sunni and Kurdish peoples as well. Iraq also differs from Lebanon
on less cosmetic lines, because its economy has the potential to be largely successful,
once its oil production is reestablished. Its identity currently is muddled. Many Kurds are
demanding a separate, autonomous state. Other citizens are worried that a Shii majority
could turn the state into an Islamic republic imitating its neighbor Iran.
In Iraqs case its successful economy could manage to let there be more peace in
its transition to a democracy. After oil trade is re-established, there will be significantly
increasing funds towards internal administration, education, and infrastructure, something
in which Lebanon is lacking. The downward turn in Lebanons economy has caused great
discord and fractionalization within its political arena.

It is the economy, not its

confessional political system that has caused that fractionalization.


Iraq has similar problems of identity when it comes to its politics. The lines that
established its borders are not indicative of a common culture, they were drawn by the
British along their own divide and rule policy that included the wilayat of Mosul,
largely Kurdish in population.
Avoiding a Polyarchy

Volume 23, Issue 2 (Jan., 1991), p.127

In order for Iraq to be successful, it must create a true confessional system, based
on the realities. It cannot allow its constitution to be made with haste, and must be very
careful not to let outside parties to pervert and interpret its representational make-up.
As we have seen previously, the inability for Lebanon to stay true to its confessional
nature has led to continues economic and political failure.
Kora Mehta put it best, when she said:
What Lebanon shows about the challenges of the confessional system is that
manipulation is easier, because youre not violating the tenants of the system. By
increasing manipulation, youre buying into the system itself, but weakening the
system as a whole. This is because your therere representing your sect or
religion. Youre not advocating democracy in the pluralistic sense It doesnt
require systems to become pluralistic.30
What is required is ultimately a pluralistic, operating democratic society. To Mehta, Iraq
could work as a democracy, but it has to avoid the problems of Lebanon. It could be
argued that perhaps Theres a difference in identity between Iraq and Lebanon Iraq as
an identity means more that Lebanon to the Lebanese. If that is the case, then you have a
unifying force to counter the confessional system problems that occur in Lebanonyou
have an overarching identity.
That identity may be the glue that could create a working confessional system in
Iraq. However, as Alison Lawlor points out;
The people of Iraq need time to consider what will be best for them. There must
be a civil society that works before they can establish a true democracy. NGOs
must work with Iraqis to form civil service organizations that can advocate the
needs and wants of their constituents. There must be a point at which there is an
understanding of what it means to provide for the people as a political
representative, not just the state providing for the people.31
Lawlor points out that the state of Iraq has a history of being an oil-welfare state. This
history of state welfare, where taxes and oil revenues provided, until the 1980s, for the

Paper for Globalization in the Middle East: IAFF 190: November 2003.
Mehta, Kora. Personal Interview. December 9, 2003.
31
Lawlor, Alison. Personal Interview. December 5, 2003.
30

people, meant that there was a lack of civil services. While the regimes may have been
authoritarian and repressive, they also provided most of the services the populace needed,
pushing out the service sector. Now, the state of Iraq needs to look at privatizing its
industries and allowing for free markets. Opening up its industry to privatization may
have a devastating effect at first, causing public outrage.
Furthermore, Lawlor considers the timing of the US agenda in democracy
building in Iraq. She contends that with the reform of the public sector, assuming that
Iraqis can adapt to and accept a truly democratic regime by the US administrations
deadline of June 2004 is unreasonable, these things take time.32
However, the US wants elites to stay in power. Perhaps the deadline is to ensure
that their representatives are those in power in the political realm. Mehta raises a good
point:
There are people in the US administration who truly want [democracy in the
Middle East. There is a dilemma when people start to assume that the US
government should have moral ethics in its actions, that they should do what is
morally right all the time. I believe they should but the reality is that the US
will serve in the interest of its population, Americans. I believe that encouraging
democracy in the Middle East would serve in the interests of the American
people, but the US administration doesnt necessarily believe that.33
What the US needs is stability, not democracy. Stability in Iraq would open up oil
production once more. An elite in power that the US is friendly with could lead to
inexpensive oil, and a new state for US exports, furthering its world market. Iraq will
most likely turn into another polyarchic state, unless the US backs off with its rhetoric
and deadlines.
There is possibility for democracy in Iraq. It could be the confessional system, or
it could look like something else, perhaps a quota system (although such a system has
32
33

Lawlor, Alison. Personal Interview. December 5, 2003.


Mehta, Kora. Personal Interview. December 9, 2003.

failed in Jordan) or a representative list system. But whatever Iraqis choose, they must
consider that it must be chosen with attention paid to the rights of all their constituents. A
confessional system may work but they have to keep in mind that, If you want a truly
democratic system, there is no one whose rights could be lesser than anyone elses. You
can have a confessional system, as long as no one manipulates it. The problem is that not
everyone participating wants a true democracy. 34
That democracy must be pluralistic and takes time to build. If there is to be true
democracy in the Middle East, esp. in Iraq and Lebanon, it may not look like what the US
wants. The majority of both populations is Muslim, so both states might have another
Islamic Democracy outside of Iran. The US, if it wants to escape polyarchy and contend
that it is just in its programs of democracy building must accept this fact as well, that
Islam is a way of life and its a religion, but its basic tenants are very similar to other
religions. They do not contradict with democratic thought. We often assume that a
democracy will look like the U.S. It might not. But still it will be a democracy. 35

Bibliography
Basham, Patrick. Gambling with History: Bringing Democracy to the Middle East. CATO
Institute. Aug. 26, 2003. www.cato.org/cgi-bin/scripts/printtech.cgi/dailys/08-26-03.html
Carothers, Thomas. Bethany Lacina. Quick Transformation to Democratic Middle East is
a Fantasy. Seattle Post Intelligencer. March 16, 2003.

34
35

Mehta, Kora. Personal Interview. December 9, 2003.


Ibid.

Crighton, Elizabeth. Martha Abele Mac Iver. The Evolution of Protracted Ethnic Conflict:
Group Dominance and Political Underdevelopment in Northern Ireland and Lebanon.
Comparative Politics, Volume 23, Issue 2 (Jan., 1991), p.127
Duncan, Benjamin. US Security Linked to Peace in the Middle East. AlJazeera.net.
October 29, 2003.
Hawthorne, Amy., ed. Arab Reform Bulletin. Carnegie Endowment for International
Peace. November 2003, Vol. 1, Issue 5.
Kriesberg, Louis. Constructive Conflicts: From Escalation to Resolution. 1998. Rowman
& Littlefield.
Lawlor, Alison. Personal Interview. December 5, 2003.
Lipset, Seymour Martin. The Social Requisites of Democracy Revisited: 1993
Presidential Address. American Sociological Review, Vol. 59, No. 1 (Feb., 1994), 1-22.
Maktabi, Rania. The Lebanese 1932 Census Revisited. Who Are the Lebanese? British
Journal of Middle East Studies.Vol. 26, No. 2 (Nov. 1999), 224.
Mehta, Kora. Personal Interview. December 9, 2003.
Ottaway, Marina. Thinking Big: Democratizing the Middle East. Boston Globe. Jan. 5,
2003.
Robinson, William. Globalization, the World System, and Democracy Promotion in US
Foreign Policy. Theory and Society, Vol. 25, No.5 (Oct., 1996), 615-665.
Vitalis, Robert. The Democratization Industry and the Limits of the New Interventionism.
Middle East Report, No. 187/188. Intervention and North-South Politics in the 90s.
(Mar. Jun., 1994), 46-50.
Waltz, Kenneth. Globalization and Governance. PS: Political Science and Politics, Vol.
32, No.4, (Dec. 1999), 693-700.

You might also like