Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 10

Mergers and Market Share

Author(s): Dennis C. Mueller


Source: The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 67, No. 2 (May, 1985), pp. 259-267
Published by: The MIT Press
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/1924725
Accessed: 24-07-2016 17:59 UTC
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
http://about.jstor.org/terms

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted
digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about
JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

The MIT Press is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The Review of
Economics and Statistics

This content downloaded from 86.164.156.132 on Sun, 24 Jul 2016 17:59:14 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

MERGERS AND MARKET SHARE


Dennis C. Mueller*
Abstract-The impact of mergers on the market shares of
acquired companies is estimated using market share data for
the 1000 largest companies of 1950 and 1972. Market shares
are computed for conglomerate and horizontal acquisitions
between 1950 and 1972. To control for other factors that might
affect market shares, market shares of acquired firms are compared with those of a control sample of unacquired firms drawn
from the same industries. Companies acquired in a conglomerate merger and companies joining in horizontal mergers
are both found to experience substantial losses in market shares
relative to control group companies following the mergers.

M s ERGERS have over the course of the last


century transformed the corporate landscape. A careful examination of the 1,000 largest
manufacturing companies of 1950 revealed that
384 had disappeared through mergers by 1973
(Mueller, 1983, p. 4). Others from this list have
disappeared since. A look at the 100 largest corporations in the United States reveals a mere handful
for which mergers did not figure substantially in
their growth at one time or another. Exxon, United
States Steel, and General Motors were spawned in
the early merger waves. Textron, ITT and Occidental Petroleum are products of recent merger
history. The process of transformation through
merger continues unabated through today.
Despite the venerability of this process and its
profound influence on corporate structure, our
knowledge of the economic effects of mergers is
spotty, and disagreement exists regarding what the
existing evidence shows. Most studies of early
merger activity focussed on the effects of mergers
on the profitability of the merging companies.
Here a fair consensus exists that the mergers of the
first two greater merger waves are more likely to

have lowered than to have increased profitability.'

A similarly mixed picture of the effects of mergers


on the profitability of the merging companies is
presented in studies of post World War II merger
activity in this country and Europe.2
Most recent studies of the effects of mergers
have looked at their impact on the returns on
common shares. Here it appears that the shareholders of acquired companies are unquestionably
better off, but shareholders of acquiring companies
may or may not be better off, and some disagreement exists over whether the net effects of mergers
on stockholder wealth are positive or negative.3
This paper takes a fresh look at the effects of
mergers question, by examining their impact on a
heretofore almost unexplored variable, market
share. Several recent studies have found that
market shares are positively related to profitability
(e.g., Ravenscraft, 1983), and market share is a
frequently cited objective of corporate management. Thus, one might legitimately evaluate the
successfulness of mergers by their impact on
market shares. On the other hand, in certain situations, as for example, in a horizontal merger in an
industry with less than perfect collusion, the combined market share of the merging firms could fall
although their profits rose (see Salant, Switzer and
Reynolds, 1983; Perry and Porter, 1983). Thus, we
shall not attempt to relate our results to the literature on mergers effects on either profitability or
stockholder wealth. We ask instead the more modest question of whether mergers have succeeded in
increasing the market shares of the acquired firms.
The next section describes the data and empirical
tests. Results follow in section II, discussion of the
results and conclusions in sections III and IV.

Received for publication October 26, 1983. Revision accepted


for publication August 21, 1984.

*University of Maryland, College Park and Federal Trade


Commission.

Helpful comments on earlier drafts were obtained from


Ronald Brauetigam, Paul Geroski, David Ravenscraft, and two
referees. My thanks go to Carl Schwinn for his programs
aggregating the CPR data into our economic markets, and to
Paul Bagnoli, John Hamilton and Talat Mahmood for additional computer assistance. The views expressed in this paper
are my own, and should not be assumed to be shared by the
above mentioned gentlemen, any of the FTC staff, or its
commissioners.

1 For surveys of this literature and references to earlier studies


see Markham (1955) and Hogarty (1970).

I. Data and Methodology

Our sample is drawn from Federal Trade Commission surveys for 1950 and 1972 of sales at the

5-digit level for the 1,000 largest companies in


2 For the United States see Weston and Mansinghka (1971);
Melicher and Rush (1974); and Mueller (1980), ch. 9. For
Europe see Meeks (1977); Cowling et al. (1979); and 6 country
studies in Mueller (1980), ch. 3-8.

3For surveys see Steiner (1975), ch. 8; Mueller (1977,1981);


Scherer (1980), pp. 138-141; and Halpern (1982).

[259 1

This content downloaded from 86.164.156.132 on Sun, 24 Jul 2016 17:59:14 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

260 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS

Firm I's market share is assumed to follow a

each year.4 The sample of acquired firms consists


of all companies that were (1) among the 1,000
largest of 1950, and (2) were acquired by a firm
among the 1,000 largest in both 1950 and 1972.
Any company meeting this criterion that was spun
off or sold prior to 1973 was omitted from the
sample. If a company A was acquired by B which
in turn was acquired by C, and A and C met the
criterion, A was included in the sample. When
only a division of a firm was acquired, then this

division was treated as the acquired firm. Using


these criteria a sample of 209 acquired and 123
acquiring companies was constructed.5
Whenever the 5-digit product definition seemed
too disaggregate we aggregated upward until a
more meaningful economic definition of the market
was obtained, placing particular weight on sub-

stitution in production in defining the market.6


Between 1950 and 1972 there were numerous
changes in, SIC product definitions. These changes

required further combining and rearranging of


product lines to match 1950 and 1972 markets.
Fortunately, most industries that could not be
compared had small 1950 sales, so that the percentage of 1950 sales that could not be matched to
1972 markets was only 5.8%, although in some
cases the "match" was admittedly somewhat loose.
Given the changes in market boundaries and
product definitions between 1950 and 1972, a firm's
market share in 1972 in a given 1972 market might
over- or understate what its market share would be
in a truly comparable market. Overstatement can
occur if a market is too broadly defined and tbit
firm has sales in the erroneously included prod-

ucts, or because the market is too narrowly defined


and a larger fraction of the market's sales are
omitted than of the firm's. Understatement can
occur when the errors run in the opposite direction. In general, we have an errors in observation
problem and our estimated coefficients on market
share variables will be biased toward zero. To
control for these biases to some extent, we estimate the effects of mergers on market shares relative to a control group of companies whose 1950
and 1972 market shares. are defined using the same
market definitions as for the merger sample.
4The 1950 survey has been published (FTC, 1972), the 1972
survey has not been released.

5'The list of merging and control group companies is available


from the author.

6 The market definitions used are given in appendix A-2 of


Mueller (1983).

simple first order Markov process over time:


mi t+Io=amit +? Ill
or
n-I

mit

(1)

j=1

Assuming that the weighted sum of errors in (1)


has the usual mean zero, constant variance property across firms, (1) can be estimated using the
1972 and 1950 market share data as
M,=

ami

Ei

(2)

where lower case letters indicate 1950 values and


upper case letters stand for 1972. To test for the
effects of mergers on market share, we test whether

acquired companies have the same estimated a as


a control group of similar size and industry composition to the acquired firms, but were not
acquired between 1950 and 1972. We do this by
defining a dummy variable, D = 1 if the firm was
acquired, and 0 if it is in the control group, and
estimating (3) across the pooled sample.

M, = ami + bDmi + 'i (3)


If mergers have no effect on market share, b
should equal zero. We treat this prediction as the
null hypothesis.

Two modifications are made to (3) in the empirical work. A constant, c, is added to allow for
some "drift" in market shares because our industry definitions in 1950 and 1972 are not a
perfect match. Second degree terms in m are added to allow for a regression-on-the-mean effect for
larger market share firms.

For each company i acquired in a conglomerate


merger, a weighted market share for 1950 was
constructed using its 1950 sales in each market k,
Sik, as weights

m, (ESik 'mik) si (4)

where si = >kSik is i's total 1950 sales.


Firm i's market share in 1972 is computed over
the K markets in 1972 that match the k markets
in 1950 in which i had sales. In a conglomerate
merger 1950 firm i has become 1972 acquiring
firm I. Using I's 1972 sales in each market k as
weights we have

M, = SIK . MK)I s (5)

This content downloaded from 86.164.156.132 on Sun, 24 Jul 2016 17:59:14 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

MERGERS AND MARKET SHARE 261

where S. = EKSIK, and the 72 superscript indi-

cates that 1972 sales weights are used.

and then compute 1950 market shares for the


merging companies using (4).

The use of 1972 sales as weights when comput-

Vertical acquisitions are treated as conglomerate

ing 1972 market shares can in some cases give

acquisitions since both firms are in different in-

misleading results. Consider the following exam-

dustries. The FTC market share data were gathered

ple. Firm i has 1950 sales of 100 in market 1 with

on an establishment basis and include intra-firm

a market share of 0.13 and 200 in market 2 with a

shipments, so the disappearance of acquired com-

market share of 0.10. Its weighted 1950 market

pany shipments into intra-firm transfers following

share is then 0.11 = (0.13 x 100 + 0.10 x

200)/300. In 1972, it has sales of 400 in market I

a vertical acquisition is not a problem.


To measure the effects of mergers on market
shares we selected two control groups of un-

with a market share of 0.12 and zero in market 2.


If its 1972 sales are used as weights to calculate its
1972 market share, one records an increase in

glomerate and horizontal merger samples. To be in

market share from 0.11 to 0.12 = (0.12 x 400 + 0

a control group a company must (1) be in the 1000

x 0)/400, even though the firm lost market share


in both markets. To guard against this bias, we

acquired companies to compare with the con-

largest lists in both 1950 and 1972, and (2) not

have acquired a member of the 1950 list between

also calculate 1972 market shares using 1950 sales

1950 and 1972. The FTC divided the 1950 1000

weights.

largest into the 200 largest, 201-500 largest, and

501-1000 largest. In forming the control groups,

MI = (ESik MIK)S i (6)


While MJ72 in the previous example is 0.12, M150 is

0.04 = (0.12 x 100 + 0 x 200)/300.


The use of these two measures of 1972 market
shares allows us to test the Weston (1970) and

Williamson (1970) hypothesis that conglomerate

mergers improve efficiency by facilitating the redeployment of capital across divisions. Evidence in
favor of this hypothesis would be a significantly
better performance of companies acquired in conglomerate mergers relative to the control group,
when 1972 market shares are calculated using 1972
sales weights (M,72), than when 1950 weights are
used.

We define as horizontal those portions of a

merger in which both the acquiring and acquired


companies had 1950 sales in the same market.7
For horizontal mergers the combined sales of the
two companies in the k markets in which they
both operated in 1950 are compared with the
acquiring firm's sales in the k markets in 1972. Let
q be the acquiring firm, d the acquired company.
For horizontal mergers, we then define i's sales
and market shares as

Sik = Sgk + Sdk, mik = mgk + mdk (7)

companies were chosen at random from the 3 size


categories in the same proportions as exist in the
merger sample. The selection process was con-

tinued until enough firms were drawn so that the

total sales by 2 digit SIC for each control group


roughly equaled those for the merger samples.
There were so many companies acquired from the
pulp and paper industry (SIC 26) that there were
not enough firms left in the 1950 list to bring the
sales of the conglomerate-merger control group up
to the merger sample even when all possible
candidates were included. With this exception, it
was possible to select control group companies
with sales roughly equal to the acquired firms'
sales in 1950. A percentage breakdown of the two

acquired firms' samples and their control groups is


given in table 1.

II. The Results


A. Conglomerate Mergers

All market shares must fall between zero and

one and there is a heavy concentration of market

shares below 0.1, the mean for the acquired firms


is 0.067 in the conglomerate merger sample. This

heavy concentration of observations near the origin


7 Note that an acquired company having some sales in markets
in which the acquiring company had sales, and some in markets
where it did not, appeared in both the conglomerate and
horizontal merger samples. Its market share in each was calculated by aggregating over the j markets appropriate to each
definition.

raises the possibility that a few outliers swing the

regression lines in one direction or another. To

avoid this, we weighted all observations by 1950


sales. The sales weighted equations also yield more
meaningful economic estimates. A 10 percentage

This content downloaded from 86.164.156.132 on Sun, 24 Jul 2016 17:59:14 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

262 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS


TABLE 1.-PERCENTAGE BREAKDOWN OF SAMPLE COMPANIES' 1950 SALES BY 2-DIGIT INDUSTRY

Industry Major Conglomerate Conglomerate Horizontal Horizontal

SIC Industry Merger Merger Merger Merger


Code Group Sample Control Group Sample Control Group

20 Food & Kindred Products .180 .203 .093


21 Tobacco Manufactures .009 .009
22 Textile Mill Products .063 .073 .242
23 Apparel & Related Products .007 .013 .012
24 Lumber & Wood Products .013 .016 .026
25 Furniture & Fixtures .009 .015 .004

.095
0 0
.220
.006
.019
.002

26 Pulp & Paper Products .134 .068 .128 .098


27 Printing & Publishing .006 .004 0 .001
28 Chemicals & Related Products .147 .149 .019 .029
29 Petroleum & Coal Products .008 .008 .128 .113
30 Rubber Products .004 .005 .007 .007
31 Leather & Leather Products 0 0 .013 .023
32

Stone,

Clay

&

Glass

Products

.020

.021

.001

33 Primary Metal Products .062 .056 .113 .097


34 Fabricated Metal Products .042 .062 .016 .035

35 Machinery, Except Electrical .125 .128 .049 .046


36 Electrical Machinery .063 .072 .008 .017
37 Transportation Equipment .080 .128 .140 .188
38 Instruments & Related Products .013 .015 0 .009
39

Miscellaneous

Manufactures

point increase in market share for a company with


$300,000,000 in sales has greater economic significance than the same change for a firm with $30,000
in sales. All reported estimates are for sales
weighted regressions. Results of a similar qualitative nature were obtained from unweighted regres-

.014

.016

.001

declines in market shares of the acquired compa-

nies took place before they were acquired, and that

their post-acquisition performance was no worse


or even better than that of the control group. This

observation would be consistent with the failing


firm hypothesis (Dewey, 1961), or with the hy-

sions, however.

pothesis that takeovers occur to replace poor

The first two equations in table 2 present results


for the basic linear equation including a constant
term to capture market share drift.8 The coefficient
on the m term indicates a high retention of market
share even after 23 years has elapsed for companies in the top 1000 in 1950, which were not
acquired. The coefficient on the Dm term indicates
that companies that were acquired between 1950
and 1972 retained a significantly smaller percentage of their 1950 shares. For example, while
an unacquired firm retained 88.5% of its 1950
market share in 1972 using 1972 sales as weights,
an acquired firm retains but 18% of its 1950 market

managers (Manne, 1965). To test for this alterna-

tive possibility, D was redefined as D (73 YR)/23, where YR is year of acquisition, YR =


50,72. A merger occurring relatively early in the
1950-72 interval receives a heavier weight in the

merger vector than a merger occurring late in the

interval. Control group firms continue to have


D = 0. If the decline in market shares preceded

the acquisitions, this alternative weighting of observations in the Dm vector should reverse the

sign, or at least raise the coefficient of this term.


But it lowers it still further. The coefficients on

Dm are negative and larger in absolute value than

when D is a 0,1 dummy. The relative deteriora-

share.

The mergers in the sample took place throughout

tion in market shares for acquired companies is

the period 1950-72.9 It could be that the relative

more severe, the earlier they occur. Indeed, equa-

tion 3 (4) implies that a firm acquired before 1956


8 Closely analogous results to those reported were obtained
when the intercepts were suppressed.

9 Because our reference point in selecting a sample is firms in


existence and relatively large in 1950, a far smaller percentage
of our mergers took place in the late 1960s than is true for the
population of all firms in existence at each point in time. The
(unweighted) mean year for a merger in the sample is 1961,
virtually the middle of the time period.

(1952) is predicted to have a negative market share


in 1972 when 1950 (1972) sales are used as weights.
It is impossible for a firm to have a negative
market share, and the latter implication of equa-

tions 3 and 4 suggests nonlinearity. When both m2

and DM2 were added to the equation, multicollin-

This content downloaded from 86.164.156.132 on Sun, 24 Jul 2016 17:59:14 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

MERGERS AND MARKET SHARE 263


TABLE 2.-CONGLOMERATE MERGERS
Dependent

Equation Variable c m Dm Dm2 D n R


1 MSO 0.009 0.691 -0.527 1,0 313 .922
2.34 39.23 16.77

2 M72 0.011 0.885 -0.705 1,0 313 .940


2.61 45.02 20.09

3 M5O -0.003 0.727 -0.779 73 - YR 313 .929


0.78 43.49 18.30 23

4 M72 - 0.005 0.933 -1.02 73 - YR 313 .944


1.30 49.24 21.08 23

5 M5O - 0.012 0.750 -2.00 1,0 313 .901


3.31 37.84 12.34

6 M72 -0.017 0.964 -2.77 1,0 313 .920


3.97 42.62 14.93

7 M5O - 0.009 0.753 -4.43 73 - YR 313 .930


3.01 45.35 18.63 23

8 M72 -0.014 0.968 -5.83 73 - YR 313 .946


3.91 52.16 21.95 23

Notes: t-values are under coefficients. All variables and constant weighted by 1950 sales.

earity was present. The best-fit equation for D =


(73 - YR)/23 was one in which a linear relationship between m and M was assumed for the

allow for the downward bias in standard error


estimate without overturning the conclusion that
mergers have resulted in a relative deterioration in

control group firms, but a nonlinear relationship is

the acquired firms' market shares.

assumed for the acquired firms (see equations 7


and 8). The larger an acquired firm's 1950 market
share was, the larger was the percentage loss in its

market share between 1950 and 1972. The same


equations are presented with D defined as a 0,1
dummy in equations 5 and 6. The nonlinear

specification when D is zero or one is inferior, as


judged by R2, to the linear. A comparison of
equations 5 and 6 with 7 and 8 reveals again a
lower coefficient on the D terms when D weights
earlier acquisitions more heavily, however. The
implication from equations 5-8 as from 1-4 is
that the decline in market shares acquired firms
experience relative to the unacquired control group
firms occurred after their acquisition.

Heteroscedasticity was present in both the sales


weighted results reported and the reported, unweighted results based on Gleijser's test (1969).
Efforts to remove heteroscedasticity by reweighting each observation did not yield a choice of
weight that gave homoscedastic residuals for all
obvious choices of scale variable. Although heteroscedasticity is troublesome, coefficients remain unbiased estimates of the true parameters, and inefficiency does not seem so serious a problem,
given that we have 313 observations. Moreover,
the key coefficients on the Dm and DM2 terms are
12 to 22 times their standard errors. Thus, a several
fold expansion of the standard errors is possible to

B. Horizontal Mergers

The first 4 equations in table 3 reproduce results


for the horizontal merger sample and its control
group that parallel those for the conglomerate
mergers reported in table 2. The coefficient on m
indicates that nonacquired companies in the industries in which horizontal mergers occurred were
less successful at retaining their 1950 market shares
through 1972, retaining little more than 50%. But

they were considerably more successful than the


firms engaging in horizontal mergers. A comparison of equations 1 and 2 with 3 and 4 again
reveals that placing heavier weight on earlier
mergers worsens the relative performance of merging firms. A firm acquired in 1950 is projected to
lose all of its market share by 1972 using 1972
sales-weights to calculate M, all but 4% of its 1950
market share using 1950 sales-weights. The earlier
a merger occurred, the worse the relative loss of
market share.

When m2 and DM2 terms were added to the


basic linear equation for the horizontal mergers'
sample, multicollinearity did not appear to be a

problem, although the two coefficients were of


opposite signs. Equations 5 and 6 imply that the
M - m curve for nonacquired companies is concave from below, the curve for merging firms is

This content downloaded from 86.164.156.132 on Sun, 24 Jul 2016 17:59:14 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

264 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS


TABLE 3.-HORIZONTAL MERGERS

n = 176

Dependent

Equation Variable c m Dm m2 Dm2 D R2

1 M50 0.024 0.511 -0.346 1,0 .832


9.57 17.77 7.86

M72

0.027

0.547

-0.403

1,0

.818

9.48 16.94 8.15

3
4

M5O
M72

0.024

0.513

-0.472

73

9.83 18.29 8.57


0.027 0.549 -0.553 73 9.80

17.54

8.99

YR

.840

23
YR .829
23

5 M5O 0.015 0.825 -0.604 -0.936 1.21 1,0 .862


4.65 12.09 9.84 5.38 5.18

6 M72 0.015 0.962 -0.710 -1.22 1.43 1,0 .859


4.07 12.92 10.59 6.44 5.58

7 M5O 0.015 0.826 -0.784 -0.931 1.52 73 - YR .869


4.57 12.44 10.46 5.49 5.22 23
8 M72 0.014 0.966 -0.932 -1.23 1.83 73 - YR .870
4.02 13.51 11.55 6.72 5.82 23
Notes: t-values are under coefficients. All variables and constant weighted by 1950 sales.

convex. The two curves cross at a 1950 market

largest, the other not, the 1972 market share re-

share of around 0.5. Only one pair of companies

flects the contribution of both acquired firms, while


we attribute all of the sales to the one acquired
firm in our sample. The estimate of the merger's
impact on the acquired firm's market share is
biased upward, and this bias could be considerable. For example, St. Regis Paper acquired 3
firms from the 1950-1000 largest list between 1950
and 1972, each is an observation in the sample.
But, the 1973 Moody's Industrial Manual lists
some 53 companies as having been acquired by St.
Regis between 1953 and 1972 alone, and the bulk

involved in a horizontal merger has their combined 1950 market share greater than 0.5. Thus,
equations 5 and 6 predict a decline in market
share for a pair of firms in a horizontal merger
between 1950 and 1972 relative to a nonmerging

firm with the same market share in 1950 as the


combined market share of the merging firms, for
every pair of merging companies save one.

The results for equations 7 and 8 parallel 5 and


6 except that D has been redefined once again to
place heavier weight on the earlier observations.

Both D-coefficients are larger in absolute value.

of these appear to be in the lumber and paper


industries. Our comparison of 1950 and 1972

Thus, this reweighting of observations exaggerates

market shares ignoring these 50 + additional

the curvature of each relationship. The convex

mergers must certainly overestimate any increase

curves in equations 7 and 8 lie beneath their

or underestimate any decline in St. Regis' market

respective curves in 5 and 6 for all 1950 market

shares that occurred.

shares less than 0.56. For all mergers in the sample

The most important biases are for firms like St.

but one, the reweighted curves in 7 and 8 predict

Regis that made numerous acquisitions in the same

relatively lower market shares for merging firms

industries. Numerous mergers in the same industry


are more likely for horizontal mergers. Thus, the

than for nonmerging firms the earlier the merger


occurs.

C. Biases and Caveats

Before drawing conclusions, a few possible bi-

estimates for horizontal acquisitions are more likely


to be biased in favor of finding a positive effect of
mergers on market share than are the conglomerate mergers' estimates. It is important to
recall that for horizontal mergers, 1950 market

ases in the results must be reviewed. The most

shares are defined as the sum of the acquiring and

important of these is that we have data on only

acquired firms' market shares. The nonlinear re-

those acquired companies that were in the top

sults in equations 5-8 of table 3 imply that there


was a smaller loss in market share for merging
firms relative to the control group when the com-

1000 of 1950. If a company acquired two firms


with sales in the same market, one in the 1950-1000

This content downloaded from 86.164.156.132 on Sun, 24 Jul 2016 17:59:14 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

MERGERS AND MARKET SHARE 265

bined market share of the merging firms in 1950

acquired company before 1973 were excluded from

was large. Large 1950 market shares in horizontal

the sample, information allowing an adjustment

mergers tend to be due to the large market shares

for partial acquisitions was lacking. While the

of the acquiring companies. The unrecorded

control group firms also undertook unrecorded

acquisitions of these firms are also likely to be

spinoffs, it is reasonable to assume that spinoffs of

greater in number.

assets acquired through merger are more common

We define as conglomerate any acquisition, or

than internally generated assets. If a bias from

part thereof, where the two firms did not sell in the

ignoring unreported spinoffs were significant, one

same market in 1950. Often the acquiring firm had

would expect acquired firms to perform much

sales in a market neighboring the acquired com-

better when their market shares are measured using

pany's markets, and made several acquisitions in

1972 sales as weights than when 1950 sales are

these besides the one in our sample. In these

used, since the 1972 sales weights allow for the

market-extension conglomerate mergers, a consid-

spinoffs. But the deterioration in market shares for

erable upward bias in our estimates of the benefi-

acquired firms is, if anything, greater when one

cial effects of mergers on market shares is also

uses 1972 sales as weights so that whatever bias

possible. Nevertheless, the greater upward bias is

exists is more than offset by other factors.

probably in the horizontal merger results.


This bias in estimating the impact of mergers is

A bias in favor of a positive effect of mergers on


market shares is introduced by omitting entirely

offset to the extent control group firms also made

all acquisitions in which full spinoffs subsequently

acquisitions during the period in the industries in

occurred. Few firms buy a company, improve its

which they were selling in 1950. While they did, a

performance, and then sell it. A spinoff of an

comparison of the merger histories of the acquir-

acquired firm is, or at least was in the 1950s and

ing and control group companies reveals the former

1960s, an admission of failure. A hint of the

to be far more active in the market for corporate

validity of this conjecture is apparent in the few

control. This finding is not surprising. Any com-

instances in which data on both purchase and sales

pany that was among the 1000 largest in 1950, and

prices of acquired and later spunoff companies are

made many acquisitions over the next 22 years, is

available (see table 4). Taking into account infla-

likely to have acquired at least one other company

tion and the normal growth in asset values that

in the 1950 top 1000, and thus appear in the

occurred in the years between purchase and sale it

merger sample. Whatever bias exists from not

is hard to believe the operating efficiency of these

having data on premerger market shares of

companies improved following their acquisition.

acquired firms not in the 1950-1000 largest group

We expect the same is true of the 9 other spinoffs

leads toward an overestimate of the positive effects

for which no sales price is reported. Were it possi-

of mergers on market share.

ble to calculate market shares for these companies

An opposite bias could be introduced by our

in 1972 and include them in the sample we expect

neglect of spinoffs. Although all acquisitions in

they would reinforce the negative findings regard-

which the acquiring firm sold the previously

ing the effects of mergers.

TABLE 4.-PURCHASE AND SALES PRICES OF SPINOFFS OF 1000 LARGEST AcQuISITIONS

Acquiring Acquired Year Year Purchase Price Sales Price

Firm Firm Acquired Sold $'000 $ '000


Murray

Easy

1955,

57

1963

9,400

770

(Wallace- Washer
Murray)

National Godchaux 1956 1961 14,000 9,600


Sugar Sugar

Kennecott Okonite 1957 1966 31,300 31,700


Copper

Heublin Theo Hamm 1965 1973 62,006 6,000


Source: Moody's Industrial Manual, 1973.

This content downloaded from 86.164.156.132 on Sun, 24 Jul 2016 17:59:14 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

266 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS


The matching of 1950 and 1972 markets is of
varying degrees of accuracy. To the extent these

markets are not fully comparable, errors in


observation are introduced in the market share
data, and regression coefficients are biased toward

zero. The same market definitions have been used


for the merging firms and the control group com-

panies, so that this bias should be removed or


reduced for the variables measuring the impact of
the mergers, the D variables.
III. Discussion
Only one other study has examined the effect of

mergers on market shares. Goldberg (1973)

IV. Conclusion
The results of this paper would seem to require
the rejection or at least reinterpretation of several
leading hypotheses regarding mergers. No support

was found for the hypothesis that mergers improve


efficiency by consolidating the sales of the acquired
companies on their most efficient product lines.
The relative loss in market shares when 1972 sales

are used as weights to calculate 1972 market shares


are about the same or slightly greater than when

M50 is the dependent variable. Acquired firms


perform no better if not worse than nonacquired
companies in those markets in which each chose to
concentrate its sales.

examined a sample of 44 companies acquired in

Smiley (1976) and Mandelker (1974) found that

the fifties and sixties and found no significant

acquired firms had below average stock market

change in market shares or growth rates following

performance prior to their acquisition. These be-

the mergers. The longest time span following a

low average stock market returns may signal the

merger in Goldberg's sample was eleven years, the

declines in market shares we record following a

mean was 3-1/2 (p. 146). The sample used in this

company's acquisition. But if they do, and if it is

paper contains 209 acquired companies with an

bad management that precipitated the acquisi-

average post-acquisition time period of 11 years

tions, then the new management does not appear

and a maximum of 22. Moreover, Goldberg's sam-

to have done much better than the old at improv-

ple was heavily concentrated in advertising-inten-

ing company performance, as measured by com-

sive industries while ours spans all manufacturing.

paring its market share to otherwise similar but

In one important dimension, Goldberg's data

nonacquired companies.

base was richer than ours, however. He was able to

Dewey (1961) expressed the view that mergers

compute growth rates for the acquired firms in the

take place to rescue "falling firms" from bank-

years immediately preceding and following the

ruptcy. Firms acquired between 1950 and 1972 fell

mergers. Our data observations are limited to two

a long way relative to otherwise similar non-

points in time, 1950 and 1972. Goldberg's data

acquired firms. As in all merger studies, we can

allowed him to test for a change in growth rate

never truly test the counterfactual. Perhaps these

following the mergers. He found no significant

companies would have suffered similar or even

change. We were forced to attempt to infer whether

greater market share declines had they not been

observed changes in market shares between 1950

acquired. Assuming this interpretation were cor-

and 1972 preceded or followed the mergers by

rect, our results imply an important modification

reweighting the sample observations by their point

to the "falling firm" hypothesis. At best, mergers

in time.

cushion a company's fall, they do not alter its

In a previous study of 133 mergers between

trajectory. Our results also offer an alternative to

1962 and 1972, I found a significant decline in the

the falling firm hypothesis, namely, the hypothesis

growth rate of the acquiring companies in the five

that the acquired company's fall begins after its

years following the mergers compared with both a

acquisition and that it is the acquisition that causes

matched control group sample, and their industries

the fall in market share.

(1980, pp. 289-291). These results are consistent

As noted in the introduction, however, our re-

with those of the present investigation. Taken to-

gether, Goldberg's study and the two by myself

sults with respect to mergers' effects on market


shares cannot be interpreted as implying anything

strongly imply that mergers in the United States in

directly about mergers' effects on profitability or

the fifties and sixties did not increase the market

shareholder returns. Nevertheless, the relative loss

shares of acquired companies or their growth rates.

in market shares for acquired companies seems

The present study suggests a significant decline in

sufficiently large that it is difficult to believe that


rates of return on assets or sales did not also

market shares.

This content downloaded from 86.164.156.132 on Sun, 24 Jul 2016 17:59:14 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

MERGERS AND MARKET SHARE 267


decline for these companies, relative to the control
group firms. Thus, our results seem in line with
those that find that mergers reduce the profitability of the merging companies (e.g., Meeks, 1977).
Regardless of how these mergers line up along

other lines of merger success, the acquired com-

panies investigated in this paper were unsuccessful


in one important dimension of market competition, their ability to gain and retain customers.
Moreover, their failures in this competition appear

to have come after they were acquired. These


findings, if sustained in future research, raise inter-

esting questions about the motives behind mergers,


and public policy toward them.

REFERENCES

Cowling, Keith, Paul Stoneman, John Cubbin, John Cable,


Graham Hall, Simon Domberger and Pat Dutton,
Mergers and Economic Performance (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1979).
Dewey, Donald, "Mergers and Cartels: Some Reservations
about Policy," American Economic Review 51 (May

Control," Journal of Political Economy 73 (Apr. 1965),


110-120.

Markham, Jesse W., "Survey of the Evidence and Findings on


Mergers," in Business Concentration and Public Policy
(New York: NBER, 1955).
Meeks, Geoffrey, Disappointing Marriage: A Study of the Gains

from Merger (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press,


1977).

Melicher, Ronald W. and David F. Rush, "Evidence on the


Acquisition-Related Performance of Conglomerate
Firms," Journal of Finance 29 (Mar. 1974), 1941-1949.

Mueller, Dennis C., "The Effects of Conglomerate Mergers: A


Survey of the Empirical Evidence," Journal of Banking
Finance 1 (4) (Dec. 1977), 315-347.

(ed), The Determinants and Effects of Mergers: An


International Comparison (Cambridge: Oelgeschlager,
Gunn, & Hain, 1980).

______ "The Case against Conglomerate Mergers," in Roger


D. Blair and Robert F. Lanzillotti (eds.), The Conglomerate Corporation (Cambridge: Oelgeschlager,
Gunn, & Hain, 1981), 71-95.

, The Determinants of Persistent Profits (Washington,


D.C.: Federal Trade Commission, 1983).
Perry, Martin K., and Robert H. Porter, "Oligopoly and the
Incentive for Horizontal Merger," mimeo, Bell Laboratories, 1983.
Ravenscraft, David J., "Structure-Profit Relationships at the

Line of Business Level," this REVIEw 65 (Feb. 1983),


22-31.

1961), 255-262.

Federal Trade Commission, Values of Shipments Data by Product Class for the 1,000 Largest Manufacturing Companies
of 1950 (Washington, D.C., 1972).
______ Statistical Report on Mergers and Acquisitions 1978
(Washington, D.C., 1980).
Gleijser, Herbert, "A New Test for Heteroscedasticity," Journal of the American Statistical Association 64 (Mar.

Salant, Stephen W., Sheldon Switzer, and Robert J. Reynolds,


"Losses from Horizontal Merger: The Effects of an
Exogenous Change in Industry Structure on CoumotNash Equilibrium," Quarterly Journal of Economics 98
(May 1983), 185-199.
Scherer, Frederic M., Industrial Market Structure and Economic
Performance, second edition (Chicago: Rand McNally,
1980).

1969), 316-323.

Goldberg, Lawrence G., "The Effect of Conglomerate Mergers


on Competition," Journal of Law and Economics 16
(Apr. 1973), 137-158.

Halpem, Paul, "Corporate Acquisitions: A Theory of Special


Cases?" mimeo, University of Toronto, 1982.
Hogarty, Thomas F., "Profits from Merger: The Evidence of
Fifty Years," St. Johns Law Review 44 (Spec. Ed.)
(Spring 1970), 378-391.
Judge, George G., William E. Griffiths, R. Carter Hill, and
Tsoung-Chao Lee, The Theory and Practice of Econometrics (New York: Wiley, 1980).
Mandelker, Gershon, "Risk and Return: The Case of Merging
Firms," Journal of Financial Econometrics 1 (Dec. 1974),
303-335.

Manne, Henry G., "Mergers and the Market for Corporate

Smiley, Robert, "Tender Offers, Transactions Costs and the


Firm," this REVIEw 58 (Feb. 1976), 22-32.
Steiner, Peter O., Mergers: Motives Effects, Policies (Ann
Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1975).
Weston, J. Fred, " The Nature and Significance of Conglomerate Firms," St. John's Law Review 44 (Spec. Ed.)

(Spring 1970), 66-80.


Weston, J. Fred, and Surendra K. Mansinghka, "Tests of the
Efficiency Performance in Conglomerate Firms," Journal of Finance 26 (Sept. 1971), 919-936.

Williamson, Oliver E., Corporate Control and Business Behav-

ior: An Inquiry into the Effects of Organization Form on


Enterprise Behavior (Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: PrenticeHall, 1970).

This content downloaded from 86.164.156.132 on Sun, 24 Jul 2016 17:59:14 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

You might also like