Download as docx, pdf, or txt
Download as docx, pdf, or txt
You are on page 1of 3

Public Goods

Some things are free, either because they occur naturally, such as beaches and
mountains, or because they are provided by the government, such as military
protection. From an economic standpoint, there is a problem in analyzing free
goods, which are often referred to as public goods, since they are freely available to
all. Buyers do not pay for public goods nor do sellers provide them, since they
receive nothing for the provision, so there is a market failure by private markets in
allocating resources to produce public goods. Therefore, a different economic
analysis is necessary to determine how resources are allocated.
In distinguishing between private and public goods, it is useful to introduce 2
concepts: exclusion ability and rivalry in consumption.
Exclusion ability is the property whereby a person can be prevented from using that
good. Obviously, private goods have this quality. If you buy food at the supermarket,
then it is yours to eat. You can exclude everyone else from eating it. Rivalry in
consumption is a quality where the use of the good diminishes the supply for others.
If you chop down a tree on public land to supply your fireplace, then that is one less
tree for everyone else. Fishing in the ocean reduces the number of fish for others.
Private Goods
A private good is both excludable and rivalry in consumption, a public good is
neither. Some natural resources are another type of good which are rivalry in
consumption, in that their consumption reduces the supply for others, but they are
not excludable, such as the fish in the ocean.
Sometimes, a good can be excludable but is not rivalry in consumption, such as the
products of a natural monopoly. For instance, software companies are natural
monopolies in that they can supply the entire market for minimal marginal cost, yet
they have the right to exclude its use.
These different qualities of goods are broad general descriptions, not bright line
distinctions. For instance, many natural resources are excludable because their
extraction requires the permission of the landowner. Some public goods are
excludable, but often are not, such as public parking spaces and highways.
Free Riders
When a good is not excludable, then suppliers cannot charge for the benefit of the
good because people can benefit regardless of whether they pay for it or not. For
instance, fireworks are a common example of a good that is not excludable (and
also not rivalry in consumption), so private suppliers will not provide it. With these
types of public goods, people can save money by being free riders, who are people
who can enjoy the benefit of a good without paying for it. This is the reason why
most fireworks are paid for by local governments, since fireworks can be financed
out of general tax revenue, which is collected from everyone. Likewise, national
defense and public safety are provided by governments, since they are required for
any modern economy but they cannot be economically provided by private parties.

Tragedy of the Commons


Most common resources are public goods because they are not excludable.
However, they are rivalry in consumption, because their use diminishes the value or
lessens the quantity available to others. This is best illustrated by the parable of the
Tragedy of the Commons. In medieval times, people raised sheep and allowed them
to graze on common land that was freely available to everyone. When the
population was small, the land could replenish itself on its own. However, as the
population grew, they needed more sheep, so eventually, the land was being grazed
so much, that it could not replenish itself. Eventually, there was not enough
common land to support the number of sheep.
The reason why this occurs is obvious people will not protect what is not their own.
Because anyone can use the land for grazing, no one has any incentive to regrow
the grass, to protect it, or to limit the number of sheep grazing on it. Eventually, the
government started to allow people to enclose a specific amount of land which they
could claim as their own. So it became their duty to maintain their own land and
they could exclude the use of their land by anyone else, a process that began in
England during the 17th century.
The tragedy of the commons not only applies to land but also applies to many wild
animals, such as elephants, which are often killed for their valuable ivory. However,
the most important tragedy of the commons today is the harvesting of fish using
huge nets pulled behind factory ships, where the fish are processed immediately
after they're caught. Because the ships can catch a huge amount of fish, the fishing
stock is being rapidly depleted to the point where they will be unable to repopulate
under continued fishing pressure. Governments have responded to this tragedy by
restricting the size of the fish that can be caught, by regulating the size of the holes
in the fishing nets, establishing quotas that can limit the number of fish that can be
caught, limiting the days that a vessel can fish, restricting fishing to specific
seasons, and protecting the breeding grounds of threatened fish. Some
governments, such as New Zealand, allow quota shares to be bought or sold, and
quotas for halibut can be traded in the United States and Canada. In 1992, Canada
banned cod fishing off the coasts of Newfoundland and Labrador to replenish the
stock. However, no government controls the open oceans, making it difficult to
establish a global policy.
In summary, the government uses several methods to provide public goods or to
prevent the tragedy of the commons, such as granting property rights, so that
people have an incentive to protect the value of the property; it can organize a
system that uses market forces, such as the creation and trading of pollution

permits or fishing quotas. The government can also actually pay for the public good,
such as the military, which consumes the largest part of the United States budget.

Cost-Benefit Analysis
The demand and supply of private goods is largely determined by the market,
where demand is determined by the amount that people are willing to pay and the
supply is determined by the price that sellers receive for their product. The private
market provides pricing information, allowing the market to reach equilibrium when
the marginal benefit to buyers equals the marginal cost of suppliers. Since there is
no market for a public good, the government must do a cost-benefit analysis to
determine if the good should be provided. The method for doing the cost-benefit
analysis will depend on the project, but it probably will not be as accurate as market
information, and, often, the supply of public goods is determined by those with
political influence. Nonetheless, to determine what is socially optimal, the
government should measure the public demand for a good, including the quantity
desired, and how much it will cost to supply that quantity. As with private markets,
the socially optimal quantity of a public good is when the marginal benefit equals
the marginal cost.
A cost-benefit analysis can also be applied to the tragedy of the commons. Because
the marginal cost of a common resource is zero, people will continue to consume
the resource until their marginal benefit is zero. Hence, the resource is consumed,
but not replaced. Therein lies the tragedy.

You might also like