The Cost of Living Jewishly and Jewish Continuity PDF

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 14

THE COST OF LIVING JEWISHLY AND JEWISH CONTINUITY

Author(s): Carmel U. Chiswick and Barry R. Chiswick


Source: Contemporary Jewry, Vol. 21, No. 1 (January 2000), pp. 78-90
Published by: Springer
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/23455314
Accessed: 05-12-2016 15:25 UTC
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted
digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about
JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
http://about.jstor.org/terms

Springer is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Contemporary Jewry

This content downloaded from 79.115.178.193 on Mon, 05 Dec 2016 15:25:38 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

CONTEMPORARY JEWRY

THE COST OF LIVING JEWISHLY

AND JEWISH CONTINUITY


Carmel U. Chiswick
and

Barry R. Chiswick
Department of Economics
University of Illinois at Chicago

Introduction

Like most other Diaspora countries at the turn of the 21st century, the
United States is a free and open society. Long gone are the days when
Jews were compelled by non-Jewish authorities to live in ghettos, to
wear distinctive clothing, or to be otherwise publicly identified so that
their activities could be restricted. Over the course of the last two
centuries these barriers have fallen at a faster or slower rate in various

Diaspora countries, with periods of backsliding and periods of greatly


expanding freedoms and secular opportunities. American Jews are now

to be found in nearly all sectors and major institutions of society business, government, education, professions and the arts.
In this era of freedom the issue of Jewish continuity takes on a

different meaning. Can Judaism and Jewish identity survive from


generation to generation in a free and open society in which one's
Jewishness may be no more significant to others than the city in which

one was born or the baseball team one cheered for as a youth? This
paper will explore both the costs and benefits of living Jewishly and
their effects on American Jewish continuity. Pat II focuses on the costs

faced by Jewish families and their consequences for the American


Jewish community. Part III takes a broader view of Jewish continuity,
looking at the cost of living Jewishly as it affects the marriage and
career choices of young Americans.

The Cost of Jewish Living

Jewish living can be very expensive. ^ Although synagogue

memberships vary considerably as to cost, most of them involve

substantial annual dues (often accompanied by an obligatory

contribution to the "building fund" or its counterpart) as well as a


continuous stream of "opportunities" to make additional contributions
for special occasions or causes. Yet only one third of all American Jews
affiliate with a synagogue, and it is estimated that typically less than

three percent of Jewish family income is allocated to Jewish


philanthropies and synagogue memberships (Kosmin 1988; B.
Chiswick 1991; Kosmin 1991; Rebhun 1997). Compared to other

This content downloaded from 79.115.178.193 on Mon, 05 Dec 2016 15:25:38 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

CHISWICK

American religious groups the financial obligation associated with


Jewish living is fairly high, but not extremely so. Even considering

such collateral expenses as Jewish education, summer camps, or

Bar/Bat Mitzvahs, few Jewish families spend as much of their income

as the 10 percent tithe expected in some Protestant denominations.


Indeed, by any objective standard the American Jewish community can
well afford to sustain itself and support its own institutions.

So why does everyone say that Judaism is so expensive? One


reason is because Judaism tends to be a very time-intensive religion

and time budgets are seriously constrained. We speak of "spending"


time on an activity, of being unable to "afford" the time for everything

we'd like to do, and of avoiding activities that "waste" time because
they preclude spending it on a "better" alternative. Although money

incomes have risen during the last century, the amount of time
available for daily life is relatively fixed, effectively constrained (despite
a shorter work week and longer life expectancy) by the finiteness of the
day, year and life. The value of a unit of time is now very high, in part
because of the generally high productivity of American workers, in part
because of the relatively high skill levels of American Jews, and in part
because of the expanding array of non-work opportunities available to

American consumers. Indeed, it is the value of time in these many


activities that effectively measures the value of scarce time. 2
Although turn-of-the-century Jewish immigrants to America may

have been fairly traditional in their Jewish observance by today's

standards, most of them were not especially religious by the standards

of their own era. Indeed, the Jewish observance of immigrants was


typically casual at best, the perception being that old-countiy Judaism

was "unsuited" to life in the New World (i.e., "too" expensive). In


this context the major American synagogue movements (mainly the
Reform, Conservative and "modern" Orthodox) were accepted as
religious innovations that adapted Judaism to its modem environment,
primarily by reducing the time cost of Jewish observance (C. Chiswick

1995, C. Chiswick 1999). Religious innovations that raise the

efficiency of Jewish resources constitute a decline in the real cost of


being Jewish and a net gain for Jewish consumers, and indeed this is
the economic basis for the strength of these "modern" forms of Judaism
in the United States today.

Yet social innovations often have unintended consequences, and


the changes introduced by American streams of Judaism may be
perceived as reducing the quality of Jewish living in some respects even

as they increase it in others. Recent research on the economics of


religion suggests that religions most vulnerable to such a decline in
quality would share certain characteristics, including an important
social dimension to the life of the religious group and an emphasis on

religious "human capital" (Iannaccone 1988; Iannaccone 1990;

This content downloaded from 79.115.178.193 on Mon, 05 Dec 2016 15:25:38 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

79

80

CONTEMPORARY JEWRY

Iannaccone 1992). Both of these characteristics are very important to

Judaism, and their economic implications apply a fortiori to the


experience of American Jews. In effect, they raise the possibility that

reductions in the cost of Jewish living have been accompanied by a


decline in the quality of Jewish experience that at least partially offsets
the gain in communal welfare. The remainder of this section presents a
brief sketch of the economic analysis as it applies to American Judaism.

A religious group may be thought of as a special kind of "club"


which people can join for motives which are essentially social rather
than (or as well as) spiritual (Iannaccone 1988). In this respect Judaism
must compete with other "clubs" for the money, time and energy of its

members. Such competition may have been unimportant when Jews


were restricted in their memberships outside the community, but in
today's environment of freedom Jews participate widely and actively in

many social groups and political organizations. This expanded

opportunity alone would imply a reduced amount of time and other


resources spent on Jewish organizations (holding everything else
constant), and hence less participation in Jewish life (B. Chiswick

1991). But the sense of belonging to a group (whether family,


synagogue, community, or the entire Jewish People) is deeply

embedded in Jewish ritual, to the point where attempts to separate


religious adherence from Jewish identity (peoplehood) are often artificial

at best. Where the social and spiritual dimensions of Judaism are


inextricably entwined, substituting secular for religious social activities
necessarily carries with it some decline in the intensity or quality of
religious observance.
The decline in the quality of Jewish life is further exacerbated by a
"bandwagon" effect in reverse. Members who participate actively in any

social group typically raise the value of belonging not only for
themselves but for other members as well, effectively increasing the

efficiency of resources (expenditures of time and money) for all


members. People thus tend to be attracted to groups in which others
participate actively, and there is a disincentive to join groups in which

participation by others is marginal. Jewish institutions and

organizations are especially vulnerable to this bandwagon effect because

of the interaction between spiritual and social values, whereby the


spiritual life of the community is adversely affected when participation

declines. So as more people devise Jewish lifestyles that involve

relatively low time on their own part, those who continue to devote a
high level of resources to Jewish life would find that they are obtaining
less satisfaction than before. As a result, they can be expected to reduce
their own expenditures of time and money on Jewish life.
The importance of religious human capital for Judaism can scarcely
be exaggerated. Often associated with Jewish education and scholarship,
religious human capital includes any knowledge or skill that raises the

This content downloaded from 79.115.178.193 on Mon, 05 Dec 2016 15:25:38 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

CHISWICK

efficiency of resources devoted to current religious observance but has


no corresponding effect on efficiency for secular activities (lannaccone
1990). Religious human capital is acquired through previous activities,

not only religious education (formal or informal) but also through

experience with Jewish family, synagogue and community life. Perhaps


the best example of Jewish human capital is the Hebrew language itself;
the role of which is so important that basic religious education is often

called "Hebrew School." Knowledge of Hebrew has virtually no


implications for American Jews in their secular activities. Yet even a
rudimentary grasp of that language contributes greatly to the value of
any Jewish experience, and a sophisticated knowledge of Hebrew is an
entre into the rich body of literature at the core of Jewish intellectual
life.

Knowledge tends to beget knowledge, and the high levels of


secular education characteristic of American Jews can be expected to
facilitate (i.e., increase the efficiency of) Jewish learning. Yet because
skill-formation activities tend to be fairly time-intensive, making them
especially costly for a population with many attractive alternative uses
of time, the trends in Jewish education have been ambiguous at best

and often on the decline (Wertheimer 1989; Fishman and Goldstein


1993). A decline in Jewish participation for any reason, including the

social motives discussed above, carries with it the implication of a


reduction in the time spent in Jewish experience, a major avenue for
acquiring the memories, knowledge, and skills which are an important
component of Jewish human capital.

American Judaism is especially vulnerable to this decline in


religious human capital not only because it is a skill-intensive religion
(using a language that has little or no secular value) but also because of
the centrality of intergenerational continuity to Judaism itself. Parents
teach Judaism to their children in part by example and in part through
the integration of Jewish experience into ordinary family life. Low
levels of Jewish observance in the home, perhaps because low levels of
human capital make Jewish observance a less satisfying activity, give
children fewer opportunities to acquire Jewish skills and memories.
Thus a decline in Jewish human capital for one generation can have a
cascading effect on succeeding generations, a downward spiral that can
seriously erode the quality of Jewish life not only for the individual but
also for the community as a whole.

The American Jewish community has been mindful of these


concerns and remedial steps have been (and are being) taken. Indeed,

American Jewish culture exhibits many examples of an increase in

Jewish education and experiences in many dimensions of its intellectual


and spiritual life. Yet at the same time there have developed a variety of
Jewish lifestyles compatible with very high values of time and very low
levels of Jewish human capital. These Jewish identities require little or

This content downloaded from 79.115.178.193 on Mon, 05 Dec 2016 15:25:38 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

81

CONTEMPORARY JEWRY

82

no religious education and emphasize elements common to Judaism


and the non-Jewish society in which Jews live and work. To the extent

that these Jewish lifestyles have been accepted by the Jewish

community, they further reduce the incentive to acquire Jewish human


capital and thus contribute to the perception of a decline in the quality

of Jewish life.

Consider a continuum along which American Jews would be


ranked not by their religious beliefs or even practices but by the
importance of specifically Jewish human capital for their preferred
lifestyle. At one extreme would be those who ignore (or characterize as

"obsolete") Jewish religious ritual, who avoid associating themselves


with the particularistic aspects of Jewish society, or who limit their
definition of Judaism to its humanistic or universalistic precepts. At the

other extreme would be those who emphasize specifically Jewish


culture in any of its various manifestations, not only as religious ritual
but also as politics, literature, history and the arts. The former would

see little point to investments in Jewish human capital, focusing


instead on acquiring skills that are of general use for both work and
leisure in the larger society. But everywhere else along the continuum

there would be some benefit to acquiring Jewish knowledge and


experience, so the optimal investment decisions would include some
Jewish as well as general human capital.
Although American Jews have experimented with lifestyles nearly
all along this continuum, economic incentives tend to discourage those
in the center of the continuum. Many attractive alternatives compete
with Judaism for their time, and high levels of secular human capital
raise productivity in these other activities. The implicit cost of Jewish
life is thus veiy high. If Judaism is perceived as an inferior choice the

optimal response would be to allocate less time to it, thus beginning


the downward spiral that leads to low levels of Jewish human capital
and little commitment to Jewish communal life. If instead Judaism is

perceived as a valuable "economic good" the optimal response would


be to raise efficiency by acquiring more Jewish human capital, making
Jewish life more satisfying and further stimulating the time and effort
devoted to Jewish activities and communal participation. Both of these
economically "rational" responses have contributed to the paradox of
American Judaism described by one observer as "apathy and renewal"
(Wertheimer 1993).
Love and Work

The cost of Jewish living in a free and open Diaspora community goes
beyond the immediate concern with expenditures of money and time,
whether on current activities or on investments in Jewish human capital
for the future. "Jewish living" refers to a lifestyle, and lifestyle choices

have implications for selection of a mate and for labor market

This content downloaded from 79.115.178.193 on Mon, 05 Dec 2016 15:25:38 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

CHISWICK

opportunities. To the extent that different Jewish lifestyles impose


different constraints, they may be viewed as having different cost

implications for these two spheres of activity. Each of these very

personal decisions on the part of individual Jews can collectively have


an enormous impact on the Jewish community as a whole.
Marriage is an enterprise that entwines two persons in multiple
aspects of their adult lives, especially in the family life that they share
as parents, as adult siblings, as cousins, and as the children of aging

seniors. Although romantic love can strike anywhere, selection of a


marriage partner is inevitably influenced by the potential for mutual
productivity gains associated with this enteiprise. For various reasons,

human capital characteristics are generally subject to positive

assortative mating in this selection process (homogomy), so that


highly educated, very healthy, or especially attractive men and women
tend to marry each other, as do those with low levels of these desirable

traits (Becker 1981; C. Chiswick and Lehrer 1991). A lifestyle that


makes heavy use of Jewish human capital is far easier (less costly) to

sustain with a partner who has chosen a similar lifestyle, and the
human capital intensity of Jewish observance enhances the gains from
marriage the higher the spouse's level of Jewish human capital. The
greater the human capital intensity of one's Jewish lifestyle, the greater
the gain from marriage to a person with more Jewish human capital and
the lower the likelihood of selecting a non-Jewish partner. Conversely a
lifestyle in which specifically Jewish human capital plays little role
extends the pool of potential marriage partners by including non-Jews
whose religious human capital is similarly non-specific, or specific to
another religion that is less family oriented.

If there are many human capital attributes to which the marriage


market is sensitive, the complexity of the search process is greatly
reduced by the tendency for them to be mutually correlated with each

other. The highly educated tend to devote more resources to

maintaining good health and vice versa, for example, and people with
high skill levels in the workplace are more efficient at developing high

skills related to home and family (Michael 1973; Becker 1981). But

Jewish human capital seems to be something of an exception, in part


because of the destabilizing forces discussed in the previous section of

this paper. So the marriage market in which Jews participate is


effectively sorting on two dimensions, one being a bundle of various
types of secular attributes and the other a somewhat smaller bundle of
Jewish skills and experiences. Those persons whose Jewish lifestyle is
towards the low end of the Jewish human capital continuum will be
sorting primarily on the secular dimension, while those at the high end

of the Jewish human capital continuum will be sorting on both

dimensions simultaneously. Searching simultaneously on both secular


and Jewish dimensions introduces the possibility of tradeoffs and hence

This content downloaded from 79.115.178.193 on Mon, 05 Dec 2016 15:25:38 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

83

CONTEMPORARY JEWRY

84

a "poorer" outcome with respect to one or the other (secular vs. Jewish)

attributes.

The pool of potential marriage partners is also much larger for


those satisfied by low levels of Jewish human capital, for it includes
many non-Jews with similarly low levels of religious human capital.

The 20th century has seen the breakdown of many social barriers
between Jews and non-Jews, virtually removing the adverse effects for
Jews of residential segregation and discrimination in higher education,
the labor market, clubs, etc. With the expansion of social interactions
between Jews and non-Jews there is less of the anti-Jewish prejudice
that would make interfaith dating and interfaith marriage unacceptable
to the non-Jewish party. Taken together with reduced levels of religious
human capital in many non-Jewish groups, this further reduces the
proportion of Jews in the relevant potential marriage market pool. The
number of non-Jewish potential marriage partners in the United States
can be substantial, since Jews comprise only two percent of the total

population and less than four percent of the college educated (B.
Chiswick 1992; Goldstein 1992; B. Chiswick 1993; C. Chiswick
1995).3
Jewish lifestyles also vary considerably in the extent to which they
impose costs when Jewish identity or observance interferes with secular
educational attainment and with the labor force processes of hiring,
promotion and career advancement. For many these costs may be small
or trivial, while for others they may be substantial. Undoubtedly, the
cost is larger the greater the extent of involvement in visible Jewish

practices. In the corporate or academic world (outside of Jewish


Studies) wearing a kipa might be considered embarrassingly parochial,
observing kashrut perceived as irrational, and not working on Shabbat
and Jewish holidays viewed as a sign of low commitment to firm or
profession.^ These are certainly not new issues, but neither have they

entirely disappeared with the reduction of social barriers between

American Jews and non-Jews.

While such costs may be reduced by entering a sheltered sector of


the economy (for example, Jewish communal service, the rabbinate or a
profession in which these penalties are smaller), this has little appeal for
most American Jews. Jews are too diverse in their career choices, and
too small a minority in most of occupations, for the development of an
enclave economy which would not substantially limit the scope of their

labor force activities and hence incomes. Moreover, most American

Jews value their interactions with the non-Jewish world and believe

that the Jewish community as a whole would be disadvantaged if the


observant were to be segregated into a "Jewish" economic sphere. Yet

the secular labor market, nevertheless, imposes a cost to Jewish

observance that is greater the greater the "visibility" of Jewish practice

This content downloaded from 79.115.178.193 on Mon, 05 Dec 2016 15:25:38 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

CHISWICK

85

and the closer its adherence to the Jewish calendar and rhythms of daily

life (C. Chiswick 1996).

Throughout the first half of the 20th century, Jewish

"assimilation" referred to integration into the larger society and was


viewed as a highly desirable goal in itself as well as a prerequisite for
financial and political security. Jewishness itself was taken for granted
as an ascribed characteristic which could not be shed, but which might
become transparent in an "Americanized" Jewish community. By the
end of the century it was economic and social integration that was taken
for granted by American Jews and "assimilation" refers to the loss of
Jewish identity associated with outmarriage and apathy. Human capital
has played a key role in this reversal, for in the earlier period Jews
allocated most of their educational investments to secular achievements
without fully appreciating the extent to which Judaism requires Jewish
specific human capital to sustain itself in an open society (C. Chiswick

1999).

Policy Recommendations
The Jewish community has made many adjustments to enhance its
intergenerational continuity as a religious group, focusing its concern

on both the number of Jews and the content of what it means to be

Jewish in a modem, democratic, free Diaspora. Even so, the American


Jewish community has not yet stabilized and the challenges that remain

are enormous. The economic perspective developed in this paper is


suggestive of some directions for continuing adjustment in the future.
Jewish continuity requires the transmission of Jewish knowledge,
skills, experiences and memories. These must be imparted to Jewish

youth by their parents (many of whom may require education


themselves in order to fill this role) and by Jewish institutions in the
community. Yet they can not come at the expense of the high level of
secular education that not only generates economic security but also
constitutes an important aspect of American Jewish identity. Moreover,
the suburban Jewish community of today can not benefit from the
concentrated residence patterns of the past, whether a European-style
ghetto or a densely Jewish urban neighborhood. Thus the formation of

Jewish human capital must rely on a system of Jewish education,


whether formal or informal, that supplements and reinforces the secular

education received by Jewish children.5 Jewish day schools that


combine the secular and Jewish subjects are promising in this respect,
insofar as they educate youth to live and work simultaneously in both

the secular and Jewish spheres. Yet much of Jewish human capital
requires maturity beyond childhood, suggesting the need to develop
comparable institutions for the education of older youths and adults.
The expansion of Jewish education will be very expensive (in both
time and money), and even families who desire Jewish continuity may

This content downloaded from 79.115.178.193 on Mon, 05 Dec 2016 15:25:38 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

86

CONTEMPORARY JEWRY

find it too great a sacrifice. Greater emphasis needs to be placed in fund

raising on the importance of Jewish education for continuity. Yet


contributions to Jewish philanthropies are under increased competitive
pressure as declines in Jewish identity, increases in secular activities,
and rising intermarriage rates have all been associated with a shift in
giving toward non-Jewish causes (B. Chiswick 1991). At this point in
American Jewish history the will to acquire a Jewish education may be
the key factor in the decision to finance it. Perhaps a redirection of
fiindraising priorities would be appropriate, placing less emphasis on

the amount of money to be raised and more on the function of


contributions (of time and/or money) as an expression of Jewish
identity. A reappraisal of priorities may also be necessary for the
expenditures of philanthropic dollars. With the low birth rate and

consequent aging of the American Jewish population, many

communities find themselves providing high-quality services to the


aged but low-quality services for youth. A partial redirection of
resources from the aged to the young may be a necessary adjustment for
Jewish communal survival, and one would hope that the grandparents
would appreciate the importance of this reallocation of resources.
While hardly a panacea for the American Jewish community, the

school choice/school voucher movement has some promising

implications (Wertheimer 1999b). Zero-tuition public schools present


tough competition for tuition-charging Jewish day schools. A voucher
program that successfully levels the playing field by reducing (or
eliminating) the discrepancy in the money cost for the two types of
schooling may be very effective in promoting Jewish education among
American youth. Moreover a substantial increase in Jewish school
enrollments would permit "economies of scale," reducing the average
commuting time for Jewish students, encouraging the development of
new educational materials and techniques, and lowering the cost per
student of providing Jewish schooling.
Although much Jewish human capital is formed in the home, there

are many parents who largely missed out on this aspect of Jewish
education when they were young. Rather than viewing them as a lost

generation, they should be viewed as an opportunity. "Night school"


was an essential part of the American education of adult Jewish
immigrants at the turn of the 20th century. A new night school
movement may be needed for the Jewish education of young adults at
the turn of the 21st century. The facilities exist in synagogues, JCCs
and Jewish day schools, and most are already providing some form of

adult education. But its scope needs to be broadened, including

community-wide efforts that promote the idea that "Jewish education is


not just for children anymore" and that continuity begins with Jewishly
educated and involved parents.

This content downloaded from 79.115.178.193 on Mon, 05 Dec 2016 15:25:38 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

CHISWICK

87

While out-marriage should be recognized as symptomatic of low


levels of Jewish human capital, reducing the relative cost of in-marriage
should be a high priority for the American Jewish community. Surely
the synagogues should try to develop roles for Jewish singles, whether
teenagers or adults, that would integrate them into the community as
well as providing a social outlet. Yet it is on the college and university
campuses, while in undergraduate, graduate or professional school, that

so many youths find their mates. Hillel Houses (or a comparable


institution) can serve a useful function there, but they require
imaginative programming and perhaps more linkages to other Jewish
communal institutions.

If the entire community would probably benefit by paying more


attention to the Jewish potential of its youth, the traditional two-parent,

and the increasingly common single-parent, Jewish family also needs to


be better integrated into Jewish communal life. Synagogues, Jewish

Community Centers and Jewish summer camps need to be more

responsive in their dues/fee structures to lower income households. The

increasing family orientation of synagogues is a plus. Yet most


communal institutions need to broaden their approach so as to

incorporate single-parent families and Jewish singles of all ages into

their structures.

Workplace barriers to Jews have fallen dramatically over the past


century. Yet many professions (outside of Jewish communal service
itself) still present barriers to members who wish to combine Jewish
religious practice with full participation in their profession. The goal
should be that Jewish religious practice should not have to come at the
expense of occupational choice and professional advancement. Usually
this merely requires raising the level of consciousness of others, but
sometimes it may require legal action. Always, however, it requires the
support of other Jews, for nothing is more undermining of the exercise
of Jewish observance than the lack of support from Jewish colleagues
who prefer other lifestyles. The community as a whole needs to focus
attention on mutual supportiveness among Jews and to work toward
removal of remaining workplace barriers, whether implicit or explicit.
Judaism has survived 3,500 years, mostly in Diaspora. There has

been no period in which Judaism and Jewish continuity has been


achieved without cost, and today is no exception. Jews and Judaism
have in the past shown a remarkable resilience to stresses introduced by
these costs and by changes in the secular world around them. Surely
modern Jewry should be able to do the same. Indeed, the ingredients
exist for a successful response to the challenges ahead in the early 21st
century United States. All that is required is the imagination and will
of a committed Jewish community.

This content downloaded from 79.115.178.193 on Mon, 05 Dec 2016 15:25:38 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

CONTEMPORARY JEWRY

NOTES

1 For an interesting estimate of the out-of-pocket costs for various


categories of Jewish expenditures see (Monson and Feldman 1995).

2 By this measure even children can have a high value of time. For
example, time in Hebrew school competes with time for secular school

studies as well as the myriad of after-school and weekend activities


ranging from ballet lessons to football practice.

3 Suppose, for example, that by ignoring Jewish human capital a


person would be willing to consider as a potential spouse any highly
educated person (which for the sake of this example would include all
Jewish partners). Then the pool of potential partners would be 25 times
larger than if it were limited to Jews only. Even if only 40 percent of
these non-Jews were available because of the low specificity of their
own religious human capital, the pool of potential marriage partners
would still be larger by a factor of ten.

4 As but one example of the cost of Shabbat observance, many


academic professional associations now schedule their meetings over
the weekend to take advantage of reduced airfares if there is a Saturday
overnight and the lower hotel room rates on weekends. Or consider the

long-time Shabbat-observing employee who Chrysler Corporation


wishes to fire after reassigning him to a shift that includes Friday night

(Forward 1997).

5 See (Wertheimer 1999) for an excellent delineation of the Jewish


education system in the U.S.

This content downloaded from 79.115.178.193 on Mon, 05 Dec 2016 15:25:38 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

CHISWICK

REFERENCES

Becker, Gary S. (1981). A Treatise on the Family. Cambridge, Mass:


Harvard University Press.

Chiswick, Bany R. (1991). "An Economic Analysis of Philanthropy"


in Contemporary Jewish Philanthropy in America. B. A. Kosmin

and P. Ritterband. Savage (Maryland): Rowman & Littlefield, 3

15.

. (1992). "The Postwar Economy of American Jews" Studies


in Contemporary Jewry 8. New York: Oxford Press, 85-101.

. (1993). "The Skills and Economic Status of American


Jewry: Trends over the Last Half Century." Journal of Labor
Economics 11 (1, Part 1: Essays in Honor of Jacob Mincer), 229

242.

Chiswick, Carmel U. (1995). "The Economics of American Judaism."


Shofar, 13(4): 1-19.

(1996). "Israel and American Jewry in the Year 2020: An

Economic Analysis" in The Macro Scenarios: Israel and the


Jewish People. A. Gonen and S. Fogel. Haifa: The Technion, 257
272.

. (1999). "The Economic Adjustment of Immigrants: Jewish


Adaptations to the United States" in Roberta R. Farber and Chaim

Waxman (eds.), Jews in America: A Contemporary Reader.

Brandis University Press: 16-27.

Chiswick, Carmel U. and Evelyn L. Lehrer (1991). "Religious


Intermarriage: An Economic Perspective." Contemporary Jewry,

12,21-34.

Fishman, Sylvia Barack and Alice Goldstein (1993). "When They Are
Grown They Will Not Depart: Jewish Education and the Jewish
Behavior of American Adults," Cohen Center for Modern Jewish
Studies, Brandis University.
Forward, "Shabbath Observer Faces Firing at Chrysler," December 26,

1997, p.3.
Goldstein, Sidney (1992). "Profile of American Jewry: Insights from

the 1990 National Jewish Population Survey." American Jewish


Yearbook 1992.

This content downloaded from 79.115.178.193 on Mon, 05 Dec 2016 15:25:38 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

CONTEMPORARY JEWRY

Iannaccone, Laurence R. (1988). "A Formal Model of Church and


Sect." American Journal of Sociology 94 (Supplement), S241
S268.

. (1990). "Religious Practice: A Human Capital Approach."


Journal for the Scientific Study of Religion, 29(3), 297-314.

. (1992). "Sacrifice and Stigma: Reducing Free-riding in


Cults, Communes, and Other Collectives." Journal of Political
Economy, 100(2), 271 -291.

Kosmin, Barry A. (1988). Understanding Contemporary American


Jewry: Implications for Planning. New York, CUNY Graduate
Center, North American Jewish Data Bank.

. (1991). "The Dimensions of Contemporary American Jewish


Philanthropy" in Contemporary Jewish Philanthropy in America.

B. A. Kosmin and P. Ritterband. Savage (Maryland): Rowman &


Littlefield, 17-30.

Michael, Robert T. (1973). "Education and the Derived Demand for


Children." Journal of Political Economy 81(2, part 2): S128
S164.

Monson, Rela Geffen and Ruth Pinkenson Feldman (1995). "The


Cost of Living Jewishly in Philadelphia." Journal of Jewish
Communal Service, 148-159.

Rebhun, Uzi (1997). "Similarities and Dissimilarities in National and


Community Surveys: The Case of American Jews." Papers in
Jewish Demography 1993, 55-78.

Wertheimer, Jack (1989). "Recent Trends in American Judaism" in


American Jewish Yearbook. 89, 63-162.

. (1993). A People Divided: Judaism in Contemporary

America. New York: BasicBooks.

. (1999a). "Jewish Education in the United States: Recent

Trends and Issues." American Jewish Yearbook 1997. New York:


American Jewish Committee: 3-115.

. (1999b). "Who's Afraid of Jewish Day Schools?"

Commentary (December 1999): 49-53.

This content downloaded from 79.115.178.193 on Mon, 05 Dec 2016 15:25:38 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

You might also like