MUELLER Competitive Pricing Within Pharmaceutical Classes

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 10

Eur J Health Econ (2015) 16:7382

DOI 10.1007/s10198-013-0555-3

ORIGINAL PAPER

Competitive pricing within pharmaceutical classes: evidence


on follow-on drugs in Germany 19932008
Michael T. Mueller Alexander Frenzel

Received: 15 August 2013 / Accepted: 11 December 2013 / Published online: 27 December 2013
Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2013

Abstract classes with a low degree of therapeutic differentiation.


Objectives Competition from follow-on drugs has Prices remain relatively constant over time.
been a highly controversial issue. Manufacturers launching Conclusion This study contributes to assessments of
new molecules in existing drug classes have often been competition in pharmaceutical markets focusing on price
criticized for inflating health systems expenses, but it has strategies of new market entrants. After an initial phase of
been argued that such drugs increase therapeutic options. market building, further follow-on products induce price
Economic theory suggests that follow-on drugs induce competition. Largely unchanged prices after 4 years may
price competition. We contribute to this discussion by be interpreted as quality competition and can be attributed
addressing the topic of pricing at market entry and price to prices in Germany being anchor points for international
development in the German market. price referencing.
Methods We measure determinants of price strategies of
follow-on drugs using regression analyses, considering all Keywords Pharmaceuticals  Pricing  Me-too drugs 
new molecules launched in the German market from 1993 Therapeutic classes
to 2008. Prices of products are standardized on defined
daily dosages controlling for sales volumes based on data JEL Classification I11  I18  L11  L13  L52  L65
from the IMS Health DPM database and for the therapeutic
quality of a new product using ratings by Fricke/Klaus as a
proxy for innovation. Introduction
Results We identify prices correlating with therapeutic
value at market entry. While the first two molecules engage Competition within therapeutic drug classes from follow-
in quality competition, price discounts below the market on or me-too drugs has been a highly controversial
price can be observed from the third entrant on. Price issue. Manufacturers launching therapeutic substitutes in
discounts are even more distinct in development races with existing drug classes have often been criticized for inflating
several drugs entering the market within 2 years and in health systems expenses and misallocating R&D resources
while providing little or no incremental therapeutic benefit
to patients [13]. On the other hand, it has been argued that
such drugs increase therapeutic options [4, 5] and that the
M. T. Mueller (&) commercialization is the result of R&D races between
Lehrstuhl fur Institutionenokonomik und
manufacturers in many cases [69]. With regards to market
Gesundheitssystemmanagement, Universitat Witten/Herdecke,
Alfred-Herrhausen-Str. 50, 58448 Witten, Germany impact, economic theory suggests that follow-on drugs
e-mail: michael.t.mueller@gmail.com induce price competition, which has been confirmed for
unregulated markets in selected analyses [913].
A. Frenzel
We contribute to this discussion by addressing the topic
IMS Health GmbH & Co. OHG, Darmstadter Landstr. 108,
60598 Frankfurt, Germany of pricing at market entry and price development in the
e-mail: AFrenzel@de.imshealth.com German market. We adapt a methodology used by Lu and

123
74 M. T. Mueller, A. Frenzel

Comanor [10], henceforth LC, in the USA as well as influence on launch prices. Although the regulator is
Ekelund and Persson [14], henceforth EP, in the price- granting higher premiums at market entry, the price trend
regulated Swedish market. Conducting the analysis with 4 years after entry is characterized by a decline across
the distinct focus on competition within pre-existing drug classes. This result is in line with the price-cap regulation
classes, we aimed to evaluate price strategies of follow-on in Sweden which does not permit price increases across the
drugs and their consequences in the German market. overall product portfolio on manufacturer level.
The paper is structured as follows: First we review Studies on pricing at market entry in Germany have
previous research to develop our hypotheses and then focused on selected parameters of competition or the ana-
introduce the data and methods used. The results are out- lysis of specific therapeutic classes so far. Kanavos et al.
lined and discussed and the paper concludes with impli- [12] compare price effects arising from the entrance of
cations for further research. additional competitors in the class of statins across four
European countries. In this limited sample, they find pre-
miums in Germany for two of the four follow-on drugs
Previous research and hypotheses which maintain these price points over time. Haussler et al.
[9] make the first distinct assessment of competition from
Previous research follow-on drugs in the German market describing price and
volume effects in 12 therapeutic classes. They find that
LC conducted a holistic assessment of new molecule new molecules enter the market with price discounts,
pricing for the period from 1978 to 1987 in the USA, thereby limiting price increases and inducing price com-
identifying the therapeutic value and the competitive petition among existing branded substitutes. Price compe-
environment in the respective markets as main explanatory tition among existing brands is also further reinforced by
variables for price setting. LC confirm previous empirical the existence of generics.
findings [1517] on imitative pricing strategies for thera-
peutically equivalent drugs and premiums for innovations. Hypotheses
They also find markups for acute and discounts for chronic
drugs hinting at skimming and penetration strategies Like in the USA, the German Statutory Healthcare Insurance
respectively. Intensified competition from an increasing (SHI) system allows free pricing. Prices actually paid in the
number of branded substitutes at market entry leads to USA may, however, be determined by price regulations in
additional price discounts, whereas an increasing share of public programs as well as discounts negotiated with Phar-
generic competition, weakening the competitive position of macy Benefit Management companies [19]. In Germany, list
existing molecules, allows an additional premium. prices historically were fully reimbursable within the SHI
For the price development of new drugs 48 years after system. With the introduction of reference pricing for on-
launch, LC find proof of skimming for innovative as well patent drugs in 2005 and the benefit analysis introduced as
as acute and penetration strategies for therapeutically part of the Arzneimittelmarktneuordnungsgesetz (AMNOG)
equivalent as well as chronic drugs. An increasing number in 2011, the reimbursement level of new drugs can, however,
of competitors have an additional depressing effect on be limited. Prices actually paid may also vary depending on
prices, whereas competition from off-patent drugs does not rebate contracts for on-patent drugs that can be negotiated
influence price trends. between individual sickness funds and manufacturers from
In a more recent descriptive assessment with focus on 2007 on [20].
launches in the USA from 1995 to 1999, DiMasi [18] Yet, for our observation period from 1993 to 2008, we
confirms LCs results. He finds relative price premiums for expect results at market entry to be closely related to LCs
innovations and drugs used in acute conditions as well as findings for the US market (hypothesis 1). As we focus on
price discounts taken when the number of competitors pre-established therapeutic classes only, price premiums
increases. for more innovative drugs should, however, be less
EP adopt LCs approach for an analysis of the Swedish prominent than in the US sample. LC might also consider
market in which new drug prices are set by the National competitive situations in which products are compared
Social Insurance Board in order to be reimbursable within across pharmacological classes, whereas this stronger
the health system. For the period from 1987 to 1997, they product differentiation could lead to wider distributed price
find significant premiums for all new drugs. The magnitude points.
of the markup, however, correlates with therapeutic value. The phenomena of skimming strategies for drugs used in
Variables controlling for the number of competitors and acute and penetration strategies for drugs used in chronic
drugs in acute conditions show negative, yet insignificant, conditions have only been described in the US market so
values. Competition from generics does not have any far. Price discounts for chronic drugs are backed by

123
Competitive pricing within pharmaceutical classes 75

economic theory, since doctors and patients need to build [30]. Another influential factor inhibiting price decreases
experience with the application of new drugs. Switching may be the importance of the German market as a major
costs are furthermore relatively higher for drugs that are anchor point for external price referencing of new drugs in
used continuously (chronic) than sporadically (acute) [21, numerous health care systems [31, 32]. Hence, it may be in
22]. LC, however, also base their explanation of price the prime interest of manufacturers to maintain price levels
discounts for chronic drugs on their stronger pervasion in Germany instead of reacting to changes in the market
among more elderly patients who face higher co-payment environment in order not to endanger profits in other
rates and hence are more price sensitive. In the German markets (hypothesis 7).
SHI system there are fixed co-payments, whereas patients Major price changes may, however, be induced by
can be exempt from co-payments when a certain level of regulatory measures such as therapeutic reference pricing
financial burden is reached. Physician drug budgets may, for on-patent drugs, which was, however, not implemented
however, be a limiting factor on the selection of new drugs before 2005.
[23]. Hence, we expect penetration strategies to be less
distinct than in the USA (hypothesis 2).
Intensified competition from an increasing number of Data and methods
branded substitutes has been described to lead to additional
price discounts taken at market entry [11, 13] (hypothesis Data
3). In therapeutic classes where substitutability among
drugs is especially high and differentiation is low, physi- We consider all new molecules launched in the German
cians may have become experienced with/accustomed to market in the period from 1993 to 2008 (n = 458)
prescribing the general class drugs [12]. New molecules according to the publication series Neue Arzneimittel. We
might therefore need to enter the market with additional limit our selection of new drugs to the year 2008 to obtain a
discounts in such homogeneous classes to win customers consistent data set for the analyses of entry prices and the
(hypothesis 4). price development after 4 years.
Apart from the competition between horizontally dif- Ratings by Fricke/Klaus, a widely known and influential
ferentiated products, the timing of their market entry could classification system from the same series Neue Arznei-
also play an important role in new molecule pricing mittel from 1982 on, are adapted as a proxy for the ther-
(hypothesis 5). As a result of development races, physicians apeutic quality of a new product. The authors rate the grade
may be faced with several new drugs with similar thera- of innovation of new drugs along a scale comparable to the
peutic value within a short period of time. This might one applied by the US Food and Drug Administration
require additional detailing efforts from manufacturers or (FDA):
larger price discounts taken to motivate doctors to change
A Innovative structure or novel mechanism of action
prescription habits. Such a behavior would also be in line
with therapeutic relevance,
with limit pricing theory according to which the entry of
B Improvement of pharmacodynamic or pharmacokinetic
successors may be deterred through aggressive pricing [24].
features of pre-existing mechanisms of action,
With reference pricing and aut idem substitution being
C Me-too drug with no or only marginal differences to
in place, a strong reducing effect of generic competition on
existing molecules,
the prices of respective branded drugs has been described
D Not sufficiently proven mechanism of action or
for Germany in numerous studies [13, 2527]. Therefore,
uncertain therapeutic relevance.
new drugs are expected to enter with premiums in situa-
tions where prices of off-patent drugs have been driven Fricke and Klaus rating has gained widespread atten-
down by generic competition (hypothesis 6). tion. For example, it is used for analyses of potential cost
Concerning the development of new products entrance savings in classes with me-too drugs in the series Ar-
prices, we would expect competition from on-patent and zneiverordnungs-Report and even serves as a basis for
off-patent drugs to be main explanatory variables as iden- regional mandatory me-too prescription quotas and sub-
tified by LC for price changes in the first years after stitution lists introduced in the Nordrhein SHI region in
commercialization. However, more recent findings on 2006. Owing to its similarity to the FDA rating, which,
competition in selected therapeutic classes in prescription however, only focuses on therapeutic relevance, we adapt
and hospital drug markets in various countries [12, 28, 29] this German rating scheme as a proxy for new molecule
suggest that manufacturers engage in quality competition quality in our empirical analysis.
based on product attributes instead of price competition This rating, however, has been subject to broad criticism.
after market entry and these quality attributes may be the As assessments are made on the basis of the respective
dominant factor for a physicians prescription decision market situation at market entry [33], the winner of a

123
76 M. T. Mueller, A. Frenzel

development race can be classified as highly innovative, innovator of the substance class (rated A by Fricke/Klaus),
whereas the runner-up will be considered a me-too drug. not with related hypertension medication such as ACE
Also, ratings remain fixed and are not revised later on the inhibitors or calcium antagonists. If a new drug can be used
basis of results from phase IV studies or new indications. for several diseases, only the main indication is considered.
Furthermore, the classification has been characterized as In case of doubt, the main indication is defined by higher
being made from a predominantly pharmacological point of sales of a specific dosage/package combination of a new
view. Hence, A ratings may be awarded for new mecha- product. For substances that can be used in various topical
nisms even if the clinical value is not yet evident [34]. As a areas (e.g., steroids as inhalants or dermatological agents),
consequence, Fricke and Klaus have been implementing all forms for which the product has been discussed and rated
mixed ratings (e.g., A/C, B/C) from 1991 on a low scale to by Fricke/Klaus are considered. In accordance with LC and
cope with this problem. An overall modification of the EP, new products are classified as acute for indications
rating scheme differentiating between pharmacologic and lasting no more than 3 months and chronic otherwise.
therapeutic levels of innovation for every new molecule As a result of these selection criteria, our sample is
has, however, not been made. limited to 108 new molecules from 38 different therapeutic
To avoid these controversies, drugs with mixed Fricke/ classes. Our approach differs from LC and EP with regards
Klaus ratings (e.g., A/C, C/D) are excluded from the to three characteristics: Drugs must be prescribed (pri-
analyses. Molecules rated A are also not considered as it is marily) outside hospitals, enter an established drug class as
not always obvious whether this grade is awarded for a real a successor, and be fundamentally therapeutically substi-
therapeutic innovation or only for a new pharmacological tutable within this class. This provides for great analytical
mechanism [34]. We thereby also avoid the problem of clarity to identify pricing effects.
finding appropriate substitutes of A drugs discussed by EP. We compare prices of products based on the defined
As A drugs always establish a new substance class, our daily dose (DDD) recommendations at the time of market
analysis hence solely focuses on new competition within entry from the World Health Organization (WHO), Ger-
pre-existing therapeutic classes. man Institute of Medical Documentation and Information
Next, drugs that are (primarily) used in hospitals are (DIMDI), and the Rote Liste drug directory where neces-
excluded, as paid prices and resulting pricing strategies in sary. Similar to the approaches adopted by LC and EP,
this segment may differ from the prescription market [35, prices are compared for the main application form (usually
36]. In accordance with LC and EP, several therapeutic tablets for systemic preparations). On package level, the
classes are also not considered. This applies to antineoplas- largest package containing 1 DDD per tablet is selected
tics as well as systemic antivirals that can be used in com- where possible and reasonable. Otherwise, the most com-
bination therapies and hence might react to price changes of parable dose/package combination, usually the one with
supplements. Furthermore, vaccines, diagnostics, and indi- highest sales, across competitors is chosen. In accordance
vidually dosed medications such as anesthetics are excluded. with EP, competitor prices are weighted with market shares
Drugs with differing therapeutic and resistance spectrums at brand level in the year before market entry. Observations
such as antibiotics or antimycotics are also not considered of new molecule prices after 4 years are deflated to the
unless they are classified as essentially substitutable. We respective base year using the German consumer price
conduct this assessment as well as the identification of index (CPI).
therapeutic substitutes considering various evaluations of We use data from the IMS DPM database from IMS
substance classes [9, 3739] as well as further clinical lit- Health to perform our analysis. IMS DPM covers the entire
erature and consultation with physicians where necessary. German pharmaceutical market at the interface of phar-
For the definition of the competition landscape, the rele- macy purchasing through a complete coverage of pur-
vant, direct therapeutic substitutes of a new drug at the time chases from 16 full-line wholesalers as well as a
of market entry are considered, reflecting the strategic pric- representative pharmacy panel covering direct business
ing decision the manufacturer must have taken when the from short-line wholesalers, parallel importers, and man-
product was launched. This is usually, but not always, ufacturers. Prices in the database are adapted from the
restricted to competitors within the same ATC level 4 sub- Lauer-Taxe and represent net manufacturer sales prices.
group.1 For instance, we compare the price of valsartan as the Volume and price data have been extracted with annual
first AT2 antagonist in our sample only with losartan as the observations in the period from 1992 to 2012.

1
Methods
We use the ATC classification developed by the European
Pharmaceutical Marketing Research Association (EphMRA), which
categorizes drugs rather by indications than the more pharmacolog- To estimate pricing at market entry and price development,
ically oriented WHO ATC. we adopt the linear regression models used by LC and EP.

123
Competitive pricing within pharmaceutical classes 77

Several alternative variables measuring competition from bg Dummy variable, equals 1 if at least one
on- as well as off-patent drugs are added on in order to competitor is off-patent at time t when there
specify effects within therapeutic classes further on. was none at market entry.
lrelp b0 b1 rateb b2 acute b3 comp b4 gx e lgs Logarithm of 1 ? the ratio of the share of
Model I branded substitutes that are off-patent at time
t over the share of branded substitutes that
lratiot d0 d1 rateb d2 acute d3 dblp d4 dclp were off-patent at market entry, whereas the
d5 comp d6 gx c share is expressed as a whole number.
Model II gs(t)(z) Dummy variable, equals 1 if there are exactly
z off-patent molecules at time t.
gs(t)(z)min Dummy variable, equals 1 if there are at least
lrelp Logarithm of the ratio of the new molecule price z off-patent molecules at time t.
per DDD to the volume weighted price of
therapeutic branded substitutes.
lratio(t) Logarithm of the ratio of the CPI deflated price
t years after introduction to its real introduction Results
price.
Table 1 summarizes statistics on relative introduction pri-
General control variables ces in the German marketplace in comparison to previous
rateb Dummy variable for therapeutic quality, equals 1 US and Swedish data. As expected, innovative B sub-
for B and 0 for C ratings. stances show a distinct price premium of an average
acute Dummy variable, equals 1 for acute and 0 for ?182 %, which is higher than in the US, but lower than in
chronic indications. the Swedish market. The median in the German sample is,
dblp Interactive variable, product of lrelp and rateb for however, only at 1.00. This suggests a highly skewed
rateb = 1. distribution with predominately imitative pricing strategies
dclp Interactive variable, product of lrelp and rateb for and only a few very highly priced outliers. For C-rated
rateb = 0. drugs, median and mean values show proof of pricing at
competitors levels. In comparison to the Swedish and
Variables controlling for on-patent competition (comp): especially the US data, the standard deviation is consid-
lns(t) Logarithm of 1 ? the number of branded erably smaller, again supporting imitative pricing in most
substitutes at t years. cases.
launch(y) Dummy variable, equals 1 if another In contrast to the other countries data, no differences
competitor enters the market within between prices of drugs in acute and chronic conditions are
y years (proxy for a development race). observable. While acute B drugs show a 12 % discount as
launch(y)a/p Dummy variable, equals 1 if launch(y) = 1 median and a 401 % price premium as mean values, sample
and competitors enter the market before size (n = 5) and standard deviation in this subgroup
(ante) and/or after (post) the new molecule. diminish a possible significance of these observations.
me2class Dummy variable, equals 1 if the class has been Descriptive statistics on the price development 4 years
characterized in the literature as a substance after entry in Table 2 reveal a decline of real prices of
class with very high substitution potential and 25 % for B as well as C drugs. In contrast to the US
a low perceived differentiation among market, there is no indication for penetration or skimming
molecules by patients and physicians. strategies, nor does the price decrease reach levels like the
average minus 1027 % in Sweden. Since the standard
Variables controlling for off-patent competition (gx): deviation in our sample is very small, this minor average
dg Dummy variable, equals 1 if at least one price change can most likely be attributed to the deflation
competitor is off-patent (and has generic of nominal prices exclusively.
competitors) at the time of market entry of The econometric analysis is conducted using Stata 12.0.
the new molecule. To ensure comparability with previous results, we compute
lg Logarithm of 1 ? the share of branded standard ordinary least squares (OLS) regressions for the
substitutes that are off-patent at market regressions used by LC and EP and estimate heteroske-
entry, whereas the share is expressed as a dasticity robust standard errors only in enhancements of
whole number. these basic models.

123
78 M. T. Mueller, A. Frenzel

Table 1 Relative introduction prices at market entry (relp)


Class Type Germany 19932008 USA 19781987 (LC 1998) Sweden 19871999 (EP 2003)
n Median Mean SD Range n Median Mean SD Range n Median Mean SD Range

A Acute 3 2.97 3.12 0.88 2.324.07 5 1.43 1.59 0.56 1.102.55


Chronic 10 2.07 3.11 2.76 0.208.08 3 10.97 9.40 4.88 3.9313.30
Combined 13 2.47 3.11 2.47 0.208.08 8 2.04 4.52 4.83 1.1013.30
B Acute 5 0.88 5.01 5.52 0.6614.20 19 1.72 3.09 3.65 0.4013.60 30 1.64 3.75 4.96 0.1719.28
Chronic 14 1.00 2.04 2.34 0.758.31 29 1.19 1.63 1.14 0.485.97 42 2.55 3.92 4.77 0.0920.32
Combined 19 1.00 2.82 3.71 0.6614.20 48 1.35 2.21 2.53 0.4013.60 72 2.25 3.86 4.85 0.0920.32
C Acute 26 0.98 1.08 0.38 0.402.01 16 1.23 1.37 0.68 0.553.13 63 1.26 2.16 3.09 0.0416.70
Chronic 63 1.00 1.04 0.29 0.651.92 53 0.94 1.07 0.80 0.376.00 75 1.13 2.18 3.54 0.1226.17
Combined 89 1.00 1.05 0.32 0.402.01 69 0.97 1.15 0.78 0.376.00 138 1.16 2.17 3.33 0.0426.17

Table 2 Real price changes 4 years after market entry (ratio4)


Class Type Germany 19932008 USA 19781987 (LC 1998) Sweden 19871999 (EP 2003)
n Median Mean SD Range n Median Mean SD Range n Median Mean SD Range

A Acute 3 1.11 1.06 0.23 0.811.26 16 0.78 0.83 0.28 0.521.65


Chronic 10 0.87 0.92 0.17 0.681.19 12 0.75 0.73 0.12 0.440.91
Combined 13 0.87 0.95 0.19 0.681.26 28 0.77 0.78 0.21 0.441.95
B Acute 5 0.95 0.98 0.11 0.941.03 19 0.95 1.00 0.20 0.791.59 20 0.93 0.90 0.33 0.342.05
Chronic 14 0.97 1.00 0.10 0.821.22 29 1.18 1.13 0.16 0.841.42 26 0.82 0.84 0.13 0.641.10
Combined 19 0.97 0.99 0.11 0.821.22 48 1.09 1.08 0.19 0.791.59 46 0.86 0.86 0.24 0.342.05
C Acute 26 0.98 0.97 0.04 0.611.19 16 1.04 1.11 0.26 0.811.71 42 0.89 0.89 0.29 0.402.51
Chronic 62 0.95 0.98 0.10 0.661.29 53 1.26 1.26 0.30 0.682.01 33 0.79 0.81 0.10 0.641.07
Combined 88 0.95 0.97 0.09 0.611.29 69 1.22 1.23 0.29 0.682.01 75 0.84 0.85 0.23 0.402.51

Table 3 compares determinants of relative prices at our constant term is still slightly insignificant at the 5 %
market entry with previous results from LC and EP level. However, it becomes apparent that this term is
respectively. We find a small (yet insignificant) price pre- overcompensated by the effect from one additional com-
mium for new products in the constant term. As expected, petitor expressed in lns0. This implies that the first com-
B-rated drugs show a significant markup (hypothesis 1). petitor in a substance class is entering the market with a
The strong effect of ?44 % almost reaching Swedish premium. Pricing below the average competitors level is
levels can, however, most likely be attributed to few rela- first observed when the number of drugs in a substance
tively high priced outliers we identified in our sample. The class increases from two to three2 (hypothesis 3).
dummy for acute drugs is, however, insignificant and only Apart from the number of substitutes, a distinct influence of
shows a negligible effect (hypothesis 2). Hence, we drop development races on the pricing of new molecules becomes
this variable in further regressions. apparent. We find an additional price discount of 18.7 % in
Like in the two previous studies, price discounts taken at scenarios in which at least one additional competitor enters the
market entry increase with the number of branded competitors market within a period of up to 2 years (hypothesis 5). There
per substance class (hypothesis 3). Interestingly, competition is, however, no separate effect indicating intensified compe-
from off-patent drugs and respective generics controlled for in tition from development races when controlling for additional
regressions #23 improves the model quality drastically. This entries within a time frame of 3 years or more. Results on
implies that off-patent drugs engage in a price competition whether price discounts for parallel launches within 2 years
induced by the entry of generics (hypothesis 6). are only made when another competitor is entering the market
Regressions with further detailed variables on compe- before (ante) and/or after (post) the new molecule are weak
tition from patent and generic drugs are displayed in
Table 4, now involving the estimation of heteroskedasticity 2
We find further evidence on a gradually intensifying price
robust standard errors. Omitting the dummy for acute drugs competition by conducting a sensitivity analysis on the impact from
and controlling for on- as well as off-patent competition, the number of competitors.

123
Competitive pricing within pharmaceutical classes 79

-0.197 (-1.38)
-0.119 (-1.12)
and insignificant. Hence, this price discount can be charac-

0.486** (2.89)

0.463** (2.98)

-0.077 (0.15)
0.921* (2.44)
terized as both proactive and reactive when facing intensified
competition during parallel product launches.
In addition, we find a negative impact on price when

0.08
0.06
3.82
218
(3)

applying a tightened definition of therapeutic class effects.


Controlling for those classes which are characterized as

-0.197 (-1.35)
-0.124 (-1.14)
0.485** (2.89)

0.463** (2.98)
0.920* (2.48)

having highly interchangeable products with a low degree of

0.004 (0.02)
differentiation perceived by physicians and patients [9, 37],
a price discount of 17.6 % becomes apparent (hypothesis 4).

0.08
0.06
3.82
218
(2)

Finally, effects arising from an increasing number of


Sweden (EP 2003)

off-patent competitors are tested. Price premiums in sce-


-0.197 (-1.37)
-0.124 (-1.24)
0.485** (2.90)

0.463** (2.99)
0.920* (2.45)

narios with only one or multiple generic molecules per


drug class differ only marginally. In a sensitivity analysis,
we find a premium of more than 80 % in classes with at
0.08
0.07
4.79
218
(1)

least five generics; this effect can, however, only be


attributed to observations in the class of nonsteroidal anti-
-0.376*** (-4.41)

inflammatory drugs.
0.335** (2.84)

0.086** (2.96)
(0.221* (2.32)

0.285* (2.34)

Regressions for the price development after 4 years are


0.387 (1.88)

presented in Table 5. Results confirm the indications from


the descriptive analysis that only minimal price movements
0.32
0.29
130

n/a
(3)

take place (hypothesis 7). All independent variables as well


as the overall model are highly insignificant. The relatively
-0.386*** (-4.45)

strongest explanatory value is provided by the number of


0.336** (2.84)

0.332** (2.78)

substitutes (t = -1.13), hinting at a slight price decrease


0.293* (2.39)
0.230 (1.82)
0.388 (1.78)

when competition intensifies. A possibly positive effect can


be attributed to the interactive variable dclp (t = 1.16),
0.32
0.29
130

n/a

suggesting that price decreases are more distinct among C


(2)

drugs that have been priced relatively higher at market entry.


-0.332*** (-3.75)

New regressors introduced to detail effects on branded


USA (LC 1998)

0.334** (2.75)

and generic competition have been tested for collinearity.


0.295* (2.32)

0.267* (2.13)
0.374 (1.76)

Models at market entry demonstrate cluster robustness


when clustering effects by substance groups, manufactur-
0.27
0.25
130

ers, or launch years.


n/a
Table 3 Determinants of relative introduction prices 1/2 (model I: lrelp)

(1)

-0.263** (-2.83)
0.435*** (3.85)

0.141*** (4.87)

Discussion
0.155 (1.18)

0.077 (0.82)

We find strong evidence for characteristics of a functioning


10.12
0.28
0.25
108
(3)

pricing mechanism for new products in accordance with


economic theory: Discounts correlate with competitiveness
-0.291** (-2.91)

of the market, i.e., the number of branded substitutes, and


0.444*** (3.86)

0.482*** (4.45)

t Statistics in parentheses, p values for S.E

premiums correlate with therapeutic value.


0.199 (1.46)

0.045 (0.47)

* p \ 0.05, ** p \ 0.01, *** p \ 0.001

Applying a stricter definition of substitutability than LC


and EP to our data, we only consider molecules whose ther-
0.26
0.23
9.01
108
(2)

apeutic class has already been established by an originator.


The skewed distribution of prices for B-rated drugs with only
-0.030 (-0.34)
0.436*** (3.49)

few highly priced outliers might, however, reveal one of the


0.031 (0.21)

0.082 (0.79)

weaknesses of the classification system by Fricke/Klaus,


Germany

which may reward innovation on pharmacological as well as


0.12
0.09
4.59
108
(1)

therapeutic level with the same grade, ignoring the real per-
ceived value a new drug may bring into the marketplace.
constant

adj.r2

Competition within therapeutic classes seems to be


acute
ratea
rateb

lns0
dg

r2

characterized by a low degree of product heterogeneity and


lg

F
n

123
80 M. T. Mueller, A. Frenzel

Table 4 Determinants of relative introduction prices 2/2 (model I: lrelp)


(4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9)

constant 0.206 (1.98) 0.299* (2.55) 0.187 (1.62) 0.297* (2.51) 0.345* (2.91) 0.201 (1.91)
rateb 0.444* (2.26) 0.417* (2.29) 0.447* (2.23) 0.423* (2.29) 0.382* (2.23) 0.445* (2.23)
lns0 -0.228** (-3.16) -0.255** (-2.84) -0.294** (-3.07) -0.255** (-2.82) -0.205* (-2.13) -0.284** (-3.23)
dg 0.487*** (3.81) 0.460*** (3.74) 0.492*** (3.70) 0.461*** (3.72) 0.435*** (3.62)
launch2 -0.187* (-2.10) -0.142 (-1.03) -0.185* (-2.16)
launch3 0.033 (0.35)
launch2a -0.012 (-0.12)
launch2p 0.067 (-0.68)
me2class -0.176* (-2.08)
gs01 0.490*** (3.46)
gs02 min 0.470*** (4.38)
n 108 108 108 108 108 108
r2 0.26 0.29 0.26 0.29 0.31 0.26
F 4.99 4.06 3.81 2.66 3.60 5.20
t Statistics in parentheses, p values for heteroskedasticity robust SE
* p \ 0.05, ** p \ 0.01, *** p \ 0.001

spatial agglomeration in the marketplace. In order to anchor point for external price referencing of new drugs in
address customers, new entrants must therefore take price numerous health care systems [19]. Manufacturers there-
discounts which are even more distinct in classes with little fore pursue strategic anchor pricing by launching drugs first
product differentiation. This also holds for timing of mar- in the German market and aim to maintain these price
ket entries as a result of development races. points over time in order not to endanger profits in other
Price competition at entry, however, first sets in when international systems [31, 32]. Second, manufacturers may
the third competitor enters a class. These results are in line be penalized for increasing prices. Apart from mandatory
with findings from Lexchin [40] who identifies price dis- manufacturer rebates off the list price, the German SHI
counts in the Canadian market first taken by the fourth system has traditionally implemented price freezes peri-
molecule. Earlier entrants therefore have the opportunity to odically, during which any list price increases must be
build a new market and retain customers. As Kanavos et al. given as additional discounts to sickness funds. However,
[12] point out, physicians become familiar with prescribing in a sensitivity analysis of price changes by calendar year,
these general class drugs over time. When markets mature, no effects that could be attributed to price freeze periods3
the small differentiation of new substitutes does not offset or other modifications of the Social Insurance Code (SGB
the level of experience physicians have reached with the V) become apparent. We also find no influence of rebate
general class. New substitutes therefore need to compen- contracts, which have been introduced into the system in
sate for switching costs with lower prices. 2003 and allow negotiations of (non-disclosed) rebates off
Competition from generics is an indispensable explan- the list price between individual sickness funds and man-
atory variable in our model. Off-patent molecules engage ufacturers. Yet, this option has been exerted rarely for on-
in price competition with generics. This supports the strong patent drugs in initial years [20].
generics culture in the German market with phenomena
such as branded generics and also affirms the functioning
of mechanisms such as reference pricing or aut idem sub- Conclusion
stitution in the German market.
Whereas price competition gradually sets in at market We have applied an approach used by LC and EP with a
entry, quality competition seems to hold for the price focus on competition within therapeutic classes in the
development of new drugs. In line with various recent German marketplace between 1993 and 2008. Our study
studies [12, 28, 29], we find constant prices and no vari- confirms previous research identifying the therapeutic
ables explaining the price development after 4 years in our
3
data beyond the influence of deflation. Apart from com- In a study of overall price movements in the German market
between 2004 and 2006, Stargardt [13] identifies quarterly price
petition based on product attributes, the lack of price
reductions during a price freeze of 0.38 % compared to an increase of
reactions may also be attributed to two other specificities in 0.32 % before and after this period. Our model would, however, not
Germany: First, the German market serves as a major be able to capture such small movements precisely.

123
Competitive pricing within pharmaceutical classes 81

-0.168** (-2.90)
value of a new molecule as a main explanatory variable for

-0.137 (-0.93)

-0.008 (-0.31)
-0.003 (-0.20)
-0.010 (-0.87)
-0.010 (-0.40)

-0.313 (-1.28)
price setting at market entry. While new classes allow

0.005 (0.06)
0.075 (1.90)
market building through quality competition of the first
two molecules, price competition sets in when further

0.10

2.04
(12)

128

.0.5
successors enter the market. The principle of quality
competition holds for the price development of new mol-
-0.174** (-3.00)

ecules, whereas the role of strategic anchor pricing con-


-0.130 (-0.88)

-0.008 (-0.32)
-0.001 (-0.08)
-0.009 (-0.71)
-0.014 (-0.54)
-0.032 (-0.47)
tributes to lacking price reactions in the market.
0.004 (0.05)
0.077 (1.94)

Our study raises various questions for further research.


Although new molecules do not engage in price competi-

0.10
0.04
1.85
(11)

128
tion in initial years, their entry might induce price com-
petition among existing substitutes, especially towards the
Sweden (EP 2003)

-0.175** (-3.04)

end of their patent periods. Previous results on this issue


-0.126 (-0.85)

-0.008 (-0.33)
-0.001 (-0.04)
-0.009 (-0.76)
-0.008 (-0.09)

are mixed, describing price [9] as well as quality compe-


0.003 (0.04)
0.076 (1.93)

tition [12, 29] in selected classes.


Other issues worth exploring may be whether the pro-
0.09
0.05
2.09
(10)

128

cess of market building is limited to a certain time frame


[12], if market shares correspond to therapeutic quality and
-0.339*** (-4.11)

-0.138** (-2.62)
-0.076** (-2.79)
-0.093* (-2.16)

-0.106* (-2.46)

first mover advantages [11, 12], or how price anchoring


-0.054 (-1.29)
-0.007 (-0.13)
0.300*** (7.59)

influences prices and shares in other systems.


0.004 (0.39)

Our paper reflects the old reality in Germany where


freely priced new drugs automatically were fully reim-
0.25
0.20
(12)

130

n/a

bursed. With the benefit analysis as a process having come


into place with the AMNOG in 2011, reimbursement levels
-0.337*** (-4.08)

-0.136** (-2.57)
-0.075** (-2.74)
-0.092* (-2.12)

-0.107* (-2.47)

of new molecules are subject to negotiations with sickness


-0.052 (-1.26)
-0.008 (-0.15)
0.295*** (6.00)

funds. Drugs may also be included in reference price


0.002 (0.05)

clusters when no significant additional therapeutic benefit


over present therapies is shown. As a result, reimbursement
0.25
0.20
(11)

130

n/a

prices should become less skewed, reflecting the thera-


peutic value of a new drug even more strongly. With
-0.339*** (-4.14)

-0.139** (-2.66)
-0.077** (-2.82)
-0.092* (-2.15)

-0.108* (-2.50)

regards to launch prices, we would expect that manufac-


USA (LC 1998)

-0.055 (-1.33)
-0.007 (-0.13)
0.302*** (6.56)

turers will add additional premiums, factoring in possible


price discounts that the negotiation process might bring.
The first empirical results [41, 42] also hint at the selection
Table 5 Deflated price ratios 4 years after launch (model II: lratio4)

0.25
0.21
(10)

130

n/a

of inappropriate competitors in manufacturers dossiers as


a possible means to secure higher reimbursement levels.
-0.001 (-0.07)

-0.006 (-0.25)

-0.023 (-1.13)

With many major market impacts having occurred in the


0.005 (0.15)

0.018 (0.59)

0.048 (1.16)

0.004 (0.48)

past years such as the AMNOG benefit evaluation or the


-0.02

increasing share of rebate contracts for on-patent drugs, we


0.03

0.57
(12)

107

believe that a new holistic empirical investigation will be


feasible in a few years when sufficient data on launches
-0.002 (-0.09)

-0.010 (-0.40)

-0.019 (-0.95)
-0.026 (-0.69)

under these changed market conditions is available.


0.002 (0.07)

0.025 (0.83)

0.045 (1.08)

t Statistics in parentheses, p values for S.E


* p \ 0.05, ** p \ 0.01, *** p \ 0.001
-0.02
0.04

0.62
(11)

107

References
-0.002 (-0.09)

-0.008 (-0.31)

-0.021 (-1.06)
0.004 (0.12)

0.020 (0.68)

0.047 (1.13)

1. Angell, M.: The Truth About the Drug Companies: How They
Germany

Deceive Us and What to Do About It. Random House, New York


-0.02

(2005)
0.03

0.65
(10)

107

2. Hollis, A.: Comment on The economics of follow-on drug


research and development: trends in entry rates and the timing of
constant

development. Pharmacoeconomics 23, 11871192 (2005)


adj.r2
acute
ratea
rateb

3. Glaeske, G.: Mit bitteren Pillen gesunde Geschafte: von man-


dalp
dblp
dclp
lns4

lgs
bg

r2

gelnder Differenzierung des Marktes und den Erfolgen von


N

123
82 M. T. Mueller, A. Frenzel

Analogprodukten. In: Neubauer, G., Rebscher, H. (eds.) Ges- 25. Pavcnik, N.: Do pharmaceutical prices respond to potential patient
undheitsokonomie und Gesundheitspolitik im Spannungsfeld out-of-pocket expenses? Rand J. Econ. 33, 469487 (2002)
zwischen Wissenschaft und Politikberatung: [Festschrift fur 26. Kanavos, P., Costa-Font, J., Seeley, E.: Competition in off-patent
Gunter Neubauer], pp. 543559. Economica, Heidelberg (2006) drug markets: issues, regulation and evidence. Econ. Policy 23,
4. Wertheimer, A., Santella, T.: Pharmocoevolution: the benefits of 499544 (2008)
incremental innovation. http://www.who.int/intellectualproperty/ 27. Vandoros, S., Kanavos, P.: The generics paradox revisited:
submissions/Pharmacoevolution.pdf (2005). Accessed 14 Aug 2013 empirical evidence from regulated markets. Appl. Econ. 45,
5. Blochl-Daum, B.: Me-too drugs und das Konzept des Klas- 32303239 (2013)
seneffekts. Wien. Med. Wochenschr. 156, 1718 (2006) 28. Jena, A.B., Calfee, J.E., Mansley, E.C., Philipson, T.J.: Me-
6. DiMasi, J.A., Paquette, C.: The economics of follow-on drug Too innovation in pharmaceutical markets. Forum Health Econ.
research and development: trends in entry rates and the timing of Policy 12(1), 121 (2009)
development. Pharmacoeconomics 22, 114 (2004) 29. Hostenkamp, G.: Do follow-on therapeutic substitutes induce
7. DiMasi, J.A., Faden, L.B.: Competitiveness in follow-on drug price competition between hospital medicines? Evidence from
R&D: a race or imitation? Nat. Rev. Drug Discov. 10, 2327 the Danish hospital sector. Health Policy 111, 6877 (2013)
(2011) 30. Serra-Sastre, V.: McGuire, A: Information and diffusion of new
8. Munnich, F.W.: Innovatorischer Wettbewerb auf dem Arznei- prescription drugs. Appl. Econ. 45, 20492057 (2013)
mittelmarkt. In: Bausch, J., Klauber, J., Schroder, H., Selke, G.W. 31. Frenzel, A.: Pricing insights, prescription patterns and average
(eds.) Innovation im Arzneimittelmarkt, pp. 107129. Springer, treatment costs across six therapy areas and 19 European coun-
Berlin (2000) triesDiscussing the effect of international price referencing on
9. Haussler, B., et al.: Analog-Wirkstoffe im Arzneimittelmarkt: average treatment cost of pharmaceuticals. Poster presented at
Therapeutischer Nutzen und Bedeutung fur die Ausgaben der ISPOR 14th Annual European Congress, Madrid (2011)
Krankenversicherungen. IGES, Berlin (2002) 32. Augurzky, B., Gohlmann, S., Gre, S., Wasem, J.: Effects of the
10. Lu, Z.J., Comanor, W.S.: Strategic pricing of new pharmaceuti- German reference drug program on ex-factory prices of prescrip-
cals. Rev. Econ. Stat. 80, 108118 (1998) tion drugs: a panel data approach. Health Econ. 18, 421436 (2009)
11. Danzon, P.M., Chao, L.: Does regulation drive out competition in 33. Fricke, U.: Arzneimittelinnovationen-Neue Wirkstoffe: 19781999:
pharmaceutical markets? J. Law Econ. 43, 311358 (2000) Eine Bestandsaufnahme. In: Bausch, J., Klauber, J., Schroder, H.,
12. Kanavos, P., Font, J.C., McGuire, A.: Product differentiation, Selke, G.W. (eds.) Innovation im Arzneimittelmarkt, pp. 8597.
competition and regulation of new drugs: the case of statins in four Springer, Berlin (2000)
European countries. Manag. Decis. Econ. 28, 455465 (2007) 34. Kaber, G., Twarock, S.: Beurteilungsverfahren neuer Arznei-
13. Stargardt, T.: Modelling pharmaceutical price changes in Ger- mittel: Eine kritische Bewertung. http://www.uni-duesseldorf.de/
many: a function of competition and regulation. Appl. Econ. 43, kojda-pharmalehrbuch/FortbildungstelegrammPharmazie/Ser
45154526 (2011) ieApothekenpraxis/Beurteilung_NAM_FORTE_PHARM2009.
14. Ekelund, M., Persson, B.: Pharmaceutical pricing in a regulated pdf (2009). Accessed 14 Aug 2013
market. Rev. Econ. Stat. 85, 298306 (2003) 35. Frank, R.G.: Prescription drug prices: why do some pay more
15. Reekie, W.D.: Pricing new pharmaceutical products. Croom than others do? Health Aff. 20, 115128 (2001)
Helm, London (1977) 36. Hajen, L., Paetow, H., Schumacher, H.: Gesundheitsokonomie.
16. Reekie, W.D.: Price and quality competition in the United States Kohlhammer, Stuttgart (2011)
drug industry. J. Ind. Econ. 26, 223237 (1978) 37. Albrecht, M. et. al.: Ausweitung selektivvertraglicher Versor-
17. Weston, F.: Pricing in the pharmaceutical industry. In: Chien, R.I. gung: Auswirkungen auf die Gesundheitsversorgung und Anfor-
(ed.) Issues in pharmaceutical economics, pp. 7195. Heath, derungen an den zukunftigen regulatorischen Rahmen. Hans-
Lexington, MA (1979) Bockler-Stiftung, Dusseldorf (2011)
18. DiMasi, J.A.: Price trends for prescription pharmaceuticals 38. Beubler, E.: Kompendium der Pharmakologie: Gebrauchliche
19951999. http://aspe.hhs.gov/health/reports/drug-papers/ Arzneimittel in der Praxis. Springer, Wien (2011)
dimassi/dimasi-final.htm (2000). Accessed 25 Oct 2013 39. Derendorf, H., Schulz, M., Wemhoner, R.: Arzneimittelkunde.
19. OECD: Pharmaceutical Pricing Policies in a Global Market. Deutscher Apotheker Verlag, Stuttgart (2011)
OECD, Paris (2008) 40. Lexchin, J.: Do manufacturers of brand-name drugs engage in
20. Mandl, J.: Rabattvertrage uber Patentgeschutzte Arzneimittel. price competition? An analysis of introductory prices. CMAJ
Nomos, BadenBaden (2012) 174, 11201121 (2006)
21. Hellerstein, J.K.: The importance of the physician in the generic 41. McBride, D., Kilburg, A., Mauskopf, J.: An Early Assessment of
versus trade-name prescription decision. RAND J. Econ. 29, the German Federal Joint Commission Resolutions of Additional
108136 (1998) Clinical Benefit. Poster presented at ISPOR 15th Annual Euro-
22. Schmalensee, R.: Product differentiation advantages of pioneer- pean Congress, Berlin (2012)
ing brands. Am. Econ. Rev. 72, 349365 (1982) 42. Wild, L., Forster, L.: AMNOG: pricing reforms in action. Poster
23. Schreyogg, J., Busse, R.: Physician drug budgets in Germany and presented at ISPOR 15th Annual European Congress, Berlin
effects on prescription behaviour. J. Pharm. Finance Econ. Policy (2012)
14, 7795 (2005)
24. Bergman, M.A., Rudholm, N.: The relative importance of actual
and potential competition: empirical evidence from the pharma-
ceuticals market. J. Ind. Econ. 51, 455467 (2003)

123

You might also like