Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 6

American Economic Association

The Optimality of Free Trade: Science or Religion?


Author(s): Rachel McCulloch
Source: The American Economic Review, Vol. 83, No. 2, Papers and Proceedings of the
Hundred and Fifth Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association (May, 1993), pp.
367-371
Published by: American Economic Association
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2117692
Accessed: 06-11-2017 16:12 UTC

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
http://about.jstor.org/terms

American Economic Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend
access to The American Economic Review

This content downloaded from 116.72.52.125 on Mon, 06 Nov 2017 16:12:47 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
The Optimality of Free Trade: Science or Religion?

By RACHEL MCCULLOCH*

Ominous trends in America's interna- The past decade, however, has not been
tional position and overall economic perfor- friendly to American proponents of a liberal
mance have generated increasing public dis- trade policy. With help from a strong dollar
satisfaction with the nation's laissez-faire in the mid-1980's, firms abroad challenged
approach to trade. Recent academic re- U.S. producers in a widening range of in-
search has meanwhile cast new doubt on dustries. Trading partners with activist pol-
the theoretical case for free trade, espe- icy regimes enjoyed prosperity fueled by
cially where high-technology industries are export surpluses, while employment and
concerned. As a consequence of these par- wages sagged in America's own manufactur-
allel developments, much of both academic ing sector. U.S. exports continued to grow,
and public debate over appropriate trade but imports grew faster. The resulting trade
policy now centers on the practical implica- deficits were startling in size and seemingly
tions of the modeling approach known as resistant to the usual remedies. Of still
the new trade theory. Some look to the new greater concern was the perceived nature of
theory for a better understanding of trade foreign competition. Where lost market
policy's potential role in improving overall share had once been concentrated in ma-
economic performance; others seek theoret- ture industries such as apparel and footwear,
ical justification of policies from which they powerful rivals (some bankrolled by foreign
themselves expect to benefit. governments) began to contest U.S. domi-
nance even in advanced high-technology
I. The Eroding Consensus on Free Trade sectors. Innovative products, including ones
based on U.S. research, seemed as likely to
Until the mid-1980's, the doctrine of free come to the American market from foreign
trade enjoyed broad popular support in the as from domestic producers.
United States. The nation emerged from Rising concern about U.S. economic per-
World War II a staunch crusader for liberal- formance has promoted new skepticism re-
ization of global trade, notwithstanding oc- garding the merits of a laissez-faire ap-
casional lapses from its own stated ideals. proach to trade. This in turn has created
For most firms, neither exports nor compet- new interest in whatever rationale economic
ing imports played an important role in theory can provide for trade-policy activism.
overall profitability. If a few industries had The resulting debate has created the im-
grievances about foreign competition, pression even among economists that the
America as a whole seemed to prosper along new theory represents the first serious intel-
with, and because of, the steady expansion lectual challenge to a previously airtight
of its trade. In any case, the translation into theoretical case for free trade.
actual policy of the American free-trade In fact, nothing could be further from the
doctrine remained a pragmatic mixture of truth. Theoretical challenges to the optimal-
measures to open international markets with ity of free trade have always been the bread
measures to accommodate the mercantilis- and butter of international economics. Like
tic impulses of governments. the new theory, older arguments for inter-
vention are predicated on departures from
the paradigm of perfect competition. The
new theory is thus solidly in an old tradi-
* Department of Economics, Brandeis University,
tion: "Ingenious economists properly make
Waltham, MA 02254. Gary Chamberlain, Douglas A.
Irwin, Peter A. Petri, and J. David Richardson pro- their mark by proving the improbable"
vided helpful comments. (Jagdish Bhagwati, 1991 p. 5). While the
367

This content downloaded from 116.72.52.125 on Mon, 06 Nov 2017 16:12:47 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
368 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY 1993

new theory does broaden the set of theoret- Postwar theorists formalized and ex-
ical exceptions to the conventional wisdom, tended long-established critiques of free
its emphasis on scale economies also serves trade (the optimum tariff and infant-
to underscore the potential gains from open industry protection were much debated
international markets. by 19th-century economists; see Douglas A.
Irwin, 1991) and also developed a wide-
II. Traditional Theory and New Arguments ranging literature on departures from per-
fect competition. One standard graduate
The theoretical case for the optimality of text on traditional (i.e., pre-new) trade the-
free trade rests on the same logic as the ory (Bhagwati and T. N. Srinivasan, 1983)
case for unfettered competition in domestic devotes no less than 11 chapters to situa-
markets: given suitable conditions, private tions where free trade is suboptimal. In fact,
profit-seeking behavior ensures an efficient traditional theory offers so many plausible
allocation of resources (for a concise discus- reasons why intervention can raise national
sion, see Anne 0. Krueger [19901). As in and sometimes even world welfare that the
domestic markets, these conditions are not theme of this literature is perhaps better
always satisfied. Throughout the 20th cen- described as the nonoptimality of free trade.
tury and even before, economists have Departures from perfect competition are
probed not only the theoretical benefits of likewise the focus of the new trade theory,
free trade but also the multitude of circum- so in some respects the new theory simply
stances (e.g., monopoly and monopsony, in- carries on a centuries-old tradition. Yet the
creasing returns, externalities, labor-market new theory is new in its modeling tech-
distortions) in which maximization of na- niques, which yield formal results concern-
tional income requires policy intervention. ing aspects of economic reality that had
However, an international context opens previously stymied trade theorists. Drawing
one new issue: maximizing national income on tools recently developed by industrial-
is not the same as maximizing global in- organization (10) theorists, the new trade
come. Traditional theory shows that a large theory offers fresh insights into policy's im-
country can benefit from limiting the vol- pact in markets characterized by scale
ume of its trade; the tariff rate that maxi- economies, oligopoly, and externalities. Al-
mizes national welfare is called the opti- though these conditions had been analyzed
mum tariff. However, gains come entirely at earlier, traditional tools limited their theo-
the expense of foreigners; the optimizing retical depiction. For example, the extensive
country in effect grabs a larger slice of a traditional literature on scale economies
smaller global pie. Emulation or retaliation considered mainly external economies at the
by trading partners changes the likely out- industry level, with individual firms assumed
come to losses for all.' The new theory's to experience constant returns and zero
analysis of rent-grabbing by oligopolistic profits. This approach precludes a role for
global competitors is similar in both struc- firms' strategic behavior, which is central to
ture and implications. the new models. (Paul Krugman [1992] re-
views the new theory's key innovations.)
One reason why the new models are par-
ticularly relevant today is that they apply
best to high-technology industries, where
1The most important practical application of this
logic concerns trade liberalization. Because of adverse spending for research and development cre-
effects on its terms of trade, a large country's unilateral ates significant scale economies internal to
liberalization may raise world welfare yet lower its the individual firm. Learning-by-doing and
own. The apparently mercantilistic resort to reciprocal knowledge spillovers are also important, and
trade liberalization in multilateral negotiations pro-
vides needed assurance that each participant will cap-
the number of competitors in a given mar-
ture part of the gains from the resulting increase in ket is often small. As public officials search
global efficiency. for the best way to nurture high-tech indus-

This content downloaded from 116.72.52.125 on Mon, 06 Nov 2017 16:12:47 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
VOL. 83 NO. 2 FREE TRADE: A LOSS OF (THEORETICAL) NERVE? 369

tries, the new trade theory appears to bol- David Ricardo's discussion of comparative
ster the case for policy activism. advantage, the traditional practical case
draws also on Adam Smith and Joseph
III. From Theory to Policy: The Leap of Faith Schumpeter. Integration of national mar-
kets provides benefits from scale economies
The gap between traditional and new (the division of labor is limited by the extent
trade theory is less in the nature of the of the market) and from intensified pro-
theory itself than in the public perception of ducer rivalry. Such effects, often termed the
what the findings imply for policy. In fact, dynamic benefits of trade, are notoriously
both bodies of theory abound with demon- hard to formalize and measure, yet many
strations that government intervention can, economists believe they are of far greater
under plausible conditions, raise national importance than the more theoretically
and perhaps even world welfare. Yet to go tractable static benefits from Ricardian
from theory (whether new or traditional) to comparative advantage. For example, Bela
policy (whether activist or laissez-faire) re- Balassa's (1967) classic evaluation of the
quires a substantial leap of faith. Activists potential gains from liberalized trade among
eager to translate the new theory into policy industrial economies concludes that result-
believe that traditional analysts place too ing trade expansion and static welfare gains
much faith in the wisdom of the market and would be small but that larger markets could
are thus too ready to ignore aspects of real- produce substantial additional gains through
ity that do not conform to the competitive scale economies and increased innovation.
paradigm. For their part, traditional Canadian support for a free-trade agree-
economists believe that policy activists in- ment with the United States has likewise
spired by new 10-based theory place too rested mainly on presumed efficiency gains
much faith in the robustness of theoretical from a greatly enlarged market.
results and the feasibility of identifying and Indeed, international economists' strong
carrying out policies that actually improve belief in the importance of larger markets
social welfare. helps explain their generally optimistic as-
Given the enormous energy international sessment of regional free-trade initiatives,
economists devote to theoretical demonstra- despite the ambiguous welfare conclusions
tions of the nonoptimality of free trade, it of traditional customs-union theory. The
may seem incongruous that as a group they theoretical ambiguity arises because gains
have been for centuries and today remain from increased trade among partners can be
free-traders, virtually unanimous in reject- offset by losses from trade diversion (sub-
ing most trade intervention. Intimately stitution of partner imports for lower-cost
familiar with the leaky and incomplete goods produced elsewhere). However, even
theoretical case for the optimality of free selective trade liberalization means a larger
trade, traditional international economists market and associated dynamic benefits. The
nonetheless share a faith in what might be new 10-based theory supports this conven-
termed the practical case: that, as a real- tional wisdom, and recent empirical studies
world choice, free trade is almost always confirm that welfare gains from regional
optimal. Even the most prolific contributors liberalization can be far greater when mar-
to both old and new theories of optimal kets are imperfectly competitive (for refer-
trade intervention are notably reluctant to ences and evaluation, see J. David Richard-
translate their research findings into pre- son [1989] and Robert E. Baldwin [1992]).
scriptions for real-world policies. The practical case for free trade also rec-
ognizes the formidable obstacles to translat-
IV. Policy in Practice ing theoretically optimal intervention into
real-world welfare gains. Real-world poli-
In contrast to the traditional theoretical cies are chosen not by omniscient social-
case for free trade, with intellectual roots in welfare-maximizing technocrats, but by

This content downloaded from 116.72.52.125 on Mon, 06 Nov 2017 16:12:47 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
370 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY 1993

incompletely informed government officials vor. However, traditional discussions usually


vulnerable to influence from interested par- stress that strong theoretical conditions are
ties. Trade policy's impact on national wel- required for infant-industry protection to
fare is the net effect of much larger gains improve welfare; that most governments lack
and losses within the domestic economy. An the expertise to single out appropriate in-
industry can benefit handsomely from pro- dustries and the political will to reject pleas
tection that has a negligible or even a nega- from others; that even economically justi-
tive effect on national welfare.2 Moreover, fied infant-industry protection raises costs
implementation of optimizing intervention and thus harms prospects of downstream
requires detailed information on industry sectors; and finally, that no grown-up for-
cost and demand-future as well as current. mer infant relinquishes favorable treatment
The most reliable sources (but far from without a fight. The dismal track record in
neutral ones) are the industries themselves. most countries of interventions based on
A related problem is that the theoretical the infant-industry argument speaks for it-
standard against which optimality is mea- self (see Rodrik, 1992).3
sured in both traditional and newer IO- An additional complication is that most
based models is maximization of aggregate theoretical arguments, old and new, over-
national income or its present discounted state the benefits of change by comparing
value. No notice is taken of effects on distri- alternative equilibria without considering
bution; the implicit assumption is that unin- costs of moving between them.4 Yet real-
tended redistribution can be reversed cost- world discussions of trade policy often cen-
lessly through ideal lump-sum transfers and ter precisely on problems of adjustment.
that required government funding can be Adjustment costs not only temper the theo-
obtained costlessly through ideal lump-sum retical case for change, but are also crucial
taxes. In fact, neutralization of policy- at the practical level. Displaced resources
induced redistribution is the rare exception, that remain idle for an extended period are
and a policy's distributive consequences are both costly in terms of forgone output and
always considered along with its impact on politically troublesome.
aggregate performance. Significant redistri- Despite a widespread impression to the
bution implies large political costs and thus contrary, practitioners of the new trade the-
a strong bias in favor of the status quo. ory are no different from traditional ana-
(Dani Rodrik [1992] uses this observation to lysts in their reluctance to translate theory
explain why less-developed countries seem into practice. While some (e.g., Krugman,
to liberalize trade only under crisis condi- 1992) profess to a stance of "cautious ac-
tions.) tivism," all emphasize the same real-world
The traditional interpretation of the in- difficulties as traditional analysts. In fact,
fant-industry argument for protection is typ- the leap of faith from theoretical model to
ical in its reluctance to make the leap of policy prescription is even more hazardous
faith from theory to policy. The theory for the new theory than for the old. The
hinges on the dynamic nature of compara-
tive advantage: through learning-by-doing,
protection today yields benefits tomorrow
when an erstwhile infant becomes interna- 3Even apparent successes-former infant industries
tionally competitive. Despite its antiquity, now competitive in world markets-may not represent
the result of optimal policies, since today's benefits
this argument has a decidedly modern fla-
must be compared with earlier costs. The impressive
growth performance of Japan and Korea owes much to
policies inspired by infant-industry logic, yet no re-
search has demonstrated net social benefits even for
2The growing literature on rent-seeking and the these conspicuously successful cases of policy-guided
political economy of trade policy formalizes and mea- development.
sures these influences; see Krueger (1990) for discus- 4In Richardson's (1980) folksy analogy, we could be
sion and references. A pioneering contribution is better off at our lakeside cabin on a hot summer day,
Gordon Tullock (1967). yet worse off going there.

This content downloaded from 116.72.52.125 on Mon, 06 Nov 2017 16:12:47 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
VOL. 83 NO. 2 FREE TRADE: A LOSS OF (THEORETICAL) NERVE? 371

new theory's results usually hinge on as- Baldwin, Robert E., "Are Economists' Tradi-
sumptions about optimizing behavior of tional Trade Policy Views Still Valid?"
large individual firms, but economics is best Journal of Economic Literature, June 1992,
at modeling the actions of many agents, 30, 804-29.
worst when it comes to just a few. Conclu- Bhagwati, Jagdish N., The World Trading Sys-
sions are highly sensitive to assumptions tem at Risk, Princeton, NJ: Princeton
concerning competitors' behavior in University Press, 1991.
oligopolistic industries; what seems to be and Srinivasan, T. N., Lectures on
the case for a government subsidy under International Trade, Cambridge, MA: MIT
one assumption can become the case for a Press, 1983.
tax under a second and equally plausible Grossman, Gene M., "Strategic Export Pro-
assumption (Gene Grossman, 1986). motion: A Critique," in Paul R. Krug-
man, ed., Strategic Trade Policy and the
V. That Old Free-Trade Religion New International Economics, Cambridge
MA: MIT Press, 1986, pp. 47-68.
The noneconomist's stock discourse on Irwin, Douglas A., "Challenges to Free
trade policy begins, "Of course free trade is Trade," Journal of Economic Perspectives,
best in theory, but...," where what follows Spring 1991, 5, 201-7.
reveals scant familiarity with the content of Krueger, Anne 0., "The Political Economy of
the theory thus dismissed. International American Protection in Theory and in
economists, however, appear to have exactly Practice," National Bureau of Economic
the opposite view: that free trade is subopti- Research (Cambridge, MA) Working Pa-
mal in theory yet optimal in practice. The per No. 3544, December 1990.
theoretical suboptimality of free trade is the Krugman, Paul, "Does the New Trade The-
product of science; the belief in the practi- ory Require a New Trade Policy?" World
cal suboptimality of most intervention re- Economy, July 1992, 15, 423-42.
flects an appreciation of what lies beyond Richardson, J. David, Understanding Interna-
the narrow limits of that science. Although tional Economics, Boston: Little, Brown,
the new trade theory has significantly ex- 1980.
tended the domain of science, it has done , "Empirical Research on Trade Lib-
nothing to erode economists' traditional eralization Under Imperfect Competi-
skepticism concerning the prospects for tion: A Survey," OECD Economic Stud-
translating scientific possibility into real- ies, Spring 1989, 12, 7-51.
world results. Rodrik, Dani, "The Rush to Free Trade in
the Developing World: Why So Late?
Why Now? Will It Last?" National Bu-
REFERENCES reau of Economic Research (Cambridge,
MA) Working Paper No. 3947, January
Balassa, Bela, Trade Liberalization Among In- 1992.
dustrial Countries: Objectives and Alterna- Tullock, Gordon, "The Welfare Cost of Tar-
tives, New York: Council on Foreign Re- iffs, Monopolies, and Theft," Western
lations, 1967. Economic Journal, June 1967, 5, 224-32.

This content downloaded from 116.72.52.125 on Mon, 06 Nov 2017 16:12:47 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

You might also like