Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 17

!"#$%&'(%()*$+)&(%&,-*(%&.#$+(/-%&0"1$+%#$%*2&!3$%4&!3$+$4&-%5&!

367
.8*3"+9):2&'-+(-&;)/"<-+=,$##"%&-%5&'(/3$>>$&'?&@-6>"+=A"<(%)"%
B"8+/$2&.#$+(/-%&C"8+%->&"D&E">(*(/->&B/($%/$4&F">?&GH4&I"?&G&9J/*?4&KLLM:4&NN?&OKH=OGG
E8<>()3$5&<62&Midwest Political Science Association
B*-<>$&PA,2&http://www.jstor.org/stable/3647700 .
.//$))$52&LQRLGRKLQQ&QG2SS

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at .
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless
you have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you
may use content in the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use.

Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at .
http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=mpsa. .

Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed
page of such transmission.

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of
content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms
of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

Midwest Political Science Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to
American Journal of Political Science.

http://www.jstor.org
Women Ministers in Latin American Government:
When, Where, and Why?

MariaEscobar.LemmonTexasA&MUniversity
MichelleM.TaylorRobinson
TexasA&MUniversity

We examine factors that affect the supply of and demand for female cabinet ministers in Latin America and seek to
understandthefrequencywith which womenjoin cabinets and the types of portfolios women receive.Our analysis covers
18 Latin American democraciesfrom 1980 to 2003. Wefind that presidentsfrom parties of the left appoint more women.
Increasesin the percentageof women in the legislatureand higher human developmentcorrelatewith more women in the
cabinet. Intensepartisan competition increasesthe likelihoodthat a cabinet will contain a woman. Womenare more likely
to receivehigh-prestigecabinetpostsfrom leftistpresidentsand when the percentageof women in the legislatureincreases.
In addition, an internationaldiffusion effectappearsto explain the rapid expansion of women in Latin Americancabinets.

or manyyears,therehasbeeninternationalanddo- ing, women typicallyhold few top executiveposts.Latin


mesticinterestin expandingwomen'srepresenta- America,however,providesapuzzle.Relativeto theglobal
tion in politics.TheU.N. Conventionon the Elim- averageof women filling 12%of ministerialand vice-
ination of all Formsof DiscriminationagainstWomen ministerialposts, manywomen servein LatinAmerican
(1979) and the FourthWorld Conferenceon Women cabinets.In 2003, 18%of ministerswerefemale(up from
(Beijing1995)put women'srepresentationon the global 5% in 1980 and 7% in 1990). In some countries,such
agenda.Women'smovementspressuredgovernmentsto as Colombiaand Honduras,womenplayedan extremely
addressgenderinequalityin economic, social, and po- largerole in the cabinet,holding 50 and 29%of minis-
litical spheresand to follow through on international terialposts in 2003 and 2002, respectively.In generalin
commitments. the world'sdemocracies,when women are found in the
In responseto this pressure,some democracieshave cabinetit is in a subsetof allministries-typicallythe less
seen a significantexpansionin women'srepresentation. prestigiousportfolios:culture,education,environment,
In Argentina,the 1991 Leyde Cuposestablisheda 30% family,health,women'saffairs(Davis 1997;IPU 1999).
quotafor women in electablepositionson partylists for In a growingnumberof LatinAmericancountries,how-
the Chamberof Deputies,and women'srepresentation ever,womenhold high-prestigeposts.Between2000and
increasedfrom 5% in 1983 to 21% in 1993, and 32% 2003 womenheld prestigiousministriessuch as Finance
in 2001 (Jones1996).Women'srepresentationin Costa (CostaRica,Ecuador,Guatemala,Honduras,Venezuela),
Rica'sLegislativeAssemblyincreasedfrom 7% in 1974 ForeignRelations(Chile,Colombia,Ecuador,ElSalvador,
to 19%in 1998beforeimplementationof a 40%gender Mexico),andDefense(ChileandColombia).Whyis there
quota law; to 35%in 2002 afterthe law took effect. In apparentlyless genderbiasin the cabinetsof theseosten-
Scandinavia,women havereachednearparitywith men siblymore"macho"countries?
in legislatures,and thereis significantrepresentationof Thisarticleexploresreasonsfor this strongrepresen-
womenin cabinets(Skjeie1991). tationof womenin thisseeminglyunlikelyregionbyseek-
Globally,genderparity remainsthe exceptionand ingto understandtheconditionsunderwhichwomenjoin
evenwherewomen'snumbersin legislaturesareincreas- president'scabinetsand the types of portfolioswomen
MariaEscobar-Lemmonis assistantprofessorof political science, TexasA&M University,TAMU-4348,College Station, TX 77843-4348
(escobar@polisci.tamu.edu).MichelleM. Taylor-Robinsonis associateprofessorof political science,TexasA&MUniversity,TAMU-4348,
College Station,TX 77843-4348 (e339mt@polisci.tamu.edu).
We thankMarkJonesand LeslieA. Schwindt-Bayerfor lending us data for this project.We thank JudithBaer,LisaBaldez,and MarkJones
for commenting on the article and David A.M. Petersonfor helpful discussions regardingmethodology and analysis.Finallywe thank
ZeynepSomer and ChristinaSuthammanontfor extensivedata entry for this project.Any errorsare our own.
AmericanJournal of Political Science,Vol. 49, No. 4, October2005, Pp. 829-844

?2005 by the MidwestPoliticalScienceAssociation ISSN 0092-5853

829
830 MARIAESCOBAR-LEMMON M. TAYLOR-ROBINSON
AND MICHELLE

receive. Representation of women in cabinets is impor- factors affect women in the same way.' We acknowledge,
tant for many reasons, including the cost to democracy however, that there are differences between presidential
of excluding half of the citizens from the highest levels of and parliamentary systems that may affect cabinet ap-
policymaking (Jaquetteand Wolchik 1998; Phillips 1991; pointment decisions. A Prime Minister's need to sustain
Sapiro 1981), and because cabinet posts are often an im- a vote of confidence in the parliament versus the sepa-
portant recruiting group for chief executives. We test hy- rate origin and survival of the executive in presidential
potheses about supply and demand factors thought to systems should allow presidents more freedom in mak-
influence representation of women and juxtapose those ing cabinet appointments than Prime Ministers (Blondel
findings againstthe diffusion hypothesis (Htun and Jones 1985: Chapter 3). In addition, parliamentarysystems of-
2001; True and Mintrom 2001). The next section reviews ten have a norm, if not a legal rule, that cabinet ministers
the literature and presents hypotheses. Then we present are members of parliament. No such requirement exists
the findings of our cross-national, time-serial analysis of in presidential systems, and some countries require that
Latin American presidents' cabinets. We conclude that a legislator resign her seat to take an executive post.
diffusion is a more likely explanation for increased repre-
sentation of women in Latin American cabinets than the
slower process of change in domestic supply and demand FactorsAffecting the Supply
found in highly industrialized democracies. of FemaleMinisters
The supply of potential women ministers is determined
in part by whether women desire such jobs. We assume
Literature and Hypotheses some ambitious politicians of both genders want to be
cabinet ministers because ministers influence policy and
control extensive resources (e.g., budgets, pork, jobs).
A varietyof explanations havebeen offered for why leaders
The pool of qualified women also affects the supply.2
appoint women to their cabinets and place them in pres- Ministers are typically well educated and professionals
tige positions including political and socioeconomic fac-
(Davis 1997; Norris 1987; Sainsbury 2004; Studlar and
tors and diffusion effects. Norris (1987, 1997a) presents
Moncrief 1997;Thiebault 1991). Htun (2003) cites the in-
"supply"and "demand"components of political recruit-
ment. Supply components include candidates' motiva- creasing education and percentage of women in the labor
force in LatinAmerica as reasons why women's represen-
tions and political capital (e.g., financial assets, party
tation in politics has increased. More generally,education
experience, connections, occupational and educational and participation in the labor force has a positive effect on
qualifications, legislative skills). The demand side of re-
cruitment to the legislature is determined by those who political activity by women (True and Mintrom 2001).3
select candidates and decide the qualifications needed. People enter the cabinet in various ways (e.g., the
For cabinet recruitment, demand should be a function military, bureaucracy), but experience in elected office is
the main path in most parliamentary systems (Blondel
of political benefits and costs of filling a cabinet post
with a woman vs. a man, or representing another group
(e.g., ethnic minority, coalition partner). Benefits may 'The "thirdwave"of democratizationbeganin SouthernEuropein
also come from compliance with treaties, or increased re- 1974 and spreadto LatinAmericain the 1980s,and then to Eastern
Europein the late 1980s (Huntington 1991).
spect for a country as international pressure for women's
2Normsand legalrequirementsfor servingin the cabinetvary(e.g.,
equality increases (see Htun and Jones 2001; True and whetherministersarespecialistsor generalists).Parliamentarycab-
Mintrom 2001). inet composition can be affectedby the need to satisfythe portfolio
Norris developed her conceptualization of supply and requestsof coalitionpartners,while presidentshavemore freedom
demand factors affecting recruitment to understand the in makingappointments(Blondel 1985). SeeBlondel(1991), Davis
(1997), and Laverand Shepsle (1994) about requirementsto be a
relationship between gender and attainment of legislative ministerin a WesternEuropeancabinet.
seats in established democracies in Western Europe. We
3However,Matland (1998) found participationin the labor force
transfer her concepts to Latin America for two reasons.
only had a positive and significant effect on election of women
One, supply and demand factors affecting cabinet ap- in industrializedcountries. In less-developedcountries it was not
pointments incorporate forces presidents do and do not significant. Inglehartand Norris (2003) caution that, even when
women's education and professionalstatus increase,culturalbar-
control when making cabinet selections. Two, this frame- riers such as attitudesabout the proper role of women and about
work allows us to make a direct comparison between es- gender (in)equality,may still impede qualifiedwomen from par-
tablished and third-wave democracies to see if the same ticipatingin politics.
WOMENMINISTERSIN LATINAMERICANGOVERNMENT 831

1987; Davis 1997; Kobayashi2004; Norris 1997a).4 Davis 1987; Studlar and Moncrief 1999; Thidbault 1991).6 In
expected increased numbers of female parliamentarians Latin America as well, left parties have adopted women-
to create "an irreversible process of change" (1997, 64) friendly platforms (Htun 2003).7 Presidents from left
in attitudes and expectations about women that would parties may anticipate greater benefits from appointing
lead to more women in the cabinet. We test for such women to their cabinets than do presidents from right
an effect on Latin American cabinets. It is worth not- parties. Thus:
ing, however, that other researchersargue that election to
the legislature may not be sufficient, or even necessary. H2: Theprobabilitythat women will be appointed
Kobayashi (2004) explains that few women have served to the cabinet, and that they will receivetop posts,
in the JapaneseDiet long enough to develop the connec- increaseswhen thepresidentis from a leftparty.
tions and patronagenecessaryfor rising to top party ranks
(also see Rodriguez [2003] about Mexico)." Studlar and The effect of party ideology may diminish over time,
Moncrief (1997) found that high turnover in parliamen- however.In establishedparliamentarydemocracies center
tary systems decreasesthe length of service needed before and right parties adopted women-friendly policies due to
appointment to the cabinet. As turnover is high in many concern about losing votes to left parties (Caul 2001; Davis
LatinAmerican legislatures(Morgensternand Nacif 2002; 1997; IPU 1999; Matland and Studlar 1996; Norris 1987,
Schwindt-Bayer2005), long service in congress may not 1997b; Phillips 1991; Skjeie 1991; Studlar and Matland
be necessary for cabinet appointments in Latin America 1996;Studlarand Moncrief 1997). In LatinAmerica in the
either. In addition, in presidential systems ministers do 90s, diverse parties sought to woo women voters (Baldez
not have to come from the legislature, so increasing rep- 2002; Htun 2003, 128), so party ideology may only weakly
resentation of women in the congress may not affect se- affect cabinet appointments in third wave democracies.
lection of women for cabinet posts. The president's support in the legislature may affect
Thus, we expect the probability that women will be the cost to the president of appointing women ministers
appointed to the cabinet and will receive top-ranking and the posts they receive (Reynolds 1999). A president
posts increases as: whose party has a majority does not need to form a coali-
tion to pass bills.8 A majority president does not pay the
H1a: More women have advancededucation. cost of giving up scarce cabinet seats that he could give to
leaders of other parties to form alliances when he gives a
H lb: More women have experience in the
cabinet post to a woman, so he can use cabinet appoint-
workforce. ments to reach out to new groups, such as women, if he
H1c: Thereare more women in the legislature. chooses to do so. A president without a majority (or with

6Caul(2001) found that both "old"and "new"left partiesaremore


FactorsAffecting the Demand likelythan centerand rightpartiesareto adoptpartygenderquotas.
for FemaleMinisters
7Interestingly,the "gendergap"in LatinAmericanvoting indicates
Demand for women ministers is a function of political that women are more likely than men are to vote for conservative
parties(Htun 2003, 126-28; Baldez2002, 26-27).
benefits and costs for a president of appointing a woman
to a post. Research in Western Europe and Canada has 8Whenpresidentscontrolpartynominationsorappointmentto fu-
ture politicaljobs for legislators,as in many LatinAmericancoun-
found that left parties are more "women friendly" than tries, these "partisanpowers"mean the president rarelyneeds to
are right parties. Left parties included women's rights and worry about maintainingthe support of his party'sbackbenchers.
LatinAmericanpresidentsoften have constitutionaldecree pow-
feminist issues in their platforms and spearheaded ef-
ers that allow them to legislatewithout the legislature,particularly
forts to enact gender quotas (Davis 1997; Duverger 1955; when theyarelikelyto lackpartisanpower(CareyandShugart1998;
Lovenduski and Norris 1993; Norris 1987, 1997b; Rule Mainwaringand Shugart1997;Shugart1998). However,we focus
on whether the president'sparty has a majority in the congress,
becausepresidentswho lack partisanpowersoften face confronta-
tional legislatures,and decree powers are often limited to specific
4ManyU.S. cabinetsecretariesareformerbusinessleaders,lawyers,
topical areasor may be temporallyconstrained.An importantdif-
professors,governors,membersof congress,or civilservants.How- ferencebetweenpresidentialand parliamentarysystemsis that,due
ever, Blondel describesthe United Statesas a very "open"system
where "the 'routes'to ministerialoffice are scarcelydeterminedat to separationof survival,a presidentis guaranteeda full term in
office evenif he lacksthe backingof the congress,whilea primemin-
all"(1985, 14).
istercould be removed.Thus,presidentsdo not alwayshavecontrol
5InWesternEurope,women are more likelythan are men to enter over theirparty'sbackbenchers,so a president'sexpectationsabout
the cabinet from outside parliamentor to have servedfeweryears executive-legislativerelationsought to be part of the cost/benefit
in the parliament(de Winter 1991). analysiswhen the presidentis selectingcabinetmembers.
832 MARIAESCOBAR-LEMMON
AND MICHELLE
M. TAYLOR-ROBINSON

a narrow,unreliable majority) may pay a high cost for ap- Effectsof Timeon Demand
pointing women to his cabinet, as those posts arenot used for FemaleMinisters
to bring other parties into the cabinet to build an informal
coalition government, as party leaders are usually male The cost or benefit of appointing women to the cabinet
and they will expect to occupy these posts (Amorim Neto can change over time. Change can occur slowly, as people
2002; Shvedova 1997). Therefore, a president who is not become accustomed to women holding important gov-
concerned with building legislative support, or shoring ernment positions (Caul 2001). They may question the
up copartisan support, can afford the luxury of reaching first president to appoint a woman to his cabinet, but if
out to new groups through his cabinet appointments if successive presidents also appoint women, doing so be-
he chooses to do so. Thus: comes the norm (see Sainsbury 2004), and a later presi-
dent maybe criticized for not appointing any women. The
amount of time since women received the right to vote
H3: Theprobabilitythat women will be appointed
and to hold office or since the first woman was elected to
to the cabinet,and receivetopcabinetpostsincreases
the legislature may indirectly measure how accustomed
when the president'sparty has a securemajorityin
the legislature. people are to women in politics, and thus the cost a pres-
ident will pay for not including women in the cabinet.
Time passing may also lead to women receiving top cab-
However, the literature examining women's recruit- inet posts if the norm is to enter the cabinet in lower
ment in industrialized democracies makes an alternative
ranking ministries (de Winter 1991;Studlarand Moncrief
argument: "Close competition among political parties 1999). A society may become more accepting of women
should be beneficial to women being appointed to the cab- in government as it becomes more educated (Davis 1997;
inet since the government wants to appealto women swing Studlar and Moncrief 1997), thus lowering the cost to
voters"(Studlarand Moncrief 1997, 69; Davis 1997). That a president of appointing women. Surveys show Latin
literaturemeasures party competition in terms of seats in Americans are becoming receptive to women in politics
the legislature. Party competition was an important fac-
(Htun 2003; Inglehart and Norris 2003).10Therefore, we
tor in the increasing election of women to the Swedish
expect the probability women will be appointed to the
parliament in the 1970s, and women's representation in cabinet to increase as:
appointed positions in the 1990s (Sainsbury 2004; Skjeie
1991). Latin American parties, when locked in a closely H5: More years have passed since women became
competitive electoral situation may also view appealing to visible in politics.
women voters as a useful strategy,particularlyas their ca-
pacity to differentiatethemselves on economic policy has H6: The overall education level of the people of a
been diminished by economic structuraladjustment poli- country increases.
cies.9 Forpresidentswho are eligible for reelection (e.g., in
Argentina, Brazil, Peru, Venezuela), wooing women sup- International incentives or pressures to incorporate
porters for future elections may be an appealing strategy, women have also changed over time. Unlike the domestic
as some gender issues cut acrosspartylines. In sum, a com- factors mentioned above that gradually increase bene-
petitive electoral environment may cause the president to fits and reduce costs to a president of appointing women
perceive reaching out to women voters as beneficial to ministers, international change may rapidly raise the cost
himself or his party in the next election, which may be a of not having at least token representation of women
nonconcurrent legislativeor local election and not simply in top levels of government (see Htun and Jones 2001).
the next presidential election. Therefore: Trueand Mintrom (2001) explore how transnational net-
works and international norms have produced a rapid
H4: When the electoralsituation for parties is in- global diffusion effect, putting pressure on governments
to incorporate women. They expect a period effect to
tensely competitive, women are more likely to be
model pressures for expanded women's rights, becom-
appointed to the cabinet and receive top cabinet
posts. ing most pronounced after the 1995 Beijing Conference
on Women.

makesa similarargument
9Phillips forwhypartiesin Scandinavian "A woman president might also increase acceptanceof women
countries would try to differentiatethemselveson women's con- as cabinet ministers, but its rarity makes it difficult to test (i.e.,
cerns "againstthe deadeningweight of inter-partyconsensus on Argentina1974-76, Bolivia 1979-80, Nicaragua1990-97, Panama
economic affairs"(1991, 88). 1999-04).
WOMENMINISTERSIN LATINAMERICANGOVERNMENT 833

With regardto the generalstatusof women, things theirportfolioandgender.13 Wethenplacedeachministry


were not the same in 2000 as they were in 1980. The into a categorybasedon its areasof responsibility(e.g.,we
reasonsfor this are myriadand reflecta changingen- groupedministriesrelatingto landmanagement,agricul-
vironment, both domestic andinternational,as women's ture,livestockandfisheriesinto anAgriculturecategory).
movementsand organizations,NGOs,and international Thisgaveus 23 distinctministerialcategories.
organizationshaveput pressureon governmentsto im- We then grouped these categories into high-,
prove women's rights(Htun2003;Jaquette1997;Jaquette medium-, and low-prestigeministries. High-prestige
and Wolchik 1998; Luciak2001; Rodriguez 2003). Thus: ministriesexercisesignificantcontroloverpolicy,arevery
prestigious,andarehighlyvisible:FinanceandEconomy,
H7: Womenwill become more numerous in cabi- and PublicSecu-
ForeignAffairs,Government/Interior,
nets and gain accessto prestigepositions over time.
rity and Defense.14Medium-prestigeministerscontrol
significantfinancialresources,butlackthe prestigeof top
Dataand Variables posts:Agriculture,ConstructionandPublicWorks,Edu-
cation,Environmentand NaturalResources,Healthand
SocialWelfare,Industryand Commerce,Justice,Labor,
We assembled data on cabinet composition for 18 Latin
Transportation, Communicationsand Information,and
American countries from 1980 to 2003. We include only
democratic periods in our analysis because the cabinet
Planning Development.All otherministriesarelow-
and
prestigeand offer few resourcesfor patronage:Children
may be a signal of the president's policy intentions in and Family,Culture,Science and Technology,Sports,
a democracy, but it is not clear it serves that purpose
Tourism,Women'sAffairs,ministersfor reformof the
in authoritarian regimes. We could not collect data on
state,temporaryand transientministries,and ministers
cabinets before 1980, so we begin observing a country in
withoutportfolio.'5
or
1980 the start of democracy whichever is later."1
The composition of cabinets is from data compiled
by the U.S. State Department and the CIA in Countriesof
We only retainedfor our analysispeople whose title was Minister
the Worldand TheirLeadersYearbooks. This annual publi- or Secretary.The exception is AttorneysGeneralwho function as
cation records the name and title of all ministers. Because JusticeMinisterin countrieswithout a Ministerof Justice.
cabinet changes occur often in a president'sterm (45% of 13The authors and a native Spanish speakerindependentlycoded
the ministers in our study serve only a single year and only each minister'sgender. We resolved disagreementsby consulting
16%serve four years or more), we recorded the composi- country expertsand with web searchesfor photos or referencesto
the minister,using genderedSpanishpronouns.
tion of the cabinet yearly.' For each minister we recorded
'4TheMinistryof Government(analogousto Interior)is included
in the high-prestigecategorybecause in much of Latin America
11Thedataset includes: Argentina (1984-2003), Bolivia (1983- this ministeris responsiblefor shepherdingthe president'sdomes-
2003), Brazil (1985-2003), Chile (1990-2003), Colombia (1980- tic agenda through congress,and it is a common springboardfor
2003), CostaRica(1980-2003), Dominican Republic(1980-2003), presidentialcandidates.
Ecuador(1980-2003), El Salvador(1986-2003), Guatemala(1986-
2003), Honduras (1983-2003), Mexico (1980-2003), Nicaragua 15Prestige of cabinet portfolios has been measuredin the United
Statesbasedon cabinettransfersand size of budgetsand personnel
(1986-2003), Panama (1991-2003), Paraguay(1990-2003), Peru
(1980-2003), Uruguay(1986-2003), and Venezuela(1980-2003). (Weisberg1987). Rose (1987) categorizedBritishministriesbased
Wedefinedthe "startdate"of democracyin eachcountryas the first on media and parliamentaryattention, use as a stepping stone to
time competitivepresidentialelectionswere held. While questions higherposts, and chairingcabinetcommittees.Suchindicatorsare
not feasibleto implement acrossour 18 countries.However,a sur-
surroundingthe "freeness"of this electionmayarisefor a few cases,
we arguethatevenif competitionwasrestricted,presidentsstillmay vey of literatureon cabinetsshows a largelyconsistent listing of a
have felt pressuredto take steps after the election to try to legiti- few "core"ministries.Financeand ForeignAffairsare listed most
mate the results (in part through cabinet appointments).We also frequently;Defense, Interior,and Justiceare also often listed as
addressedthis statistically,by estimating models using only data high prestige(see Blondel and Thiebault 1991;Laverand Shepsle
after 1990 (which excludesmany of the questionableelections) as 1994). Though even within this short list of prestigiousministries,
well as by reestimatingthe model and excludinga differentcountry there are exceptions. In interviews,ministers in Norway did not
each time. The results were substantivelysimilar (see Appendix) list Defense in the top six most prestigiousportfolios, and Social
and give us confidence in the validityof our chosen start date for Affairswas listed as the second most important(Skjeie1991). Due
each country.The laterapproachalso allowedus to control for the to the absenceof studyof cabinetassignmentsin LatinAmerica,we
impactof Colombiaadoptinga quotafor representationof women categorizedministries loosely based on two dimensions:national
in the executivebranchin 2000. policy prestigeand budgetsize (as a measureof porkand patronage
control enjoyedby the minister,since such resourcesare often key
12Blondel (1985) also found that the durationof ministersin Latin to building political power in LatinAmerica).We place the Justice
Americawas short.Thereis a lag in the datadue to publishingtime. ministry in the Medium prestigecategorybecause its jurisdiction
The cabinetdata recordsthe name of the president,so we used the often overlapswith the SupremeCourt and it lacks the visibility,
presidentto line up the cabinet data with the electoralvariables. prestige,and policy influence of other high-prestigeministries.
834 MARIAESCOBAR-LEMMON
AND MICHELLE
M. TAYLOR-ROBINSON

We measurewomen'seducation(Hla) as the per- measure to test both hypotheses. Presidentshave a secure


centageof women of secondaryschool age enrolledin majority if their party controls 55% or more of the seats
secondaryeducation.16 Theliteratureanticipatesthatad- in a unicameral congress or both chambers of a bicameral
vancededucationqualifiespeopleto be ministers,butdata congress. The party of a near majority/narrowminority
arenot availablefor most countriesconcerningwomen's president holds 45 to 54.9% of the seats in a unicam-
attainmentof tertiaryeducation.Workforceparticipation eral congress or in the chamber of a bicameral congress
(Hlb) is measuredwith the percentageof the laborforce in which the party is least well represented. A minority
comprisedof women.17Joiningthe workforceas a maid president's party holds less than 44.9% of the seats in a
or agriculturallaboreris not the same as holdinga pro- unicameral congress or in the chamber of a bicameral
fessionaljob, and theoryexpectsthat more women will congress in which the party is least well represented. H3
obtaintopgovernmentpostsasthenumberof femalepro- suggests a positive coefficient for secure majority presi-
fessionalsincreases(Jaquette1997).Becausedataregard- dents. H4 suggests a positive coefficient for near major-
ingwomenholdingprofessionaljobsarenot available,the ity/narrow minority presidents. We adopt this trichoto-
percentageof womenin the workforceis commonlysub- mous measure instead of simply using the percentage of
stituted.Wemeasurerepresentation in congress(HIc) as seats held by the president'spartybecause the relationship
thepercentageof womenin thelower(oronly)chamber.'18 is not a simple linear (or even curvilinear) one. Consider
Tomeasurewhetherthe presidentis froma left party a 10-point change in the percentage of seats held by the
(H2) we want to accountfor the fact that left and right president's party. A 10-point gain for a president whose
arerelativewithina givencountry,thuswe codewhether party has 65% of the seats in the legislature is unlikely to
the presidentwas to the left or rightof the second-place change his legislative strategy because his party already
finisher.19We use this variableinsteadof a region-wide controls the majority needed to legislate (even a loss of
ideologicalcodingbecausewe do not wishto testwhether 10 points would not change his status). The same could
presidentswho areleftists,relativeto all partiesin Latin be said for a president at the other extreme whose party
America,are friendlierto women. Instead,we wish to controls 25% of the seats. Adding 10 percentage points
test whetherpresidentswho are perceivedas liberalin will not change the fact that he still needs another party
theircountry(regardlessof whethera country'sideolog- to support his proposals for them to pass. However, for
icalspectrumis narrowor wide or centeredon the left or a president whose party controls only 40% of the seats,
right)werefriendlierto women. that 10-point change could make all the difference. Thus,
To test H3 and H4, which concernhow intraparty the trichotomous variable better captures the incentives
and partysystempoliticscan affectthe president'sdeci- the president faces. Additionally, party switching occurs
sion calculus,we collecteddataon the percentageof seats frequently in some countries (Brazil, Ecuador, Panama)
held by the president'sparty.H3 concernswhetherthe making broad categories a more accuratereflection of the
president'spartyhas a securemajorityin the legislature. president's support than a percentage that might change
H4 concernswhetherthe partysystemis highlycompeti- during a president'sterm.20
tiveor dominatedby one party.Theliteratureexamining To test the effect of increased visibility of women
appointmentof womento cabinetsin parliamentary sys- in politics (H5) we include the number of years since
tems,wherethislaterhypothesiswasdeveloped,measures a woman was first elected to the legislature.21We use the
partysystemcompetitivenessin termsof seatsin the leg- Human Development Index (HDI) to measure the over-
islature,thuswe do the same.Wedevelopa trichotomous all education level of a country (H6).22 The percentage
of a country's population with higher education might
16Dataarefromthe WorldBank'sGenderStats.We use dataon
current enrollment for the only years available1980, 1990, 1995, better capture the open-minded, more egalitarian out-
2000. Data from 1980 were entered for 1980-87, data from 1990 look that is expected to come with increasing levels of
for 1988-94, data from 1995 for 1995-99 and data from 2000 for education in a society, but tertiary education statistics are
2000-03.
17Dataare from the WorldBank'sGenderStats. 20Weobtainsubstantivelysimilarresultsfor all othervariablesusing
the percentageof seats the president'sparty has in the legislature.
"8Dataare from the Inter-Parliamentary Union (IPU 1995). The coefficient for this variableis negative,but not significantin
'9Data on the of
ideologicalplacement partiesare from Coppedge the model predictingappointment of any women to the cabinet
(1997) and AlcantaraSaez and Freidenberg(2001). We combined and positiveand significantat the .10 level in the model predicting
the two sources to better cover our 1980-2003 time period. The the percentageof the cabinetthat is female.
correlationbetween the two indices is quite high. Differenceswere
resolvedin consultationwith countryexperts.Usingonlythe coding 21Dataare from the Inter-Parliamentary
Union (IPU 2000).
from a single sourceproducednearlyidenticalresults(allowingfor 22Data are from the United Nations Human Development
a differencein sample size). Indicators.
WOMENMINISTERSIN LATINAMERICANGOVERNMENT 835

often lacking for countries and years, and are unreliable Gaussian distribution, which produces OLS coefficients,
for comparison across countries. Instead, we use HDI to again correcting for first-order autocorrelation. In the
measure the overall education level in society. This is ad- models presented in Table 1, we include the number of
vantageous because it encompasses several development cabinet positions (range 8-26) as a control to capture the
measures (education, life expectancy,GDP/capita) allow- greater cost (perceived or real) of appointing women in
ing for a more well-rounded picture of societal education. small vs. large cabinets.
In addition to being theoretically separate from women's Only two of the three supply variables exert a statis-
education levels, it is empirically separate, which allows tically significant effect. The percentage of women in the
us to assess the effect of women's education and societal workforce did not approach statistical significance. This
education simultaneously. reinforces Matland's (1998) finding about the impact of
To test for period effects (H7) we include dummy labor force participation on election of women to the leg-
variables for each five-year lapse of time in our data set. islature in less developed countries. Matland (1998, 118)
Following True and Mintrom (2001), these five-year in- argues that in developing countries women are often em-
tervals coincide with the periods of the U.N. world con- ployed in the primary sector in jobs that are unlikely to
ferences on women. This operationalization allows for an raise their consciousness or empower women, as union-
explicit comparison of previous periods with the current ized jobs in industrialized countries are expected to (also
one. see Jaquette 1997). We concur, and add that low prestige
jobs do not increasethe supply of women with the qualifi-
cations to serve in the cabinet. Surprisingly,an increase in
women's secondaryschool enrollment decreasesthe prob-
Analysis and Results ability women will be appointed to the cabinet. In Model 1,
each 1%increase in women's enrollment decreasesby 3%
Cabinet shuffles are frequent in Latin America, and 45% the chances that there will be a woman in the cabinet.
of the ministers in our sample serve only one year.23 In Model 2, higher enrollment translates into a .16% de-
Therefore, we model the appointment of women annu- creasein the percentageof female ministers. Inglehartand
ally because typically at least a few ministers change each Norris (2003, 131) found that in some cases increases in
year. We do recognize, however, that within a presiden- women's education and professional status do not corre-
tial administration, the composition of each cabinet is not late with higher representationof women in the legislature
independent of the previous one and that serialautocorre- and argue that cultural attitudes about women may be the
lation is likely to be present within each panel. We correct explanation.
for this by estimating all models using Generalized Esti- More women in the legislature increases the num-
mating Equations (GEE).24Model 1 considers the factors ber of female ministers, as expected. In Model 1, a coun-
that prompt a president to appoint any women to the cab- try with the minimum observed percentage of women
inet. The dependent variablefollows a binary distribution in congress (0%) has only a .46 probability of having a
(does the cabinet contains at least one woman?), which woman in the cabinet, holding all other variables at their
leads us to specify the use of the logit link and to correct mean. The same country, with an average percentage of
for first-order autocorrelation within each panel.25The women in the congress (9%) has a .71 probability of hav-
Model 1 coefficients are in fact logit coefficients, and all ing at least one woman in cabinet. When the percentage
the usual caveats regardinginterpretation apply. Model 2 of women in the chamber reachesthe maximum observed
uses the percentage of cabinet seats held by women as value (35%) the probability the cabinet will include a
the dependent variable. We specify the identity link and a woman is .98. In Model 2, each 1% increase in women
in the chamber increases the percentage of women in the
23Inour dataset 23% of the ministers serve two years, 14%three cabinet by .29%, thus if a country moved from an average
years,9%fouryears,and 7%fiveyearsor more. Blondel(1985) also
found that ministersin presidentialsystems, particularlyin Latin percentage of women in congress (9%) to near the maxi-
America,serveshort terms. mum (say 30%), we would expect a concomitant increase
of 6% in the number of women in the cabinet.
24Likethe GeneralizedLinearModel,GeneralizedEstimatingEqua-
tions (GEE)allows us to specify the distributionof the dependent Hypothesis 2 predicts presidents from left parties will
variableandthe link function,but unlikeGLM,it is intendedspecif- be more likely to appoint women to their cabinet than will
icallyfor panel data (see Zorn 2001). presidents from right parties. In Model 1, the coefficient
25Forall models, we tested for serialautocorrelationusing the test is positive, but not significant. In Model 2, the impact of
for autocorrelationin paneldataderivedbyWooldridge(2002) and
left presidents on the gender composition of cabinets is
implementedby Drukker(2003). The test statisticis positive indi-
cating autocorrelationis present.Resultswere substantivelyiden- small, as left presidents are expected to have only about
tical correctingfor AR2 and AR3 disturbances. 1.6% more women in their cabinets.
836 MARIAESCOBAR-LEMMON
AND MICHELLE
M. TAYLOR-ROBINSON

TABLE
1 Determinants of the Appointment of Women to a President'sCabinet
Model 1: A Model 2: B
Dependent Variable Any Womenin Cabinet Percent Female Cabinet

SupplyVariables
Percent of women enrolled -.033* -.159***
in secondaryeducation (.017) (.043)
Percentof women in labor force -.038 .099
(.064) (.164)
Percentof chambercomposed .117* .292**
of women (.055) (.113)
Demand Variables
Presidentfrom left party .452 1.556'
(.379) (.939)
Securemajoritypresident -.244 -1.737
(.554) (1.459)
Near majority/Narrow .795A 1.576
minority president (.429) (1.049)
Human DevelopmentIndex .532 22.371*
(4.417) (10.567)
Number of yearssince first woman .034 .104
elected to legislature (.030) (.076)
ControlVariables
Number of ministersin cabinet .102 .042
(.065) (.148)
1980-1984 -2.295* -7.680***
(.989) (2.449)
1985-1989 -1.922* -8.476***
(.825) (1.958)
1990-1994 -1.176A -6.922***
(.689) (1.603)
1995-1999 -.413 -7.058***
(.628) (1.372)
Constant .168 -5.182
(3.529) (8.581)
N 311 311
Wald X2 25.23 75.91
Prob > X2 (.022) (.000)
Pseudo R2C .22 .30
Ap > .10, *p > .05, **p> .01, ***p> .005.
ADependentvariableis coded 1 if the cabinetcontains one or more women, zero otherwise.Estimatesproducedusing
Stata'sXTGEEcommand and specifying logit link, binomial family and AR(1) correlation.Coefficients should be
interpretedas Logit coefficients.
BDependent variableis the percentageof ministerialpositionsgivento women.EstimatesproducedusingStata's
XTGEEcommandand specifyingidentitylink, Gaussianfamily,and AR(1)correlation.Coefficientsshouldbe
asOLScoefficients.
interpreted
CSquaredcorrelationbetween the dependentvariableand the predictedvalues from the model.

In both models, the coefficientfor SecureMajor- likelyto appointwomento theircabinets.Thecoefficient


ity presidentis negative,but not significantindicating for Near Majority/Narrow Minoritypresidentis signif-
thatthey arenot more or less likelythan minoritypresi- icant and positivein Model 1 (they are 2.2 times more
dentsto appointwomen.This contradictsH3, whichex- likelyto appointat leastone womanto theircabinetthan
pected that SecureMajoritypresidentswould be more a minoritypresident),andpositive,but not significantin
WOMENMINISTERSIN LATINAMERICANGOVERNMENT 837

1 Number of Women Holding Ministerial Positions Over


FIGURE
Time

30
E High Prestige Ministers
MediumPrestige Ministers
25 25 -
0 Low Prestige Ministers

20

15

10

N N N \Ob

Model 2.26 This provides limited support for H4, which presented in Figure 1 this is not surprising-by the mid-
predicted women would be more likely to be appointed 1990s a president had to have at least one woman in his
to the cabinet when partisan competition is intense. cabinet. This is similar to Trueand Mintrom's finding that
The number of yearssince a woman was elected to the "momentum for adoption of gender mainstreaming built
legislature (H5) has the expected sign, but is not signifi- up in the 1990s" (2001, 47). All coefficients in Model 2
cant in either model. HDI (H6) is positive as expected in are statisticallysignificant and substantivelylarge. All else
both models, but is not significant in Model 1. It is signif- being equal, the model predicts that a cabinet appointed
icant in Model 2, but while the coefficient is large (22.4), between 1980 and 1984 will contain 7.7 percentagepoints
the substantive impact is small because HDI ranges be- fewer women than a cabinet appointed between 2000 and
tween zero and one (mean of.71, observed range of.55 to 2003. In an average-sizedcabinet (14 members), that de-
.84). Moving from our observed minimum to maximum cline represents one fewer woman minister and in the
(a major feat) would increase the expected percentage of largestcabinet (26 members), it representstwo fewer.That
women in the cabinet by 6.5%. A more realistic increase difference is still noticeable in the 1990s (when all third-
of one standarddeviation (.07) would result in 1.6%more wave democracies are in our dataset), as we would expect
women in the cabinet. the percentage of the cabinet that is female to be 6.9%
Finally, we examine how diffusion (spread of ideas lower between 1990 and 1994 than 2000 and 2003. (See
and norms) affects appointment of women (H7). The co- Appendix for robustness tests.)
efficients for all the time variables are negative, implying We now turn to whether cabinet assignments differ
that present day cabinets aremore likelyto contain women by gender. Figure 1 shows a steady increase in the number
(or have higher percentages of women) than earlier pe- of female ministers, but indicates that women have not
riods. In Model 1, all time coefficients, except the 1995- done as well at obtaining top ministries, as most female
99 period, achieve statistical significance. All else being ministers occupy low- or medium-prestige posts.
equal, the chance of an all-male cabinet was the same be- A common expectation is that when there arewomen
tween 1995 and 1999 as today, but that chance was much in the cabinet they receive "soft" or low-prestige portfo-
greaterin earlier periods than it is now. Given the trends lios (Reynolds 1999; Rodriguez 2003; Skjeie 1991).27 Is

26The difference between Secure Majority Presidents and Near 27Skjeie(1991) shows that this expectation is not accurate in
Majority/NarrowMinorityPresidentsis significantbasedon aWald Norway,where portfolios rankedas important by both male and
chi-squaretest (2 with one degreeof freedomis 6.41, with p = .01), femaleministersand MPsinclude"women'straditionalportfolios"
which providesadditionalsupport for Hypothesis4. such as educationand social services.
838 MARIAESCOBAR-LEMMON
AND MICHELLE
M. TAYLOR-ROBINSON

TABLE
2 Distribution of Ministries by Type,Time, and Gender
1980s 1990s 2000s

Men Women Men Women Men Women

High PrestigeMinistries
Defense and Public Security(includingmilitary) 117 0 166 9 77 3
Financeand Economy 142 1 229 8 84 7
ForeignAffairs 111 0 182 8 64 10
Government/Interior 108 2 165 2 60 2
Totalfor Category 478 3 742 27 285 22
99.4% 0.6% 96.5% 3.5% 92.8% 7.2%
Medium PrestigeMinistries
Agriculture,Fisheries,and Livestock 126 2 178 7 74 2
Constructionand PublicWorks 98 0 154 5 63 2
Education 82 24 140 33 51 21
Environmentand NaturalResources 87 0 150 10 56 22
Healthand SocialWelfare 120 8 188 27 78 15
Industryand Commerce 91 2 115 6 44 6
Justice(inc. AttorneyGeneral) 67 8 114 14 41 6
Labor 103 4 152 14 57 8
Transportation,Communications,Information 59 3 79 5 27 5
Planningand Development 78 4 103 9 29 2
Totalfor Category 911 55 1373 130 520 89
94.3% 5.7% 91.4% 8.6% 85.4% 14.6%
Low PrestigeMinistries
Childrenand Family 5 5 3 12 5 4
Culture 24 2 19 7 6 5
Reformof State,Temporaryand TransientMinistries 0 0 11 0 2 0
Scienceand Technology 17 0 21 3 9 0
Sports 11 2 26 3 14 2
Tourism 33 3 53 5 14 6
Without Portfolio (includingpart of presidency) 52 0 93 4 33 3
Women'sAffairs 0 5 0 4 0 18
Unclassifiable 6 3 26 1 9 0
Totalfor Category 148 20 252 39 92 38
88.1% 11.9% 86.6% 13.4% 70.8% 29.2%

this true? Table 2 lists categories of ministerial positions ucation or health-ministries that control large budgets
by decade and whether they were assigned to a man or a in Latin America, given the state's role as a public goods
woman. While women hold far fewer positions than men provider. In short, Table 2 suggests that women are still
do in almost all categories (Women's Affairs and Chil- less successful at cracking the inner circle. Women held
dren and Family are exceptions), the male/female ratios high-prestige ministries only three times during the 1980s
are not the same across decades or across categories of (Interior and Police in the Dominican Republic in 1981
ministries within a decade. Women have been best rep- and 1982, and Economy and Commerce in Honduras in
resented in low-prestige posts. In the 1980s, women oc- 1984). This increased to 3.5% in the 1990s, and women
cupied only 12% of low-prestige ministries, by 2000 that are 7% of high-prestige ministers so far since 2000.
had increased to almost 30%. Women have increasingly The logic of the hypotheses tested in Table 1 should
gained access to medium-prestige ministries, occupying also be relevantfor predicting when women breakinto the
15% of these posts in 2000 compared to 6% in the 1980s, cabinet'sinner circle,so we include the same variables.We
and women are most likely to head the ministries of ed- do not include the number of cabinet positions because
WOMENMINISTERSIN LATINAMERICANGOVERNMENT 839

the number of high-prestige positions remains relatively 3 Predictors of the Appointment of


TABLE
constant within a country. We add a count of the number Women to High-Prestige Positions
of female ministers (of any type) in the previous year's
cabinet as a control for women moving up the ranks in a Model 3 A Any
cabinet. Womanin High
Our dependent variable in Model 3 is whether any Dependent Variable: PrestigePost
women hold high-prestige portfolios. There are only six Supplyvariables
instances where a cabinet had two women occupying Percentof women enrolled -.034
high-prestige posts.28 This rarity leads us to adopt a di- in secondaryeducation (.026)
chotomous measure of whether a cabinet contained any Percentof women in laborforce .087
women in high-prestige posts. Again, we estimate the (.095)
models for a binomial distribution and a logit link us- Percentageof chamber .244***
ing GEEand correcting for first-order autocorrelation. composed of women (.067)
Of the supply variables in Model 3, the percentage Demand Variables:
of women in the chamber is the only significant predic- Presidentfrom left party 1.420**
tor of women receiving high-prestige posts (see Table 3). (.509)
Holding all other variables at their mean, when there is Securemajoritypresident -.380
an average percentage of women in the chamber (9%), (.837)
there is only a .05 chance that a woman will obtain a high- Near majority/Narrow .798
prestige post. However, the probability of a woman re- minority president (.548)
ceiving one of these plum appointments skyrocketsto .97 Human DevelopmentIndex -7.341
when the percentage of women in the chamber reaches (6.094)
the maximum observed value of 35.1%. This could be Number of yearssince first .041
an example of advantages accruing to women when they woman elected to legislature (.042)
achieve a "criticalmass" in politics. Literatureabout rep- Number of women in previous .069
resentation argues that until a new group gains a thresh- year'cabinet (.166)
old level of representation that goes beyond token status, ControlVariables
they will not be able to get much done or be taken se- 1980-1989 -1.655A
riously (Kanter 1977; Thomas 1994; but see Studlar and (.964)
McAllister 2002 for a dissenting view). Dahlerup (1989) 1990-1999 -.952
hypothesized that achieving a critical mass of women (.589)
would "legitimize the presence of women in legislatures, constant -2.107
leading to even more women being chosen" (from Studlar (4.327)
and McAllister2002, 234). Possibly,it also spills over into N 297
the selection of women for top cabinet posts. Davis (1997) WaldX2 22.49
found such an influence of critical mass on women's par- (.021)
p> X2
ticipation in cabinets in WesternEurope. We cannot con- Pseudo R2B .13
firm here, however, whether this advantage accrues only
after a threshold level of women members of the legisla- "p > .10, *p > .05, **p> .01, ***p> .005.
AEstimatesproducedusing Stata'sXTGEEcommand and specify-
ture is achieved, as would be predicted by critical mass
ing logit link, binomial family,and AR(1) correlation.Coefficients
theory, or if the increase is incremental. should be interpretedas logit coefficients.
Consistent with H2, if the president is to the left of BSquaredcorrelation between the dependent variable and the
the second-place finisher, the odds increase by 4.1 that a predictedvalues from the model.
woman will be appointed to a high-prestige post. As in
Models 1 and 2, the coefficient for Secure Majority presi- tem competitiveness (H4), nor the support base (or lack
dents is negative, and is not significant, so again H3 lacks thereof) that a president has in the congress (H3) appears
support. While the coefficient for Near Majority/Narrow to influence whether a president appoints women to top
Minority presidents is positive, it is not significant, so cabinet posts.29
here we also find no support for H4. Neither party sys-
29Wealso do not find any difference between Secure Majority
28Theseare Chile and Colombia (Defense and ForeignRelations) Presidentsand Near Majority/NarrowMinorityPresidentsin their
in 2003, Guatemala(Financeand ForeignRelations)in 1995-96, propensity to appoint women to top cabinet posts (X2 with
and Honduras(Finance,Interior,and Security)in 2001-02. one degreeof freedom is 2.59, with p = .11).
840 MARIAESCOBAR-LEMMON
AND MICHELLE
M. TAYLOR-ROBINSON

A country's HDI and the number of years since the the mix of people needed in a cabinet had changed. At
first woman was elected to the legislature (H6 and H5, re- least one female minister had become the norm, and many
spectively) have no significant effect on whether a woman cabinets had severalwomen.
is appointed to a high-prestige post.30 The number of A higher percentage of women in the legislature de-
women in the previous year's cabinet also does not effect creases the chances a cabinet is all male and increases the
the chance a woman will receive a high-prestige ministry. percentage of the cabinet expected to be female. Cabinets
Women are more likely to receive high-prestige posts are also expected to contain a largerpercentage of women
now, than they were in the past.31The odds of a woman when societal education (HDI) is higher and when pres-
receiving a high-prestige ministry were 81% lower in the idents are from leftist parties. Presidents facing a com-
1980s than in this decade. While the coefficient for the petitive partisan environment are more likely than are
1990s is negative, as expected, the difference is not statis- minority party presidents to include at least one woman
tically significant. Additionally, there is not a difference in their cabinet.
between the 1980s and 1990s (test statistic of .79 p > Some of the same factors matter for appointment
.37 following a X2 distribution with one degree of free- of women to cabinets in Latin America as in industri-
dom), which underscoresthat it is only in recentyearsthat alized, established democracies. In particular,increasing
women have regularlyoccupied positions in the inner cir- representation of women in the legislature and left pres-
cle of power. In sum, appointment of women to cabinets idents both correlate positively with women's represen-
appears to be positively affected by period effects (mod- tation in the executive (Davis 1997; Moon and Fountain
els 1 and 2). International diffusion can thus be argued to 1997; Siaroff 2000; Studlar and Moncrief 1997).32 How-
be positively affecting women's representation in the ex- ever, in other ways Latin America is a different political
ecutive branch, but any international diffusion effect on arena for women. Increasing the amount of women with
the chances of women being appointed to high-prestige education and workforce experience does not have the
cabinet posts (model 3) is very recent. (See Appendix for expected positive impact on representation of women in
robustness tests.) the executive branch, nor does time since women began
to win election to the legislature. This may be due to the
imprecision of the availableindicators (e.g., secondaryed-
ucation ratherthan university or post-graduate degrees).
Conclusion
However, it could also indicate that "labor force partic-
ipation [and education] does not mean the same thing"
Women are becoming more common in Latin American
in industrialized and less developed democratic countries
cabinets. It is now unusual for a cabinet not to have at
(Matland 1998, 118).
least one woman of full ministerial rank, which suggests
While domestic factors do contribute to women join-
that the political cost of excluding women has become
ing the cabinet, international pressure (the diffusion ef-
too high for presidents to ignore. The rising number of
fect) appearsto be powerful in LatinAmerica. Third-wave
women ministers may also mean the political benefit to
democracies faced intense pressure to increase represen-
presidents of including women has increased. In the early tation of women in government. International pressure
1980s, Latin America'sestablished democracies (Colom-
may complement pressurefrom women at home and may
bia, Costa Rica, the Dominican Republic, and Venezuela) overwhelm the effect of more gradual domestic forces in
often had a token woman in the cabinet. Presidents of
creating a more women-friendly environment. It is likely
new, third-wave, democracies apparentlywere more con- not just the passage of time on its own that is benefiting
cerned with other groups, as even a token woman was rare
women's chances at the highest echelons of the executive
in their cabinets (Baldez 2002; Valenzuela 1998). By the
branch in Latin America, but rather the passage of this
late 1990s, however, presidents' decision calculus about
particular period of time in world events. In response to
precipitating world events (such as the 1995 Beijing Con-
30Weobtain substantivelysimilar results if we use the number of ference) presidents in LatinAmerica may perceive a ben-
yearssince women first got the vote insteadof yearssince the first efit from moving rapidly to incorporate women. As True
woman was elected,or illiteracyinsteadof HDI. and Mintrom write, "much has gone on in the 1990s in
31Weuse dummy variablesfor decades in Model 3 (rather than
five-yeartime incrementsas in Models 1 and 2) because there are
no women in high-prestigeposts from 1985 to 1989.This presents 32Moonand Fountain (1997) find that the percentageof women
problemsfor model estimation,so we collapse 1980-84 and 1985- ministersin Australiaexceedsthe percentageof women in the par-
89 into a single category.Forcomparison,we also collapse1990-94 liament. Studlarand Moncrief (1997) also find this to be the case
and 1995-99 into a single category. in Canadianprovincialparliaments.
WOMENMINISTERSIN LATINAMERICANGOVERNMENT 841

[the gender] policy area and the building to and the after- prestige position. But, increasingwomen's education, so-
math of the Beijing conference in 1995 were characterized cietal education, or a competitive party system did not
by unprecedented efforts by both the UN and large num- increase the chances a woman received a high-prestige
bers of women's international- and national-level NGOs post. The glass ceiling appearsto be disappearingbecause
to place gender issues in the political limelight and to international conditions are changing more than because
ensure that they stay there" (2001: 48). Htun and Jones of gradual changes in the domestic environment, but this
(2001, 35) arguethat a central cause of the rapid diffusion has only been true very recently.
of gender quotas for elections in Latin American coun- This article provides the first cross-national, time-
tries was pressure from women politicians domestically, serial analysis of factors that influence the representa-
paired with pressure produced by international norms, tion of women in cabinets in Latin America. It allows
such as governments signing the Beijing Platform for Ac- us to determine whether the same factors known to affect
tion. These same pressures may also be producing the the participation of women elsewhere matter for Latin
rapid rise in representation of women in cabinets. America. Some factors appear to have a universallyposi-
The dramatic increase in representationof women in tive impact (e.g., percentage of women in the legislature,
cabinets since the mid-1990s indicates the presence of a presidents from left-leaning parties). However, in Latin
strong regional contagion effect. In Latin America, rep- America women appear to have quickly increased their
resentation of women in cabinets has increased rapidly, numbers and the prestige of their executive posts through
surpassed only by the record of the Scandinavian coun- a regional push to empower women (a diffusion effect),
tries. Women have also recently begun to receive high- rather than waiting through the slow process requiredfor
prestige posts with some frequency, which is different structural factors or societal attitudes toward women in
from the world norm (Davis 1997; Moon and Fountain government to change. Further research needs to deter-
1997; Studlar and Moncrief 1999). International confer- mine if the same women are moving up the ranks in the
ences and treaties have drawn attention to the need to cabinet and whether women ministers are former legis-
increase participation of women in government. Such lators or bureaucrats or held top posts in their party, or
pressureappearsto have shifted the demand side of the re- if women ministers are political outsiders.33Case stud-
cruitment equation for the executivebranch,by increasing ies would provide insight into the career trajectories of
the perceived political benefit to presidents of appointing women in the top echelons of the executive branch, al-
women to their cabinet (Craske 1998, 107; Htun 2003, lowing us to better predict whether women will move
121-22; Luciak2001, 233; Sapiro 1981). As Sapiro noted, toward parity in executive branch representation.
"the role of women may be used as a national sign of It is important for women's representationand equal-
status or a symbol to other nations" (1981, 707). Inter- ity in Latin America for women to have a presence in the
national pressure gives governments a reason to sign pro- highest levels of the executive branch, since the executive
women international conventions, and it may increasethe is often the leader in policymaking in LatinAmerica. The
perceived political value of appointing women to cabinet high visibility of cabinet ministers and the power over re-
posts. sources and policy that medium- and high-prestige min-
At the same time, there is room to expand women's isters have make it important to ensure that women have
participation in the executive branch. In 2003, women a fair shot at receiving these positions. Identifying the
constituted an average of 18% of Latin American presi- supply and demand factors that convince a president ap-
dents' cabinets, but held high-prestige ministries in only pointing women to their cabinet is a smart choice helps us
six of 18 countries. Women have enjoyed the most suc- understandwhen women will obtain top executivebranch
cess, in terms of numbers in the cabinet and the pres- representation.
tige of their posts, in Chile, Colombia, Costa Rica, the
Dominican Republic, Guatemala, Honduras, Nicaragua,
and Venezuela.That women have not receivedtop cabinet Appendix
posts in Argentinais interestinggiven Argentina'spioneer- RobustnessTests
ing gender quota law and the Evita legacy in the Peronist
Party (see Feijo6 1998, 43). We find that many of the We estimated several alternative specifications of
same factors that increasedwomen's participation in cab- Models 1 and 2. We dropped all pre-1990 observations
inets also determine whether they receive appointments to determine whether the effects were robust if we only
that are more prestigious. A larger number of women in
33Siaroff(2000) found in industrializedcountriesthat politicalsys-
the legislature as well as presidents from left-leaning par- tems that appoint specialists,often political outsiders,ratherthan
ties both increase the chances a woman receives a high- generalistsadvantageappointmentof women to cabinets.
842 MARIAESCOBAR-LEMMON
AND MICHELLE
M. TAYLOR-ROBINSON

Data Appendix:Summary Statistics for all Variables


Standard
Variable Obs. Mean Deviation Minimum Maximum

Any women in cabinet? 357 .672 .470 0 1


Percentcabinetthat is female 357 7.970 7.805 0 50
Any women in high-prestigeposts? 357 .129 .336 0 1
Percentof women enrolledin secondaryeducation 357 53.499 19.018 17 114
Percentof women in labor force 357 31.106 4.440 20.1 41.54
Percentageof chambercomposed of women 357 9.019 5.070 0 35.1
Presidentfrom left party 312 .516 .500 0 1
Securemajoritypresident 354 .186 .390 0 1
Near majority/Narrowminority president 354 .373 .484 0 1
Human DevelopmentIndex 357 .713 .074 .548 .844
Number of yearssince first woman elected to legislature 357 39.521 10.818 14 70
Number of ministersin cabinet 357 14.776 3.520 8 26
Number of women in previousyear'scabinet 339 1.106 1.107 0 5
1980-1984 357 .106 .309 0 1
1985-1989 357 .193 .395 0 1
1990-1994 357 .246 .432 0 1
1995-1999 357 .252 .435 0 1

consider the most recent period. The results obtained References


from this estimation for Model 1 are identical in terms of
sign and significance except that the coefficient for Near AlcintaraSiez, Manuel,and FlaviaFreidenberg(eds.). 2001.
Majority/Narrow Minority President is no longer sig- Partidos Politicos de America Latina [Political Parties in
Latin America].Salamanca,Spain:EdicionesUniversidad
nificant, although it is still positive. For Model 2, all
Salamanca.
coefficients are identical in sign and significance. We
AmorimNeto, Octavio.2002. "PresidentialCabinets,Electoral
also estimated the models including a lagged dependent
Cycles,andCoalitionDisciplinein Brazil."In Legislative
Pol-
variable. While we believe turnover within cabinets is itics in Latin America, ed. Scott Morgenstern and Benito
sufficiently high that the specification we use is theoret- Nacif. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 48-
78.
ically more desirable, we obtain substantively identical
estimates in both models. The lagged dependent variable Baldez, Lisa. 2002. Why WomenProtest:Women'sMovements in
Chile.Cambridge:CambridgeUniversityPress.
is not significant in Model 1, although it is significant is
Blondel,Jean.1991."CabinetGovernmentand CabinetMinis-
Model 2. ters."In TheProfessionofGovernmentMinisterin WesternEu-
For Model 3 we estimated a model using only post- rope,ed. JeanBlondeland Jean-LouisThiebault.New York:
1990 observations and including five-year time dummies St. Martin'sPress, pp. 5-18.
for 1990-94 and 1995-99 instead of the decade dummy. Blondel, Jean. 1987. Political Leadership.London: Sage.
All variablesthat are statisticallysignificant remain so and Blondel, Jean. 1985. GovernmentMinistersin the Contemporary
retain their signs and no additional variablesbecome sig- World.London:Sage.
nificant. The coefficient for 1990-94, while negativeis not Blondel,Jean,and Jean-LouisThi bault(eds.). 1991. ThePro-
fession of GovernmentMinister in WesternEurope.New York:
significant; however the coefficient for 1995-99 is both St. Martins Press.
negative and significant at the .10 level. We also replaced Carey,JohnM., and MatthewSobergShugart(eds.). 1998.Ex-
"number of women in the previous cabinet"with a lag of ecutive Decree Authority. New York: Cambridge University
the dependent variable.We obtain identical signs and sig- Press.
nificances for this model, except for the 1990s coefficient Caul,Miki.2001."PoliticalPartiesandtheAdoptionof Candi-
that is now negative and significant at the .10 level. dateGenderQuotas:A Cross-National Analysis."Journalof
Politics 63(4):1214-29.
For all models, we ruled out the possibility that a
single country was driving our results by estimating the Coppedge,Michael.1997."AClassificationof LatinAmerican
PoliticalParties."
WorkingPaper#244.TheHelenKelloggIn-
model without each country. Our results remain substan- stitutefor InternationalStudies,WorkingPaperSeries,Uni-
tively similar. versityof NotreDame.
WOMENMINISTERSIN LATINAMERICANGOVERNMENT 843

Countriesof the Worldand TheirLeadersYearbook.1980-2003. Jones, Mark P. 1996. "IncreasingWomen's Representation Via
Detroit: Gale ResearchCompany. Gender Quotas: The Argentine Ley de Cupos." Womenand
Craske, Nikki. 1998. "Remasculinisation and the Neoliberal Politics 16(4):75-98.
State in Latin America." In Gender,Politicsand the State, ed. Kanter, Rosabeth M. 1977. "Some Effects of Proportions on
Vicky Randalland GeorginaWaylen.London: Routledge, pp. Group Life: Skewed Sex Ratios and Responses to Token
100-20. Women." AmericanJournalof Sociology82(5):965-90.
Dahlerup, Drude. 1989. "From a Small to a Large Minor- Kobayashi, Yoshie. 2004. "Has the Closed Door Opened for
ity: Women in Scandinavian Politics." ScandinavianPolitical Women? The Appointment of Women Ministers in Japan."
Studies 11(2):275-97. Symposium on Open Boundaries Workshop: Women and
Davis, Rebecca Howard. 1997. Womenand Powerin Parliamen- Politics in Comparative Perspective, APSAnet January
tary Democracies:Cabinet Appointments in WesternEurope, 2004.
1968-1992. Lincoln: University of Nebraska Press. Laver, Michael, and Kenneth A. Shepsle (eds.). 1994. Cabinet
de Winter, Lieven. 1991. "Parliamentaryand Party Pathwaysto Ministersand ParliamentaryGovernment.Cambridge:Cam-
the Cabinet." In The Professionof GovernmentMinister in bridge University Press.
WesternEurope,ed. Jean Blondel and Jean-Louis Thiebault. Lovenduski, Joni, and Pippa Norris (eds.). 1993. Gender and
New York:St. Martin's Press, pp. 44-69. Party Politics. London: Sage.
Drukker, David M. 2003. "Testingfor Serial Correlation in Lin- Luciak,IljaA. 2001. Afterthe Revolution:Genderand Democracy
ear Panel-Data Models." Stata Journal3(2):168-77. in El Salvador,Nicaragua, and Guatemala. Baltimore: Johns
Duverger, Maurice. 1955. The Political Role of Women. Paris: Hopkins University Press.
United Nations Economic and Social Council. Mainwaring, Scott, and Matthew Soberg Shugart, 1997. "Con-
Feijo6, Maria del Carmen. 1998. "Democratic Participation clusion: Presidentialism and the Party System." In Presiden-
and Women in Argentina." In Women and Democracy: tialism and Democracyin Latin America,ed. Scott Mainwar-
Latin America and Central and Eastern Europe,ed. Jane S. ing and Matthew SobergShugart.New York:CambridgeUni-
Jaquetteand Sharon L. Wolchik. Baltimore:The Johns Hop- versity Press, pp. 394-439.
kins University Press, pp. 29-46. Matland, Richard E. 1998. "Women's Representation in Na-
GenderStats database of Gender Statistics. 2003. The World tional Legislatures:Developed and Developing Countries."
Bank Group. http://devdata.worldbank.org/genderstats/ LegislativeStudies Quarterly23(1):109-25.
gender (accessed December 30, 2003). Matland, RichardE., and Donley T. Studlar. 1996. "The Conta-
Htun, Mala N. 2003. "Women and Democracy." In Constructing gion of Women Candidates in Single-Member District and
DemocraticGovernancein LatinAmerica,2nd. ed, ed. JorgeI. Proportional RepresentationSystems:Canadaand Norway."
Dominguez and Michael Shifter. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins Journalof Politics 58(3):707-33.
University Press, pp. 118-36. Moon, Jeremy,and Imogen Fountain. 1997. "Keepingthe Gates?
Htun, Mala N., and Mark P. Jones. 2001. "Engendering the Women as Ministers in Australia, 1970-96." AustralianJour-
Right to Participate in Decision-making: Electoral Quotas nal of Political Science32(3):455-66.
and Women's Leadership in Latin America." In Genderand Morgenstern, Scott, and Benito Nacif (eds.). 2002. Legislative
the Politics of Rights and Democracy in Latin America, ed. Politics in Latin America. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Nikki Craske and Maxine Molyneux. London: Palgrave,pp. Press.
32-56.
Norris, Pippa. 1997a. "Introduction:Theories of Recruitment."
Huntington, Samuel P. 1991. The ThirdWave.Norman: Univer- In Passages to Power: Legislative Recruitment in Advanced
sity of Oklahoma Press. Democracies,ed. Pippa Norris. Cambridge:Cambridge Uni-
Inglehart, Ronald, and Pippa Norris. 2003. Rising Tide:Gender versity Press, pp. 1-14.
Equalityand CulturalChangearound the World.Cambridge: Norris, Pippa. 1997b. "Conclusions: Comparing Passages to
Cambridge University Press. Power." In Passagesto Power:LegislativeRecruitmentin Ad-
IPU. 1995. "Women in Parliaments 1945-1995, A World Sta- vanced Democracies, ed. Pippa Norris. Cambridge: Cam-
tistical Survey." Reports and Documents No. 23. Inter- bridge University Press, pp. 209-31.
ParliamentaryUnion, Geneva. Norris, Pippa. 1987. Politics and Sexual Equality: The Compar-
IPU. 1999. "Participationof Women in Political Life."Reports ative Position of Women in WesternDemocracies. Boulder:
and Documents No. 35. Inter-ParliamentaryUnion, Geneva. Rienner.
IPU. 2000. "Women in Politics 1945-2000, Information Kit." Phillips, Anne. 1991. EngenderingDemocracy.University Park:
Reports and Documents No. 37. Inter-ParliamentaryUnion, The Pennsylvania State University Press.
Geneva. Reynolds, Andrew. 1999. "Women in the Legislaturesand Exec-
Jaquette, Jane S. 1997. "Women in Power: From Tokenism to utives of the World: Knocking at the Highest Glass Ceiling."
Critical Mass." ForeignPolicy 108(Autumn):23-37. WorldPolitics 51(4):547-72.
Jaquette, Jane S., and Sharon L. Wolchik. 1998. "Women and Rodriguez, Victoria E. 2003. Womenin ContemporaryMexican
Democratization in Latin America and Central and East- Politics.Austin: University of Texas Press.
ern Europe: A Comparative Introduction." In Women and Rose, Richard.1987. Ministersand Ministries:AFunctionalAnal-
Democracy:Latin America and Central and Eastern Europe, ysis. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
ed. JaneS. Jaquetteand Sharon L. Wolchik. Baltimore:Johns Rule, Wilma. 1987. "Electoral Systems, Contextual Factors
Hopkins University Press, pp.1-28. and Women's Opportunity for Election to Parliament in
844 AND MICHELLE
MARIAESCOBAR-LEMMON M. TAYLOR-ROBINSON

Twenty-Three Democracies." Western Political Quarterly cruitment of Women Cabinet Ministers in the Canadian
40(3):477-98. Provinces." Governance:An International Journal of Policy
Sainsbury, Diane. 2004. "Women's Political Representation and Administration 10(1):67-81.
in Sweden: Discursive Politics and Institutional Presence." Studlar, Donley T., and Gary F. Moncrief. 1999. "Women's
ScandinavianPolitical Studies 27(1):65-87. Work? The Distribution and Prestige of Portfolios in the
Sapiro, Virginia. 1981. "ResearchFrontier Essay:When Are In- Canadian Provinces." Governance:An InternationalJournal
terests Interesting?The Problem of Political Representation of Policyand Administration 12(4):379-95.
of Women." AmericanPoliticalScienceReview 75(3):701-16. Thiebault, Jean-Louis. 1991. "The Social Background of West-
Schwindt-Bayer,LeslieA. 2005. "TheIncumbency Disadvantage ern European Cabinet Ministers." In The Professionof Gov-
and Women's Election to LegislativeOffice." ElectoralStudies ernment Minister in WesternEurope, ed. Jean Blondel and
24(2):227-44. Jean-Louis Thiebault. New York:St. Martin's Press, pp. 19-
30.
Shugart, Matthew Soberg. 1998. "The Inverse Relationship be-
tween Party Strength and Executive Strength: A Theory of Thomas, Sue. 1994. How WomenLegislate.New York:Oxford
Politician'sConstitutional Choice." BritishJournalofPolitical University Press.
Science28(1):1-29. True, Jacqui,and Michael Mintrom. 2001. "TransnationalNet-
Shvedova, Nadezdha. 1997. "Obstacles to Women's Participa- works and Policy Diffusion: The Case of Gender Main-
tion in Parliament." Women in Politics: Beyond Numbers. streaming." International Studies Quarterly45(1):27-57.
Stockholm: International IDEA. United Nations Human Development Indicators. Human De-
Siaroff, Alan. 2000. "Women's Representation in Legislatures velopment Reports 2003. http://www.undp.org/hdr2003/
and Cabinets in Industrial Democracies." International Po- indicator (accessed December 11, 2003).
litical ScienceReview 21(2):197-215. Valenzuela, Maria Elena. 1998. "Women and the Democrati-
Skjeie, Hege. 1991. "The Rhetoric of Difference: On Women's zation Process in Chile." In Women and Democracy:Latin
Inclusion into PoliticalElites."Politicsand Society19(2):233- America and Centraland EasternEurope,ed. JaneS. Jaquette
63. and Sharon L.Wolchik. Baltimore:Johns Hopkins University
Studlar,Donley T., and RichardE. Matland. 1996. "TheDynam- Press, pp. 47-74.
ics of Women's Representation in the Canadian Provinces, Weisberg, Herbert F. 1987. "Cabinet Transfers and Depart-
1975-1994." CanadianJournalofPolitical Science29(2):269- mental Prestige: Someone Old, Someone New, Someone
93. Borrowed.. ." AmericanPolitics Quarterly15(2):238-53.
Studlar, Donley T., and Ian McAllister. 2002. "Does a Critical Wooldridge, J.M. 2002. EconomicAnalysis of CrossSection and
Mass Exist?A Comparative Analysis of Women's Legislative Panel Data. Cambridge:MIT Press.
RepresentationSince 1950." EuropeanJournalofPolitical Re- Zorn, ChristopherJ.W.2001. "GeneralizedEstimatingEquation
search41(2):233-53. Models for Correlated Data: A Review with Applications."
Studlar, Donley T., and Gary E Moncrief. 1997. "The Re- AmericanJournalof Political Science45(2):470-90.

You might also like