Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 15

J Bus Ethics (2017) 146:111–124

DOI 10.1007/s10551-015-2914-8

Does Ownership Structure Matter? The Effects of Insider


and Institutional Ownership on Corporate Social Responsibility
Won-Yong Oh1 • Jongseok Cha2 • Young Kyun Chang3

Received: 15 August 2015 / Accepted: 15 October 2015 / Published online: 23 October 2015
 Springer Science+Business Media Dordrecht 2015

Abstract The extant literature has examined the effects Keywords Corporate social responsibility  Ownership
of ownership structures on corporate social responsibility structure  Non-linearity  Complementary mechanisms
(CSR), yet it has overlooked the non-linear and interactive
effects among major shareholder groups. In this study, we
examine the non-linear effects of insider and institutional Introduction
ownerships on CSR. We also examine whether it is nec-
essary to have both incentive alignment and monitoring Over the past years, management research (Arora and
mechanisms (complementary view) or it is sufficient to Dharwadkar 2011; Barnea and Rubin 2010; Johnson and
have either mechanism (substitutive view) to promote Greening 1999; Waddock and Graves 1997) has examined
CSR. Using a sample of the U.S. Fortune 1000 firms, our the effects of ownership structures on corporate social
results suggest that insider and institutional ownerships responsibility (CSR). The results based on empirical evi-
have non-linear effects on CSR. We also find support for dence of the relationships between major shareholders and
the complementary mechanisms view, in that the highest CSR, however, have been mixed. For example, while some
CSR rating is observed when both ownership levels are found that institutional shareholders had a positive effect
high. Therefore, firms need to maintain strong governance on CSR (e.g., Graves and Waddock 1994; Johnson and
structures to realize synergistic effects in promoting CSR. Greening 1999; Sethi 2005), others found that they had a
Our findings provide a more in-depth understanding of the negative effect (e.g., Arora and Dharwadkar 2011). Simi-
relationships between ownership structures and corporate larly, the effects of insider ownership on CSR are positive
social outcomes. in some studies (e.g., Johnson and Greening 1999; Kock
et al. 2012), but negative in others (e.g., Arora and Dhar-
wadkar 2011; Oh et al. 2011). This inconsistent relation-
ship between ‘good’ ownership structure and CSR in the
& Young Kyun Chang previous studies calls for reexamination of the corporate
changy@sogang.ac.kr governance research framework.
Won-Yong Oh Therefore, it is necessary to provide a more theory-
woh@ucalgary.ca grounded and systematic explanation of the lack of con-
Jongseok Cha sistency in these empirical results. In this study, we inte-
jscha@hansung.ac.kr grate the multiple theoretical perspectives by proposing
1
Haskayne School of Business, University of Calgary, 2500
that major shareholders have non-linear effects on CSR,
University Drive NW, Calgary, AB T2N 1N4, Canada and that there are interactive effects among them. First,
2 non-linear inferences beyond simple linearity often better
Department of Business Administration, Hansung University,
116 Samseongyoro-16gil, Seongbuk-gu, Seoul 136-792, capture the complex realities (Edwards and Parry 1993). In
Korea particular, non-linearity is a suitable pattern because it
3
Sogang Business School, Sogang University, 35 Baekbeom- recognizes relationships that are ‘‘multifaceted’’ (and even
ro, Mapo-gu, Seoul 04107, Korea moving in opposite directions). A notable example is a

123
112 W.-Y. Oh et al.

U-shaped (or inverted U-shaped) non-linear relationship high. This implies that both incentive alignment (by insider
since it fully formulates both positive and negative direc- ownership) and effective monitoring (by institutional
tions simultaneously. As such, we argue that exploring ownership) mechanisms work synergistically in promoting
non-linearity can help reconcile diverging findings on the CSR. Our findings shed additional light on the corporate
relationships between ownership types and CSR. governance literature by illustrating the interactive effects
Second, several researchers have begun to recognize the of major shareholder groups on CSR.
interactive effects among shareholders (Aguilera et al.
2012; Barnea and Rubin 2010; Hoskisson et al. 2002). For
instance, Aguilera et al. (2012, p. 381) noted that organi- Theoretical Background
zational outcomes are ‘‘dependent on the bundle of gov-
ernance mechanisms rather than the effectiveness of any Ownership Structures and Corporate Social
one mechanism.’’ Barnea and Rubin (2010) also docu- Responsibility
mented that the presence of ‘‘conflict’’ between different
major shareholders is a determinant of CSR. Surprisingly, Previous research has found that ownership structures have
despite the existence of different dynamics among share- a significant influence on organizational decisions (Con-
holder groups, no study has directly theorized and empir- nelly et al. 2010), including R&D spending (Baysinger
ically tested the interaction among shareholder groups in et al. 1991), innovation (Kochhar and David 1996), capital
relation to CSR. It is worthwhile to research this interactive structure (Chaganti and Damanpour 1991), and diversifi-
mechanism because internal and external owners’ coali- cation (Eisenmann 2002). Consistent with this line of
tions interact with each other in order to influence the research, key shareholder groups, such as insider and
firm’s decisions (Chaganti and Damanpour 1991). institutional owners, were found to be associated with a
The purpose of this study, therefore, is to fill this firm’s social engagement (e.g., Arora and Dharwadkar
research gap by exploring the non-linear and interactive 2011; Barnea and Rubin 2010; Johnson and Greening
effects between two major shareholder groups on CSR. 1999; Kock et al. 2012; Oh et al. 2011; Waddock and
Specifically, in this paper, we used insider ownership as a Graves 1997).
proxy for an incentive alignment mechanism and institu- However, research on the effects of ownership structures
tional ownership as a proxy for a monitoring mechanism. on CSR has produced inconclusive findings. For instance,
Using a dataset from the Fortune 1000 list in the U.S., we insider ownership is either positively (Johnson and
found strong support for non-linear and interaction effects Greening 1999; Kock et al. 2012) or negatively (Arora and
on CSR among shareholders. Insider ownership was shown Dharwadkar 2011; Oh et al. 2011) associated with CSR.
to have a curvilinear effect on CSR (i.e., U-shape), indi- The relationship between institutional shareholding and
cating that firms are less likely to engage in CSR as insider CSR is also either positive (Graves and Waddock 1994;
ownership levels increase from low to moderate, but more Johnson and Greening 1999; Sethi 2005) or negative
likely to engage in CSR as their ownership levels increase (Arora and Dharwadkar 2011).
from moderate to high. Institutional ownership, however, We assume that such inconsistencies may result from
followed a different pattern in that institutional owners tend oversimplifying the complex mechanisms through which
to push firms to engage in CSR as their ownership levels ownership affects a firm’s socially responsible decisions.
increase, but this is attenuated once the levels of institu- First, the corporate governance literature suggests that a
tional ownership reach a critical mass. More importantly, high level of insider ownership can be a double-edged
we found support for interaction effects between major sword. Agency theory argues that insiders’ and share-
shareholder groups. The pattern of interaction can be holders’ interests converge when insiders become share-
interpreted using a complements versus substitutes con- holders (Eisenhardt 1989; Jensen and Meckling 1976)
ceptual framework (Aguilera et al. 2012; Hoskisson et al. through ‘‘incentive alignment’’ mechanisms. A high level
2009; Rediker and Seth 1995; Schepker and Oh 2013; of insider ownership leads to strategic decisions that are
Zajac and Westphal 1994). This framework helps us consistent with shareholders’ long-term interests. Accord-
determine whether it is necessary to have both incentive ing to good management theory (Beurden and Gössling
alignment by insider ownership and monitoring mecha- 2008; Orlitzky et al. 2003; Waddock and Graves 1997),
nisms by institutional ownership (i.e., governance as socially responsible decisions enhance the firm’s long-term
complements) or sufficient to have either mechanism (i.e., value. For example, Orlitzky et al. (2003), in a meta-
governance as substitutes) for inducing CSR. We found analysis of 52 studies, found that CSR is positively asso-
support for the governance-as-complements view in that ciated with firm’s financial performance. Therefore, the
the highest CSR rating was observed in cases in which both research on incentive alignment mechanism implies that
insider and institutional ownership levels were relatively managers with high levels of ownership are likely to be

123
Does Ownership Structure Matter? The Effects of Insider and Institutional Ownership on Corporate… 113

supportive of CSR, which contributes to the shareholders’ Table 1 encapsulates the complex mechanisms that
long-term wealth. In contrast, other scholars contend that underlie the relationships between ownership structures
power acquired by substantial ownership may induce and CSR. Failing to fully address these complex mecha-
‘‘management entrenchment’’ in that managers with sig- nisms of ownership effects may be the source of the
nificant shareholdings may seek self-interest even at the inconsistency in previous findings. Accordingly, to better
expense of shareholders (Morck et al. 1988; Shleifer and understand these relationships, all feasible mechanisms
Vishny 1989). McClelland et al. (2012, p. 1388) noted that should be taken into account.
executives with high levels of ownership have ‘‘a greater
capacity to be free from the discipline of the firm’s board, Governance Mechanisms as Complements Versus
shareholders, and the market for corporate control.’’ In Substitutes
particular, because investment in CSR does not necessarily
get translated into immediate returns (Burke and Logsdon Regarding the effect of governance structure on organiza-
1996; Chang et al. 2013), entrenched managers with sig- tional outcomes, there are two competing perspectives:
nificant shareholdings may try to avoid CSR-related governance mechanisms as complements and governance
decisions. mechanisms as substitutes. The first perspective suggests
Similarly, there are also complex mechanisms in the that governance mechanisms are complementary (Hoskis-
relationships between institutional ownership and CSR. son et al. 2009; Schepker and Oh 2013), whereby effective
Agency theory (Eisenhardt 1989; Jensen and Meckling monitoring (by institutional owners) and incentive align-
1976) suggests that monitoring by institutional investors ment (by insider ownership) together lead to long-term
leads managers to make decisions aligned with the share- shareholders’ wealth in an additive fashion. As such, firms
holders’ long-term interests. Therefore, a high level of can maximize shareholders’ wealth when ‘both’ effective
institutional ownership is likely to encourage firms to monitoring and incentive alignment schemes are exercised
actively engage in CSR. In contrast, other researchers (e.g., due to synergistic effects between those important share-
Brickley et al. 1988; Dalton et al. 2003) argued that holder groups.
because a high level of institutional ownership may lead to An alternative perspective, whereby governance mech-
conflicts between institutional investors, the effectiveness anisms act as substitutes, argues that shareholder value
of monitoring may be diminished. This idea is confirmed maximization does not require so many governance
by Hoskisson et al. (2002)’s argument that different types mechanisms. This perspective assumes that using multiple
of owners have their own distinct and potentially con- governance mechanisms is costly and may not be efficient
flicting (rather than unified) preferences for strategic (Rediker and Seth 1995). Thus, using one effective gov-
decisions. Thus, an excessive level of institutional owner- ernance mechanism does not require the use of another. For
ship may trigger conflicts among institutions, which may instance, Zajac and Westphal (1994) found that a firm’s
distract them from encouraging firms to engage in CSR. incentive alignment is negatively associated with its use of

Table 1 Various mechanisms between ownership structure and CSR


Mechanism of positive effects Mechanism of negative effects

Insider Incentive alignment Management entrenchment


ownership A high level of insider ownership leads to managerial decisions that Organizational power by stockholdings enables managers
are consistent with the shareholders’ long-term interests. to seek entrenchment by pursuing self-serving decisions.
Thus, a high level of insider ownership is positively associated with Thus, a high level of insider ownership is negatively
CSR. associated with CSR.
Exemplary Eisenhardt (1989), Johnson and Greening (1999) Shleifer and Vishny, (1989), Morck et al. (1988), Oh et al.
literature (2011).
Institutional Effective monitoring Conflicts among shareholders
ownership Oversight from high-level institutional holdings leads to managerial Institutional owners have different propensities to engage
decisions that are consistent with the shareholders’ long-term in monitoring and distinctive time horizons & risk
interests. aversions.
Thus, a high level of institutional ownership is positively associated Thus, a high level of institutional ownership is negatively
with CSR. associated with CSR.
Exemplary Eisenhardt (1989), Jensen and Meckling (1976). Brickley et al. (1988), Dalton et al. (2003), Hoskisson
literature et al. (2002).

123
114 W.-Y. Oh et al.

monitoring mechanisms. This observation implies that Korean Cheabol firms tend to disengage from CSR as they
firms with weak incentive alignment (i.e., low insider acquire more shareholdings.
shareholdings) tend to use the stronger monitoring mech- Due to these countervailing mechanisms, it is reasonable
anisms (i.e., high institutional ownership) instead, or vice to assume that the effects of insider ownership on share-
versa. holder value could be non-linear, which encompasses both
In this paper, we adopt the complementary versus sub- positive and negative directions. Empirical evidence sup-
stitutive framework for the CSR context. Therefore, we ports a non-linear effect. For instance, Morck et al. (1988)
theorize and test the relationships by posing competing found a U-shaped curvilinear relationship between man-
hypotheses. If the complementary perspective is supported, agerial shareholding and financial performance, such that
the higher levels of both insider ownership and institutional Tobin’s Q ratio was highest at a low level of ownership
ownership are likely to generate a high level of CSR. (below 5 %) and a high level of ownership (above 25 %),
However, if the substitutive perspective is supported, a with moderate ownership leading to lower performance.
higher level of either shareholder group will be sufficient to Bhabra (2007) also reported the same pattern in the rela-
produce a high level of CSR. tionship between insider ownership and multiple measures
of a firm’s performance. Furthermore, Schepker and Oh
(2013) reported the U-shaped pattern of the relationship
between insider ownership and the likelihood of poison pill
Hypotheses Development
repeal, which is assumed to be beneficial decision for
shareholders.
Effects of Insider Ownership on CSR
Similar logic may be applied to a firm’s social perfor-
mance. As insider ownership increases from a low to
Agency theory (Eisenhardt 1989; Jensen and Meckling
moderate level, managers and directors are likely to
1976) suggests that providing stock to managers and
become entrenched in self-seeking behavior with their
directors is an effective way to mitigate agency problems
increased ownership power, and in turn, they will become
by aligning their interests with those of the owners. If
reluctant to engage in long-term investments such as CSR.
insiders own significant shareholdings, they should make
However, as the ownership increases substantially, man-
decisions that will maximize the long-term shareholder
agers and directors are more incentivized to align them-
wealth because of this incentive alignment (Connelly et al.
selves more closely with shareholders’ long-term wealth,
2010). Previous studies consistently found that stock
and therefore, they are expected to promote social
ownership by managers and directors is positively associ-
engagement. Following this logic, we predict that there will
ated with shareholder value (e.g., Kosnik 1987; Gedajlovic
be a convex relationship (i.e., U-shaped pattern) between
and Shapiro 2002). If socially responsible decisions
insider ownership and CSR. Therefore, we hypothesize:
increase the firm’s value, as good management theory
(Beurden and Gössling 2008; Orlitzky et al. 2003; Wad- Hypothesis 1 The relationship between insider owner-
dock and Graves 1997) suggests, insiders with significant ship and CSR is curvilinear, such that CSR is likely to
shareholdings might be willing to promote the organiza- decrease as insider ownership increases to a certain point,
tion’s proactive social initiatives. Indeed, Johnson and but then is likely to increase as insider ownership sub-
Greening (1999) found a positive relationship between top stantially increases after passing that point (i.e., a U-shaped
management equity and social performance targeted to pattern).
environmental issues and product quality.
However, the role of insider ownership is more complex Effects of Institutional Ownership on CSR
(e.g., Himmelberg et al. 1999). While agency theory sug-
gests that greater insider ownership benefits shareholders’ Many scholars suggest that institutional owners lead firms
wealth because it induces incentive alignment, a competing to make decisions in the shareholders’ best interests
argument focuses on the effect of management entrench- because of effective monitoring roles (Agrawal and Man-
ment by significant insider ownership (e.g., McClelland delker 1992; Kochhar and David 1996; Shleifer and Vishny
et al. 2012; Shleifer and Vishny 1989). As insider owner- 1997), even though the voices of all institutional holders
ship increases, they are likely to have a greater control of might not be always aligned (e.g., Brickley et al. 1988).
the firm, which may lead to a greater chance that powerful They can exercise significant voting power and have
managers will entrench themselves for self-serving pur- information advantages over other minority shareholders
poses. If this is the case, insider ownership is expected to (Schnatterly et al. 2008). Moreover, since institutional
be negatively associated with CSR. Oh et al. (2011) found owners with significant shares cannot easily sell their
a similar pattern, arguing that entrenched top managers in equity without lowering stock prices, they are more

123
Does Ownership Structure Matter? The Effects of Insider and Institutional Ownership on Corporate… 115

attentive than other shareholders to the firm’s strategic to increase at a decreasing rate as institutional ownership
decisions. increases from low to high.
With respect to an organization’s decisions on social
investments, good management theory (Beurden and Gös-
Interaction Effects Between Insider
sling 2008; Orlitzky et al. 2003; Waddock and Graves
and Institutional Ownerships on CSR
1997) implies that the effect of institutional ownership on
CSR should be positive. If the long-term shareholder value
We propose that both insider ownership (incentive align-
can be enhanced through socially responsible practices,
ment vs. management entrenchment) and institutional
institutional shareholders are willing to engage in CSR
ownership (effective monitoring vs. conflicts) have non-
more proactively (e.g., Coffey and Fryxell 1991). Empiri-
linear effects on CSR. However, in order to fully capture
cal evidence also supports this argument. Graves and
the effects of ownership structure on CSR, we should also
Waddock (1994) found that institutions invest more heav-
consider interactive effects between insider owners and
ily in firms with better corporate social performance. Teoh
institutional owners. For this, there are two contrasting
and Shiu (1990) also found that institutional investors look
perspectives on governance mechanisms: complementary
favorably upon firms actively engaging in CSR. In addi-
(e.g., Hoskisson et al. 2009; Schepker and Oh 2013) versus
tion, Sethi (2005) argued that public pension funds tend to
substitutive (e.g., Rediker and Seth 1995; Zajac and
consider a firm’s long-term effects on the environment,
Westphal 1994). We employ the two perspectives with
sustainability, and good corporate citizenship when they
competing hypotheses in an exploratory manner.
make investment decisions.
One group of researchers has argued that governance
However, we argue that while effective monitoring
mechanisms should be implemented complementarily in
mechanisms by institutional shareholding have positive
order to maximize shareholders’ wealth. Based on agency
effects on CSR, these effects are not linear. A marginal
theory, this line of research proposed the idea of ‘‘gover-
increase in institutional ownership will have differential
nance mechanisms as complements’’ (Hoskisson et al.
effects on CSR, depending on the level of institutional
2009; Schepker and Oh 2013). For instance, the combi-
ownership. Specifically, when the level of institutional
nation of incentive alignment (e.g., insider ownership) and
ownership is relatively low, the marginal increase in
effective monitoring (e.g., institutional ownership) can
institutional ownership will significantly increase the
contribute more to shareholders’ long-term interests. This
monitoring role. In contrast, when the level of institutional
logic suggests that firms with both high levels of incentive
ownership is high, the monitoring activities by many dif-
alignment and effective monitoring will make value-cre-
ferent institutions may be redundant. In such situations, an
ating decisions through the synergistic effects of multiple
incremental increase in institutional ownership might not
governance mechanisms. In contrast, other stream of
have a significant additional impact on monitoring. More-
researchers has claimed that governance constituencies
over, a high level of institutional ownership creates a pool
work as substitutes (e.g., Rediker and Seth 1995; Zajac and
of multiple institutional investors, which may induce
Westphal 1994); shareholder value maximization does not
‘‘conflicting’’ preferences among them regarding CSR
require the maximum possible number of governance
(e.g., Hoskisson et al. 2002). This situation may even have
mechanisms. A main logic of this claim is that executing
a detrimental impact on CSR; CSR can be achieved
multiple governance mechanisms is costly and inefficient
through continuous commitment necessitating unified
to achieve strategic goals (Rediker and Seth 1995).
support from large shareholders. Conflicting voices from
Taken together, if a complementary perspective is sup-
different institutional investors may deter such continuous
ported, greater levels of both insider ownership and insti-
commitment to CSR. Empirically, Arora and Dharwadkar
tutional ownership are likely to generate the highest level
(2011) found that a high level of block institutional own-
of CSR due to an additional synergistic effect. However, if
ership leads to lower CSR ratings.
a substitutive perspective is supported, either incentive
Given the argument above, we predict that institutional
alignment or effective monitoring (i.e., by either type of
ownership will have positive effects on CSR at the low to
owner) is sufficient to produce a high level of CSR.
modest level of institutional ownership. However, we fur-
ther hypothesize that there will be a curvilinear relation- Hypothesis 3a There is a complementary effect between
ship, in that a marginal increase in institutional ownership incentive alignment and effective monitoring on CSR. When
after a certain critical point will not improve CSR. Hence, both insider ownership and institutional ownership levels are
we hypothesize: high, firms are likely to have a higher level of CSR.
Hypothesis 2 The relationship between institutional Hypothesis 3b There is a substitutive effect between
ownership and CSR is curvilinear, such that CSR is likely incentive alignment and effective monitoring on CSR.

123
116 W.-Y. Oh et al.

When either insider ownership or institutional ownership characteristics such as financial performance, leverage,
levels are high, firms are likely to have a higher level of size, and age are included in the analysis. First, we con-
CSR. trolled for firms’ financial performance and leverage. Since
a firm’s social engagement may be influenced by financial
conditions (e.g., Waddock and Graves 1997), CSR may be
Methods driven by better financial performance and lower debt
obligations. Thus, we controlled for return on assets
Sample and Data (ROA), net income divided by total assets, as a measure for
financial performance, and debt-to-asset ratio, long-term
To test our hypotheses, we used a sample that was initially debt divided by total assets, as a measure for leverage. This
derived from the U.S. Fortune 1000 list in 2004. Therefore, information is obtained from Standard and Poor’s Com-
all our sample firms are large public firms headquartered in pustat. Previous research (e.g., Chang et al. 2012) found
the U.S. To be included in the sample, firms had to have that a firm’s size is positively associated with its level of
corporate social responsibility data in the subsequent year, CSR, because larger firms have more visibility and a larger
as assessed by Kinder, Lydenberg, Domini (KLD) scale of activities. For this study, Firm Size was measured
Research and Analytics. The source for firm financial data as total sales, from Compustat. Because this variable has
is Standard and Poor’s Compustat database. Board and positively skewed distribution, it was transformed loga-
ownership information is obtained from the Corporate rithmically. We also controlled for Firm Age since it is
Library database. Due to the lack of full data availability, associated with firms’ level of CSR (Cochran and Wood
our final sample size is 654 firms. 1984). Firm Age was measured by the number of years
since a firm’s foundation, and was obtained from the
Variables Corporate Library database.
Prior studies also argued that corporate board attributes
Dependent Variables affect a firm’s CSR (e.g., Johnson and Greening 1999).
Thus, we included the proportion of outside directors and
We used archival sources for CSR ratings as the dependent board size. Greater representation of independent directors
variable, obtained from KLD. The use of KLD ratings of is positively associated with better monitoring and
CSR is a fairly standard practice in the literature (e.g., external legitimacy (e.g., Chang et al. 2012), leading to a
Arora and Dharwadkar 2011). KLD is a CSR rating pro- higher level of CSR. The proportion of outside directors
vider that assesses a firm’s social responsibility across a was calculated by dividing the number of unaffiliated
wide range of dimensions associated with the interests of directors on a board by the total number of board mem-
multiple stakeholders. KLD scores consist of multiple sub- bers. Lastly, board size, measured by the number of
domains: Environment, Community, Diversity, Employee directors on the board, was included in the analysis.
Relations, Human Rights, Product Quality and Safety, and Boards with fewer members may have stronger interper-
Corporate Governance. Each major domain contains a set sonal ties, which leads to less independence (Hatfield
of ‘‘strength’’ and ‘‘concern’’ ratings. We used the sum of et al. 1999). In addition, Zahra and Pearce (1989) noted
strengths as a measurement for CSR (Mattingly and Ber- that firms with large boards are more likely to contain
man 2006). expertise and diverse perspectives, which may encourage
CSR. Board composition information was also obtained
Independent Variables from Corporate Library, as well as firm proxy statements,
when necessary.
All ownership data were collected from the Corporate
Library database and firm proxy statements (i.e., SEC Analysis
Form DEF 14A) when necessary. Insider Ownership was
calculated by the proportion of shares owned by executives After running conventional ordinary least squares (OLS)
and directors. We also collected Institutional Ownership, regressions, an analysis of the residuals indicated the
the proportion of shareholdings by all institutional presence of heteroskedasticity by the Breusch–Pagan/
investors. Cook–Weisberg test (p \ 0.001). In order to correct for
heteroskedasticity, robust standard errors are used in our
Control Variables regression models (Huber 1967; White 1982). To test the
curvilinear relationship, we use the quadratic equation in
We included a number of control variables in order to OLS regression (Cohen and Cohen 1983). The expression
control for firm and board characteristics. Firm for linear and quadratic equations is as follows, where X

123
Does Ownership Structure Matter? The Effects of Insider and Institutional Ownership on Corporate… 117

represents ownership and Y represents the firm’s CSR Results


ratings:
Y ¼ b0 þ b 1 X1 þ e ð1Þ The means, standard deviations, and correlations for sam-
ple firms are presented in Table 2. The average value of
Y ¼ b0 þ b1 X1 þ b2 X12 þ e ð2Þ CSR rating is 2.55 with the standard deviation of 3.00.
Comparing the linear Eq. (1) with the quadratic Eq. (2), if Table 3 reveals the results of regression analyses
the incremental change in F-statistics due to the addition examining non-linear and interaction effects of insider and
X12 is significant, or coefficient b2 is significant, then the institutional ownership on CSR ratings. Model 1 includes
only control variables. In Model 2, insider and institutional
relationship between X and Y can be said to be curvilinear.
ownerships were added to assess the linear effects on the
And the sign of b2 indicates whether the quadratic curve is
CSR ratings. In Model 3, the interaction term between two
U-shaped (?) or inversely U-shaped (-). In the quadratic
ownership types was included. In Model 4 and Model 5,
Eq. (2), the maximum or minimum value in Y is when
the quadratic term of insider ownership and institutional
X1 ¼ b2b2 (i.e., a point of inflection).
1
ownership was added, respectively, to assess the possibility
Also, the interactive effects of different types of share- of a curvilinear relationship with the CSR ratings, as pre-
holder groups (i.e., insider ownership and institutional dicted in Hypotheses 1 and 2. As a full model, Model 6
ownership) are tested by conducting a regression analysis represents the full regression equation, including the linear,
with interaction terms. quadratic, and interaction terms for assessing the possi-
Y ¼ b0 þ b 1 X1 þ b 2 X2 þ b 3 X 1 X2 þ e ð3Þ bility of the interaction effect between ownership groups
even after considering the non-linear effects of ownerships
To test the interactive effects between shareholder groups,
on CSR. It should be noted that if the interaction effect is
we conduct a regression analysis for interaction terms
not significant in Model 3, but significant only in Model 6,
along with squared terms, which allows the testing of the
one can argue that the interaction effect between insider
complex relationship between independent variables as
and institutional ownerships on CSR could be better
well as their joint effects (Edwards and Parry 1993) in one
understood under a curvilinear logic.
equation model. The general expression for the equation
Hypothesis 1 predicts that the relationship between
with two independent variables is as follows, where X1
insider ownership and CSR would follow a U-shaped pat-
represents insider ownership and X2 represents institutional
tern. Comparing the linear regression model (Model 2) with
ownership:
the quadratic regression model (Model 4), adding squared
Y ¼ b0 þ b1 X1 þ b2 X2 þ b3 X12 þ b4 X22 þ b5 X1 X2 þ e ð4Þ term of insider ownership significantly improves the sta-
tistical model (DF = 8.26, p \ 0.01). This indicates that
The results from Eqs. (4) are used to test the comple-
the quadratic regression model is a better fit than the linear
mentary (or substitutive) effect by examining if Y is
model. The coefficient of linear term (X1 ) in the quadratic
increasing (or not) when the interaction term X1 X2 is
regression model is negative and significant (b1 = -3.57,
increasing.
p \ 0.001), indicating that the CSR level is decreasing as

Table 2 Descriptive statistics and correlations


Mean SD 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9

1 Return on assets 0.05 0.06


2 Debt-to-asset ratio 0.21 0.17 -0.35
3 Firm size 3.70 0.49 0.08 -0.10
4 Firm age 52.99 43.39 0.04 -0.10 0.07
5 Proportion of outside directors 0.70 0.16 0.01 -0.07 0.15 0.17
6 Board size 10.38 2.53 -0.09 0.00 0.33 0.17 0.08
7 Insider ownership 0.09 0.13 -0.05 0.13 -0.21 -0.02 -0.41 -0.12
8 Institutional ownership 0.72 0.16 0.14 0.01 -0.02 -0.08 0.10 -0.19 -0.25
9 CSR (sum of KLD strengths) 2.55 3.00 0.09 -0.12 0.56 0.19 0.17 0.32 -0.22 -0.06
10 CSIR (sum of KLD concerns) 2.96 2.42 -0.06 0.07 0.56 0.10 0.17 0.23 -0.16 -0.09 0.45
Correlations with absolute values greater than .08 are significant at p \ .05 and absolute values greater than .10 are significant at p \ .01
Two-tailed coefficient test

123
118 W.-Y. Oh et al.

Table 3 Regression analyses on CSR (DV: sum of strengths in KLD ratings)


Variable Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5 Model 6

Constant -11.51*** -10.68*** -10.69*** -10.51*** -10.57*** -10.60***


(1.13) (1.14) (1.15) (1.14) (1.13) (1.15)
Control variables
Return on assets 2.19 2.33 2.33 2.56 2.74 3.05
(2.10) (2.09) (2.09) (2.14) (2.08) (2.19)
Debt-to-asset ratio -0.81 -0.62 -0.62 -0.81 -0.51 -0.80
(0.53) (0.53) (0.53) (0.54) (0.54) (0.56)
Firm size 3.00*** 2.95*** 2.94*** 2.88*** 2.91*** 2.85***
(0.32) (0.32) (0.32) (0.32) (0.31) (0.31)
Firm age 0.01*** 0.01*** 0.01*** 0.01*** 0.01*** 0.01***
(0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00)
Proportion of outside directors 1.24* 0.60 0.60 0.34 0.65 0.40
(0.52) (0.55) (0.55) (0.56) (0.55) (0.55)
Board size 0.17*** 0.16*** 0.16*** 0.16*** 0.14*** 0.13***
(0.04) (0.04) (0.04) (0.04) (0.04) (0.04)
Ownership characteristics
Insider ownership (X1 ) -2.16*** -2.21** -3.57*** -2.36*** -6.61***
(0.64) (0.86) (0.95) (0.65) (1.69)
Institutional ownership (X2 ) -0.58 -0.57 -0.47 1.87* 2.60**
(0.40) (0.41) (0.40) (0.83) (0.86)
Insider ownership-squared (X12 ) 5.99** 10.01***
(2.08) (2.93)
Institutional ownership-squared (X22 ) -3.76** -3.98**
(1.29) (1.30)
Insider ownership 9 institutional ownership (X1 X2 ) 0.16 6.06*
(2.32) (3.00)
R-square 0.362 0.368 0.369 0.372 0.375 0.381
F (d.f.) 32.51 26.01 23.08 23.66 23.84 20.17
(6)*** (8)*** (9)*** (9)*** (9)*** (11)***
DF (d.f.) 0.00 8.26 8.45 6.08
(1) (1)** (1)** (3)***
Robust standard errors are in parentheses. DF (d.f.) is based on the changes in F-statistics over Model 2, which has only linear terms
* p \ 0.05, ** p \ 0.01, *** p \ 0.001 level, two-tailed coefficient test

insider ownership increases. However, the coefficient of term of institutional ownership in Model 5 significantly
quadratic term (X12 ) is positive and significant (b3 = 5.99, improves the model (DF = 8.45, p \ 0.01). The coeffi-
p \ 0.01), showing that the relationship between insider cient of linear term (X2 ) in Model 5 is positive and sig-
ownership and CSR has a U-shaped pattern. Taken together, nificant (b2 = 1.87, p \ 0.05), which means that the CSR
the CSR rating decreases as insider ownership increases to a rating increases as institutional ownership increases. The
certain point, and then beyond that point, it increases as coefficient of quadratic term (X22 ) in Model 5 is negative
insider ownership increases. Thus, Hypothesis 1 is sup- and significant (b4 = -3.76, p \ 0.01), which confirms a
ported. Figure 1 displays a U-shaped pattern of the rela- curvilinear pattern of the relationship between insider
tionship between insider ownership and CSR. ownership and CSR. As shown in Fig. 2, the CSR rating
Hypothesis 2 predicts that CSR would increase at a increases as the level of institutional ownership increases;
decreasing rate as institutional ownership increases. The however, the marginal increase by additional institutional
quadratic regression model (Model 5) is compared with the ownership becomes less significant. Thus, Hypothesis 2 is
linear regression model (Model 2). Adding the squared also supported.

123
Does Ownership Structure Matter? The Effects of Insider and Institutional Ownership on Corporate… 119

CSR Ratings CSR Ratings

High
High
Institutional
Ownership Insider
Ownership
Low
Low High
Fig. 3 Effects of interaction between insider and institutional own-
Insider ownership erships on CSR

Fig. 1 Non-linear relationship between insider ownership and CSR


Figure 3 shows three-dimensional surfaces, in which the
CSR Ratings vertical axis represents CSR ratings and the two horizontal
axes represent insider ownership and institutional owner-
ship, respectively. As displayed in Fig. 3, the highest level of
CSR is observed when the levels of both insider and insti-
tutional ownership are high. This graphical pattern also
confirms the complementary effects among governance
constituencies. Thus, Hypothesis 3a is supported.
As shown in Fig. 3, the patterns in three-dimensional
surfaces confirmed that both insider and institutional
ownerships have curvilinear effects on CSR ratings. The
relationship between insider ownership and CSR ratings
follows a U-shaped pattern regardless of the level of
institutional ownership. The relationship between institu-
tional ownership and the CSR rating also shows a similar
Low High pattern, reported in Fig. 2.
Institutional ownership
Supplementary Analysis: Ownership Structures
Fig. 2 Non-linear relationship between institutional ownership and and CSIR
CSR
Recent research has begun to recognize that there is a
Hypothesis 3 proposes that insider and institutional significant difference between the corporate social
ownerships will have either complementary or substitutive responsibility (CSR) and corporate social irresponsibility
effects on CSR. The full regression model (Model 6) was (CSIR) (Arora and Dharwadkar 2011; Mattingly and Ber-
compared with the linear regression model (Model 2). The man 2006; Oh et al. 2014). While CSR represents forms of
incremental changes in terms of F-statistics in Model 6 are proactive stakeholder management, such as corporate phi-
statistically significant (DF = 6.08, p \ 0.001), indicating lanthropy and sustainable practices, CSIR involves reactive
that a non-linear relationship and interaction effect were compliance with minimum social and ethical standards. For
found in the relationship between the two types of own- instance, CSIR is likely to be the consequence of having
ership and CSR ratings. Specifically, the interaction term is violated environmental regulation, equal employment
positive and significant (b5 = 6.06, p \ 0.05), which sup- opportunity, and health/safety guidelines. Since CSR and
ports that there is a complementary effect between incen- CSIR are conceptually and empirically distinct concepts,
tive alignment and effective monitoring on CSR. we conducted another set of regression analysis using CSIR
To illustrate these complex findings, we plotted the sur- (i.e., measured by the sum of ‘‘concerns’’ listed in the KLD
faces that correspond with the polynomial regression model. ratings) as dependent variables, as shown in Table 4.

123
120 W.-Y. Oh et al.

Table 4 Regression analyses on CSIR (DV: sum of concerns in KLD ratings)


Variable Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5 Model 6

Constant -8.69*** -8.01*** -7.94*** -7.93*** -7.93*** -7.87***


(0.91) (0.92) (0.93) (0.92) (0.91) (0.93)
Control variables
Return on assets -2.72 -2.50 -2.48 -2.39 -2.23 -2.10
(1.50) (1.50) (1.50) (1.52) (1.50) (1.53)
Debt-to-asset ratio 1.62** 1.78*** 1.77** 1.69*** 1.85*** 1.74***
0(0.51) (0.51) (0.51) (0.52) (0.51) (0.51)
Firm size 2.79*** 2.77*** 2.77*** 2.74*** 2.75*** 2.72***
(0.25) (0.25) (0.25) (0.25) (0.25) (0.25)
Firm age 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00
(0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00)
Proportion of outside directors 1.17* 0.83 0.80 0.71 0.87 0.74
(0.46) (0.50) (0.50) (0.51) (0.50) (0.51)
Board size 0.01 0.00 0.00 0.00 -0.01 -0.01
(0.04) (0.04) (0.03) (0.04) (0.04) (0.04)
Ownership characteristics
Insider ownership (X1 ) -1.23 -0.86 -1.89* -1.36* -2.50
(0.64) (1.05) (0.87) (0.65) (1.87)
Institutional ownership (X2 ) -0.85* -0.93* -0.80* 0.76 0.95
(0.35) (0.38) (0.35) (0.72) (0.79)
Insider ownership-squared (X12 Þ 2.80 3.66
(2.65) (3.62)
Institutional ownership-squared (X22 ) -2.47* -2.57*
(1.09) (1.09)
Insider ownership 9 Institutional ownership (X1 X2 ) -1.19 0.89
(2.44) (3.30)
R-square 0.353 0.359 0.360 0.361 0.364 0.365
F (d.f.) 34.60 27.17 24.19 24.04 24.51 20.09
(6)*** (8)*** (9)*** (9)*** (9)*** (11)***
DF (d.f.) 0.24 1.12 5.16 2.14
(1) (1) (1)* (3)
Robust standard errors are in parentheses. DF (d.f.) is based on the changes in F-statistics over Model 2, which has only linear terms
* p \ 0.05, ** p \ 0.01, *** p \ 0.001 level, two-tailed coefficient test

Table 4 shows the results of a series of regression ownership and CSIR is an inverted U-shape. This result
analyses on the CSIR ratings. Model 4 shows that the indicates that a firm’s irresponsible actions are likely to
coefficient of linear term (X1 ) is negative and significant increase up to a moderate level of institutional owner-
(b1 = -1.89, p \ 0.05), but the coefficient of quadratic ship, but decrease as institutional ownership increases
term (X12 ) is not significant, indicating that CSIR past the inflection point. However, as shown in Model 6,
decreases overall as insider ownership increases, but not any complementary or substitutive effects of ownership
in a curvilinear fashion. This result suggests that insiders structures on CSIR were not found. Taken together, our
with significant shareholdings are likely to discourage a supplementary analysis shows that ownership structure
firm from taking irresponsible actions. While the linear that leads to proactive social engagement (i.e., CSR
term of institutional ownership in Model 5 is positive ratings), and ownership structure that prevents the vio-
and not significant (b1 = 0.76), the quadratic term is lation of minimum social and ethical standards (i.e.,
negative and significant (b4 = -2.47, p \ 0.05), sug- CSIR ratings) have theoretically and empirically dis-
gesting that the relationship between institutional tinctive mechanisms.

123
Does Ownership Structure Matter? The Effects of Insider and Institutional Ownership on Corporate… 121

Discussion decisions (Chaganti and Damanpour 1991). In relation to


CSR, surprisingly, no meaningful attempt has been made to
The corporate governance literature has focused on address the interactive effects among different types of
examining the relationships between ownership structures shareholders. To our knowledge, this study is the first to
and strategic decisions (e.g., Baysinger et al. 1991; explore the possibility and finds the evidence of compli-
Eisenmann 2002). Given that corporate social initiatives cated interactions between them.
can be seen as a form of social ‘‘investment’’ (McWilliams Furthermore, the interaction between different types of
and Siegel 2001), it is not surprising that key owners are ownership shows complementary mechanisms, given that
likely to be involved in their firm’s strategic decisions on the highest level of CSR is observed when the levels of
CSR. Several attempts have been made to investigate the both insider ownership and institutional ownership are
effects of ownership structures on CSR, yet empirical high. Our findings are also consistent with the ‘bundle’
evidence has shown a mix of positive and negative results. perspective of governance (Aguilera et al. 2012); simulta-
Because of this empirical inconclusiveness, we proposed neous corporate governance mechanisms, rather than the
that ownership structures and CSR may not have simple effectiveness of any single mechanism, are important in
linear relationships; instead, they could be best presented in enhancing the firm’s value. The addition of one mechanism
non-linear terms that contain both positive and negative enhances the other and leads to more effective governance
aspects. We also proposed that each type of ownership may functions. In other words, even if monitoring by institu-
interact in shaping complicated strategic decisions on CSR. tional shareholders is in place, the incentive alignment by
As such, we tested the non-linear interaction between types insider ownership still provides additive value, or vice
of ownership and its relationships with CSR, and found versa. In this sense, our findings suggest that strong gov-
strong support. ernance mechanisms are necessary in order to induce a
Our findings provide a breakthrough within the growing firm’s social commitment.
literature on CSR and corporate governance. First, while a In fact, the complementary versus substitutive debate on
number of studies have focused on the consequences (e.g., corporate governance mechanisms has received an
financial outcomes) of CSR (e.g., Chang et al. 2013; increasing attention from the field of management (Cha-
Godfrey et al. 2009; Margolis and Walsh 2003), less is ganti and Damanpour 1991; Schepker and Oh 2013; Zajac
known about the ‘‘antecedents’’ of CSR. As gaining credits and Westphal 1994). The complementary perspective
and legitimacy of research from the field of management indicates that better organizational outcomes are more
(Walsh et al. 2003), it is important to broaden the scope of likely to be observed when both incentive alignment and
inquiry from what CSR brings to what brings CSR. We monitoring mechanisms are implemented well. The sub-
offer a rich description of how ownership structures, one of stitutive perspective alternatively suggests that multiple
the core corporate governance mechanisms, affect CSR. governance mechanisms may not in fact be necessary. For
Second, our study shows that the ownership–CSR link- instance, when effective monitoring to limit managers’
age is non-linear. The non-linear model often resolves the opportunism is in place, additional effort in granting
empirical inconclusiveness by offering nuanced predictions incentives to them may not be necessary, and may even be
for various causal inferences and allows for more sophis- costly. While recent studies have considered these con-
ticated assessments. In our study, insider ownership is trasting views in other contexts, such as executive com-
negatively associated with CSR to a certain point, but pensation (Hoskisson et al. 2009) and anti-takeover
positively associated beyond that point. We also found that provisions (Schepker and Oh 2013), no study has examined
as the level of institutional ownership increases, CSR such a competing mechanism in the CSR context. In this
increases at a decreasing rate. In short, the non-linear sense, our findings shed additional light on the debate about
model helps reconcile the empirical tension by embracing corporate governance by extending the discourse to the
the opposing evidence found in the previous studies. topic of CSR.
Third, the existing literature (e.g., Barnea and Rubin Finally, previous research on CSR has been challenged
2010; Johnson and Greening 1999) on the ownership–CSR in terms of operationalizing the construct of CSR;
linkage has been based on the assumption that each type of responsibility (or positive) and irresponsibility (or nega-
ownership affects a firm’s strategy or performance inde- tive) dimensions are mostly combined. While CSR
pendently since different owners may have different involves more promotional and proactive stakeholder
objectives and decision-making horizons (Hoskisson et al. management, CSIR involves more preventive and reactive
2002). Recent literature on strategic management, how- compliance with minimum standards; hence, these should
ever, points to cases in which internal and external owners’ not be combined (Arora and Dharwadkar 2011; Godfrey
coalitions interact with each other to influence the firm’s et al. 2009; Mattingly and Berman 2006). As such, we

123
122 W.-Y. Oh et al.

make two discrete composite ratings—CSR and CSIR— classification of institutional investors in predicting the
and conduct separate analyses. Given the different findings relationship between institutional ownership and CSR.
of each analysis (see Tables 3 and 4), our study shows that Second, even though we used the time-lagged method
the ways in which ownership structures affect CSR and between independent variables and dependent variables,
CSIR are not identical. The insider and institutional own- this does not rule out causality issues completely. Thus,
erships interact to affect CSR in a non-linear fashion, future research can utilize longitudinal methods in order to
whereas such a non-linear interaction pattern is not minimize the causality concerns. Lastly, we used a sample
observed for CSIR. Thus, consistent with previous studies of large U.S. public firms, which could limit the general-
on this topic, CSR and CSIR should be treated as separate izability of our findings outside the U.S.
concepts; furthermore, our study shows that their deter-
minants (e.g., ownership structure) are also different.
Our findings also offer practical implications for cor- Conclusion
porate leadership. Given the U-shaped relationship
between insider ownership and CSR, executives and In sum, there has been growing recognition that it is crucial
directors may need to be provided sizeable stock ownership for corporate leaders to promote their firm’s social per-
in order to promote the firm’s social performance. It is formance. Our study shows that ownership structure, a key
noteworthy that in our sample, as levels of ownership governance mechanism, affects the firm’s engagement in
increase to a certain level, insider ownership can be a CSR. By examining the dynamics of major shareholder
poison since it malfunctions by inducing managers’ groups, we found non-linearity as well as interactive
entrenchment, and discourages them from taking strategic effects. This study supports the governance mechanisms as
endeavors for long-term investments like CSR. However, complements view: when both insider and institutional
once ownership levels go beyond a certain level, managers ownership levels are relatively high, firms tend to make the
with substantial shares would be more committed to CSR. strongest commitment to CSR. Based on our findings, we
Our findings may hint at the idea of how top managers’ offer a simple yet convincing argument that firms need to
incentive alignment should be designed and practiced to maintain strong governance mechanisms to maximize their
promote a firm’s social engagement. social performance. Overall, this study advances our
Our findings also inform us that organizations can understanding of the relationships between ownership
benefit from encouraging ‘‘cooperative’’ rather than com- structures and corporate social outcomes.
petitive relationships between governance mechanisms in
their pursuit of social agendas. In our analysis, incentive Acknowledgement This research was funded by the Haskayne
alignment by insider ownership and monitoring by insti- School of Business, University of Calgary and Hansung University.
tutional ownerships interact in a complementary way to
promote CSR as the level of ownership increases. Thus,
even if different owners have different objectives and
References
strategic stances (Hoskisson et al. 2002), they can still Agrawal, A., & Mandelker, G. N. (1992). Shark repellents and the
work hand in hand. Specifically, given the occurrence of role of institutional investors in corporate governance. Manage-
complementary effects, firms need to maintain strong rial and Decision Economics, 13, 15–22.
governance mechanisms in order to make incentive align- Aguilera, R., Desender, K., & Kabbach de Castro, L. (2012). A
bundle perspective to comparative corporate governance. In T.
ment and effective monitoring work better. Clarke & D. Branson (Eds.), The SAGE handbook of corporate
governance (pp. 379–405). London: Sage Publications.
Limitations and Future Research Arora, P., & Dharwadkar, R. (2011). Corporate governance and
corporate social responsibility (CSR): The moderating roles of
attainment discrepancy and organization slack. Corporate
Despite this study’s significant contributions and implica- Governance: An International Review, 19, 136–152.
tions, it is not without limitations. First, we assumed that Barnea, A., & Rubin, A. (2010). Corporate social responsibility as a
institutional investors have different preferences and levels conflict between shareholders. Journal of Business Ethics, 97,
of attention toward CSR. However, we do not elaborate on 71–86.
Baysinger, B. D., Kosnik, R. D., & Turk, T. A. (1991). Effects of
the distinction between different types of institutional board and ownership structure on corporate R&D strategy.
investors in terms of their actual preferences and levels of Academy of Management Journal, 34, 205–214.
attention to CSR. Previous literature pointed out the dif- Beurden, P. V., & Gössling, T. (2008). The worth of values: A
ferences in propensity to engage in monitoring between literature review on the relation between corporate social and
financial performance. Journal of Business Ethics, 82, 407–424.
pressure-resistant and pressure-sensitive institutional Bhabra, G. S. (2007). Insider ownership and firm value in New
investors (e.g., David et al. 1998; Kochhar and David Zealand. Journal of Multinational Financial Management, 17,
1996). Thus, future research can benefit from a detailed 142–154.

123
Does Ownership Structure Matter? The Effects of Insider and Institutional Ownership on Corporate… 123

Brickley, J. A., Lease, R. C., & Smith, C. W, Jr. (1988). Ownership Hoskisson, R. E., Hitt, M. A., Johnson, R. A., & Grossman, W.
structure and voting on antitakeover amendments. Journal of (2002). Conflicting voices: The effects of institutional ownership
Financial Economics, 20, 267–291. heterogeneity and internal governance on corporate innovation
Burke, L., & Logsdon, J. M. (1996). How corporate social respon- strategies. Academy of Management Journal, 45, 697–716.
sibility pays off. Long Range Planning, 29, 495–502. Huber, P. J. (1967). The behavior of maximum likelihood estimates
Chaganti, R., & Damanpour, F. (1991). Institutional ownership, under nonstandard conditions. In Proceedings of the Fifth
capital structure, and firm performance. Strategic Management Berkeley Symposium on Mathematical Statistics and Probability.
Journal, 12, 479–491. Jensen, M. C., & Meckling, W. H. (1976). Theory of the firm:
Chang, Y. K., Oh, W. Y., Jung, J. C., & Lee, J. Y. (2012). Firm size Managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure.
and corporate social performance: The mediating role of outside Journal of Financial Economics, 3, 305–360.
director representation. Journal of Leadership & Organizational Johnson, R. A., & Greening, D. W. (1999). The effects of corporate
Studies, 19, 486–500. governance and institutional ownership types on corporate social
Chang, Y. K., Oh, W. Y., & Messersmith, J. G. (2013). Translating performance. Academy of Management Journal, 42, 564–576.
corporate social performance into financial performance: Explor- Kochhar, R., & David, P. (1996). Institutional investors and firm
ing the moderating role of high-performance work practices. innovation: A test of competing hypotheses. Strategic Manage-
International Journal of Human Resource Management, 24, ment Journal, 17, 73–84.
3738–3756. Kock, C. J., Santaló, J., & Diestre, L. (2012). Corporate governance
Cochran, P. L., & Wood, R. A. (1984). Corporate social responsibility and the environment: What type of governance creates greener
and financial performance. Academy of Management Journal, companies? Journal of Management Studies, 49, 492–514.
27, 42–56. Kosnik, R. D. (1987). Greenmail: A study of board performance in
Coffey, B. S., & Fryxell, G. E. (1991). Institutional ownership of corporate governance. Administrative Science Quarterly, 32,
stock and dimensions of corporate social performance: An 163–185.
empirical examination. Journal of Business Ethics, 10, 437–444. Margolis, J. D., & Walsh, J. P. (2003). Misery loves companies:
Cohen, J., & Cohen, P. (1983). Applied multiple regression/correla- Rethinking social initiatives by business. Administrative Science
tion analysis for the behavioral sciences (2nd ed.). Hillsdale, NJ: Quarterly, 48, 268–305.
Lawrence Erlbaum. Mattingly, J. E., & Berman, S. L. (2006). Measurement of corporate
Connelly, B. L., Hoskisson, R. E., Tihanyi, L., & Certo, S. T. (2010). social action. Business and Society, 45, 20–46.
Ownership as a form of corporate governance. Journal of McClelland, P. L., Barker, V. L., & Oh, W. Y. (2012). CEO career
Management Studies, 47, 1561–1589. horizon and tenure: Future performance implications under
Dalton, D. R., Daily, C. M., Certo, S. T., & Roengpitya, R. (2003). different contingencies. Journal of Business Research, 65,
Meta-analyses of financial performance and equity: Fusion or 1387–1393.
confusion? Academy of Management Journal, 46, 13–26. McWilliams, A., & Siegel, D. (2001). Corporate social responsibility:
David, P., Kochhar, R., & Levitas, E. (1998). The effect of A theory of the firm perspective. Academy of Management
institutional investors on the level and mix of CEO compensa- Review, 26, 117–127.
tion. Academy of Management Journal, 41, 200–208. Morck, R., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1988). Management
Edwards, J. R., & Parry, M. E. (1993). On the use of polynomial ownership and market valuation: An empirical analysis. Journal
regression equations as an alternative to difference scores in of Financial Economics, 20, 293–315.
organizational research. Academy of Management Journal, 36, Oh, W. Y., Chang, Y. K., & Cheng, Z. (2014). When CEO career
1577–1613. horizon problems matter for corporate social responsibility: The
Eisenhardt, K. M. (1989). Agency theory: An assessment and review. moderating roles of industry-level discretion and blockholder
Academy of Management Review, 1, 57–74. ownership. Journal of Business Ethics,. doi:10.1007/s10551-
Eisenmann, T. R. (2002). The effects of CEO equity ownership and 014-2397-z.
firm diversification on risk taking. Strategic Management Oh, W. Y., Chang, Y. K., & Martynov, A. (2011). The effect of
Journal, 23, 513–534. ownership structure on corporate social responsibility: Empirical
Gedajlovic, E., & Shapiro, D. M. (2002). Ownership structure and evidence from Korea. Journal of Business Ethics, 104, 283–297.
firm profitability in Japan. Academy of Management Journal, 45, Orlitzky, M., Schmidt, F., & Ryne, S. (2003). Corporate social and
565–575. financial performance: A meta-analysis. Organization Studies,
Godfrey, P. C., Merrill, C. B., & Hansen, J. M. (2009). The 24, 403–441.
relationship between corporate social responsibility and share- Rediker, K. J., & Seth, A. (1995). Boards of directors and substitution
holder value: An empirical test of the risk management effects of alternative governance mechanisms. Strategic Man-
hypothesis. Strategic Management Journal, 30, 425–445. agement Journal, 16, 85–99.
Graves, S. B., & Waddock, S. A. (1994). Institutional owners and Schepker, D. J., & Oh, W. Y. (2013). Complementary or substitutive
corporate social performance. Academy of Management Journal, effects? Corporate governance mechanisms and poison pill
37, 1034–1046. repeal. Journal of Management, 39, 1729–1759.
Hatfield, G., Worrell, D. L., Davidson, W. N, I. I. I., & Bland, E. (1999). Schnatterly, K., Shaw, K. W., & Jennings, W. W. (2008). Information
Turbulence at the top: Antecedents of key executive dismissal. advantages of large institutional owners. Strategic Management
Quarterly Journal of Business and Economics, 38, 3–24. Journal, 29, 219–227.
Himmelberg, C. P., Hubbard, R. G., & Palia, D. (1999). Understand- Sethi, S. P. (2005). Investing in socially responsible companies is a
ing the determinants of managerial ownership and the link must for public pension funds—because there is no better
between ownership and performance. Journal of Financial alternative. Journal of Business Ethics, 56, 99–129.
Economics, 53, 353–384. Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1989). Management entrenchment:
Hoskisson, R. E., Castleton, M. W., & Withers, M. C. (2009). The case of manager specific investments. Journal of Financial
Complementarity in monitoring and bonding: More intense Economics, 25, 123–140.
monitoring leads to higher executive compensation. Academy of Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1997). A survey of corporate
Management Perspectives, 23, 57–74. governance. Journal of Finance, 52, 737–783.

123
124 W.-Y. Oh et al.

Teoh, H. Y., & Shiu, G. Y. (1990). Attitudes towards corporate social White, H. (1982). Maximum likelihood estimation of misspecified models.
responsibility and perceived importance of social responsibility Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, 53, 1–25.
information characteristics in a decision context. Journal of Zahra, S. A., & Pearce, J. A. (1989). Boards of directors and corporate
Business Ethics, 9, 71–77. financial performance: A review and integrative model. Journal
Waddock, S. A., & Graves, S. B. (1997). The corporate social of Management, 15, 291–334.
performance-financial performance link. Strategic Management Zajac, E. J., & Westphal, J. D. (1994). The costs and benefits of
Journal, 8, 303–319. managerial incentives and monitoring in large US corporations:
Walsh, J. P., Weber, K., & Margolis, J. D. (2003). Social issues and When is more not better? Strategic Management Journal, 15,
management: Our lost cause found. Journal of Management, 29, 121–142.
859–881.

123
Reproduced with permission of copyright owner. Further reproduction
prohibited without permission.

You might also like