Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 21

Urban Studies at 50

50(1) 107–127, January 2013

Neighbourhood Income Sorting and the


Effects of Neighbourhood Income Mix on
Income: A Holistic Empirical Exploration
Lina Hedman and George Galster

[Paper first received, March 2011; in final form, March 2012]

Abstract
An econometric model is specified in which an individual’s income and the income
mix of the neighbourhood in which the individual resides are endogenous, thus pro-
viding a holistic model of phenomena that previously have been fragmented into
neighbourhood effects and neighbourhood selection literatures. To overcome the
biases from selection and endogeneity, the parameters of this model are estimated
using instrumental variables in a fixed-effect panel analysis employing annual data on
90 438 working-age males in Stockholm over the 1995–2006 period. Evidence is
found of both neighbourhood effects and neighbourhood selection, but more impor-
tantly, it is found that the magnitudes of these effects are substantially altered when
taking selection and endogeneity biases into account, compared with when only con-
trolling for selection. When taking endogeneity into account, the apparent impact of
neighbourhood income mix on individual income is magnified and the effect of indi-
vidual income on the percentage of high income in the neighbourhood is magnified.

1. Introduction
Two substantial, interdisciplinary literatures the degree to which residential context exerts
have developed over the past three decades. independent effects on a variety of outcomes
One has focused on neighbourhood selection for residents. Unfortunately, they have long
and sorting by income, building our under- remained artificially segregated from each
standing about why and where people move. other in conceptual and empirical terms
The other has focused on neighbourhood Recently, Galster (2003), Doff (2010) and
effects, building our understanding about Hedman (2011) have provided distinctive

Lina Hedman is in the Institute for Housing and Urban Studies, Uppsala University, Box 785,
Gävle, 80129, Sweden. E-mail: lina.hedman@ibf.uu.se.
George Galster is in the Department of Urban Studies and Planning, Wayne State University,
Detroit, Michigan, USA. E-mail: george.galster@wayne.edu.

0042-0980 Print/1360-063X Online


Ó 2012 Urban Studies Journal Limited
DOI: 10.1177/0042098012452320
108 LINA HEDMAN AND GEORGE GALSTER

but complementary conceptual models link- addresses both sources of bias that have been
ing these two literatures by illuminating endemic (although often unrecognised) in
their numerous mutually causal intercon- prior neighbourhood effect and neighbour-
nections.1 They argue that: individual char- hood selection studies: endogeneity and
acteristics affect what neighbourhood is selection on unobservables. We demonstrate
selected when they move; the neighbour- that these biases can be substantial.
hood selected affects some individual char-
acteristics; these, in turn; affect whether
that individual remains in the current 2. Research Challenges from the
neighbourhood and, if not, what different Perspective of the Holistic Model
neighbourhood will be selected; and failure
to recognise these interrelationships leads to Incorporating neighbourhood selection and
biased statistical estimates. The upshot is neighbourhood effects into a holistic frame-
that both neighbourhood selection and work raises several methodological chal-
neighbourhood effects literatures would be lenges (Hedman, 2011). In this paper, we
enriched by a more holistic, unifying focus on two critical ones: selection on
approach. unobservables (omitted variables) and
Our paper aims to advance such an endogeneity (mutual causation). In any sta-
approach empirically, building on these tistical study there is likely to be a set of
conceptual models. We first summarise the unobserved individual characteristics that
key empirical challenges a holistic frame- influence both selection into and out of
work raises, and the scant empirical research neighbourhoods and observed individual
advancing such an approach. We then spe- behaviours and outcomes that are not only
cify an econometric model in which an indi- of intrinsic interest but may also influence
vidual’s income and the income mix of neighbourhood selection. In these circum-
her neighbourhood are endogenous—i.e. stances, partial correlations between neigh-
mutually causal in a structural equation bourhood characteristics and individual
system. We estimate parameters using both characteristics will not provide unbiased
fixed-effects (i.e. person-specific dummy estimates of the true magnitude of the causal
variables serving as proxies for unobserved influence of one on the other, regardless of
characteristics) alone and then in combina- which direction of causation is posited. An
tion with instrumental variables (i.e. exo- illustration of an unobserved characteristic
genous variables that serve as proxies for is the salience given to visible symbols of
endogenous ones), employing annual data prestige; those placing great weight on this
on 90 438 working-age males in Stockholm will both work harder to evince higher
over the 1995–2006 period. We find strong incomes and will try to live in prestigious
support for our empirical approach. neighbourhoods. In a model testing the
Our paper makes two primary contribu- effect of neighbourhood prestige on individ-
tions. First, it represents the first holistic ual income, how much causal impact can be
econometric model to specify endogenous rightfully attributed to the former with
relationships between an individual’s ‘prestige salience’ uncontrolled? The same
income and the income mix of the neigh- can be asked of a model testing the effect of
bourhood in which the individual resides. an individual’s income on what neighbour-
Secondly, because it uses both instrumental hood prestige will be selected. The selection
variables as substitutes for the endogenous on the unobservables problem is well known
variables and a fixed-effect panel analysis, it in the neighbourhood effects literature (for
NEIGHBOURHOOD AND INDIVIDUAL INCOMES 109

example, Jencks and Mayer, 1990; Galster, neighbourhood effect scholars (Sampson
2008).2 It should be of equal concern in the and Sharkey, 2008). Only three studies in
neighbourhood selection literature but has this genre to our knowledge have tried to
been largely ignored. model neighbourhood selection and then
The other challenge is endogeneity. The use this model to correct for selection on
selection of neighbourhood is often made unobservables bias in a subsequent neigh-
jointly with other decisions, such as dwell- bourhood effects model.
ing tenure and expected length of stay, and Ioannides and Zabel (2008) investigated
thus it is challenging to separate the inde- how neighbourhood population externalities
pendent causal effect of the neighbourhood affected housing structure demand in US
on subsequent individual outcomes from metropolitan areas. They took a two-stage
the effects of other interrelated decisions approach wherein they first estimated a
(Galster, 2003). Moreover, all these interre- nested conditional logit model of neighbour-
lated decisions are made on the basis of the hood selected by movers while the second
individual’s resources, yet arguably these are used these estimates as Heckman-style prob-
also affected in turn by the neighbourhood abilistic control variables for selection bias
that ultimately is chosen, if indeed neigh- when analysing housing demand. Their first-
bourhood effects are present. Thus, there are stage results showed that US households
several dimensions of complex, mutual caus- move to places inhabited by people similar
ality embedded here. In these circumstances, to themselves in terms of income, age and
the researcher cannot blithely place one race. Their second-stage results showed that
endogenous variable on the right-hand side controlling for selection had large impacts,
of the equation and another on the left-hand in this case strengthening the apparent effects
side and claim that the resulting partial cor- of neighbourhood characteristics on housing
relation provides an unbiased measure of structure demand. However, given its focus,
causation in one direction or the other. this study did not explore potential recipro-
Endogeneity is rarely addressed by the cal causal relationships.
neighbourhood effect literature, with the Galster et al. (2007) developed a model
exception of studies of spatial mismatch wherein parental housing tenure, expected
where discussions about the simultaneity of length of stay and neighbourhood poverty
the choices of residential location and (access rate were endogenous over the first 18 years
to) employment or earnings are relatively of a child’s lifetime and, in turn, jointly
frequent (Ihlanfeldt and Sjoquist, 1998). affected their outcomes measured as young
Numerous empirical neighbourhood adults. They used two-stage least squares to
effects studies have tried to address the obtain instrumental variable (IV) estimates
challenge of selection on unobservables by for: shares of childhood years spent in a
using one of several methodologies that try home owned by parents, shares of childhood
to break the correlation between unob- years when there were no residential moves,
served individual characteristics and the and mean neighbourhood poverty rate expe-
predictor neighbourhood characteristics rienced during childhood, which they
and individual outcomes being modelled; employed in second-stage equations predict-
see Galster (2008) and Hedman (2011) for ing education, fertility and income outcomes.
recent reviews. However, most studies The results indicated that being raised in
employ methods that do not tell us any- higher-poverty neighbourhoods had a sub-
thing about selection processes, something stantial negative effect on educational attain-
that should be of intrinsic interest to ments and indirectly on incomes.
110 LINA HEDMAN AND GEORGE GALSTER

Sari (2012) developed a two-equation database, containing annual income, educa-


simultaneous model using 1999 census data tion, labour market and population infor-
on Paris-region adult males wherein resi- mation on all Swedish residents age 15 and
dence in a deprived neighbourhood or not above. With the collaboration of Roger
was one outcome and being employed or Andersson we have created a longitudinal
not was the other, and the two were database including all males who were resi-
mutually causal. Sari employed a bivariate dents of Sweden’s largest metropolitan area,
probit maximum likelihood method with a Stockholm, in each year from 1994 to 2006.4
family fertility IV to obtain an unbiased Since we focus on labour earnings as the endo-
estimate of the effect of deprived neigh- genous individual characteristic of interest, we
bourhood residence on an individual’s further confine our analysis to working-age
employment probability. He found that males (ages 25–49 in 1994). This restriction
residence in a deprived neighbourhood was means that we analyse a sub-population that
associated with substantially lower employ- constitutes 58.2 per cent of the age-appropriate
ment probabilities. Unfortunately, Sari did male Stockholm population in 1994 and 54.2
not attempt to estimate the deprived neigh- per cent of same in 2006. We emphasise that
bourhood residence equation with an our full dataset includes observations of virtu-
instrumental variable for employment, so a ally the entire Stockholm population and thus
holistic empirical portrait is missing. we can compute annual population-based
Thus, in the literature, there is no example income-mix characteristics of neighbourhoods
of estimating fully a structural equation with great precision.
model where neighbourhood characteristics We operationalise ‘neighbourhood’ as
and the effects of these characteristics on the area delineated by a ‘SAMS’ defined by
individuals are endogenous. We advance the Statistics Sweden. The SAMS classification
literature by specifying such a model of scheme is designed to identify relatively
income mix of neighbourhood of residence small, homogeneous areas by taking into
and individual income.3 For estimating para- account housing type, tenure and construc-
meters of this model we agree with Galster tion period. In urban areas, they come
et al. (2007) and Sari (2012) that the IV strat- relatively close to people’s notion of neigh-
egy holds the greatest potential because, in bourhoods (Andersson, 2001). They have
principle, estimates based on valid and strong been used as proxies for neighbourhoods in
instruments should overcome biases from many previous Swedish studies of neigh-
both selection on unobservables and endo- bourhood effects (for example, Galster
geneity. Moreover, we extend beyond the et al., 2008, Galster and Hedman, 2011)
approaches of these aforementioned authors and residential mobility (for example,
by employing a fixed-effects panel model in Andersson and Bråmå, 2004; Hedman
addition to IV as further a control for time- et al., 2011). The mean population of the
invariant unobservables. 184 SAMS in Stockholm during our analy-
sis period is 4259. Areas with less than 50
inhabitants are excluded from the dataset.
3. Data and Empirical Model
3.2 Our Structural Model of Individual
3.1 The Swedish Data Files Income and Neighbourhood Income Mix
The variables we employ are constructed Our two outcomes of interest are the
from register data from the GeoSweden individual’s annual income from work
NEIGHBOURHOOD AND INDIVIDUAL INCOMES 111


(‘income’ hereafter, measured in Swedish ln Itij = a + b(PItij ) + g(PIij )
kronor, SEK)5 and the income mix of the + u(Mtij ) + m(Lt ) + eIti ð1Þ
neighbourhood. We focus on income from
work since it encapsulates the net impact of where, Itij = annual income from work
educational credentials, labour force partic- earned by individual i during year t; PItij =
ipation, employment regularity, hours personal characteristics in year t for indi-
worked and hourly compensation. Thus, vidual i that affect income and can vary
any effect of neighbourhood income mix over time (such as level of education);
on individual income can be thought of as PIij = personal characteristics for individual
a reduced-form estimate working through i that affect income but do not vary over
any or all of the above causal paths.
time (such as year of birth); Mtij = average
Our choice of income mix as our neigh-
income mix of neighbourhood j where
bourhood variable has three reasons. First, it
individual i resides during year t (percen-
has been the focal point of several public
tages of low- and high-income males); Lt =
policy initiatives in both the US and western
macroeconomic characteristics during year
Europe (Murie and Musterd, 2004; Berube,
t (a set of year dummy variables); and eIti =
2005; Briggs, 2005; Musterd and Andersson,
a random error term associated with the
2005; Norris, 2006). Secondly, previous lit-
individual income equation. (Note that
erature on neighbourhood sorting has
Greek symbols represent parameters to be
observed powerful patterns related to indi-
estimated.)
vidual income and income mix of the neigh-
Neighbourhood selection, our second
bourhood (for example, Jargowsky, 1997;
outcome of interest, is modelled with two
Andersson, 1998; Andersson and Bråmå,
equations operationalising neighbourhood
2004; Musterd, 2005; Sampson and Sharkey,
income mix (Mtij ) as the average percen-
2008; Hedman et al., 2011). Thirdly, previ-
tages of high-income males and low-income
ous Swedish studies have found neighbour-
males in the neighbourhood over the period
hood income mix to be more strongly
t - 1 to t, with the generic form
correlated with individuals’ subsequent
socioeconomic outcomes than neighbour-
Mtij = s + v(It1i ) + c(PMti ) + ∂(PMi ) + eMti
hood mix defined by ethnicity (Urban,
2009), education, ethnicity, family status or ð2Þ
housing tenure (Andersson et al., 2007).
To measure neighbourhood income mix, where, PMti = other characteristics in year t
we specify the percentages of working-age for individual i that affect residential selec-
(20–64 years) males in the lowest and high- tion and can vary over time (such as family
est 30 per cent of Sweden’s nation-wide male size); PMi = personal characteristics for
income distribution; the middle 40 per cent individual i that affect residential selection
becomes the excluded reference category.6 and cannot vary over time (such as year of
For brevity we will subsequently refer to birth); and eMti = a random error term
these groups as low-income, middle-income associated with neighbourhood income mix
and high-income neighbours. equation. (All other symbols as before.)
In our model of neighbourhood effects To clarify the timing notation, we specify:
on income, we model in log-linear form7 the in equation (1), that the average neighbour-
annual income during year t (current year hood income mix (mean of observations
t = 0) for individual i residing in neighbour- from December t - 1 and December t) affects
hood j as income earned during the same period
112 LINA HEDMAN AND GEORGE GALSTER

(measured at December of t); in equation (2), may both produce biased estimates. The direc-
that the income measured in December t - 1 tion of bias on measured neighbourhood
affects average neighbourhood income mix effect size from selection on unobservables is
experienced during the next year. Since we generally thought to be upward, although it
measure income as lagged, we only employ may depend on the outcome under investiga-
data from 1995 to 2006 in the analysis. tion (see Galster et al., 2008; and Ludwig et al.,
We operationalise the personal charac- 2001). The direction of bias on measured indi-
teristics of individuals PIt and PI in equa- vidual income effect size from selection on
tions (1) and (2) with a set of variables unobservables is likely to be the same, but has
describing their individual demographic never been investigated.
and household characteristics, educational The direction of bias imparted by endo-
attainments and features of their employ- geneity is less straightforward and can be
ment status. We also include a series of year explored with the aid of a simplified thought
dummies to measure unspecified macroeco- experiment portrayed in Figure 1. Imagine
nomic conditions. We also have a number that four individuals who are identical
of variables that are exclusive to either equa- except for income (AL and BL lower income;
tion. These variables and the exclusion CH and DH higher income) are randomly
restrictions are discussed further in what assigned to two neighbourhoods (AL and CH
follows, given their importance in the IV to a higher-income neighbourhood; BL and
specification. The full set of control vari- DH to a lower-income neighbourhood).
ables and their descriptive statistics are pre- Now consider various possibilities involving
sented in Table 1. assumed neighbourhood effects on income
and sorting across neighbourhoods on the
3.3 Considerations of Potential basis of income. First, if there is neither
Estimation Bias effect, all four individuals will remain at
their initial positions in Figure 1 and there
We model income and neighbourhood would be no statistical association indicated
income mix as endogenous for straightfor- by the scatter of these four observations.
ward reasons. Individual income may affect Secondly, assume that there is a linear neigh-
what neighbourhood status can be afforded bourhood effect whereby income is inversely
and/or preferred for reasons of status and related to the percentage of lower-income
quality of life. We recognise that selection neighbours by the factor b, but there is no
may not be based on income mix per se, but sorting by income. In this case, residents BL
on its many visible correlates. Nevertheless, and DH in the lower-income neighbourhood
powerful geographical patterns of income would see their incomes fall ceteris paribus
sorting have been observed (Andersson and (to B0L and D0H ), while the incomes of resi-
Bråmå, 2004; Ioannides and Zabel, 2008; dents AL and CH in the higher-income
Hedman et al., 2011). The income mix of neighbourhood would rise (to A0L and C0H ).
the neighbourhood of residence may affect The researcher would observe an inverse
the income earned by individual residents.8 linear relationship being the best OLS fit and
Income mix may serve as a proxy for a vari- would correctly deduce that a neighbour-
ety of potential endogenous and correlated hood effect was being measured. Things get
neighbourhood effect processes affecting decidedly less clear when sorting is assumed.
earnings (see Galster, 2012). If we assume only sorting, no independent
Endogeneity and the aforementioned chal- neighbourhood effect, we should see the
lenge of potential selection on unobservables ‘misallocated’ individuals AL and DH move
NEIGHBOURHOOD AND INDIVIDUAL INCOMES 113

Table 1. Descriptive statistics


Mean S.D. Minimum Maximum

Income (measured in 100 SEK) 2 751.902 2 878.812 1 294 950


Percentage low-income neighbours 31.9351 9.031033 5.833333 93.75
Percentage high-income neighbours 37.39921 12.56275 0 75.46895
Received pre-retirement benefits during year 0.0657651 0.2478712 0 1
Received parental leave benefits during year 0.1812605 0.385234 0 1
Received sick leave benefits during year 0.1005191 0.3006911 0 1
Swedish–Swedish couple (ref = single)a 0.354415 0.4783359 0 1
Swedish–foreign couple (ref = single)a 0.0487784 0.2154044 0 1
Foreign–Swedish couple (ref = single)a 0.0290328 0.1678985 0 1
Foregn–foreign couple (ref = single)a 0.0687976 0.2531097 0 1
Swedish–Swedish couplea 3 number of children 0.5079474 0.9097447 0 10
Swedish–foreign couplea 3 number of children 0.0498297 0.3150832 0 7
Foreign–Swedish couplea 3 number of children 0.0422103 0.3006143 0 9
Foregn–foreign couplea 3 number of children 0.105295 0.5063653 0 10
Swedish–Swedish couplea 3 partner’s income 759.2669 1 407.12 0 230 166
(lagged, 100 SEK)
Swedish–foreign couplea 3 partner’s income 68.29545 447.0276 0 37 000
(lagged, 100 SEK)
Foreign-Swedish couplea 3 partner’s income 55.23246 402.9153 0 37 782
(lagged, 100 SEK)
Foregn–foreign couplea 3 partner’s income 69.08856 394.0547 0 13 991
(lagged, 100 SEK)
Couple (ref = single) 0.5010237 0.4999992 0 1
Couple to single status change in last year 0.0158663 0.1249583 0 1
(ref = no change)
Single to couple status change in last year 0.0216474 0.1455295 0 1
(ref = no change)
Partner’s income (measured in 100 SEK) 10420.342 15730.807 0 230166
(zero if no partner)
Number of children in ages 0–5 0.2266599 0.5412706 0 5
Number of children in ages 6–12 0.3090626 0.6392266 0 5
Number of children in ages 13–18 0.2047075 0.5162915 0 5
Received student allowances during year 0.0282072 0.1655643 0 1
Education 12-13 years (ref = LT 12 years) 0.1619544 0.3684092 0 1
Education 14 years (ref = LT 12 years) 0.1689362 0.3746957 0 1
Education 15+ years (ref = LT 12 years) 0.2513757 0.4338043 0 1
N (90 438 individuals * 12 years each) 1 085 256
a
First ethnicity listed refers to male in sample, second to partner.

from their initial assignments into more erroneously that a neighbourhood effect
appropriate neighbourhoods (to A00L and exists.
D00H ). Now an OLS fit of the four-person However, this is not a general conclu-
scatterplot produces a line with slope b00 sion. Assume that there is a linear neigh-
and the researcher is tempted to conclude bourhood effect of the aforementioned
114 LINA HEDMAN AND GEORGE GALSTER

INDIVIDUAL INCOME suspected endogenous measure, its coeffi-


CH’ Slope = β’’ [if all sorng by income]
cient proves highly statistically significant
(p value of 0.000), although it does not in
CH DH’’ DH Slope = 0 [if no sorng the equation predicting the percentage of
or neigh’d. effect]
Slope = β’ low-income neighbours.
D H’
[if all neigh’d. AL’
effect]
3.4 Our Econometric Strategies
AL AL’’ BL % LOWER-
INCOME
NEIGHBOURS
We address these concerns over bias with
BL’
both fixed effects and instrumental vari-
Figure 1. Illustration of potential biases cre- ables strategies. Our fixed-effect strategy
ated by neighbourhood sorting by income essentially adds a set of individual-specific
and neighbourhood effects on income. dummy variables to each equation esti-
mated over a 12-year panel. This procedure
controls for any time-invariant unobserved
magnitude b, but also neighbourhood sort- characteristics of individuals that may be
ing by income. In this case, it is impossible correlated with income and neighbourhood
to predict a priori how the observed scatter selection, and thus removes the potentially
of observations in Figure 1 will manifest biasing impact of these omitted unobserva-
itself, as both individuals AL and DH are bles (but not time-varying ones).
‘moving’ in uncertain ways. Whether the Our IV strategy employs the well-known
resulting estimate of b will be biased two-stage procedure for generating instru-
upwards or downwards will depend on the ments. In the first stage, the endogenous
relative magnitudes of the two effects and, variable is regressed on exogenous variables
with more than one observation each of that are its predictors but are excluded from
type AL and DH, on the shares of each type the equation predicting the other endogen-
of individual that sort and the speed at ous variable.9 The predicted values from
which neighbourhood effects manifest this first stage, which by construction will
themselves compared with the speed of be uncorrelated with the error term in the
sorting. Analogous arguments yielding the second-stage equation, are then used in
equivalent conclusions can be made when place of the actual endogenous variables
neighbourhood income mix is considered individual income and neighbourhood
the dependent variable. income mix in the second stage where the
Empirically, is endogeneity a concern in parameters of equations (1) and (2) are esti-
equations (1) and (2)? Indeed, Hausman mated.10 In principle, these IV estimates
tests show convincingly that it is. When the should therefore avoid both sources of bias
residuals of the first-stage equations pre- and produce consistent estimates of the
dicting percentages of low- and high- effects of neighbourhood income mix on
income neighbours are added to equation individual income and of individual income
(1) along with the suspected endogenous on neighbourhood income mix respectively.
measures of these variables, their coeffi- To be an appropriate and efficacious
cients prove highly statistically significant technique, instrumental variables must be
(p values of 0.000 and 0.007 respectively). both valid and strong (Murray, 2006). To
When the residuals of the first-stage equa- be valid, IVs must: be uncorrelated with the
tions predicting individual income are error term; be correlated with the endogen-
added to equation (2), along with the ous variable; and, not be otherwise included
NEIGHBOURHOOD AND INDIVIDUAL INCOMES 115

in the given equation. We posit that there that, controlling for total number of chil-
are three variables that only affect individ- dren in each age category, the gender mix of
ual income, not neighbourhood income children will affect the individual’s income.
mix other than through income (ceteris par- Parents may, however, have special con-
ibus), and thus serve as indentifying cerns about neighbourhood environmental
instruments—whether the individual was: influences when more of their children are
on sick leave during the year; on parental of a specific gender.
leave during the year; and/or receiving pre- The strength of the IVs is the degree to
retirement benefits. Taking sick leave which they are correlated with the endo-
should affect annual income but not neigh- genous variable for which they stand in.
bourhood income mix once income is con- Our first-stage regressions results show that
trolled, because being ill is usually an we have acceptably strong instruments,
exogenous, transitory event. Similarly, using conventional standards (Table 2). In
being in pre-retirement status will affect all three equations, we obtain F-statistics
income but should have no impact upon well above Stock–Yogo critical values. The
income mix once individual income, age IVs for the percentage of low-income
and other family life-cycle characteristics neighbours pass the Sargan exclusion test.
are controlled. The same can be argued for However, our IVs for income and the per-
taking parental leave, controlling for the centage of high-income neighbours do not
characteristics of children in the household. completely meet the standard exclusion cri-
Analogously, we posit that four sets of teria. The R2 values that we obtain when
variables will affect neighbourhood income regressing the residuals from our second-
mix observed during year t but not the indi- stage regressions on our IVs are very low
vidual’s income earned during that year (0.0001) as desired, but still exceed the crit-
(ceteris paribus): individual–partner ethnic ical chi-squared values due to the extraor-
combination; individual–partner ethnic dinarily large number of observations.11
combination interacted by number of chil- We nevertheless argue for the validity of
dren; individual–partner ethnic combina- our IVs, based on logic and these empirical
tion interacted by partner income; and tests.
proportion of males in each of three age
categories of children in the household.
These first three sets of variables may serve 4. Findings
as proxies for the preferences to live with
various ethnic combinations of neighbours, The current methodological standard in
which are highly correlated with neighbour- neighbourhood effect studies using non-
hood income profile. They may also be experimentally generated data is to employ
related to limitations in residential options fixed-effect models on longitudinal datasets
due to discriminatory barriers. However, of individuals and their residential circum-
controlling for the individual’s ethnicity, stances, in an effort to circumvent bias from
the number of children in each age category selection on unobservables (for example,
and the partner’s income, neither the ethni- Musterd et al., 2012). We therefore estimate
city of the partner nor this ethnicity inter- such a model to obtain parameters of equa-
acted by that total number of children or tions (1) and to (2) and serve as a baseline
partner’s income should affect the individu- comparison for results from our more ambi-
al’s income. Similarly, we think it unlikely tious model where we add IVs.12
116 LINA HEDMAN AND GEORGE GALSTER

Table 2. Estimated coefficients (standard errors), first-stage regressions with instrumental vari-
ables (N = 1 085 256)
Dependent variable
Individual Percentage of Percentage of
income low-income high-income
neighbours neighbours

Instrumental variable
Received parental leave benefits during year 10.51877
(8.557545)
Received sick leave benefits during year 8.549466
(5.15439)
Received pre-retirement benefits during year 2774.2868
(12.48773)***
Swedish–Swedish couple (ref = single)a 20.491728 1.131418
(0.0491908)*** (0.150987)***
Swedish–Foreign couple (ref = single)a 20.4527389 0.6544031
(0.1099564)*** (0.1549472)***
Foreign–Swedish couple (ref = single)a 20.7866322 0.6865547
(0.2120022)*** (0.2804926)*
Foregn–foreign couple (ref = single)a 0.2723618 20.2266381
(0.150671) (0.155254)

Swedish–Swedish couplea 3 number of children 20.6310559 0.7827561


(0.021205)*** (0.0329014)***
Swedish–foreign couplea 3 number of children 20.3753642 0.5904009
(0.0613388)*** (0.0905092)***
Foreign–Swedish couplea 3 number of children 20.4626777 0.3877604
(0.0841064) *** (0.1082599)***
Foregn–foreign couplea 3 number of children 0.0184823 20.0297809
(0.0693435) (0.0701678)
Swedish–Swedish couplea 3 partner’s income 26.15e-06 0.0006058
(lagged, 100 SEK) (7.66e-06) (0.0000727)***
Swedish–foreign couplea 3 partner’s income 23.92e-06 0.0007295
(lagged, 100 SEK) (0.0000319) (0.0000557)***
Foreign–Swedish couplea 3 partner’s income 20.000119 0.0008139
(lagged, 100 SEK) (0.0000462)* (0.000076)***
Foregn–foreign couplea 3 partner’s income 20.0006925 00.0009779
(lagged, 100 SEK) (0.0000605)*** (0.0000672)***
Share of children age 0–5 being male 20.2958943 0.007909
(0.0403545)*** (0.0610977)
Share of children age 6–12 being male 20.4533736 0.8241233
(0.0377739)*** (0.0526931)***
Share of children age 13–18 being male 0.0339875 0.3987193
(0.0345379) (.0491464)***

R2 0.0533 0.0544 0.0988


F 1328.92 182.41 274.31
a
First ethnicity listed refers to male in sample, second to partner.
Notes: * = p \ 0.05; ** = p \ 0.01; *** = p \ 0.001.
NEIGHBOURHOOD AND INDIVIDUAL INCOMES 117

4.1 Control Variables opposite correlation—partner’s income has


the greatest effect on sorting for couples
In all variants of our models, the control with two foreign-born individuals. The
variables generally perform as expected in share of children being males is negatively
equations (1) and (2); results from the fixed- correlated with the percentage of low-
effect model are reported in the Appendix income neighbours. Results are more or less
(Table A1). All the subsequent results the reverse when modelling the percentage
should be interpreted in the context of of high-income neighbours as the depen-
models containing these control variables. dent variable.
Incomes are greater for those who:
have better educational credentials, recently
4.2 Fixed-effects Model Results
changed their civil union status from
couple to single, and have more children We estimate parameters of equations (1)
age 6–18. Younger children have a negative and (2) using the generalised least squares
effect on income. Income is also positively (GLS) algorithm in STATA IC-11 for the
correlated with being on sick or parental estimation of fixed-effect panel models.
leave which is most likely to indicate that Results for the endogenous explanatory
individuals who make use of these benefits variables are reported in the left panel of
are often employed. We also find a positive Table 3. In overview, they provide strong
correlation between personal income and evidence that neighbourhood income mix
partner’s income. Receiving pre-retirement and individual resident income are mutually
benefits, studying or changing civil status causal.
from single to couple are associated with The individual income equation indicates
lower incomes. The coefficients of our year that, across the entire spectrum of working-
dummies signal a business cycle with the age Stockholm males, middle-income
years around the turn of the millennium neighbours generally provide the most salu-
being the most prosperous. tary economic environment. Decreasing the
As for the two neighbourhood income low-income share by one standard deviation
mix equations, living in areas with greater (and implicitly increasing the middle-
percentages of high-income neighbours is income share correspondingly) is associated
positively correlated with higher educational with a 12.6 per cent income increase. In line
credentials, going from couple to single with previous studies (Galster et al., 2008),
status and number of children of all ages, decreasing the high-income share by one
while negatively correlated with being a stu- standard deviation (and implicitly increas-
dent and going from single to couple status. ing the middle-income share correspond-
When regressing the same variables on the ingly) is associated with a 6.9 per cent
percentage of lower-income neighbours, the income increase. Higher shares of low-
opposite results are found. Couples with income neighbours may reduce residents’
two or one Swedish-born persons are less employment and income prospects due to,
likely than couples with two foreign-born for example, anti-work socialisation effects,
individuals to reside in areas with high per- resource-poor networks and/or area-based
centages of low-income people, a relation- stigmatisation. Higher shares of either
ship that pertains when interacted with middle-income or high-income males may
number of children in household. However, engender the opposite causal processes, but
when interacting the ethnic combinations of only the middle-income ones may have suf-
couples with partner’s income, we find the ficiently close social distances to all resident
118

Table 3. Estimated coefficients (standard errors) for endogenous variables in neighbourhood effects and neighbourhood sorting linear models
(comparing fixed-effects and fixed-effects instrumental variables specification) (N = 1 085 256)
Endogenous explanatory variable Fixed-effect model dependent variable Fixed-effect-IV model dependent variable
Individual Percentage of Percentage of Individual Percentage of Percentage of
Income low-income high-income Income low-income high-income
LINA HEDMAN AND GEORGE GALSTER

neighbours neighbours neighbours neighbours

Percentage of low-income neighbours 20.0140352 20.0629898


(0.001341)*** (0.0147896)***
Percentage of high-income neighbours 20.0054859 20.0170836
(0.0009573)*** (0.0073197)*
Individual income (lagged) 20.0000354 0.0001199 20.0000558 0.0008278
(4.00e-06)*** (8.53e-06)*** (.0000921) (.0001053)***
R2 0.3437 0.0652 0.1209 0.3366 0.0680 0.1614
F 690.08 958.52 1574.22 691.47 955.52 1575.21

Notes: * = p \ 0.05; ** = p \ 0.01; *** = p \ 0.001.


NEIGHBOURHOOD AND INDIVIDUAL INCOMES 119

income groups to become effective peers, INDIVIDUAL INCOME

role models and transmitters of employ-


CH’’’
ment information resources through local DH’’’
CH DH
networks.
Slope = β’’’ [measured neigh’d.
Fixed-effect model coefficients for the Slope = β’ effect with differenal sorng]
[true neigh’d. AL’’’
endogenous individual income variable in effect]
the two neighbourhood mix equations (2)
AL BL
indicate that income is associated with % LOWER-
BL’’’ INCOME
neighbourhood sorting as expected, but NEIGHBOURS

effect sizes are small. A one standard devia-


Figure 2. Illustration of downward endo-
tion increase in individual income is associ- geneity bias in measured neighbourhood
ated with a 0.10 percentage-point decrease effect from differential income sorting.
in the percentage of low-income neigh-
bours and a 0.33 percentage-point increase
in high-income neighbours, on average neighbours. Thus, it appears that endogene-
over the next year. ity arising from mutual causality results in
substantially downward-biased estimates
for both neighbourhood selection of high-
4.3 Fixed Effects: IV Model Results
income residential areas and neighbour-
The second set of parameters, reported in hood mix effects on income, even when
the right-hand panel of Table 3, estimates using state-of-the-art, fixed-effect panel
equations (1) and (2) in a similar fixed- models.
effects panel data approach, but replaces the One potential explanation for this is dif-
respective endogenous variables of neigh- ferential sorting by income producing selec-
bourhood income mix and individual tive neighbourhood effects; see Figure 2.
income with their respective instruments Referring again to the thought experiment
whose estimates are presented in Table 2. In introduced in Figure 1, the ‘true’ neigh-
overview, this approach substantially affects bourhood effect measured in the absence of
the size of the endogenous variables’ coeffi- sorting would be b0 . Yet suppose that (con-
cients (the control variables perform simi- sistent with our results) high-income
larly to the baseline fixed effects model). person DH quickly sorted into a much-
The results of the individual income higher-income neighbourhood than ini-
model show that the negative coefficients of tially assigned, thereby minimising the
low-and high-income neighbour share IVs exposure to a low-income environment and
remain highly statistically significant and obviating its negative impact. High-income
are magnified by a power of 10 when endo- person CH may eventually sort into an
geneity is controlled, compared with the even-higher-income neighbourhood, but
fixed-effects model when only selection on perhaps not before reaping some positive
time-invariant unobservables is controlled. effect from the initial neighbourhood. By
Roughly the same magnification occurs for contrast, low-income individuals have
the coefficient of individual income IV in fewer sorting options. AL already lives in a
the high-income neighbour equation. The high-income neighbourhood, most likely
only exception to this pattern is that the IV because the neighbourhood has mixed
for individual income becomes considerably tenure or because AL bought her dwelling
smaller and statistically insignificant in the when prices were lower. Even though
equation predicting share of low-income AL may benefit from her high-income
120 LINA HEDMAN AND GEORGE GALSTER

7 Fixed-Effects Model,
Income (Logged)

%Low-Income Neighbours
6

5 Instrumental Variable
Model, %Low-Income
4 Neighbours
3 Fixed-Effects Model,
%High-Income Neighbours
2

1 Instrumental Variable
Model, %High-Income
0 Neighbours
0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100
% Low or High Income Neighbours

Figure 3. Results from the neighbourhood effects model (dependent variable = income).

neighbours, her initially low income makes endogeneity (Black line) yields much larger
it unlikely that she will be able to translate estimates than the fixed-effects model
income gains into an even-higher-income (grey line) when the percentage of high-
neighbourhood. Low-income person BL income earners in the neighbourhood
who lives in a low-income neighbourhood increases.
may, however, persistently incur a negative In Figure 4, the corresponding results
neighbourhood effect (in situ) or be forced are shown for the neighbourhood selection
to move into an even-lower-income neigh- model, where neighbourhood income mix
bourhood if her income is eroded. The net (either percentage low- or high-income
result of this income-differentiated mobility neighbours) on the vertical axis varies
is a scatter of observations (denoted by the according to both model used and individ-
triple apostrophes in Figure 2) potentially ual income (on the horizontal axis). As
yielding a substantial underestimate of the shown in Figure 4, the differences in results
‘true’ neighbourhood effect. between the fixed-effects (grey line) and the
Results from the fixed-effects and fixed- fixed-effects instrumental variable (Black
effects instrumental variable models of line) models are very small when the per-
both neighbourhood effects and neigh- centage of low-income neighbours is the
bourhood sorting are shown graphically in dependent variable (solid lines). However,
Figures 3 and 4. In Figure 3, the neighbour- when modelling the selection according to
hood effect model is plotted. As shown in the percentage of high-income neighbours
the figure, individual income (shown on (dotted lines), there are substantial differ-
the vertical axis) varies extensively with the ences between the two models. The change
share of low-income neighbours (solid in percentage of high-income neighbours
lines) or percentage of high-income neigh- associated with an increase in individual
bours (dotted lines), regardless of the income is much larger in the fixed-effects
model. Yet, there are clear differences instrumental variable model controlling for
between the two models, where the instru- endogeneity compared with the fixed-
mental variable model controlling for effects model.
NEIGHBOURHOOD AND INDIVIDUAL INCOMES 121

50

% Low or High Income Neighbours


45
Fixed-Effects Model,
40 %Low-Income Neighbours

Instrumental Variable
35 Model, %Low-Income
Neighbours
30 Fixed-Effects Model,
%High-Income Neighbours
25
Instrumental Variable
3 std 2 std 1 std mean 1 std 2 std 3 std Model, %High-Income
dev dev dev dev dev dev N i hb
Neighbours
below below below above above above
mean mean mean mean mean mean
Income

Figure 4. Results from the neighbourhood selection model (dependent variable = neighbour-
hood income mix).

5. Discussion percentage of low-income or high-income


neighbours, but the differences between the
Both the fixed-effects and the fixed-effects two models are substantially larger when we
with IV models indicated a statistically look at the percentage of low-income neigh-
and economically significant relationship bours. Our findings thus suggest that virtu-
between the percentage of low-income or ally all previous statistical studies (that do
high-income neighbours and an individual’s not control for endogeneity bias) may have
income. As previously discussed in the underestimated neighbourhood effects, as
paper, higher shares of low-income neigh- also suggested by Ludwig et al. (2001).
bours may reduce residents’ employment Although we urge caution in emphasising
and income prospects through a number the precise magnitudes of neighbourhood
of potential transition mechanisms—for effects (and implicit bias) estimated by our
example, poor local networks, socialisation fixed-effect IV model, the patterns across
and/or area-based stigmatisation. High- the models are dramatic and suggestive.
income neighbours, on the other hand, may Unlike the neighbourhood effects litera-
be too socially distant to become effective ture, which clearly is cognisant of the
role models or bridges to (parts of) the statistical bias problems confronted in this
labour market. These results challenge those paper, a similar discussion seems to be
who claim that there is no important, inde- more or less missing in the neighbourhood
pendent effect of neighbourhood context on selection literature. Nevertheless, neigh-
economic outcomes (see Smolensky, 2007; bourhood sorting processes appear strongly
Cheshire, 2007). Furthermore, our results affected by selection on unobservables
suggest that this relationship becomes sub- (Ioannides and Zabel, 2008). Moreover, we
stantially larger when endogeneity is find that endogeneity leads to a substantial
addressed statistically. This finding holds downward bias of the measured effect of
true regardless of whether we look at the individual income on the high-income
122 LINA HEDMAN AND GEORGE GALSTER

share of the neighbourhood in which one verified the endogenous nature of these pre-
resides. Thus, conclusions about income dictors. By adopting a fixed-effects model
sorting based on conventional, point-in- with instrumental variable proxies of the
time correlations between income and endogenous predictors, we addressed both
neighbourhood characteristics risk being sources of bias.
seriously erroneous. We found that both selection on unob-
Our results suggest that marginal gains in servables and endogeneity are empirically
income have a much stronger impact on important sources of potential bias in stud-
obtaining more high-income neighbours ies of neighbourhood effects and neigh-
than fewer low-income neighbours. One ele- bourhood selection. Our IV approach
ment of explanation could be the relative dis- produced substantially larger coefficients
persal of lower-income males, as evinced by compared with a conventional fixed-effects
the lack of ‘disadvantaged’ neighbourhoods in model (with the exception of income
Stockholm. Only 10 per cent of neighbour- predicting low-income neighbour share),
hoods exceeded 40 per cent low-income males implying that endogeneity generally biased
in 2006, and only six neighbourhoods exceeded measured neighbourhood effect and neigh-
60 per cent.13 Another potential part of the bourhood income sorting processes down-
explanation is the geography of tenure mix wards. In other words, our results suggest
that, coupled with non-market aspects of the that previous research not controlling for
Swedish rental housing regulations, often endogeneity may have underestimated the
makes it possible to stay in a neighbourhood true neighbourhood effect. Similarly, indi-
despite a decrease in income. Conversely, vidual income and marginal increases in
moving into homeownership is costly and such may have a stronger effect on type of
homeownership areas tend to be the most neighbourhood chosen than suggested by
homogeneous in terms of tenure and (higher) previous research, especially in terms of the
income. The positive correlation between share of high-income residents in the
income and share of high-income neighbours neighbourhood.
may thus be partly explained by housing career We close by acknowledging that our
aspirations. results may not necessarily be generalised,
produced as they were with a specific set of
endogenous variables generated in one met-
6. Conclusion ropolitan area embedded in a particular
social welfare state structure. We thus urge
In this paper, we argued for a holistic replication in other contexts. Nevertheless,
approach when empirically estimating we think our findings are sufficiently pro-
neighbourhood effect and neighbourhood vocative to warrant concluding that endo-
selection models to avoid two sources of geneity bias (not just bias from selection on
bias: selection on unobservables and endo- unobservables) needs to be taken into con-
geneity. We estimated a structural equation sideration by studies empirically estimating
system wherein neighbourhood income mix neighbourhood effects and/or neighbour-
and individual resident income are specified hood selection processes.
as mutually causal—individual income
affects the income mix of the neighbour-
hood (through neighbourhood selection) Notes
and income mix of the neighbourhood 1. Ioannides and Zabel (2008), van Ham and
affects individual income. Statistical tests Manley (2010), Hedman and van Ham
NEIGHBOURHOOD AND INDIVIDUAL INCOMES 123

(2012) and Hedman et al. (2011) argue that 6. We choose a nation-wide standard for
one must uncover neighbourhood selection income groups, just as the US has adopted
processes to accurately assess neighbour- a nation-wide poverty standard. The
hood effects. They do not, however, extend Stockholm population is slightly overrepre-
the argument conceptually or empirically to sented among both high- and low-income
consider how neighbourhood effects may earners compared with the nation-wide dis-
alter neighbourhood selection. tribution. In year 2000, the cut-off points
2. As Gennetian et al. (2011) show, these for low-income were SEK 99 000 in
biases can be substantial enough to seri- Stockholm and SEK 118 000 nation-wide.
ously distort conclusions about the magni- Correspo-nding values for high-income
tude and even the direction of were SEK 296 220 (Stockholm) and SEK
neighbourhood effects. 261 600 (nation-wide).
3. We do not model neighbourhood selection 7. The log-linear transformation is not only
directly, but do so indirectly in two ways. appropriate given the positive skew of the
First, given that neighbourhoods typically income distribution, but also has sound
do not change their income mix radically grounding in economic theory, implicitly
over short periods, neighbourhood selec- suggesting that income is a multiplicative
tion decisions made by relatively recent in- (not additive) function of personal, neigh-
movers will still be reflected in their current bourhood and labour market characteristics.
neighbourhood income mix. Moreover, to 8. We recognise that by specifying contem-
the extent that these in-movers failed to poraneous (M) we are suggesting that
predict future, unanticipated changes in neighbourhood income mix has a rapid
income mix, these errors should be random effect on individual income. There are sev-
and not bias the relationship between their eral causal processes that make this possible
current income and the current neighbour- (Galster, 2008) and new evidence indicates
hood income mix. Secondly, current that short-term effects occur, although sus-
income mix should also reflect the selection tained exposures may be more powerful
of longer-term residents in as much as they (Musterd et al., 2012).
would have moved out if the mix had 9. Since we are employing panel data, we also
turned unsatisfactory. Thus, the correlation use fixed effects as exogenous predictors in
between individuals’ incomes and the this first stage. In preliminary trials we
income mix in locations they occupy does also experimented with the classic 2SLS
tell us something about how income affects procedure and regressed the endogenous
both moving into and out of neighbour- variables on all the exogenous variables in
hoods of particular income mixes. the three-equation system: PIt , PI, PMt ,
4. More precisely, our analysis populations are PM, and Lt . These IV estimates proved
drawn from the metro Stockholm municipa- extremely unreliable and are not reported.
lities of Stockholm, Solna and Sundbyberg, 10. We constrained all predicted values to the
which together roughly constitute the urban range of actual values.
core. 11. Sargan test results are available upon
5. Formally, income from work is computed request.
here as the sum of: cash salary payments, 12. In a companion paper (Galster and
income from active businesses and tax- Hedman, 2011), we estimate neighbour-
based benefits that employees accrue as hood effect models with a wide range of
terms of their employment (sick or parental alternative statistical models and compare
leave, work-related injury or illness com- results.
pensation, daily payments for temporary 13. Most studies with an ‘avoidance of disad-
military service or giving assistance to a dis- vantage’ perspective focus on the most
abled relative). deprived areas.
124 LINA HEDMAN AND GEORGE GALSTER

Funding Statement Neighbourhood Effects Research: Theory and


Evidence, pp. 23–56. Dordrecht: Springer.
This research received no specific grant from any Galster, G. and Hedman, L. (2011) Alternative
funding agency in the public, commercial or not- ways of measuring neighborhood effects: do
for-profit sectors. methods matter? Unpublished paper, Depart-
ment of Urban Studies and Planning, Wayne
References State University, Detroit.
Galster, G., Andersson, R. and Musterd, S. (2010)
Andersson, E. (2001) Från sorgedalen till glädje- Threshold effects of neighborhood income mix.
höjden: omgivningens betydelse för socioekono- Paper presented at the Association for Public
misk karriär. Geografiska Regionstudier No. Policy Analysis and Management Conference,
44, Department of Social and Economic Geo- Boston, MA, November.
graphy, Uppsala University. Galster, G., Andersson, R., Musterd, S. and
Andersson, R. (1998) Socio-spatial dynamics: Kauppinen, T. (2008) Does neighborhood
ethnic divisions of mobility and housing in income mix affect earnings of adults? New
post-Palme Sweden, Urban Studies, 35, pp. evidence from Sweden, Journal of Urban Eco-
397–428. nomics, 63, pp. 858–870.
Andersson, R. and Bråmå, Å. (2004) Selective Galster, G., Marcotte, D., Mandell, M., Wolman,
migration in Swedish distressed neighbour- H. and Augustine, N. (2007) The influence of
hoods: can area-based urban policies coun- neighborhood poverty during childhood on
teract segregation processes?, Housing Studies, fertility, education and earnings outcomes,
19, pp. 517–539. Housing Studies, 22, pp. 723–752.
Andersson, R., Musterd, S., Galster, G. and Gennetian, L., Ludwig, J. and Sanbonmatsu, L.
Kauppinen, T. (2007) What mix matters? (2011) An overview of moving to opportu-
Exploring the relationships between individ- nity, in: H. Newburger, E. Birch and S. Wach-
uals’ incomes and different measures of their ter (Eds) Neighborhood and Life Chances: How
neighborhood context, Housing Studies, 22, Place Matters in Modern America, pp. 163–
pp. 637–660. 178. Philadelphia, PA: University of Pennsyl-
Berube, A. (2005) Mixed communities in England: vania Press.
a U.S. perspective on evidence and policy pro- Ham, M. van and Manley, D. (2010) The effect of
posals. Joseph Rountree Foundation, York. neighbourhood housing tenure mix on labour
Briggs, X. (Ed.) (2005) The Geography of Oppor- market outcomes: a longitudinal investigation
tunity. Washington, DC: Brookings Institu- of neighbourhood effects, Journal of Economic
tion Press. Geography, 10, pp. 257–282.
Cheshire, P. (2007) Are mixed-income commu- Hedman, L. (2011) The impact of residential
nities the answer to segregation and poverty? mobility on measurements of neighbourhood
Joseph Rowntree Foundation, York. effects, Housing Studies, 26, pp. 501–519.
Doff, W. (2010) Puzzling Neighbourhood Effects. Hedman, L. and Ham, M. van (2012) Understand-
Amsterdam: IOS Press, BV. ing neighbourhood effects: selection bias and
Galster, G. (2003) Investigating behavioral residential mobility, in: M. van Ham, D. Manley,
impacts of poor neighborhoods: towards N. Bailey, L. Simpson and D. Maclennan (Eds)
new data and analytic strategies, Housing Neighbourhood Effects Research: Theory and Evi-
Studies, 18, pp. 893–914. dence, pp. 79–99. Dordrecht: Springer.
Galster, G. (2008) Quantifying the effect of Hedman, L., Ham, M. van and Manley, D. (2011)
neighbourhood on individuals: challenges, Neighbourhood choice and neighbourhood
alternative approaches and promising direc- reproduction, Environment and Planning A,
tions, Journal of Applied Social Science Stud- 43, pp. 1381–1399.
ies, 128, pp. 7–48. Ihlanfeldt, K. R. and Sjoquist, D. L. (1998) The
Galster, G. (2012) The mechanism(s) of neigh- spatial mismatch hypothesis: a review of
bourhood effects: theory, evidence, and policy recent studies and their implications for wel-
implications, in: M. van Ham, D. Manley, N. fare reform, Housing Policy Debate, 9, pp.
Bailey, L. Simpson and D. Maclennan (Eds) 849–892.
NEIGHBOURHOOD AND INDIVIDUAL INCOMES 125

Ioannides, Y. and Zabel, J. (2008) Interactions, Musterd, S. and Andersson, R. (2005) Housing
neighbourhood selection and housing mix, social mix and social opportunities,
demand, Journal of Urban Economics, 63, pp. Urban Affairs Review, 40, pp. 761–790.
229–252. Musterd, S., Galster, G. and Andersson, R. (2012)
Jargowsky, P. (1997) Poverty and Place. New Temporal dimensions of neighbourhood
York: Russell Sage Foundation. effects, Environment and Planning A, 44(3),
Jencks, C. and Mayer, S. (1990) The social con- pp. 605–627.
sequences of growing up in a poor neighbor- Norris, M. (2006) Developing, designing and
hood, in: L. Lynn and M. McGeary (Eds) managing mixed tenure housing estates, Eur-
Inner-city Poverty in the United States, pp. opean Planning Studies, 14, pp. 199–218.
111–186. Washington, DC: National Acad- Sampson, R. and Sharkey, P. (2008) Neighbor-
emy Press. hood selection and the social reproduction of
Ludwig, J., Duncan, G. and Hirschfield, P. (2001) concentrated racial inequality, Demography,
Urban poverty and juvenile crime: evidence 45, pp. 1–29.
from a randomized housing-mobility experi- Sari, F. (2012) Analysis of neighbourhood effects
ment, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116, pp. and work behaviour: evidence from Paris,
655–679. Housing Studies, 27, pp. 45–76.
Murie, A. and Musterd, S. (2004) Social exclu- Smolensky, E. (2007) Children in the vanguard
sion and opportunity structures in European of the U.S. welfare state, Journal of Economic
cities and neighbourhoods, Urban Studies, 41, Literature, 45, pp. 1011–1023.
pp. 1425–1443. Urban, S. (2009) Is the neighbourhood effect an
Murray, M. (2006) Avoiding invalid instruments economic or an immigrant issue? A study of
and coping with weak instruments, Journal of the importance of the childhood neighbour-
Economic Perspectives, 20, pp. 111–132. hood for future integration into the labour
market, Urban Studies, 46, pp. 583–603.
Appendix
Table A1. Parameter estimates for exogenous variables in both neighbourhood effect and sorting models in fixed-effect models (N = 1 085 256)
126

Dependent variable

Individual income Percentage of low-income Percentage of high-income


neighbours neighbours

Coefficient S.D. Coefficient S.D. Coefficient S.D.

Endogenous explanatory variables


Income 20.0000354 4.00e-06*** .0001199 8.53e-06***
Percentage of low-income neighbours 20.0140352 0.001341***
Percentage of high-income neighbours 20.0054859 0.0009573***

Control variables
Received parental leave benefits during year 0.287972 0.0070303***
Received sick leave benefits during year 0.0915299 0.0096982***
LINA HEDMAN AND GEORGE GALSTER

Received pre-retirement benefits during year 220.580728 0.0342994***


Swedish–Swedish couple (ref = single)a 20.6929599 0.0582339*** 1.128994 0.1005458***
Swedish–foreign couple (ref = single)a 20.7201906 0.1139049*** 1.416327 0.1574599***
Foreign–Swedish couple (ref = single)a 210.059124 0.214801*** 1.41956 0.2675944***
Foregn–foreign couple (ref = single)a 0.0485903 0.155384 0.018098 0.1609953
Swedish–Swedish couplea 3 number of children 20.1340699 0.0450558 0.1772196 0.0622839**
Swedish–foreign couplea 3 number of children 0.1195239 0.0711345 20.3209014 0.1000892**
Foreign–Swedish couplea 3 number of children 0.0449637 0.0927058 20.2778965 0.1186231*
Foreign–foreign couplea 3 number of children 0.50356 0.079005*** 20.6986093 0.0889678***
Swedish–Swedish couplea 3 partner’s income (lagged) 4.72e-06 8.25e-06 0.0001846 0.000029***
Swedish–foreign couplea 3 partner’s income (lagged) 0.0000191 0.0000321 0.0001661 0.0000487**
Foreign–Swedish couplea 3 partner’s income (lagged) 20.0000983 0.0000461* 0.0002474 0.0000638***
Foreign–foreign couplea 3 partner’s income (lagged) 20.0006915 0.0000605*** 0.0004 0.0000655***

Share of children age 0–5 being male 20.1066714 0.0444472* 0.1104623 0.061111
Share of children age 6–12 being male 20.1455107 0.0407227*** 0.2248434 0.0543422***
Share of children age 13–18 being male 20.1145137 0.0380955** 0.1503267 0.049495**

Education LT 12 years ref ref ref ref ref ref


Education 12–13 years (ref = LT 12 years) 0.1788842 0.0468036*** 20.1130686 0.1082484 0.1642298 0.1451767
Education 14 years (ref = LT 12 years) 0.1227967 0.0479508* 0.0899579 0.1292638 0.0223536 0.1590932
(continued)
Table A1. (Continued)

Dependent variable

Individual income Percentage of low-income Percentage of high-income


neighbours neighbours

Coefficient S.D. Coefficient S.D. Coefficient S.D.

Education 15 + years (ref = LT 12 years) 0.5465274 0.0514116*** 20.5374361 0.1462849*** 0.9080442 0.178993***
Received student allowances during year 210.501609 0.0205862*** 0.2945304 0.0459671*** 20.132617 0.0546008*
Couple (ref = single) 0.0196793 0.0164013
Couple to single status change in last year (ref = no change) 0.0739207 0.0145647*** 20.5772914 0.0413568*** 1.125563 0.0534598***
Single to couple status change in last year (ref = no change) 20.0256898 0.0112921* 0.4402551 0.0397079*** 20.6298747 0.0654057***
Number of children in ages 0–5 20.0544885 0.0072132*** 20.3255037 0.0456738*** 1.038368 0.0668365***
Number of children in ages 6–12 0.016932 0.0060452** 20.6200522 0.0461365*** 1.139469 0.0626323***
Number of children in ages 13–18 0.068196 0.0059027*** 20.3255037 0.0456738*** 0.6416061 0.0619553***
Partner’s income (zero if no partner) 0.0000334 4.76e-06***

1995 20.2794951 0.0097379*** 0.096797 0.0280313** 22.586324 0.0389578***


1996 20.2403834 0.0094307*** 0.2257006 0.02708*** 22.592476 0.0370322***
1997 20.212018 0.0091542*** 20.2467092 0.025708*** 22.066332 0.0346313***
1998 20.1441218 0.0087189*** 20.4980049 0.0241044*** 21.338301 0.0322431***
1999 20.0515887 0.0082558*** 20.778838 0.0224548*** 20.2024204 0.0298709***
2000 0.0362725 0.0077194*** 21.159504 0.0203002*** 0.9819188 0.0272276***
2001 0.1022521 0.0073453*** 21.356924 0.0178867*** 2.078161 0.0244864***
2002 0.0719113 0.0070603*** 20.9842613 0.0161188*** 2.123741 0.0218771***
2003 0.0108264 0.006731 20.2874107 0.0141406*** 1.237263 0.0188368***
2004 20.0513358 0.0062124*** 0.3261692 0.0113082*** 0.359626 00.0148806***
2005 20.0516593 0.0050995*** 0.4221166 0.0065132*** 20.0791159 00.0086206***
2006 ref ref ref ref ref ref

Constant 7.414354 0.0801599*** 33.29678 0.0747411*** 35.53857 0.0961439***


NEIGHBOURHOOD AND INDIVIDUAL INCOMES

R-squared 0.3437 0.0652 0.1209


F 690.08 958.52 1574.22
127

a
First ethnicity listed refers to male in sample, second to partner.
Notes: * = p \ 0.05; ** = p \ 0.01; *** = p \ 0.001.

You might also like