VanBiezenKopecky Published

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 15

See discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.

net/publication/272356303

The cartel party and the state: Party-state linkages in European democracies

Article  in  Party Politics · March 2014


DOI: 10.1177/1354068813519961

CITATIONS READS

27 419

2 authors:

Ingrid van Biezen Petr Kopecký


Leiden University Leiden University
48 PUBLICATIONS   1,653 CITATIONS    35 PUBLICATIONS   1,090 CITATIONS   

SEE PROFILE SEE PROFILE

Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects:

The constitutional regulation of political parties in post-war Europe View project

All content following this page was uploaded by Ingrid van Biezen on 17 February 2015.

The user has requested enhancement of the downloaded file.


Party Politics
http://ppq.sagepub.com/

The cartel party and the state: Party−state linkages in European democracies
Ingrid van Biezen and Petr Kopecký
Party Politics published online 7 February 2014
DOI: 10.1177/1354068813519961

The online version of this article can be found at:


http://ppq.sagepub.com/content/early/2014/02/07/1354068813519961

Published by:

http://www.sagepublications.com

On behalf of:
Political Organizations and Parties Section of the American Political Science Association

Additional services and information for Party Politics can be found at:

Email Alerts: http://ppq.sagepub.com/cgi/alerts

Subscriptions: http://ppq.sagepub.com/subscriptions

Reprints: http://www.sagepub.com/journalsReprints.nav

Permissions: http://www.sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.nav

>> OnlineFirst Version of Record - Feb 7, 2014

What is This?

Downloaded from ppq.sagepub.com at Universiteit Leiden \ LUMC on February 10, 2014


Article
Party Politics
1–13
The cartel party and the state: ª The Author(s) 2014
Reprints and permission:
Party–state linkages in European sagepub.co.uk/journalsPermissions.nav
DOI: 10.1177/1354068813519961
ppq.sagepub.com
democracies

Ingrid van Biezen


Leiden University, The Netherlands

Petr Kopecký
Leiden University, The Netherlands

Abstract
This article focuses on the nature and strength of the relationship between political parties and the state. Expanding on the
analytical framework we developed earlier (van Biezen and Kopecký, 2007), we identify three different dimensions of the
party–state linkage: the dependence of parties on the state, the management of parties by the state, and the capture of
the state by parties. We provide an updated cross-national empirical analysis of the relationship between political parties
and the state in contemporary European democracies, building on two recently developed datasets on party regulation and
party patronage. Our analysis underscores the considerable importance of the state for political parties in general, but also
highlights important differences between the older democracies, and the more recently established democracies that
emerged in the third wave of democratization. We show that the different dimensions of the party–state linkage do not
necessarily work in the same direction, which suggests that the assumption of a close relationship between parties and the
state ultimately undermining the democratic legitimacy of political parties requires some qualification.

Keywords
cartel party, party finance, party patronage, party regulation

Introduction growing importance of the state features prominently in the


original cartel party article and is illustrated by the word cloud
One of the key contentions of the Katz and Mair (1995) cartel
in Figure 1, which visually represents the word frequency of
party article holds that the process of organizational transfor-
the cartel party article (excluding the words ‘political party’
mation of European political parties is best characterized by
or ‘parties’). Indeed, Katz and Mair are to be credited for the
a weakening of the parties’ linkages with society and a conco-
significant readjustment in the scholarly debate on the per-
mitant intensification of their relationship with the state. One
ceived ‘decline of parties’, emphasizing that the strengthen-
part of this process of adaptation, i.e. the erosion of the relation-
ing of the party–state linkage has compensated for many of
ship between parties and society, has been relatively well docu- the parties’ societal weaknesses. As a result, the relationship
mented empirically and does not concern us here. Suffice it to
between political parties and the state has become more
say, this weakening of the parties’ social anchorage is evident
important in contemporary analyses of democracy and party
from a variety of indicators, which all point more or less in the
government (e.g. Dalton et al., 2011; Kopecký and Mair,
same direction, including the waning of party identification,
2003). In particular, in Mair’s publications the increased
the erosion of traditional cleavages, increasing partisan deal-
ignment, rising levels of electoral volatility, declining party
memberships, deteriorating relationships between parties and Paper submitted 2 August 2013; accepted for publication 19 December
collateral organizations, and so on (e.g. Dalton and Watten- 2013
berg, 2000; Inglehart, 1997; van Biezen et al., 2012). Corresponding author:
This article addresses the other side of the equation, i.e. Ingrid van Biezen, Leiden University, 2300 RB Leiden, The Netherlands.
the relationship between political parties and the state. The Email: i.c.van.biezen@fsw.leidenuniv.nl

Downloaded from ppq.sagepub.com at Universiteit Leiden \ LUMC on February 10, 2014


2 Party Politics

state subventions was given such ‘a pre-eminent position


as the key indicator of cartelization’ (Katz and Mair, 2009:
754; see also Mair, 1994). The underlying argument is well
known and can be summarized succinctly: the introduction
of public subsidies has made political parties increasingly
dependent on the state at the expense of their financial lin-
kages with society, such as membership contributions or
other forms of grassroots funding. In addition, state subven-
tions may serve to consolidate the status quo and therefore
contribute to the cartelization of the party system by penaliz-
ing smaller parties and making it difficult for newcomers to
enter the system. As the practice of state subsidies for par-
Figure 1. Word cloud cartel party article.
Source: Katz and Mair 1995. ties, or indeed party finances more generally, has now begun
to be relatively well documented and analysed (e.g. Koss,
relevance of the state as an organizational resource for parties 2010; Nassmacher, 2010; Scarrow 2006), we can suffice in
is not only of critical importance with regard to their own sur- this section to provide only a brief albeit systematic and
vival but also for the low levels of popular trust and legitimacy comprehensive overview. As our focus is on the parties,
as well as the uncertain future of party democracy (e.g. Mair, rather than the party system, we concentrate on the availabil-
1995, 2006). ity of direct subsidies to the national party organizations, as
In this article, we analyse the nature and intensity of the well as the relative importance of state support provided to
relationship between parties and the state. In doing so, we start the total party incomes.
from the analytical framework developed previously (van State subsidies are now available to political parties in
Biezen and Kopecký, 2007), which underscores that the rela- nearly every European democracy. This can be seen from Fig-
tionship between parties and the state is best conceived as ure 2, which reveals the years of direct public funding to party
multi-faceted rather than uni-dimensional. More particularly, organizations, beginning with Germany in 1959, followed by
we have identified three key dimensions of the party–state Finland ten years later (1969) and concluding with the rela-
linkage: (1) the dependence of parties on the state; (2) the tively late introduction of state subventions in Latvia in
management of parties by the state; and (3) the capture of the 2010. The differences between long-established and more
state by parties.1 The first element comprises the financial recent democracies are not particularly large, except perhaps
dependence of parties on the state, which results from the dis- that the only countries in which political parties (at the national
tribution of direct public subsidies; the second entails the reg- level) do not have access to regular public subsidies are three
ulation of party activity, behaviour and organization by public older democracies – Malta, Switzerland and the UK – although
law; the third involves the extent of party patronage appoint- provides so-called policy development grants to parties with at
ments within the state administration. least two parliamentary seats. Another difference between old
Below we provide an updated cross-national empirical anal- and new democracies concerns the sequence of events, i.e. the
ysis of the relationship between political parties and the state in timing of the introduction of public subsidies vis-à-vis the
contemporary European democracies, building on two recently development and institutionalization of political parties and
developed datasets on party regulation and party patronage.2 democracy. In most of the newer democracies, public funding
These newly available data allow for a more comprehensive was introduced at a relatively early stage of the democratiza-
and systematic analysis of the patterns of party–state linkages tion process – already before the first democratic elections in
than in the past. In what follows, we examine each of the three Spain (1977), Hungary (1989) and former Czechoslovakia
dimensions of the party–state linkage in more detail. Our anal- (1990) for instance, or shortly thereafter in many others. In the
ysis underscores the considerable importance of the state for older democracies, public funding was inevitably introduced at
political parties in general, but also highlights important differ- a much later stage of democratic development. While the early
ences that exist between the older democracies, on the one availability of state support may have aided the institutionaliza-
hand, and the more recently established democracies of the tion of the young and fragile party organizations in the newer
third and fourth waves of democratization, on the other. democracies, it may also have removed a key incentive for
the development of structural linkages with civil society;
this has served to consolidate the centralized top-down
structures that characterize many of the party organizations
The dependence of parties on the state –
in these young democracies (e.g. Lewis, 1996; van Biezen,
Public funding 2003).
The importance of public funding has received considerable Nevertheless, public subsidies have become a widespread
attention since the cartel party article was first published, in phenomenon worldwide, in old and new democracies alike,
particular because the increasing dependence of parties on although they are perhaps more prominent in the latter. Katz

Downloaded from ppq.sagepub.com at Universiteit Leiden \ LUMC on February 10, 2014


Biezen and Kopecký 3

Figure 2. Introduction of public funding.


Source: www.partylaw.leidenuniv.nl.

and Mair were thus right to note a growing availability of state compliance with the existing anti-corruption stan-
state subventions, and they were also correct to anticipate dards – evaluations from 2007 to 2011. These estimates,
a further growth in the years that would follow (Katz and however imprecise and despite ignoring within-country
Mair, 1995): since the cartel party article was first submitted, variation, offer what is perhaps the best comparative
public funding has been introduced in an additional eight aggregate evidence currently available.3
countries, bringing the number of European democracies Figure 3 displays the financial dependence on the state for
in which political parties are directly subsidized by the parties in the 23 countries for which GRECO evaluations
state to 29 (out of 32). This increased availability of public have been completed thus far, providing both the lowest and
funding may in itself be taken as an indication of a grow- highest values of their estimates. Being approximations, the
ing financial dependence of parties on the state, although actual percentages should probably not be considered as
the mere introduction of state subventions does not neces- authoritative; what is important here is the overall picture.
sarily imply that other financial resources have become The parties’ financial dependence on the state is indeed quite
entirely irrelevant. Regardless of its actual relevance in staggering, especially given the relatively recent appearance
pecuniary terms, however, public funding may, as Katz of public subsidies as a source of party income. In all countries
(2002: 115) has argued, ‘represent a fundamental change except Germany and The Netherlands, state subventions
in the character of the party, furthering its transformation amount to at least half of the total party income, while in the
from a private association into a semi-public entity’. majority of countries the state is responsible for two-thirds or
In addition, a growing amount of evidence suggests more of party income. Countries such as Belgium, Italy and
that state subventions are becoming so important that they Spain are found at the high end of the spectrum, where state
are crowding out other sources of party income. The most subsidies are estimated to account for no less than 80 to 95
interesting question then is how important these public percent of the total party income. Although some of the older
subsidies really are in relation to total party income. In our democracies sit at the high end of the range and, conversely,
previous contribution we alluded to the variations that some newer democracies are at the low end, the dependence
may exist between regions, between countries within a on the state is notably higher in the younger democracies of
particular region, and even between parties within one both Southern and Eastern Europe. On average, the state con-
country. We also noted the lack of suitable cross- tributes between an estimated 59.5 and 71.6 percent of the
national data needed to explore the financial dependence total income of the parties in the older democracies, as
of parties on the state more systematically. As the subject opposed to 68.8 to 78.4 percent in the newer democracies.
of party financing has acquired an increased importance No comparable data exist to assess developments over
in recent years, no doubt in part as a consequence of the time, but from the scattered evidence available we know
arguments advanced by Katz and Mair, data have gradu- that the relative importance of state funding in one group
ally become more widely available. Here, we use the of countries has remained more or less stable at a high
GRECO – the Group of States against Corruption estab- level, while in another it has increased significantly in
lished by the Council of Europe to monitor member recent years. Spain is an example of the former. Having

Downloaded from ppq.sagepub.com at Universiteit Leiden \ LUMC on February 10, 2014


4 Party Politics

Figure 3. Financial dependence on the state.


Source: GRECO, third evaluation round.

introduced public subsidies in the wake of the transition to become more financially dependent on the state, they are
democracy, the levels of state support for the two main par- also increasingly managed by the state through public law
ties PSOE and PP reached 75 to well over 90 percent of total and the national constitution. As a result of considerable
party income in the 1980s and 1990s (van Biezen, 2003). In growth in the scope and magnitude of regulations that are
Finland, where public subsidies were introduced as early as specifically targeted at political parties, their activities,
1969, the share of state subsidies reached 70 to nearly 85 per- behaviour and internal organizational structures have
cent already in the 1970s and 1980s. Other countries have become increasingly defined, prescribed or even pro-
seen a remarkable and rather sharp increase in the levels scribed by state law. Indeed, parties have become subject
of state support. In Denmark, for example, where state sub- to laws that govern their external behaviour and activities
sidies were introduced only in 1986, parties have seen the as well as their internal structures to such an extent that,
overall share of public income rise from around only 20 per- according to Katz (2002: 90), they have become ‘legiti-
cent in the late 1980s to an estimated 75 percent at present. mate objects of state regulation to a degree far exceeding
In Norway and Sweden, both with a relatively long-standing what would normally be acceptable for private associa-
history of public party funding, the figures have risen corre- tions in a liberal society’.
spondingly, from about 50 to 55 percent in the 1980s to an Despite the increase in state regulation of party activi-
estimated 70 to 80 percent today (early figures are extracted ties, organization and behaviour, this phenomenon has
from the contributions in Katz and Mair (1992); see also hitherto received relatively little systematic and compara-
Pierre et al. (2000)). Any cross-national variation that may tive scholarly attention, from political scientists or constitu-
have existed one or two decades ago, therefore, has now tional lawyers (for notable exceptions, see Janda, 2005;
largely levelled out, as the importance of public subsidies Müller and Sieberer, 2006; Karvonen, 2007). It has only
has continued to rise. The data and underlying trends convin- been in recent years that the empirical and normative
cingly support the assertions of Katz and Mair, at least at the dimensions of this increased propensity of the state to inter-
level of the party organization. The introduction of public vene in party politics are beginning to be systematically
subsidies has made political parties increasingly dependent (e.g. Casal Bértoa et al., forthcoming 2014; Casal Bértoa
on the state, regardless of whether the democracy in question and Spirova, 2013; van Biezen, 2012; van Biezen and Borz,
is young or relatively long-standing. 2012; van Biezen and Molenaar, 2012). More generally,
however, as Avnon (1995) observed nearly two decades
ago, the subject of party law remains a relatively neglected
The management of parties by the state –
aspect of research on political parties; discussion is limited
Party regulation to passing references and lacks a comparative dimension.
Our second dimension is that of the management of polit- In this section, we therefore discuss the nature and intensity
ical parties by legal rules. Political parties have not only of this dimension of the party–state linkage in more detail.

Downloaded from ppq.sagepub.com at Universiteit Leiden \ LUMC on February 10, 2014


Biezen and Kopecký 5

Figure 4. Chronology of party regulation and constitutionalization.


Source: www.partylaw.leidenuniv.nl

Katz and Mair (1995) highlight a number of aspects regulation is thus an important source for investigation into
regarding the importance of rules and regulations that the character of modern democracy and the prevailing
affect political parties. First, rules may provide parties with underlying conceptions regarding democracy and the place
access to public resources, in particular to state subsidies of political parties within it (cf. Persily and Cain, 2000).
and the media, which would otherwise be unavailable (Katz In this section, we provide a quantitative and qualita-
and Mair, 1995: 15). Second, the rules are not exogenous to tive assessment of the nature and intensity of party regu-
the parties, but the parties themselves are responsible for lation in post-war European democracies. First, focusing
the creation of their own institutional environment: ‘it is the on the number of laws and the amount of legal stipulation
parties, in their role as governors, who are ultimately targeted at political parties, the increased propensity of the
responsible for both the rules regarding state subventions state to intervene in party politics is immediately obvious.
as well as for the amounts of money and resources that are Figure 4 presents a chronology of party regulation and
made available’ (Katz and Mair, 1995: 15; see also Katz constitutionalization in post-war Europe, with the top half
and Mair, 2009: 756). The existing regulatory framework of the graph displaying the year in which political parties
may contribute in various ways to cartelization, although were first incorporated into the national constitutions of each
Katz and Mair appear to place primary emphasis on its pos- country, and the bottom half the years in which a party law
sible impact on the party system: as the parties in power are was first adopted. Figure 4 clearly shows a progressive codi-
ultimately responsible for designing the rules of the game, fication of political parties into public law, including the
and as these rules provide them with privileged access to national constitution and laws specifically designed to regu-
state resources, parties on the margins of the system may late political parties (hereafter: Party Laws).
be effectively excluded. The state then becomes ‘an institu- The constitutions of Western liberal democracies have
tionalized structure of support, sustaining insiders while traditionally paid little to no attention to the role of political
excluding outsiders’ (Katz and Mair, 1995: 16). parties. The long-standing absence of political parties from
Katz and Mair do not explicitly address the ways in national constitutions might be explained by a variety of
which rules affect the cartelization of individual parties, factors. These include a historical sequence in which the
however. This may indeed be less immediately obvious, adoption of the constitution generally predated the appear-
inasmuch as the public regulation of parties in itself does ance of political parties, or a prevalence of particular nor-
not necessarily imply that these parties become part of the mative conceptions of democracy, which have long been
state. Its impact may manifest itself directly or indirectly in incompatible with the phenomenon of political parties. This
important ways, however, as Mair observes in a subsequent rapidly changes in the aftermath of WWII, however. As Fig-
publication with Stefano Bartolini. If the internal and exter- ure 4 demonstrates, waves of party constitutionalization
nal activities of parties are regulated by public law, and as swept over the European continent in the second half of the
the rules governing parties become constitutional or admin- 20th century and the beginning of the 21st. These waves
istrative rules rather than internal party rules, the internal roughly correspond to those that Elster (1995) has identified
organizational autonomy of the parties will weaken corre- as waves of constitution-making and that Huntington
spondingly. Consequently, the public regulation of parties (1991) has observed for democratization processes (for a
may contribute to a redefinition of parties as public service more detailed discussion, see van Biezen, 2012). Although
agencies (Bartolini and Mair, 2001). The nature of party the earliest case of party constitutionalization occurred in

Downloaded from ppq.sagepub.com at Universiteit Leiden \ LUMC on February 10, 2014


6 Party Politics

Iceland in 1944, when the country became formally inde- A large majority of European democracies has also
pendent from Danish rule, the Basic Law of the Federal begun to adopt special Party Laws (see the bottom half of
Republic of Germany in 1949 was the first in which parties Figure 4). The Federal Republic of Germany was the first
became the direct subject of constitutionalization. In addi- democratic country in Europe to adopt a Party Law, the
tion, together with the Italian constitution of 1947, the Ger- Parteiengesetz of 1967, which has served as a model for
man Basic Law was one of the first constitutional texts that many Party Laws on the continent, in particular for the
attributed a positive and constructive role to parties within democracies of Southern and East-Central Europe (Müller
the democratic system (Tsatsos, 2002). This represented a and Sieberer, 2006). Countries with a Party Law have
novelty in the history of formal constitutional texts insofar quickly proliferated to a total of 20 at present, although the
as it explicitly recognized the constitutional role and rele- pattern has not been quite as pervasive as the process of
vance of political parties in the functioning of democratic party constitutionalization. Overall, the distinction between
politics (Pelizzo, 2004). old and new democracies is quite pronounced; younger
Subsequent cases of party constitutionalization followed democracies tend to be more inclined to adopt special Party
in the 1950s and 1960s, with the break-up of the French and Laws than older democracies. In fact, Greece is the only
British colonial empires resulting in the constitutionaliza- country among the newer democracies that has not adopted
tion of political parties in France, Cyprus and Malta. In the a Party Law. That some of the older democracies remain
1970s, parties were incorporated in each of the democracies without a Party Law can in part be explained by the fact that
that emerged from the third wave of democratization in one of the main subjects of regulation – party funding – is
Southern Europe, while the next and largest wave of party often laid down in special party finance regulation.6
constitutionalization followed from the establishment of In the process of Party Law promulgation it is possible
the newly independent democratic states in Central and to detect a similar grouping of countries as that which
Eastern Europe. Finally, Finland, Switzerland and, most regards the phenomenon of party constitutionalization
recently, Luxembourg amended their constitutions in order (Casal Bértoa et al., forthcoming 2014), although in this
to include special references to the role and functions of case the boundaries are not as neatly drawn. Clustering is
political parties. Of the 31 European democracies that pos- most clearly visible in the post-communist democracies.
sess a written constitution codified in one single text, 27 Since the passing of the first Party Law in Hungary in
have enshrined the role and position of political parties.4 1989, no Eastern European democracy has remained unaf-
As a result of this ongoing and pervasive process of party fected by this regulatory process. In most cases, as in Spain
constitutionalization, only a handful of older European coun- and Portugal in the mid-1970s, the laws regulating political
tries remain that do not make any reference to political par- parties were introduced in the years immediately following
ties in their constitutions, i.e. Belgium, Denmark, Ireland, the transition to democracy. The only exceptions are Serbia
and The Netherlands.5 and Latvia, where Party Laws were approved more than a
This development suggest that in contemporary European decade after the democratic transition, and indeed long
democracies, old and new, political parties are increasingly after their constitutions had codified the parties.
accorded a formal constitutional status. In this sense, the In the following paragraphs, a qualitative assessment is
European pattern lags behind that of other regions in the made of the phenomenon of party regulation and constitu-
world, in particular Latin America, where the phenomenon tionalization by focusing on the particular content of the
of party constitutionalization is older and more pervasive legal stipulations that apply to political parties. We concen-
(van Biezen and Kopecký, 2007; Zovatto, 2006). The trate on the content of the Party Laws (for a content analy-
increased incidence of party constitutionalization in modern sis of national constitutions, see van Biezen and Borz,
democracies attests not only to changes in historical contexts 2012) and complement this analysis with an investigation
and empirical realities but also to new ideas and normative of the intensity of regulation.
beliefs regarding parties and democracy. It suggests that, Party Laws are enacted for various purposes and may
unlike in earlier periods, political parties today have become regulate a wide variety of aspects, ranging from the legal
a permanent reality as structures of political representation status and definition of parties to issues regarding their
and points to a more or less general acceptance of parties internal organization, mechanisms of candidate selection
as the necessary foundations of democratic politics. Further- and party finances (Katz, 2004; Karvonen, 2007). The law
more, it suggests that conceptions of party democracy have may define what formally constitutes a political party, for
changed, whereby parties are no longer perceived as primar- example, and determine who qualifies for ballot access
ily private associations but as predominantly public utilities and who benefits from public resources such as state sub-
(van Biezen, 2004) or semi-state agencies (Katz and Mair, sidies and access to the media. The law may also exist to
1995), or at least as organizations whose public role has regulate the type and form of activity in which parties may
become so important that it warrants their formal codifica- engage and lay down the appropriate forms of party orga-
tion as a permanent feature of the institutional architecture nization and behaviour. It may prescribe, for example, the
of representative democracy. preferred organizational format of political parties, the

Downloaded from ppq.sagepub.com at Universiteit Leiden \ LUMC on February 10, 2014


Biezen and Kopecký 7

Table 1. Areas of party regulation. cross-national comparison (see van Biezen and Rashkova,
2012). Variation in the scope of regulation is considerable.
Area of regulation Magnitude
It ranges from countries such as Portugal, in which the law
Party finance 31.6 regulates virtually all aspects of party activity, organization
External oversight 30.7 and behaviour, to countries such as the UK, Norway and
Extra-parliamentary party 22.6 Finland, where the scope is much more restricted (usually
Secondary legislation 5.6 limited to party registration and party finance). The older
Activity / behaviour 2.8
democracies are clustered towards the lower end of the
Electoral party 1.6
Media access 1.3 spectrum; they regulate parties to a lesser extent and less
Democratic principles 1.2 intensively than the newer democracies. Moreover, addi-
Identity / programme 1.2 tional evidence suggests that party legislation on the whole
Rights and freedoms 1.0 tends to be stricter in the newer democracies than in estab-
Party in parliament 0.1 lished democracies; it includes restrictions of various types,
Party in government 0.1 such as comprehensive bans on certain types of parties
Source: www.partylaw.leidenuniv.nl (religious or ethnic, for example, in Bulgaria and Portugal),
a ban on party organization at the workplace (clearly a
necessary mechanisms for the selection of public office- legacy in post-communist democracies), or more thorough
holders, or prohibit the existence of parties that do not sanction regimes (Casal Bértoa et al., forthcoming 2014).
endorse the fundamental principles of democracy. Finally, Overall, these findings clearly show that the party–state
the law may establish a monitoring and sanctioning relationship has indeed intensified over time also as far as
regime to supervise party activity and impose penalties for their management by the state is concerned. In the follow-
violations of the law. ing paragraph, we turn to the question of whether the
Table 1 demonstrates the results of our content analysis strengthening of the party–state linkage on our first two
of Party Laws. It displays the 12 different categories of dimensions also implies that the state itself has progres-
party regulation we have identified as well as the extent sively become more partisan.
to which these areas of party activity are subject to legisla-
tive rules.7 It happens that, although the possible range of
regulation is quite broad in principle, Party Laws mostly
The capture of the state by parties – Party patronage
apply to three main subjects: the regulation of party The third dimension of the party–state linkage relates to the
finances, the monitoring of party activity, and the regula- extent to which parties penetrate and control the state and
tion of the extra-parliamentary party organization.8 The last use public offices for the purposes of party organizational
category, whereby the state intervenes in the internal orga- building and advancement. Party capture of the state can
nizational structure of the party, is perhaps the most contro- be conceptually and empirically studied in various ways,
versial as it is likely to infringe upon the associational but following recent trends in the literature (e.g. Ennser-
freedoms of parties. Under this rubric, the law may regulate Jedenastik, 2013; Grzymala-Busse, 2007; O’Dwyer, 2006;
the internal decision-making procedures of political parties, Scherlis, 2010) we focus on party patronage, i.e. on the allo-
define the powers and composition of party organs and pre- cation of jobs in the public and semi-public sectors at the dis-
scribe the frequency of their meetings, lay down internal cretion of political parties.9 Empirically, party patronage
voting and election procedures, define the rights and duties comprises partisan appointments to the civil service, over-
of party members, stipulate admission requirements for sight of the boards of public sector companies, management
party membership, proscribe the form of organizational of quangos or directorships of schools, universities and other
structure, and so on (van Biezen and Piccio, 2013). In some state institutions. This phenomenon has hitherto received
countries, as we will see in the following section, the law is minimal attention from political scientists, and especially
quite detailed to the point of intruding upon the parties’ from party scholars.10 This is regrettable considering that the
organizational autonomy. The expansion of prescriptive literature on party organizations makes frequent reference
party regulation is connected to the increasing amount of to patronage as a valuable resource for party leaders to
attention that the regulatory framework directs towards the build and maintain party organizations through the distri-
establishment of mechanisms for external oversight of bution of selective incentives to party members and elites in
party activity by special audit bodies or the general courts. exchange for organizational loyalty (e.g. Panebianco, 1988;
Finally, we show the variation between European Ware, 1996), while the literature on party government often
democracies in terms of the scope of party regulation. For refers to patronage as the key indicator of the partyness of
this purpose, Figure 5 demonstrates the country ranking on government (e.g. Blondel, 2000, 2002). In this section we
our party regulation index (PRI). This index is based on the therefore discuss party patronage in more detail.
range of party regulation and provides a standardized indi- Neither Katz and Mair in their seminal 1995 article, nor
cation of the level of party regulation that is suitable for Mair in most of his publications on parties and party

Downloaded from ppq.sagepub.com at Universiteit Leiden \ LUMC on February 10, 2014


8 Party Politics

Figure 5. Index of party regulation.


Source: van Biezen and Rashkova 2012.

organizations, make any systematic theoretical predictions public office) over party members (party on the ground) and
linking party patronage to the emergence of the cartel party. central office employees (see Katz and Mair, 1995, 2002,
The exception is one of Mair’s latest collaborative volumes 2009; Mair, 2004). It follows that in the cartel party it is the
(Kopecký et al., 2012), the results of which are the basis of party elite – the ministers, MPs and key party figures in pub-
the empirical analysis of party patronage below. This said, lic life – who will be firmly in control of, and responsible for,
there are at least two important points to highlight that the allocation of most party appointments to state institu-
appear from the literature on the emergence of the cartel tions. Correspondingly, the central office and/or regional and
party. First, the extensive access to the state – a defining local organizations of a party will play a secondary role in
feature of the cartel party era – is supposed to provide polit- the allocation of patronage, particularly at the national level.
ical parties with a major source of patronage (see Katz and In this sense, cartel parties are pictured as elite-dominated
Mair, 2009). That is, access, or privileged access, to the parties and the control of patronage resources should quite
state is thought to increase the supply of public jobs avail- clearly reflect this feature.
able to political parties for their own purposes, be they How do these two general expectations derived from the
organizational or other. Mair also argues that this increase literature on the cartel party fare in light of the recent evi-
in supply is being widely utilized by (cartel) parties in dence? We offer both a quantitative and a qualitative
Europe, observing that ‘party patronage, exercised through assessment of party patronage patterns. We start with the
the state, is becoming an increasingly prevalent (or at least Index of Party Patronage (IPP) which, based on data
noticeable) phenomenon’ (Mair, 1994: 10). Without expli- extracted from expert surveys, provides a measure of the
citly addressing the question of party patronage, much of the pervasiveness of patronage appointments in 15 contempo-
cartel party literature thus implies a general trend of increas- rary European democracies. The IPP reports standardized
ing politicization of the state in contemporary European scores: a value of 1 indicates that patronage practices
democracies, whereby parties appoint progressively more approximate a full overlap of party and state, while a value
partisans and party loyalists to public offices, for example of 0 indicates the absence of party politicization of the
in order to recruit party activists (see e.g. Bolleyer, 2009) state. In order to interpret the actual values of the index
or secure other publicly funded benefits. reported in the figure, it is useful to clarify the signification
Second, an even less explicitly addressed but obviously of intermediate values: a value of approximately 0.65
implicit point in the publications on the cartel party relates means that political parties appoint in most institutions at
to the intra-party mechanisms of patronage appointments. all levels of the administration; a value of approximately
The ascendancy of the party in public office – a defining 0.4 means that parties appoint in most institutions at top
feature of the cartel party organization – implies a significant and middle levels; a value of 0.1 indicates that parties
change of the internal distribution of patronage resources. appoint in a limited number of institutions and only at the
The internal organization of the cartel party is characterized top level. In other words, IPP values of around 0.4 or higher
by the dominance of office-holding politicians (party in represent relatively pervasive patronage practices.

Downloaded from ppq.sagepub.com at Universiteit Leiden \ LUMC on February 10, 2014


Biezen and Kopecký 9

Figure 6. Index of party patronage.


Source: Kopecký et al., 2012.

The first striking feature the data reveal is that, com- true if the countries with the highest levels of party patron-
pared to our findings on the previous two dimensions of the age are considered; Greece, Austria and Italy have long
party–state linkage, the variation among the European been considered the patronage strongholds of Europe
countries is much larger. In Figure 6, the UK records the (e.g. Müller, 2007; Piattoni, 2001).
lowest level of patronage, with an index reading of 0.09, Not all cases with extensive patronage in the past reveal
while Greece leads with a score of 0.62. The second impor- similarly high levels of patronage in the present, however,
tant finding, this time more congruous with the findings as evidenced most notably by the cases of Iceland and, to a
on party financing and regulation, is that most of the lesser degree, Ireland. These two countries, which are often
new democracies included in the study – the three post- considered patronage-ridden political systems (see, respec-
communist countries as well as Spain – are grouped tively, Carty, 1981; Kristinsson, 1996), reveal IPP values
together at or slightly above the mean for Europe as a well below the European mean. A similar story applies to
whole. This finding is consistent with many predictions a recently established democracy – Portugal (see Jalali and
on the predispositions of democracies that emerged during Lisi, 2009). Importantly, there is probably no European
the third wave of democratization of being relatively prone country where, on the basis of country accounts assembled
to party patronage (e.g. Kopecký and Spirova, 2011; in Kopecký et al. (2012) it would be possible to make a
O’Dwyer, 2006). The result is also fairly consistent with strong claim that partisan politicization of the state has
the assertions of some of the party politics literature, which grown in the past two decades. The evidence is only tenta-
argues that patterns of cartelization would be especially tive because there are no data comparable to those reported
pronounced in the young democracies (van Biezen, by the IPP that would allow for cross-time analysis. There
2003). The most evident cases in which patronage is spe- is, nevertheless, a degree of consistency, which suggests
cifically used for party building are the more recently that party patronage in Europe has either been decreasing
democratized polities – Bulgaria, Portugal and Spain and, or has remained comparable to levels observed in the past.
to a lesser extent, the Czech Republic and Hungary. In addition, there is relatively consistent evidence suggest-
The large variation in the pervasiveness of patronage ing that the instances in which party patronage is systema-
reported in Figure 6 is not particularly surprising. It is gen- tically used specifically for the purposes of party building,
erally well established in the literature that European coun- such as for example jobs being given as public honour or
tries have historically developed quite distinct bureaucratic distributed as reward for services rendered to the party, are
traditions. Consequently, they differ in the malleability of less important than in the past. There are numerous expla-
their state structures to succumb to predatory behaviour nations as to why this might be the case (see, e.g., Kristins-
of political parties and other political actors (e.g. Shefter, son, 2012). What matters here is that all these findings sit
1994). The ranking in Figure 6 is also largely consistent rather uneasily with the general idea that an increasingly
with other, albeit less precise, estimates. This is especially close relationship between parties and the state will also

Downloaded from ppq.sagepub.com at Universiteit Leiden \ LUMC on February 10, 2014


10 Party Politics

translate into, or be strongly manifested in, the higher levels much of the cartel party literature – that personal networks
of partisan capture of the state. In contrast to both party (of ministers) and other non-partisan settings, rather than
finance and party regulation, the available evidence sug- the party and the party apparatus, are becoming the primary
gests that party patronage in European democracies is not source of recruitment for political appointments. In other
necessarily more pervasive than in the past. words, not only is the (wider) party no longer in charge
Nonetheless, the evidence related to intra-party control of making decisions regarding who is appointed to key
of patronage resources seems to be far more consistent with positions in political life, the appointees themselves seem
the generalized expectations expressed in the cartel party lit- to come from settings other than traditional party back-
erature. When one looks at the question of who within the grounds and environments.
party is responsible for making appointments to public insti-
tutions, strong evidence suggests that the wider party – in
some organizational form – plays a relatively minor role (see Conclusions
Kopecký et al., 2012). Instead, most appointments to public Our findings on the three dimensions of party–state lin-
institutions are awarded by individual ministers in a way that kages show that the relationship between political parties
is relatively unconstrained by their respective party organi- and the state in European democracies has indeed become
zations. The allotment of key political positions – ministerial stronger over time, at least with regard to their financial
posts or appointments to important foreign missions – is dependence on the state and their management by the state.
likely to be discussed within the narrow party leadership, Both the public subsidization and regulation of political
i.e. the party in public office. Overall, however, political parties can be interpreted as two principal forms by which
appointments in contemporary Europe are probably better the modern state intervenes in contemporary party politics.
characterized as the result of the individual efforts of minis- The state intervenes in financial terms, providing parties
ters rather than collective efforts of the party; the party cen- with direct and indirect subsidies, while at the same time
tral offices, the congresses and their delegates, or party developing a regulatory framework in order to enforce the
members in general, certainly do not seem to play, or no lon- proper management of the parties and to ensure that they
ger play, any decisive role in party patronage. perform their unique democratic services effectively. It is
To be sure, some cross-country and, most importantly, especially the legal codification of political parties, most
cross-party variation in this respect still exists. In The Neth- notably the constitutions and party laws as well as party
erlands, Hungary and Spain, for example, the party still finance laws, that has strengthened the material and idea-
provides an identifiable filter in the process of patronage tional position of parties within the political system.
whereby the central party organs keep track of public sector Although their legally codified position may imply that,
vacancies and suggest potential candidates from within the compared to other organizations, parties are bound by tigh-
party network (see, respectively, van Thiel, 2012; Meyer- ter restrictions, existing rules have also endowed them with
Sahling and Jáger, 2012; Gómez and Verge, 2012). In Italy, special privileges. The parties’ institutional relevance not
patronage has become highly personalized in recent years, only justifies the existence of state support such as public
and public managers and other key figures appointed to subsidies, but also effectively attributes them with an offi-
state institutions are no longer likely to be recruited through cial status as part of the state and explicit recognition of
parties; instead, they are nominated by individual political their institutional importance for democracy. This clearly
actors who draw on personal networks embedded in the resonates with the arguments advanced by Katz and Mair:
professional world (see Di Mascio, 2012). In this case, it the growth of state subventions and extended party laws
seems that the party as such, except in its role as an organi- lend parties an increasingly ‘official’ status within their
zational base for use in national political competition, respective political systems.
almost disappears. However, our data on the third dimension of party–state
Italy, of course, may be an extreme case. However, the linkages – the capture of the state by the parties – do not
observed patterns of party patronage seem to provide the unequivocally support the idea of a stronger relationship
clearest support for some of the expectations expressed in between parties and the state in contemporary Europe. Our
the cartel party literature, namely the notion of ‘stratarchy’ analysis suggests that the way parties internally distribute
(Katz and Mair, 1995; see also Carty, 2004). Indeed, it is in patronage resources is highly elite and leadership-centred,
the Italian parties of the post-1992 party system collapse and hence consistent with the expectations expressed in the
that the most pronounced instances of stratarchy can be cartel party literature. However, the extent of party patron-
observed, with sub-national notables offering the national age is not necessarily higher than in the past; it has even
leaders an organizational base for national political compe- decreased in some of the countries traditionally considered
tition in exchange for a lack of interference in their own to be patronage strongholds. Moreover, the systematic use
local operations and their use of local public resources. of party patronage to reward party supporters and activists
Italy also underscores another more general trend among is also less prominent than in the past. These findings are
European political parties – again very consistent with not particularly congruent with the general essence of the

Downloaded from ppq.sagepub.com at Universiteit Leiden \ LUMC on February 10, 2014


Biezen and Kopecký 11

cartel party argument for which party patronage ought to 5. The UK has been omitted because it does not have a consti-
increase as a result of a closer party–state relationship. tution in the sense employed here.
Indeed, there might even be a certain paradox here. We 6. The regulation of party finance is not part of our inquiry here.
argued above that the increasingly legally codified position It is of note that virtually all long-established democracies
of the parties may have given them special privileges that do not have a Party Law have adopted special party
within the institutional apparatus of the state. The same finance legislation. The only exceptions are Ireland, Malta
increase in the nature and intensity of party regulation, and Switzerland, which do not have either. Many of the newer
however, may also mean that parties are bound by tighter democracies, in contrast, have adopted laws on political par-
restrictions, including those that aim to combat corrupt ties and party finance.
financial transactions or that curtail the scope of party polit- 7. For a discussion of the analytical framework, see van Biezen
ical involvement in the appointments to state institutions. and Borz (2012).
Indeed, there are numerous examples of recent institutional 8. The increased regulation and monitoring of party finance is in
reform – for example in the UK or in Iceland – that aim to part a by-product of the introduction of state funding, which
transfer the power of patronage from political parties and inevitably went accompanied with the need for further regu-
their ministers to bureaucratic and non-political actors, thus lation. In that sense, our second dimension of the party–state
potentially weakening the privileged position of the parties. linkage is not entirely independent of the first.
This suggests that an increase of the party–state linkage on 9. Other phenomena frequently used to assess the extent of party
one dimension might actually lead to its decrease on capture of the state are party clientelism and party corruption.
another. If this is so, then one of Peter Mair’s principal con- Party clientelism is generally seen as a form of linkage politics
cerns, i.e. that a close relationship between parties and the involving the selective release of public (material) resources –
state will undermine the popular legitimacy of political par- contracts, housing, subsidies, pork-barrel legislation, etc. – in
ties, and European democratic regimes may have to be order to secure electoral support from individuals or from
modified. In other words, it is not the party–state linkages selected sections of society (see Kitschelt, 2000). Party corrup-
per se, but rather the extent to which this relationship tion is seen as an exchange of money for public decisions (Piat-
strengthens the privileged position of the (established) par- toni, 2001); for example when financial donations are given to
ties within the system (cf. Mair, 1995) that is most likely to political parties in exchange for building contracts.
have an adverse effect on their democratic legitimacy. 10. Indeed, under the terms of ‘politicization of the state’ or ‘poli-
ticization of bureaucracy’, party patronage has mostly been
studied by scholars of public administration (e.g. Peters and
Acknowledgements
Pierre, 2004).
A first version of this paper was presented at the conference ‘Respon-
sive or Responsible Parties? Parties, Democracy, and Global Mar- References
kets – A Conference in Honour of Peter Mair’, held at the EUI,
Florence, from 26-28 September 2012. We are thankful to the con- Avnon D (1995) Parties laws in democratic systems of govern-
ference participants for their valuable feedback. Financial support ment. Journal of Legislative Studies 1(2): 283–300.
from the European Research Council and the Dutch Organization for Bartolini S and Mair P (2001) Challenges to contemporary political
Scientific Research is gratefully acknowledged. parties. In: Diamond L and Gunther R (eds) Political Parties
and Democracy, pp. 327–343. Baltimore, MD and London:
Funding Johns Hopkins University Press.
van Biezen I (2003) Political Parties in New Democracies: Party
Financial support from the European Research Council and The
Organization in Southern and East-Central Europe. Basing-
Netherlands Organization for Scientific Research for parts of this
research is gratefully acknowledged. stoke: Palgrave.
van Biezen I (2004) Political parties as public utilities. Party
Politics 10(6): 701–722.
Notes van Biezen I (2012) Constitutionalizing party democracy: The
1. The third dimension was referred to as ‘party rent-seeking constitutive codification of political parties in post-war Europe.
within the state’ in our previous publication. British Journal of Political Science 42(1): 187–212.
2. Re-conceptualizing party democracy (http://www.partylaw.lei- van Biezen I and Borz G (2012) Models of party democracy: Pat-
denuniv.nl) and Party patronage in contemporary democracies. terns of party regulation in post-war European constitutions.
Available at: http://socialsciences.leiden.edu/politicalscience/ European Political Science Review 4(3): 327–359
research/research-data/party-patronage.html. van Biezen I and Kopecký P (2007) The state and the parties: Pub-
3. See http://www.coe.int/t/dghl/monitoring/greco/evaluations/. lic funding, public regulation and rent-seeking in contempo-
4. For the purpose of this analysis, ‘democracy’ has been oper- rary democracies. Party Politics 13(2): 235–254.
ationalized as a country classified as ‘Free’ by Freedom van Biezen I and Molenaar F (2012) The Europeanization of party
House at the end of 2010, with the exception of small states politics? Competing regulatory paradigms at the supranational
with a population under 100,000. level. West European Politics 35(3): 632–656.

Downloaded from ppq.sagepub.com at Universiteit Leiden \ LUMC on February 10, 2014


12 Party Politics

van Biezen I, Mair P and Poguntke T (2012) Going, going, Huntington SP (1991) The Third Wave: Democratization in the
. . . gone? The decline of party membership in contemporary Late Twentieth Century. Norman, OK: University of Okla-
Europe. European Journal of Political Research 51(1): 24–56. homa Press.
van Biezen I and Piccio DR (2013) Shaping intra-party democracy: Inglehart R (1997) Modernization and Postmodernization: Cul-
On the legal regulation of internal party organizations. In: Cross tural, Economic, and Political Change in 43 Societies. Prince-
WP and Katz RS (eds) The Challenges of Intra-Party Democ- ton NJ: Princeton University Press.
racy, pp. 27–48. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Jalali C and Lisi M (2009) Weak societal roots, strong individual
van Biezen I and Rashkova ER (2012) Deterring new party entry? patrons? Patronage and party organization in Portugal. Revista
The impact of state regulation on the permeability of party sys- Enfoques 7(11): 411–470.
tems. Party Politics, doi: 10.1177/1354068812458616. Janda K (2005) Adopting Party Law. Working Paper series on
Blondel J (2000) A framework for the empirical analysis of Political Parties and Democracy in Theoretical and Practical
government-supporting party relationships. In: Blondel J Perspectives. Washington, D.C.: National Democratic Insti-
and Cotta M (eds) The Nature of Party Government. A tute for International Affairs.
Comparative European Perspective, pp. 96–116. New Karvonen L (2007) Legislation on political parties: A global com-
York: Palgrave. parison. Party Politics 13(4): 437–455.
Blondel J (2002) Party government, patronage and party decline Katz RS (2002) The internal life of parties. In: Luther KR and
in Western Europe. In: Gunther R, Montero JR and Linz JJ Müller-Rommel F (eds) Political Challenges in the New Eur-
(eds) Political Parties: Old Concepts and New Challenges, ope: Political and Analytical Challenges, pp. 87–118. Oxford:
pp. 233–256. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Oxford University Press.
Bolleyer N (2009) Inside the cartel party: Party organization in Katz RS (2004) Democracy and the legal regulation of political
government and opposition. Political Studies 57: 559–579. parties. Paper presented at the USAID conference on Change
Carty RK (1981) Party and Parish Pump: Electoral Politics in in Political Parties, Washington DC, 1 October.
Ireland. Ontario: Wilfried Laurier University Press. Katz RS and Mair P (eds) (1992) Party Organizations: A Data
Carty RK (2004) Parties as franchise systems: The stratarchical Handbook on Party Organizations in Western Democracies,
organizational imperative. Party Politics 10(1): 5–24. 1960–90. London: Sage.
Casal Bértoa F, Piccio DR and Rashkova ER (forthcoming 2014) Katz RS and Mair P (1995) Changing models of party organiza-
Party law in comparative perspective. In: van Biezen I and ten tion and party democracy: The emergence of the cartel party.
Napel H-M (eds) Regulating Party Democracy: The Netherlands Party Politics 1(1): 5–28.
in Comparative Perspective. Leiden: Leiden University Press. Katz RS and Mair P (2002) The ascendancy of the party in public
Casal Bértoa F and Spirova M (2013) Get a subsidy or perish! Public office. In: Gunther R et al. (eds) Political Parties: Old Concepts
funding and party survival in Eastern Europe. Working Paper and New Challenges, pp. 113–135. Oxford: Oxford University
Series on the Legal Regulation of Political Parties, No. 29. Avail- Press.
able at http://www.partylaw.leidenuniv.nl/uploads/wp2913.pdf. Katz RS and Mair P (2009) The cartel party thesis: A restatement.
Dalton RJ, Farrell DM and McAllister I (2011) Political Parties Perspectives on Politics 7(4): 753–766.
and Democratic Linkage: How Parties Organize Democracy. Kitschelt H (2000) Linkages between citizens and politicians in
Oxford: Oxford University Press. democratic polities. Comparative Political Studies 33: 845–879.
Dalton RJ and Wattenberg MP (eds) (2000) Parties without Par- Kopecký P and Mair P (2003) Political parties and government.
tisans: Political Change in Advanced Industrial Democracies. In: Salih MA (ed.) Political Parties in Africa, pp. 275–292.
Oxford: Oxford University Press. London: Pluto.
Di Mascio F (2012) Party patronage in Italy: A matter for solitary Kopecký P and Spirova M (2011) Jobs for the boys? Patterns of
leaders. In: Kopecký P, Mair P and Spirova M (eds) Party party patronage in post-communist Europe. West European
Patronage and Party Government in European Democracies, Politics 34(5): 897–921.
pp. 229–249. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Kopecký P, Mair P and Spirova M (eds) (2012) Party Patronage
Elster J (1995) Forces and mechanisms in the constitution-making and Party Government in European Democracies. Oxford:
process. Duke Law Journal 45(2): 364–396. Oxford University Press.
Ennser-Jedenastik L (2013) The politics of patronage and coalition: Koss M (2010) The Politics of Party Funding: State Funding to
How parties allocate managerial positions in state-owned enter- Political Parties and Party Competition in Western Europe.
prises. Political Studies, doi: 10.1111/1467–9248.12031. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Gómez R and Verge T (2012) Party patronage in Spain: App- Kristinsson GH (1996) Parties, states and patronage. West European
ointments for party government. In: Kopecký P, Mair P and Spir- Politics 19(3): 433–457.
ova M (eds) Party Patronage and Party Government in European Kristinsson GH (2012) Party patronage in Iceland: Rewards
Democracies, pp. 316–334. Oxford: Oxford University Press. and control appointments. In: Kopecký P, Mair P and Spir-
Grzymala-Busse A (2007) Rebuilding Leviathan. Party Competi- ova M (eds) Party Patronage and Party Government in
tion and State Exploitation in Post-Communist Democracies. European Democracies, pp. 186–205. Oxford: Oxford Uni-
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. versity Press.

Downloaded from ppq.sagepub.com at Universiteit Leiden \ LUMC on February 10, 2014


Biezen and Kopecký 13

Lewis PG (1996) Party Structure and Organization in East- Pierre J, Svåsand L and Widfeldt A (2000) State subsidies to polit-
Central Europe. Aldershot: Edward Elgar. ical parties: Confronting rhetoric with reality. West European
Mair P (1994) Party organizations: From civil society to the state. Politics 23(3): 1–24.
In: Katz RS and Mair P (eds) How Parties Organize: Change Shefter M (1994) Political Parties and the State: The American His-
and Adaptation in Party Organizations in Western Democra- torical Experience. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
cies, pp. 1–22. London: Sage. Scherlis G (2010) Patronage and Party Organization in Argen-
Mair P (1995) Political parties, popular legitimacy and public pri- tina: The Emergence of the Patronage-based Network Party.
vilege. West European Politics 18(3): 40–57. Unpublished PhD thesis. University of Leiden.
Mair P (2004) Party organizations: From civil society to the state. Scarrow S (2006) Party subsidies and the freezing of party com-
In: Katz RS and Mair P (eds) How Parties Organize: Change petition: Do cartel mechanisms work? West European Politics
and Adaptation in Party Organizations in Western Democra- 29(4): 619–639.
cies, pp. 1–22. London: Sage. Tsatsos DT (ed.) (2002) 30 Jahre Parteiengesetz in Deutschland:
Mair P (2006) Ruling the void: The hollowing of Western democ- Die Parteiinstitutionen im Internationalen Vergleich. Baden-
racy New Left Review 42: 25–51. Baden: Nomos.
Meyer-Sahling J-H and Jáger K (2012) Party patronage in Hun- van Thiel S (2012) Party patronage in the Netherlands: Sharing
gary: Capturing the state. In: Kopecký P, Mair P and Spirova appointments to maintain consensus. In: Kopecký P, Mair P
M (eds) Party Patronage and Party Government in European and Spirova M (eds) Party Patronage and Party Government
Democracies, pp. 163–185. Oxford: Oxford University Press. in European Democracies, pp. 250–271. Oxford: Oxford
Müller WC (2007) Political institutions and linkage strategies. In: University Press.
Kitschelt H and Wilkinson SI (eds) Patrons, Clients, and Pol- Ware A (1996) Political Parties and Party Systems. Oxford:
icies. Patterns of Democratic Accountability and Political Oxford University Press.
Competition, pp. 251–275. Cambridge: Cambridge University Zovatto D (ed.) (2006) Regulación jurı´dica de los partidos
Press. polı´ticos en Ame´rica Latina. Mexico City: UNSM/Interna-
Müller WC and Sieberer U (2006) Party law. In: Katz RS and Crotty tional IDEA.
W (eds) Handbook of Party Politics, pp. 435–445. London: Sage.
Nassmacher K-H (2010) The Funding of Party Competition:
Author biographies
Political Finance in 25 Democracies. Baden-Baden: Nomos.
O’Dwyer C (2006) Runaway State Building: Patronage Politics Ingrid van Biezen is Professor of Comparative Politics at Leiden
and Democratic Development. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University. She has previously taught at the University of Birming-
University Press. ham and the Johns Hopkins University. She is a co-editor of Acta
Politica and the author of Political Parties in New Democracies
Panebianco A (1988) Political Parties: Organization and Power.
(Palgrave, 2003). She has written on comparative party politics,
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
political finance, party law and democratic theory. Her research has
Pelizzo R (2004) From principle to practice: Constitutional prin- been published in, among others, the British Journal of Political
ciples and the transformation of party finance in Germany and Science, the European Journal of Political Research, Party Poli-
Italy. Comparative European Politics 2(2): 123–141. tics, Perspectives on Politics and West European Politics.
Persily N and Cain BE (2000) The legal status of political parties:
A reassessment of competing paradigms. Columbia Law Petr Kopecký is a Professor of Political Science at Leiden Univer-
sity. He has previously taught at Sheffield University and he is a co-
Review 100(3): 775–812.
editor of East European Politics. His current research focuses on
Peters G and Pierre J (eds) (2001) Politicians, Bureaucrats and
political parties, patronage politics and democratization. His
Administrative Reform. London: Routledge. research has been published in, among others, the European Jour-
Piattoni S (ed.) (2001) Clientelism, Interests, and Democratic nal of Political Research, European Union Politics, Party Politics,
Representation. The European Experience in Historical and Political Studies and West European Politics. His most recent book
Comparative Perspective. Cambridge: Cambridge University (co-edited) is Party Patronage and Party Government in European
Press. Democracies (Oxford University Press, 2012).

Downloaded from ppq.sagepub.com at Universiteit Leiden \ LUMC on February 10, 2014

View publication stats

You might also like