Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 14

See discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.

net/publication/312201006

Different forms of decentralization and their impact on government


performance: Micro-level evidence from 113 countries

Article  in  Economic Modelling · January 2017


DOI: 10.1016/j.econmod.2016.12.010

CITATIONS READS

3 3,877

4 authors, including:

Rajeev Goel Ummad Mazhar


Illinois State University Lahore University of Management Sciences
192 PUBLICATIONS   2,568 CITATIONS    28 PUBLICATIONS   52 CITATIONS   

SEE PROFILE SEE PROFILE

Michael A. Nelson
University of Akron
48 PUBLICATIONS   1,487 CITATIONS   

SEE PROFILE

Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects:

Innovation and Internationalization View project

http://www.ummadmazhar.com/ordinary-business-of-life View project

All content following this page was uploaded by Ummad Mazhar on 25 January 2018.

The user has requested enhancement of the downloaded file.


Economic Modelling 62 (2017) 171–183

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Economic Modelling
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/econmod

Different forms of decentralization and their impact on government MARK


performance: Micro-level evidence from 113 countries☆

Rajeev K. Goela, Ummad Mazharb, Michael A. Nelsonc, , Rati Rama
a
Illinois State University, USA
b
Forman Christian College, Pakistan
c
University of Akron, USA

A R T I C L E I N F O A BS T RAC T

JEL classification: This study of the effect of decentralization on government performance differs from the vast literature on the
H11 topic in three major ways. First, we compare the effects of four different forms of decentralization, namely, fiscal
H70 decentralization, administrative decentralization, federalism, and aggregate decentralization. Second, we study
K2 the effect on three dimensions of government performance, namely, tax administration, business licensing and
K4
permits, and corruption. Third, the effects are judged in terms of the perceptions of nearly 100,000 business
Keywords: leaders located in 113 countries. Seven statements summarize our findings. First, fiscal and administrative
Fiscal decentralization decentralization improve perceptions of government performance. Second, federalism is associated with worse
Administrative decentralization
perceptions. Third, the effect of aggregate decentralization is ambiguous. Fourth, service industries tend to
Federalism
perceive decentralization more favorably than others. Fifth, large firms perceive decentralization less favorably
Aggregate decentralization
Government performance than other firms. Sixth, the effect of the same form of decentralization varies in magnitude across the three
government activities. Seventh, therefore, decentralization may not be oversold as a policy prescription to
improve government performance; the form of decentralization and its contextualization in terms of the
targeted area of government activity need careful consideration.

1. Introduction and has found favor in recent years, as noted by Rodríguez-Pose and
Gill (2003), Stegarescu (2005) and the World Bank (1999).1
The role that decentralized government structures might play in Given its numerous possible dimensions, several classifications of
promoting good governance has intrigued policymakers and research- government decentralization have been proposed. For instance, as
ers for some time. On the one hand, decentralized governments are noted in a recent survey by Martinez-Vazquez et al. (2016), government
closer to the populace and can better understand and deliver services decentralization may be viewed along expenditure/revenue, policy, or
that are tailored to specific needs. There is also greater transparency of political dimensions (also see Rodden (2004)). While the expenditure/
government actions as citizens can better observe government actions revenue aspect of decentralization has been most widely studied,
at the local level. The scope of this has somewhat broadened with e- overlapping government jurisdictions and institutional complexities
government services. On the other hand, there are some drawbacks to make clear inferences difficult. Other aspects also come into play,
decentralization, notably regarding the (in)ability to coordinate the leading to ambiguities in formal analyses. For instance, a reliable set of
provision of services at various levels of government (see Prud’homme answers or clear policy prescriptions have failed to evolve due to a
(1995), Shah and Thompson (2004)), the appropriation of benefits due number of reasons. First, no two nations (or even regions within a
to spillovers across jurisdictional boundaries (Oates (1972)), and country) are alike and differ in numerous aspects. This poses chal-
potentially less media scrutiny of the actions of public officials. lenges in terms of applying similar policies across jurisdictions (Should
Overall, the trend towards greater decentralization has been promoted there be x number of government hospitals for every y population in
by major international organizations (e.g., International Monetary every jurisdiction? Then, what about tropical regions that are more
Fund (2009), United Nations (2009) and the World Bank (1999)) prone to certain diseases?). Second, there are many aspects to


An earlier version of this paper was circulated as CESifo working paper #6013 ("Government decentralization and international government performance"). Extremely useful
comments from three anonymous reviewers and the editor are gratefully acknowledged. The usual disclaimer applies.

Correspondence to: Department of Economics, University of Akron, OH 44325, USA.
E-mail address: nelson2@uakron.edu (M.A. Nelson).
1
See also The Online Sourcebook on Decentralization and Local Development (http://www.ciesin.columbia.edu/decentralization/).

http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2016.12.010
Received 6 August 2016; Received in revised form 10 December 2016; Accepted 10 December 2016
Available online 10 January 2017
0264-9993/ © 2016 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
R.K. Goel et al. Economic Modelling 62 (2017) 171–183

government decentralization that are qualitatively (in terms of deliver- et al. (2014)), the scope of analysis (both in terms of decentralization
ing the services) and operationally (in terms of setup costs and types and the government performance aspects considered) and the
timelines) different. For instance, geographic and administrative consideration of perceptions of government performance by actual
decentralization are legislatively quite time consuming to alter, users (i.e., business firms) are new.
whereas fiscal decentralization is somewhat easily altered. Thus, it is Key questions addressed in this research are:
quite difficult to compare the effects of different forms of government
decentralization. The related measurement issues have been noted by • Are the effects of a government decentralization measure similar
several scholars, including Blume and Voigt (2011), Brueckner (2003), across different dimensions of government performance?
Prud’homme (1995), and Stegarescu (2005).2 These issues, coupled • Do government performance perceptions differ across various
with the level of aggregation available in most data, have led to measures of decentralization?
ambiguous findings regarding the effects of decentralization on govern-
ment performance (see Martinez-Vazquez et al. (2016)). The analysis, based on World Enterprise Surveys of nearly 100,000
The present paper attempts to address the ambiguity in the effects individual business owners and top managers in 113 countries, shows
of decentralization in several ways. First, we analyze the effects of that fiscal decentralization and administrative decentralization are
different types of decentralization on government performance in a qualitatively alike in that greater decentralization in each case improves
cross-country context. These include fiscal decentralization and feder- perceptions of government performance. In contrast, opposite conclu-
alism, which have been widely used in past literature, and two sions are reached when decentralization is based on distinctions
relatively new indicators (see Ivanyna and Shah (2014)): “aggregate between federalist states and unitary states. With regard to tax
decentralization” and “administrative decentralization.” The latter two administration particularly, fiscal and administrative forms of govern-
measures are designed to assess the independence and actual authority ment decentralization result in better outcomes than aggregate decen-
in the hands of local authorities when it comes to decision making. tralization. At a related level, while a larger government results in
Such measures are intended to mitigate the comparability problems worse outcomes with regard to tax administration and business
with the more traditionally-used decentralization measures discussed licensing, it improves perceptions of government performance with
above, especially within the context of cross-country data sets. regard to corruption. This finding is consistent with the view that a
Second, we address the impacts or consequences of decentralization larger government machinery involves greater attention to checks and
from business leaders' perceptions of government performance as they balances. We also find that relative to the entire sample, business
relate to running their businesses. These include business manager manager perceptions are different in service industries and at large
perceptions as to how government licensing and permits, taxation firms. Overall, our findings provide useful insights into the effects of
(specifically, tax administration), and corruption affect their opera- various forms of devolution of powers to subnational government units.
tions.3 Government performance in the licensing and permits area is We turn next to a discussion of the underlying theory and related
especially relevant for the purpose at hand as it is an activity that is literature.
typically carried out at the local level (e.g., liquor licenses for bars,
zoning permits, etc.). We can assess how greater decision-making
authority in the hands of local officials affects business perceptions of 2. Literature and theoretical background
government performance in this area. Further, corruption is prevalent
in many societies and permeates many levels of government in its The broader literature on the choice by governments to decentralize
interactions with the public and corruption at the local level can be a operations (and provision of services) can be tied to the work of Besley
significant issue, perhaps more so than at the national level and Coate (2003), Oates (1972), and Panizza (1999); also see Faguet
(Transparency International (2009)). Bribes may be offered and/or (2014). In a nutshell, government decentralization can have positive as
solicited to speed up government functions or to get undue favors from well as negative effects on public sector performance. On the positive
government officials. These corrupt transactions might be facilitated at side, decentralization of government functions leads to greater electoral
the local level due to closer proximity between bribe givers and bribe control and greater yardstick competition among competing jurisdic-
takers. Our analysis examines business' perceptions of the impact of tions (Salmon (1987)). On the down side, decentralization reduces
corruption on their operations and how such perceptions are affected scale economies in the provision of government services, creates the
by the type of decentralization. Although the decentralization-corrup- potential for mismatch between the spatial incidence of the benefits for
tion relation has been extensively studied in the literature (e.g., Fan government services and the political boundaries, empowers local
et al. (2009), Fisman and Gatti (2002), Goel and Nelson (2011), interest groups to better drive their agendas, and likely makes
Treisman (2000)), the present analysis is at the micro level and is based attracting qualified applicants for government jobs difficult (see
on perceptions of business leaders. This is in contrast to the majority of Adams et al. (2014), Prud’homme (1995)).4 Thus, analyses with greater
the literature that uses aggregate indices of corruption perceptions (see size and scope of data are required to discern some of the underlying
Lambsdorff (2006), Treisman (2007)). linkages - which this paper attempts to do.
Third, the underlying data draw upon thousands of individual The literature on the impacts of decentralization has mostly focused
responses regarding perceptions of government services across more on the effects of fiscal decentralization on various indicators of
than a hundred countries. Thus, we are able to examine how certain government and macroeconomic performance (see, for example,
widely prevalent government functions are perceived following differ- Adam et al. (2014), Ebel and Yilmaz (2003), Kyriacou and Roca-
ent types of decentralization. All these aspects enable us to address the Sagalés (2011a), Lago-Peñas et al. (2011) and Yeung (2009)). The
role of decentralization in a deeper (using micro-level data) and wider findings vary and are sensitive to the data and methodology employed.
(across various types of decentralization and many nations) manner A few studies examine alternate or multiple forms of decentralization
than previously considered in the literature. Specifically, while some (see Fan et al. (2009), Goel and Nelson (2011), Goel and Saunoris
studies in the literature have examined the effects of decentralization (2016), Kyriacou and Roca-Sagalés (2011b), Nelson (2013) and
on government performance in some areas (see, for example, Adam Rodríguez-Pose and Ezcurra (2011)). However, these broad effects
mask qualitative distinctions across decentralization types and govern-

2 4
Also see Knack and Keefer (1995) for a broader perspective. Bodman et al. (2012) present a theoretical model of the dynamic effects of taxation
3
These aspects of government performance can be seen as tied to the wider discussion and investment on the steady state output level of an economy, with consideration of
on the quality of government (see La Porta et al. (1999)). multi-level governments.

172
R.K. Goel et al. Economic Modelling 62 (2017) 171–183

ment services. 3.1. Government performance


One aspect of government performance, namely corruption, has
garnered a fair bit of attention in regard to its nexus with government We address the impacts or consequences of decentralization from a
decentralization (see Fan et al. (2009), Fisman and Gatti (2002), Goel different perspective than has been considered heretofore, specifically
and Nelson (2011), Nelson (2013), Treisman (2000); Lambsdorff the link between decentralization and business leaders' perceptions of
(2006) and Treisman (2007) for reviews of the related literature). government performance as it relates to their business.
Fan et al. (2009) found that in nations with a larger number of The data on perceptions of government performance are drawn from
administrative tiers of government and (given local revenues) a larger firm-level responses and come from World Enterprise Surveys (WES) of
number of local public employees, corruption was more prevalent. On individual business owners and top managers of 94,000 firms in more
the other hand, when local or central governments received a larger than a hundred countries (http://www.enterprisesurveys.org/). The
share of GDP in revenue, corruption was less prevalent. In another take WES is a comprehensive annual survey that asks managers about the
in a cross-national context, Goel and Saunoris (2016) compare the various aspects of local business environment.6 Our research focuses on
relative effects of virtual and physical decentralization in terms of their data from 2006 to 2015, as it is only after 2006 that a standardized
mitigating effects on corruption and the shadow economy. They find methodology and instrument sets are used for the survey.7 The usable
virtual decentralization to be relatively more effective. Goel and Nelson number of countries in our analysis is 113 due to the need to match the
(2011) on the other hand, focused on the effects of decentralization various variables in the empirical model presented below.
across states in the United States, distinguishing between general- Given the breadth of issues covered in the WES, we focus on the
purpose and special-purpose governments. They found that while more subset of questions that asks firms about their relationship with the
general-purpose governments contributed to corruption, the effect of government. We consider three important factors surrounding govern-
special-purpose governments was mixed. Similarly, Nelson (2013) ment-business relations, specifically how tax administration
found that more fragmented municipal government structures are (TaxAdmin), business licensing and permits (BusLicense), and corrup-
associated with more corruption for a large sample of countries. tion (Corrupt) affect the current operation of their establishment.8,9
Similar mixed results have been found regarding the link between The three government outcome variables considered in this analysis
federal political structures and perceived corruption (see Fan et al. - TaxAdmin, BusLicense, Corrupt - are somewhat qualitatively differ-
(2009), Goldsmith (1999), Kunicová and Rose-Ackerman (2005), and ent, but all are potentially directly or indirectly affected by the degree of
Treisman (2000, 2007)). Generally, this literature has found greater decentralization of government functions. For instance, greater decen-
decentralization to lower corrupt activity. The present research will add tralization would increase transparency and foster greater trust be-
to this discussion by providing evidence on firm's perceptions of tween the public and government officials, but such proximity might
corruption at the local level. facilitate corrupt relations or other abuses of government power. Some
In yet another angle on the impact of decentralization, Kyriacou taxes are levied and administered by local governments, whereas most
and Roca-Sagalés (2011b) study the relation between fiscal and business licenses and permits (e.g., liquor licenses for restaurants) are
political decentralization and government quality (measured as the conferred by local governments.10
average of rule of law, regulatory quality, government effectiveness, The survey asks respondents or business firms about their first-
and corruption control). The authors find that fiscal decentralization hand impressions of various aspects of government performance. For
improves government quality, but not if such decentralization is each dimension of government performance, respondents were asked
accompanied by political decentralization. to pick one of five levels of the impact of government performance:
Focusing on OECD countries, Rodríguez-Pose and Ezcurra (2011) whether that dimension of performance was viewed as (i) no obstacle;
consider fiscal, political and administrative measures of decentraliza- (ii) minor obstacle; (iii) moderate obstacle; (iv) major obstacle; or (v)
tion and focus on how decentralization impacts economic growth.5
Their findings show a negative relation between fiscal decentralization 6
A related measure of the private sector business conditions is World Bank's Doing
and economic growth. However, their analysis reveals that the impact
Business (DB) Survey, which uses expert opinions and interviews for the purpose. The
of political and administrative decentralization on economic growth is DB survey has already acquired wide currency among students of political economy.
weaker and sensitive to how political decentralization is measured. However, it is fundamentally different from the WES, with the latter enjoying important
There are several important differences between this work and ours. advantages, as shown at length in Hallward-Driemeier and Pritchett (2015). In
Specifically, (a) the focus of the present work is on government particular, the DB Survey, being based on expert opinions, implicitly assumes that firms
are complying with the rules and regulations of their country. This is not the case with
performance, rather than economic growth; (b) the sample of countries WES. In other words, WES provides the de facto state of the business and legal
covered here is much broader than OECD and includes both developed environment in which firms are operating, while DB Survey focuses on de jure state.
7
and developing nations; (c) the data employed are based on a large Thus, Enterprises Surveys Indicator Description ESID (2015), August 2015 version
number of micro-level observations of business managers rather than states, “Uniform universe, uniform methodology of implementation, and a core ques-
tionnaire are the basis of the Global methodology under which most Enterprise Surveys
country-level aggregates; and (d) we also consider a broader range of
have been implemented since 2006” (p. 2).
aggregate decentralization measures (of which some other decentrali- 8
The reasons for selecting these aspects are their importance in the link between
zation types (e.g., administrative decentralization, etc.) are sub-com- business environment and governance, and to keep the analysis manageable. Complete
ponents). description of indicators covered in the survey is given in ESID. The World Enterprise
Survey Questionnaire Note provides details about the questions posed to managers.
These and the other survey modules related to the methodology of the Enterprise Surveys
are available at http://www.enterprisesurveys.org/methodology). The Business-
3. Measuring government performance and decentralization Government relations subsection ‘j.30’ covers eight dimensions of firms’ interactions
with the government.
9
Of course, this is not a comprehensive consideration of government performance,
Since they are central focus of the paper, we provide some details on which is multidimensional. For instance, Guccio et al. (2014) examine whether local
how we measure government performance and decentralization in the governments had better on-time performance in executing public works projects in Italy.
10
analysis that follows. Details about the overall sample and the other Another important distinction is that whereas business licenses may be procured by
potential entrants (new licenses) or by existing firms (recurring licenses), taxes are paid
variables used in the analysis are in Section 4. We consider three
by existing firms. On the other hand, corruption might be experienced by businesses
aspects of government performance across four forms of government throughout their existence, with possible variations across firm size and industry type.
decentralization. This difference relates to the age of firms and could affect their perceptions of
government performance - existing firms are likely to have a better perspective having
dealt with the full spectrum of government services and their managers are more likely to
5
Also see a recent survey by Martinez-Vazquez et al. (2016). have established long-term working relationships with government officials.

173
R.K. Goel et al. Economic Modelling 62 (2017) 171–183

very severe obstacle. WES coded these responses on a 5-point scale governments, (2) local expenditure, tax, and borrowing autonomy,
where 0=no obstacle and 4=very severe obstacle. To facilitate inter- (3) home rule for self-governance, and (4) local government control
pretation of the findings, we collapsed these five dimensions into three, regarding, hiring, firing, and other human resource policies of their
labelled as minor obstacle, moderate obstacle and major obstacle. own employees. The value of the index ranges from a high of 20.71
The reclassification adopted is based on a simple but intuitive logic. for Sweden and a minimum of 0 for Mozambique, with higher values
Specifically, extreme survey responses lying in the neighborhood of implying a larger local sector and greater local authority in decision
each other like ‘no obstacle’ and ‘minor obstacle’, and ‘major obstacle’ making.
and ‘very severe obstacle’ are not capturing substantially dissimilar • Administrative Decentralization Index (AdminDecent): This index is
perceptions. Therefore, the differences between these two sets of one of the components of the Aggregate Decentralization Index that
responses are likely to be random rather than systematic, given the focuses on local government control regarding hiring, firing, and
inherently imperfect nature of measurement involved in this question. other human resource policies of local employees. The construction
This reasoning allows us to conclude that we can merge these sets of of the index considers the local government share of total public-
responses without affecting the underlying statistical distribution of sector employment and an indicator of local government discretion
responses. The Appendix Table A1 provides additional details on this related to employment and setting the terms of that employment
classification scheme. The results are generally robust to an analysis of (Ivanyna and Shah (2014)).
all categories – see Appendix B. Relatively speaking, this index captures contract enforcement free-
Our analysis examines the strength of these perceptions for each dom at the local level, which could have interesting outcomes
form of government decentralization. It investigates whether different relative to government performance. Thus, in contrast to, say, fiscal
aspects of government performance are equally affected by any given decentralization, this index considers employment and administra-
form of decentralization and whether different forms of decentraliza- tive aspects, but not necessarily freedom regarding related
tion affect a given dimension differently. To our knowledge, these budget allocations. In our data set, the value of AdminDecent varies
questions and the scope of analysis (in terms of number of nations and from 0.9 (Sweden) to 0 (Mali, Mozambique, and Suriname), with
the number of respondents) to address these, have not been previously larger values implying greater decentralization. The correlation
considered in the literature. between this index and the broader aggregate decentralization is
0.67.
3.2. Alternate perspectives on decentralization
The above discussion explains the distinctions across decentraliza-
To address differences across decentralization types, the following tion types and government performance measures that will be con-
four measures of decentralization are considered: sidered in this analysis. We now turn to a discussion of the model setup
and estimation strategy to judge the effects of decentralization on
• Fiscal Decentralization (Fiscal Decent): As noted above, the con- government performance.
sequences of decentralization have been most often analyzed in the
literature from the perspective of the degree of fiscal autonomy of 4. Model, data and estimation
subnational units of government. This has been evaluated in a
number of ways, including (i) local government expenditure share of 4.1. Model and data
overall government expenditures, (ii) subnational tax share, and (iii)
local share of total government employment (Nelson (2013)). Based on the above discussion and to focus on the objectives of
For the purposes of this analysis we selected the former – this paper, the estimated relation takes government performance to
expenditure share as our “baseline” decentralization measure. There be a function of decentralization; economic prosperity; a vector (Z)
is considerable variation among nations with respect to this of institutional and social factors and country size; and indicators
measure. For instance, it has the maximum value of 0.55 for of industry and firm size associated with the survey respondent.
Uzbekistan. The minimum value of the variable is 0 for Many of these controls are routinely employed in the related
Mozambique and Suriname. literature (e.g., Kyriacou and Roca-Sagalés (2011a, 2011b),
• Federalist System of Government (Federalism): In a federalist state, Lambsdorff (2006), Treisman (2007)). The main interest, however,
political power is split in some fashion between the central govern- is in the decentralization-performance nexus across the various
ment and subnational (e.g., state, local governments) authorities. dimensions of each. Thus, an equation of the following general
Generally, the country's constitution assigns the duties, rights, and form is estimated (with subscript i denoting a country and j
privileges of each level of government. denoting a survey response):
A dichotomous indicator is used here that takes a value of one if
the state is classified as "federal" by Elazar (1995) and zero Perceived government performancei, j, g = f (Government decentralizationi, k ,
otherwise. See Nelson (2013) for a summary of the extant literature Economic Prosperity(GDP),
i Z i, w , Industry typei, j , Firm Sizei, j ) (1)
that has employed this political decentralization indicator in analyz-
ing public sector corruption.11 Fifteen percent of the countries in our where
sample were classified as federalist (Table 1).
• Aggregate Decentralization Index (AggDecent): This is a compre- g = TaxAdmin, BusLicense, Corrupt
hensive measure of the importance and authority of local govern- k = Fiscal Decent, Federalism, AggDecent, AdminDecent
ment compiled by Ivanyna and Shah (2014). The index starts with w = GovtSize, RuleLaw, POP, Protestant
the fiscal decentralization measure. It then adjusts it for a number of
institutional factors that are important when assessing the actual The dependent variable is one of the three areas of perceived
authority and independence of decision making by local authorities. government performance drawn from the WES survey (i.e., tax
These factors include (1) the security of the existence of local administration (TaxAdmin), business licensing (BusLicense) and cor-
ruption (Corrupt)). Firms' timing and frequency of interactions with
different government agencies vary and this shapes their perceptions of
11
Voigt and Blume (2012) note the shortcomings with capturing federalism via a
government performance. For instance, taxes are ex-post entry but
dichotomous variable. Birch (1949) provides an early view of federalism. Also, see periodic or repetitive, whereas licenses and corruption could be
Treisman (2006). sporadic. Thus, our consideration of three performance dimensions

174
R.K. Goel et al. Economic Modelling 62 (2017) 171–183

Table 1
Variable definitions, summary statistics and sources.

Variable Definition; Mean, SD Source

TaxAdmin An ordered response to the question asking how far tax administration issues affect business World Bank World Enterprise Surveys. World Bank. (www.
operations. The response ranges from 0 (no obstacle) to 3 (very severe obstacle) – see Table A1; enterprisesurveys.org)
1.56, 0.74.
BusLicense An ordered response to the question asking how far business permits and licensing issues affect World Bank World Enterprise Surveys. World Bank. (www.
business operations. The response ranges from 0 (no obstacle) to 4 (very severe obstacle) – see enterprisesurveys.org)
Table A1; 1.47, 0.73.
Corrupt An ordered response to the question asking how far government corruption affects business World Bank World Enterprise Surveys. World Bank. (www.
operations. The response ranges from 0 (no obstacle) to 4 (very severe obstacle) – see Table A1; enterprisesurveys.org)
1.90, 0.91.
Fiscal Decent Fiscal decentralization. Local government expenditures as percentage of general government Ivanyna and Shah (2014)
expenditures. Higher values indicate greater fiscal decentralization; 0.15, 0.13
Federalism Binary variable indicator of a country classified as federalist; (the coding is for unitary (0) and Treisman (2006)
federal (1) states); 0.15, 0.36.
AggDecent Aggregate decentralization. Index incorporates the relative importance of local government Ivanyna and Shah (2014)
(measured by expenditure decentralization), the security of existence of local government, and
fiscal, political decentralization and administrative decentralization indexes; Range: 0–34, with
higher values implying greater aggregate decentralization; 1.53, 2.32.
AdminDecent Administrative decentralization. Index measures the ability of local governments to hire and fire Ivanyna and Shah (2014)
and set terms of employment of local employees as well as regulatory control over own
functions; Range: 0–1, with higher values implying greater administrative decentralization;
0.35, 0.23.
RuleLaw Rule of law index. It captures perceptions of the extent to which agents have confidence in and Kaufmann and Kraay (2014) http://info.worldbank.org/
abide by the rules of society, and in particular the quality of contract enforcement, property governance/wgi/index.aspx#home
rights, the police, and the courts, as well as the likelihood of crime and violence; Range: −2.5 to
+2.5, with higher values denoting stronger institutions; -0.41, 0.67.
Protestant Dummy variable that assumes a value of 1 if the percentage of population professing Protestant La Porta et al. (1999)
faith exceeds 50%, otherwise zero; 0.03, 0.16
GDP Log of GDP per capita in constant 2005 US dollars; 7.45, 1.14. World Development Indicators (http://data.worldbank.org/
indicator/NY.GDP.PCAP.KD?page=2)
GovtSize General government final consumption expenditure (% of GDP); 13.18, 4.87. World Development Indicators http://data.worldbank.org/
indicator/NE.CON.GOVT.ZS
POP Log of country's population; 17.24, 1.94. World Development Indicators (http://data.worldbank.org/
indicator/SP.POP.TOTL)
ServiceIND A categorical variable representing firms belonging to services sector. It includes sectors like World Bank World Enterprise Surveys. World Bank. (www.
construction, hotels and restaurants, IT and IT services, retail, tourism, transport, wholesale enterprisesurveys.org)
etc.; 0.42, 0.49.
LargeFirm A categorical variable representing firms with 100 or more employees; 0.19, 0.39. World Bank World Enterprise Surveys. World Bank. (www.
enterprisesurveys.org)

enables us to address a spectrum of qualitatively different issues.12 including an index for the Rule of Law (RuleLaw), whereby nations
As explained above, for each area of government performance, firm with better institutional quality are likely to perform better, ceteris
responses in the original WES survey are reclassified into one of three paribus (see La Porta et al. (1999)). The inclusion of government size
categories depending upon whether the respondent saw that area of and country size account for varying constraints and opportunities
government activity as a minor, moderate, or major impediment to nations and governments of different sizes face in providing services.
their business operations. We report results for “major” and “minor” For instance, larger governments might be associated with greater red
responses, while keeping “moderate” as the default (see Table A1 in the tape on the one hand and with better checks and balances on the other
Appendix for the classification used). hand. The former effect will increase corruption and lower government
The main explanatory variable is one of the four forms of govern- performance, while the latter will enhance performance (see
ment decentralization discussed in the preceding section. However, we Lambsdorff (2006)). The link between government size and corruption
also control for economic prosperity, industry type (by including a has been addressed empirically in the past, with mixed results (e.g.,
dummy variable for service industry (ServiceIND)),13 and for other Fan et al. (2009), Fisman and Gatti (2002), Gerring and Thacker
country attributes (denoted by Z in Eq. (1)), including government size (2005), Goel and Nelson (1998), Kotera et al. (2012)).
(GovtSize), country size (POP), institutional quality (RuleLaw), and Finally, the social dimension is accounted for by controlling for the
religion (Protestant – accounting for social influences). More prosper- Protestant religion. Nations with majority of Protestants are perceived
ous nations generally have better government machinery and perfor- to have a stronger work ethic. Such nations have largely been found to
mance of government services, while service industries may perceive be less corrupt (Lambsdorff (2006)). The literature on determinants of
government performance differently. corruption also uses many of the regressors that we use to examine
A more direct aspect of institutional quality is considered by (aggregate) cross-national corruption (see Lambsdorff (2006) and
Treisman (2007) for surveys of the literature; and Treisman (2000)
12
for an earlier rather comprehensive study) and we will also investigate
Given that the dependent variables in our analysis are at the micro-level, while the
here their possible effects on government performance in other areas.
right-hand-side variables are at the country level, the dummy variables identifying
service industry firms and large firms enable us to better exploit the information in our Given the detail in our data, we provide additional insights by
data (compared to country-level fixed effects). An alternate way to address this might be examining whether service industry firms are different and whether
multilevel modelling. However, given the nature of survey responses (where each firm size matters. One could imagine situations where service firms
dimension of performance is considered separately), this approach seems less appro-
have different interactions with corrupt bureaucrats (compared to
priate than the estimation technique used.
13
Our cross-country sample did have information on other industries. Our choice of
manufacturing firms) and technologies such as the internet might
controlling only for service industries was dictated by the fact that this set of industries enable them to bypass such interactions (think about IT service firms
was qualitatively more distinct from others (e.g., manufacturing, construction, etc.).

175
R.K. Goel et al. Economic Modelling 62 (2017) 171–183

able to transmit software over the internet, bypassing governmental Although the methodology used to cover the universe of the survey
interference - this aspect also relates to bypassing licensing require- is consistent, the sample of firms surveyed, and the sample of countries
ments). Further, many service industries, such as banking and IT, in any year, is not the same over the years. For instance, in the year
might not require pollution permits unlike their manufacturing coun- 2006 the total number of firms surveyed was 14,903 whereas in 2009
terparts, but might offer numerous other services that might require the number was 18,784. Similar differences exist for other years. It
multiple types of regulations (e.g., the financial services firms). Forty implies that we cannot call our data set ‘a single panel of firms over
two percent of firms in our sample belonged to the service sector time’. In other words, the data structure is not suitable for panel data
(Table 1). methods. As explained below, by controlling for the various macro-
We also consider the role of firm size in perceptions of government economic and other institutional heterogeneities we can manage to
performance (Section 5.5). Broadly speaking, firm size can be seen in extract reasonable inferences.
the context of the discussion surrounding the structure of markets - The other control variables used in the analysis are from reputed
whether large or dominant firms have different government interac- international sources that are routinely used in the literature. Details
tions that affect their views of government performance. Large firms about the variables used along with summary statistics are provided in
might have greater interactions with the government because they Table 1, and Appendix Table A2 provides a list of sample countries.
might require extra licenses and permits based on size and carry more
political weight within the local community. Further, they might appear 4.2. Estimation
more easily on the radars of government inspectors and thus face
greater scrutiny and rent demands. Conversely, large firms might be Given that the firms’ responses follow logical ordering (see Section
more adept at dealing with the government because of their ability to 3), the ordered logit model is a natural choice for estimation (see
hire specialists, although internal bureaucracies might make them Maddala (1986)). Thus, firm i's response m can assume one of the three
somewhat lethargic (the “X-inefficiency” view). permissible values such as m=1, 2, 3. The responses are ordered such
The data for this study are drawn from several sources in the public that higher m values indicate “bad outcome” in terms of business-
domain and include firm level survey data and country level aggregate government relations. For instance, a firm with m=1 is facing either no
data. There were some challenges with the survey data. The large or only minor obstacles in business operations caused by the govern-
survey sample across countries was not completely uniform and we had ment's rules, regulations, and their implementation, but a firm choos-
to make some adjustments for the analysis. First, the time dimension of ing alternative 3 is facing major or very severe obstacles in firm-
the variables is not entirely uniform. For dependent variables (survey government relations. For a more focused comparison, we report
responses) the time varies from 2006 to 2015, depending upon the results for only these two extreme outcomes and do so in the form of
country under consideration. In contrast, for decentralization mea- marginal effects for each predictor. The marginal effects tell us the
sures, taken from Ivanyna and Shah (2014), the time dimension impact of each of the explanatory variable on the probability that a firm
pertains mostly to 2005 and the values remain unchanged over time. chooses alternative m under the assumption that the other variables in
The control variables are also for 2006 and remain invariant over time. the model are at their sample mean values.
Importantly, the choice of the period from 2006 to 2015 for the The reported standard errors are computed using the Delta method.
dependent variables and 2005 or 2006 for the right hand side variables The Delta method expands a function of a random variable about its
helps to mitigate the problem of endogeneity in our cross-sectional mean, usually with a one-step Taylor approximation, and then takes
analysis.14,15 the variance. In logit and probit estimation and the family of models
that belong to maximum likelihood estimators, the Delta method is
used to compute asymptotic variance which makes inference more
14
Further, since the dependent variable(s) is based on individual survey responses, it reliable. The Delta method allows us to obtain the appropriate standard
seems unlikely that reverse feedbacks affect government decentralization, especially in a
errors of any smooth function of the fitted model parameters.16
short time period.
15
Unlike World Bank's Doing Business Surveys, the Enterprise Surveys (WES) do not
rely on expert opinion. The data in later surveys is based on firm manager's responses to 5. Results
an extensive questionnaire asking firms about issues related to a broad range of local
business environment. (The topics included in enterprise surveys are: infrastructure,
In this section the estimation results are reported for the various
trade, finance, regulations, taxes and business, licensing, corruption, crime and
informality, finance, innovation, labor, and perceptions about obstacles to doing decentralization measures. Of primary interest is the effect that each
business). The initial rounds of WES gathered data under different programs e.g. decentralization measure has on survey responses regarding how each
Regional Program on Enterprise Development in Africa, Business Environment and dimension of government affects business operations. Three areas are
Enterprise Performance in Eastern Europe and Central Asia, and Investment Climate addressed: tax administration, business licensing and permits, and
Surveys. All these were conducted prior to 2005. However, from 2006 onward, the WES
have been standardized and the responses are based on same questionnaire and
corruption. Each of these can be thought of as a relevant area to assess
methodology. The post-2005 data are available, in a single file containing data of all the quality of government operations from a business person's per-
the firms surveyed in 135 countries, at www.enterprisesurveys.org to registered users spective. Tables 2–5 report the main results. In each table the left-hand
(and registration is free). columns display marginal effect estimates of how increases in the
Admittedly, the Enterprise Surveys differ in terms of questions they ask in different
decentralization measure or one of the other control variables will
countries. However, since 2005 the data are being offered in two formats (for details see
https://www.enterprisesurveys.org/portal/login.aspx): affect the probability that the survey respondent will see the factor
a. “Standardized: country data are matched to a standard set of questions. This format listed in the column heading as either a “minor” or “no obstacle” to
allows cross-country comparisons and analysis but sacrifices those country-specific
survey questions which cannot be matched.
b. Country survey: offers the complete survey information for a particular country's (footnote continued)
survey. In this format the question coding is inconsistent across country surveys, even links/procedures we have outlined in the text. In addition, the details regarding sources
where the questions are identical, and is useful for single country or limited cross-country of data for individual countries in our data can also be seen in the “catalog of all data”, an
analysis.” excel sheet that is available also at the given link.
16
Our paper uses data that falls in format (a) above. It is clear from the above-mentioned Technically, it involves applying a Jacobian matrix to the estimated variance matrix
explanation that data on standardized survey instruments are available and that this data of the fitted model parameters. The Jacobian is a matrix of partial derivatives of the
set is provided in this standardized format by the WES and we never merge multiple statistics of interest with respect to each of the fitted model parameters. The STATA's
surveys to form a single cross country data set. The link “full survey data” is https://www. routine ‘margins’ generates Delta-method standard errors by default for each marginal
enterprisesurveys.org/portal/index.aspx#/library?dataset=Combined. The combined effect (linear or nonlinear). Additional details are available at: http://www.statalist.org/
data set is available for download if one creates free account and log in on the link forums/forum/general-stata-discussion/general/98078-delta-method-standard-errors-
above. Anyone interested in replication of our findings can access the data following the for-average-marginal-effects-using-margins-command.

176
R.K. Goel et al. Economic Modelling 62 (2017) 171–183

Table 2
Effects of fiscal decentralization on government performance.

Dep. variable → (2.1a) (2.1b) (2.2a) (2.2b) (2.3a) (2.3b)


TaxAdmin TaxAdmin BusLicense BusLicense Corrupt Corrupt

Fiscal Decent 0.459*** −0.239*** 0.440*** −0.235*** 0.865*** −0.784***


(0.014) (0.007) (0.013) (0.007) (0.014) (0.013)

RuleLaw 0.095*** −0.050*** 0.105*** −0.056*** 0.176*** −0.159***


(0.003) (0.002) (0.003) (0.002) (0.003) (0.003)

Protestant 0.186*** −0.097*** 0.172*** −0.092*** 0.184*** −0.167***


(0.014) (0.007) (0.013) (0.007) (0.013) (0.012)

GDP −0.043*** 0.022*** −0.039*** 0.021*** -0.049*** 0.044***


(0.002) (0.001) (0.002) (0.001) (0.002) (0.002)

GovtSize −0.003*** 0.002*** −0.005*** 0.003*** 0.003*** −0.003***


(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)

POP −0.011*** 0.006*** −0.013*** 0.007*** −0.019*** 0.017***


(0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001)

ServiceIND 0.022*** −0.011*** 0.012*** −0.006*** 0.029*** −0.027***


(0.004) (0.002) (0.003) (0.002) (0.004) (0.003)

Observations 77,360 77,360 82,448 82,448 82,443 82,443

Notes: See Table 1 for variable details. Delta-method standard errors in parentheses; ***p < 0.01, **p < 0.05, *p < 0.1.
Reported coefficients are marginal effects, based on ordered logit regressions (the pseudo-R2s for the underlying regressions are available upon request). All predictors at their average
value. Column header indicates the outcome factor. As explained in the text, only two categories of firms’ responses are considered: the factor in question is a minor obstacle to firms’
business operations, and factor in question is a major obstacle to firms’ business operations. Columns 2.1a, 2.2a and 2.3a reflect the response that (decentralized) government structure
is a minor or no obstacle, while 2.1b, 2.2b and 2.3b reflect the perception that the government is a major or severe obstacle to business operations.

Table 3
Effects of federalism on government performance.

Dep. variable → (3.1a) (3.1b) (3.2a) (3.2b) (3.3a) (3.3b)


TaxAdmin TaxAdmin BusLicense BusLicense Corrupt Corrupt

Federalism −0.144*** 0.076*** −0.116*** 0.062*** −0.098*** 0.090***


(0.006) (0.003) (0.005) (0.003) (0.005) (0.005)

RuleLaw 0.006* −0.003* 0.029*** −0.015*** 0.060*** −0.055***


(0.004) (0.002) (0.003) (0.002) (0.003) (0.003)

Protestant 0.148*** −0.078*** 0.175*** −0.094*** 0.142*** −0.130***


(0.013) (0.007) (0.012) (0.006) (0.011) (0.010)

GDP −0.003 0.002 −0.004** 0.002** −0.001 0.001


(0.002) (0.001) (0.002) (0.001) (0.002) (0.002)

GovtSize −0.003*** 0.002*** −0.005*** 0.002*** 0.006*** −0.006***


(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)

POP 0.006*** −0.003*** 0.003** −0.001** 0.004*** −0.004***


(0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001)

ServiceIND 0.034*** −0.018*** 0.024*** −0.013*** 0.051*** −0.046***


(0.004) (0.002) (0.003) (0.002) (0.003) (0.003)

Observations 78,475 78,475 83,603 83,603 83,546 83,546

Notes: See Notes to Table 2. The coding is for unitary (0) and federal (1) states.

their business operations. The right-hand columns pertain to the 5.1. Effects of fiscal decentralization (Fiscal Decent)
likelihood of survey response of either “major” or “very severe obstacle”
impact on business operations.17 Table 2 reports the results using the local government's share of
total government expenditures to measure decentralization. As dis-
cussed above, this indicator has often been used in earlier empirical
work analyzing various decentralization topics, but with well-known
deficiencies (Ebel and Yilmaz (2003)). The results in the present case
17
We also considered the "moderate" obstacle. Results of the marginal effects for the show that survey respondents are less likely to see any of the three
baseline response option – “moderate” obstacle – are aligned more with "major" or
government areas as a serious detriment to business operation (and
"severe" obstacles that are reported in Tables 2–5. The results for all categories are
reported in Appendix B. more likely to perceive the government being a minor or no obstacle) in

177
R.K. Goel et al. Economic Modelling 62 (2017) 171–183

Table 4
Effects of aggregate decentralization on government performance.

Dep. variable → (4.1a) (4.1b) (4.2a) (4.2b) (4.3a) (4.3b)


TaxAdmin TaxAdmin BusLicense BusLicense Corrupt Corrupt

AggDecent −0.001 0.001 0.008*** −0.004*** 0.027*** −0.025***


(0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.000) (0.001) (0.001)

RuleLaw 0.050*** −0.027*** 0.071*** −0.038*** 0.111*** −0.101***


(0.003) (0.002) (0.003) (0.002) (0.003) (0.003)

Protestant 0.168*** −0.089*** 0.162*** −0.087*** 0.157*** −0.143***


(0.014) (0.007) (0.013) (0.007) (0.013) (0.011)

GDP −0.027*** 0.014*** −0.032*** 0.017*** −0.042*** 0.038***


(0.002) (0.001) (0.002) (0.001) (0.002) (0.002)

GovtSize −0.001* 0.000* −0.005*** 0.002*** 0.002*** −0.002***


(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)

POP −0.001 0.000 −0.009*** 0.005*** -0.016*** 0.014***


(0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001)

ServiceIND 0.035*** −0.018*** 0.024*** −0.013*** 0.049*** −0.045***


(0.004) (0.002) (0.003) (0.002) (0.004) (0.003)

Observations 78,208 78,208 83,326 83,326 83,306 83,306

Notes: See Notes to Table 2.

Table 5
Effects of administrative decentralization on government performance.

Dep. variable → (5.1a) (5.1b) (5.2a) (5.2b) (5.3a) (5.3b)


TaxAdmin TaxAdmin BusLicense BusLicense Corrupt Corrupt

AdminDecent 0.048*** −0.025*** 0.106*** −0.057*** 0.141*** −0.129***


(0.008) (0.004) (0.008) (0.004) (0.008) (0.008)

RuleLaw 0.051*** −0.027*** 0.065*** −0.035*** 0.092*** −0.084***


(0.003) (0.002) (0.003) (0.002) (0.003) (0.003)

Protestant 0.175*** −0.093*** 0.186*** −0.100*** 0.192*** −0.176***


(0.014) (0.007) (0.012) (0.007) (0.012) (0.011)

GDP −0.031*** 0.016*** −0.032*** 0.017*** −0.030*** 0.027***


(0.002) (0.001) (0.002) (0.001) (0.002) (0.002)

GovtSize −0.001*** 0.001*** −0.004*** 0.002*** 0.006*** −0.005***


(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)

POP −0.003** 0.001** −0.008*** 0.004*** −0.006*** 0.006***


(0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001)

ServiceIND 0.034*** −0.018*** 0.024*** −0.013*** 0.051*** −0.047***


(0.004) (0.002) (0.003) (0.002) (0.004) (0.003)

Observations 78,208 78,208 83,326 83,326 83,306 83,306

Notes: See Notes to Table 2.

countries with greater expenditure decentralization. In each case, the more positive assessment of government outcomes is observed for
parameter estimates on the Fiscal Decent variable are statistically countries with a stronger rule of law and Protestant traditions (see
significant at the 1 percent level. These results are generally consistent Lambsdorff (2006)). In contrast, larger government size (in terms of
with much of the literature that has investigated the decentralization – share of GDP) is associated with greater likelihood of a negative
corruption link (e.g., Fan et al. (2009), Nelson (2013)). Further, the assessment of the impact of government on business operations in
results are in line with Adam et al. (2014) who used OECD data two of the three areas. With regard to corruption (Corrupt), however, a
between 1970 and 2000 to examine the impact of fiscal decentraliza- larger government size in fact improves perceptions of government
tion on public-sector efficiency in education and health services. Revelli performance. This latter finding is in line with the view that a larger
(2010), however, found that local public expenditures exceeding government machinery might not necessarily be adding to greater rent-
central spending standards had a detrimental effect on English seeking. Further, a larger public sector may have stronger institutions
government performance. in place to deter such activity (see Goel and Nelson (2005) for a similar
Turning briefly to the results for the control variables in the model, finding with aggregate data; also see Kotera et al. (2012)). In countries
the estimates are generally consistent across all three aspects of with higher incomes, survey respondents are more likely to have a
government performance. As might be expected, the probability of more negative assessment of the government outcomes in all cases. The

178
R.K. Goel et al. Economic Modelling 62 (2017) 171–183

effects are, however, modest. For example, with a one standard what is reported in Table 2 as to how decentralization affects managers'
deviation increase in per capita GDP (or economic prosperity) from perceptions of government performance. A positive assessment still
the sample mean, the probability that a business manager would agree remains regarding business licensing and corruption. The parameter
that business licensing matters are only minor obstacle to business estimates are statistically significant at the 1% level in each case, but
operations would decrease by only about 4%. the magnitudes of the parameter estimates are modest. For example, if
In more populous countries business managers tend to have a more a county currently at the sample mean for AggDecent (=1.5) were to
negative assessment of government performance. This perception change its institutions such that its decentralization score increased to
might be formed due to keener competition for resources in more match Brazil (=8.1), the highest index value in the data set, other
populous nations, leading to less government attention to individual things equal, the probability that a business manager would agree that
issues. Respondents from service industries are more likely to have a business licensing matters are at most only a minor obstacle would
positive assessment of decentralization in all areas. This finding is increase by just 5%.
consistent with the view that certain regulations or taxes - such as those Regarding tax administration, the evidence indicates that the
related to pollution - are not widely imposed on many service indicator of decentralization has no statistically significant effect on
industries, decreasing their interactions with the government and business managers' perceptions of government performance (columns
thereby enhancing their views of government performance. 4.1a and 4.1b). As noted above, perceptions relative to the impact of
corruption (columns 4.3a and 4.3b) improve with this form of
decentralization.
5.2. Effects of federalism (Federalism)
For the most part, the findings for the control variables are
consistent with what is noted in Table 2. Countries with more effective
Another way to view decentralization is to focus on political rather
rule of law and Protestant-dominated populations tend to have better
than economic decentralization by distinguishing between federalist
perceptions, while nations that are more affluent and with a larger
and unitary states. In the latter, the central government holds most of
overall public sector tend to be viewed more negatively. The evidence
the power and local regional governments - to the extent they exist - are
for the population variable is mixed here also.
administrative units of the national government. Fifteen percent of the
countries in this data set are classified as federalist states (the coding is
5.4. Effects of administrative decentralization (AdminDecent)
for unitary (0) and federal (1) states).
Table 3 presents the results using a binary federalist state decen-
The last decentralization measure considered is more narrowly
tralization indicator along with the same control variables used earlier.
focused than the others and is labelled as administrative decentraliza-
Interestingly, the findings are just the opposite of what was found
tion. It reflects the local government share of all public sector employ-
relative to the fiscal decentralization measure. In particular, relative to
ment and the degree to which there is local control in hiring policies of
unitary states, federalist governments perform worse in all areas. For
these employees. Greater local control increases accountability and
example, in a federalist state the probability that a business manager
reduces free riding; however, there is the potential downside of the
would consider tax administration to be either no obstacle or only a
possibility of nepotism in hiring. Higher values of AdminDecent imply
minor obstacle to business operations decreases by over 14%, other
that local employees are relatively more important in delivering public
things equal, based on the estimate reported in column 3.1a. For
services and that there is more local control over who these employees
business licensing, it decreases by nearly 12% (column 3.2a) and by
are.
10% in the case of corruption (column 3.3a).
Table 5 summarizes the results and shows that administrative
These findings are in line with Goldsmith (1999), Kunicová and
decentralization is statistically significant at conventional levels for all
Rose-Ackerman (2005), and Treisman (2000) in their analyses of the
areas, and greater decentralization is associated with better manager
effect of federalism on perceived corruption. However, in an analysis of
assessment regarding how government affects their business opera-
survey results of business manager's experience with bribery conducted
tions. The largest impacts are in business licensing (columns 5.2a and
in the late 1990s, federal structures were not found to be important in
5.2b), activities that are most likely to lie within the purview of the local
the level of bribery payments surrounding either business licenses or
public sector. In particular, if a country currently at the sample mean
tax collection (Fan et al. (2009)). Overall, these inconsistent results
for AdminDecent in this data set (=0.35) were to change its institutions
may be attributed to the dichotomous nature of the Federalism variable
such that its decentralization score increased to match the highest
which may mask other important institutional factors.
value in the data set (=0.82), other things equal, the probability that a
As to the control variables, the impact of the Protestant ethic,
business manager would agree that business licensing matters are at
government size, and the service industry variables are similar to those
most only a minor obstacle would increase by 5%. The finding is
in Table 2. The evidence for the remaining variables in the model
consistent with arguments dating back to Oates (1972) that local
including the rule of law, GDP, and population variables is mixed.18
officials are more accountable to the citizens they serve as they are
disciplined by inter-jurisdictional competition for mobile resources.
5.3. Effects of aggregate decentralization (AggDecent) Moreover, authorities are subject to “yardstick evaluation” (Salmon
(1987)) as their performance can be more easily compared to officials
Table 4 presents the results when the Aggregate Decentralization in similar positions in neighboring jurisdictions. The estimates relative
Index is used as the decentralization measure. This measure adjusts the to corruption also indicate that decentralization improves perceptions
expenditure decentralization indicator (Fiscal Decent) through the of government performance. This result is consistent with the notion
incorporation of several other important institutional factors that are that greater accountability associated with local control of human
relevant in assessing the actual autonomy of local governments. These resource policies acts as a deterrent, improving performance. The
factors include indicators of expenditure and tax autonomy, the findings for the control variables generally mirror earlier results.
security of existence of local governments, and variables that measure
political and administrative decentralization within a country. 5.5. Additional considerations
With these adjustments a somewhat different story emerges from
5.5.1. Effects of firm size
18
For instance, the effect of affluence on corruption is insignificant in Table 3. The
To obtain additional insights and to exploit better the information
possible complexity of the relation between corruption and economic development has available in the survey, we included a dummy variable, (LargeFirm),
been noted in the literature (see, for example, Blackburn (2012)). identifying respondents from large firms.

179
R.K. Goel et al. Economic Modelling 62 (2017) 171–183

Table 6
Marginal effects of increase in decentralization on government performance.

Decentralization Dimensions of government performance


measure ↓
TaxAdmin BusLicense Corrupt

Fiscal Decent 6.00% 5.70% 11.7%


Federalisma −5.20% −4.20% −3.53%
b
AggDecent 1.80% 6.30%
AdminDecent 1.10% 2.40% 3.22%

Notes: See Table 1 for variable details. The marginal effects show the effect of one standard deviation increase in the decentralization measure from the sample mean on the probability
that respondent will see the government activity as no more than a minor obstacle to business operations. The reported effects are significant at 5% level or lower, except as noted.
a
The Federalist government structure variable is included here for consistency with the earlier analysis. Marginal effect results must be viewed with due caution as this is a binary
decentralization measure making the interpretation of a standard deviation change somewhat problematic.
b
Hypothesis that decentralization has no effect cannot be rejected at conventional levels of statistical significance.

The size of firms relates to firm vintage. Large firms are likely to be tions about specific dimensions of government performance. However,
old and established (unless they grow big by mergers and acquisitions) when openness to trade is used to account for economic freedom, the
and thus may have a more involved view of government performance findings are opposite of those for the economic freedom index. These
than new firms. In this analysis, large firms are classified as firms with robustness checks support our main findings about the role of
more than 100 employees and they formed nineteen percent of our decentralization in perceived government performance.
sample (see Table 1).
Re-estimating Tables 2–5 with LargeFirm as an additional regres- 5.6. Relative magnitudes of impacts
sor provided some interesting results. Unreported estimates indicate
that, relative to other respondents, large firms viewed tax administra- Table 6 presents side-by-side comparisons of the impact of greater
tion to be a severe impediment to their business operations across the decentralization using the estimates presented in Tables 2–5. For each
four dimensions of government decentralization considered.19 This decentralization measure the entries in the table show how greater
result is consistent with the view that large firms, either due to their decentralization affects the probability that business managers will
size or longevity (or both), are likely to have rather involved interac- have a favorable assessment (minor or no obstacle to business
tions with tax authorities and they view such interactions unfavorably operations) of the government activity in question. In each case greater
(as opposed to small or new firms who might not have enough earnings decentralization is defined here as a one standard deviation increase in
to be caught in the tax net). The findings for the decentralization the decentralization measure above the respective sample mean.
variables are unchanged by the inclusion of LargeFirm in the model. The first takeaway from this comparison is that how decentraliza-
tion is measured is an important consideration when assessing its
5.5.2. Different set of macro controls influence on government performance. Measured either by local
As further robustness checks of our findings, we considered three government expenditure share or a federalist binary variable, relatively
alternate set of regressors to Tables 2–5 by adding the following: (a) a sizable effects from greater decentralization on assessment of govern-
dummy variable identifying the OECD countries in our sample; (b) the ment performance are observed, but in opposite directions, as can be
degree of trade openness, and (c) adding indices of overall economic seen by comparing the first two rows of Table 6. Of course, neither
freedom and democracy.20 The OECD dummy enables us to consider measure addresses the institutional details as to how much actual
institutional aspects that are not otherwise accounted for in the set of authority rests with lower tiers of government and this may affect the
controls used. Further, democracy and economic freedom (measured results. Our findings suggest that this is an important consideration. In
alternately via an index and via trade openness) can affect perceptions particular, the aggregate decentralization measure attempts to account
of government performance. for these details and when this is done (row three of the table), the
For the OECD dummy and trade openness, the parameter estimates evidence reveals that the impact of greater decentralization has a more
for the four decentralization measures are similar to Tables 2–5, with modest positive impact on assessment of government performance in
Federalism again having a different impact on government perfor- two of the three areas, and no statistically significant effect in tax
mance than the other decentralization types. The OECD dummy administration.22
coefficients indicate that OECD nations are less likely to view govern- The second implication of this analysis is that greater adminis-
ment performance unfavorably across the three dimensions trative decentralization appears to hold out the most hope to improve
(TaxAdmin, BusLicense, and Corrupt). This is consistent with the view assessment of government performance with regard to tax administra-
that governments in these wealthier nations are run more efficiently. tion and business licensing as shown by the results summarized in the
On the other hand, unfavorable view of government performance is last row of the table. There are improved perceptions in the business
more likely in more democratic and more economically free nations.21 licensing area (2.4%) and also in the case of corruption (3.2%).
For instance, survey respondents might be better informed about Viewed from a somewhat different perspective, 30 countries in the
government performance in more democratic nations due to freedom data set have a zero value for the administrative decentralization index.
of press, and greater overall economic freedom might shape expecta- If these countries were to adopt policies to take them to the sample
mean in the data set, the improved perception in the business licensing
19
The results with regard to corruption were statistically insignificant and showed no
22
clear pattern with regard to business licensing. Details are available upon request. The relative magnitudes of impacts should be interpreted with some caution as
20
Specifically, the economic freedom measure is from The Heritage Foundation AggDecent and AdminDecent are based on indices, Federalism is a dichotomous
(www.heritage.org), trade openness is from the World Development Indicators and the variable, while Fiscal Decent is a continuous variable, based on "hard" data. Indices,
democracy measure is from Polity IV (www.systemicpeace.org/inscrdata.html). for instance, are based on some aggregation across different aspects and are bounded. So
21
The results mentioned in this section are not reported but are available upon their impacts are understandably different from those of (unbounded) continuous
request. variables.

180
R.K. Goel et al. Economic Modelling 62 (2017) 171–183

area would be nearly 5%. These results should not be surprising as positive effect on business manager assessment of government perfor-
licensing is typically under the purview of government officials at the mance. These results hold across different robustness checks (Section
local level. In contrast, corruption reduction is better achieved with 5.5.2). In the context of the related literature, consideration of firm
aggregate decentralization. This makes sense in light of varied nature of level perception of government performance across numerous coun-
interactions between bureaucrats and firms (i.e., potential bribe takers tries and their nexus with different decentralization measures are key
and bribe givers). contributions of this work. The main takeaway from the above analysis
The main takeaway from the above analysis is that the qualitative is that the qualitative differences across decentralization types affect
differences across decentralization types affect the nature of percep- the nature of perceptions about government performance, and a
tions about government performance. The concluding section follows. particular decentralization type may not have the same effect on
different dimensions of performance.
6. Conclusions With regard to the control variables, the estimates are generally
consistent across aspects of government performance. Consistent with
The degree and scope of decentralization of government services intuition, a more positive assessment of government performance is
continue to intrigue policymakers in their quest to conserve resources observed for countries with stronger rule of law and Protestant
and improve the delivery of government services. The elusive goal of an traditions (see Lambsdorff (2006)). In contrast, larger government
“optimal” level of decentralization has kept researchers engaged with size is associated with greater likelihood of a negative assessment in
an examination of causes and effects of government decentralization two of the three areas. In wealthier countries, survey respondents seem
with varying methodologies and data (see Feld and Schnellenbach to have a more negative assessment of the government performance,
(2011), Martinez-Vazquez et al. (2016) and Yeung (2009)). This paper possibly due to a combination of being better informed and having
adds to the literature by using data on firm's perceptions of government greater expectations from the government.23 Finally, two dimensions of
performance and examining the effect of various forms of decentraliza- size are considered: country size and firm size. Both show negative
tion on three major dimensions of performance. perceptions of government performance, especially with regard to tax
The analysis presented in this paper can be distinguished from the administration. This suggests that large firms and more populous
literature on the effects of government decentralization on quality of nations might face special challenges in this area, and this is a new
governance in several important ways. First, our focus has been insight that deserves additional consideration in the future.
business managers and their perceptions about how various govern- The policy lessons from this analysis are clear. Decentralization
ment measures in regard to tax administration, business licensing, and should not be oversold as a policy prescription to improve government
corruption control affect their operations. Second, we have employed a performance and the details behind any policy initiative to “decentra-
large micro data set spanning a wide cross-section of countries, thereby lize” matter. From a business manager perspective, both fiscal and
mitigating the potential for two-way link between government perfor- administrative decentralization can be expected to lower the adverse
mance and the extent to which government is close to the citizens. impact of corruption on their operations. Beyond that, the strongest
Third, two of the decentralization measures employed in this analysis evidence in favor of a positive linkage is in the area of administrative
are designed to account for key institutional factors that may affect how decentralization relative to business licensing and permits. Delivering
much control local governments actually have relative to the central government services and administering such activities with local
government in delivering services. employees, subject to employment and human resource policies that
Tying to the questions posed in the introduction we have found that are locally controlled, leads to a moderate, but not inconsequential
how decentralization is measured is important when assessing its improvement in business perception of how well government func-
impact on government performance relative to business operations. In tions. A large number of developing countries seems to have plenty of
particular, greater decentralization, comprehensively measured to room to make policy changes in this area.
control for institutional differences across countries, has only a modest

23
However, as Section 5.5.2 notes, the more homogeneous group of OECD nations is
somewhat different.

181
R.K. Goel et al. Economic Modelling 62 (2017) 171–183

Appendix A

See Tables A1 and A2.

Table A1
Reclassification of firms’ responses in the original WES survey.

WES No obstacle Minor Moderate Major Very


Scheme obstacle obstacle obstacle severe
obstacle
0 1 2 3 4

Modified Minor obstacle Moderate Major obstacle


scheme obstacle
used

Notes: In the case of TaxAdmin the responses ranged from 0–3, so we reclassified them in this case as: 0, 1: Minor obstacle; 2: Moderate obstacle; 3: Major obstacle.

Table A2
List of sample countries.

Albania, Angola, Argentina, Armenia, Azerbaijan, Bahamas, Bahrain, Bangladesh, Belarus, Belize, Benin, Bhutan,
Bolivia, Bosnia and Herzegovina, Botswana, Brazil, Bulgaria, Burkina Faso, Burundi, Cambodia, Cameroon,
Central African Republic, Chad, Chile, China, Colombia, Congo Democratic Republic, Congo Republic, Costa
Rica, Cote d'Ivoire, Croatia, Czech Republic, Dominican Republic, Ecuador, Egypt, El Salvador, Equatorial
Guinea, Eritrea, Estonia, Ethiopia, Fiji, Gabon, Georgia, Ghana, Guinea, Honduras, Hungary, India, Indonesia,
Israel, Jamaica, Jordan, Kazakhstan, Kenya, Kyrgyzstan, Laos PDR, Latvia, Lebanon, Lesotho, Liberia,
Lithuania, Macedonia, Madagascar, Malawi, Malaysia, Mali, Mauritania, Mauritius, Mexico, Moldova,
Mongolia, Morocco, Mozambique, Namibia, Nepal, Nicaragua, Niger, Nigeria, Oman, Pakistan, Panama,
Paraguay, Peru, Philippines, Poland, Qatar, Romania, Russia, Rwanda, Senegal, Serbia, Sierra Leone, Slovakia,
Slovenia, South Africa, Sri Lanka, Suriname, Sweden, Tanzania, Togo, Tonga, Trinidad & Tobago, Tunisia,
Turkey, Uganda, Ukraine, Uruguay, Uzbekistan, Vanuatu, Venezuela, Vietnam, Yemen, Zimbabwe.

Appendix B. Supplementary material

Supplementary data associated with this article, “Different forms of decentralization and their impact on government performance: Micro-level
evidence from 113 countries” can be found in the online version at http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2016.12.010.

Organ. 59 (1), 233–254.


Goel, R.K., Nelson, M.A., 1998. Corruption and government size: a disaggregated
analysis. Public Choice 97 (1), 107–120.
References Goel, R.K., Nelson, M.A., 2005. Economic freedom versus political freedom: cross-
country influences on corruption. Aust. Econ. Pap. 44 (2), 121–133.
Goel, R.K., Nelson, M.A., 2011. Government fragmentation versus fiscal decentralization
Adam, A., Delis, M.D., Kammas, P., 2014. Fiscal decentralization and public sector and corruption. Public Choice 148 (3), 471–490.
efficiency: evidence from OECD countries. Econ. Gov. 15 (1), 17–49. Goel, R.K., Saunoris, J.W., 2016. Virtual versus physical government decentralization:
Besley, T.J., Coate, S., 2003. Centralized versus decentralized provision of local public effects on corruption and the shadow economy. Public Budg. Financ. 36 (4), 68–93.
goods: a political economy approach. J. Public Econ. 87 (12), 2611–2637. Goldsmith, A.A., 1999. Slapping the grasping hand: correlates of political corruption in
Birch, A.H., 1949. Federalism and finance. Manch. Sch. 17 (2), 163–185. emerging markets. Am. J. Econ. Sociol. 58 (4), 865–883.
Blackburn, K., 2012. Corruption and development: explaining the evidence. Manch. Sch. Guccio, C., Pignataro, G., Rizzo, I., 2014. Do local governments do it better? Analysis of
80 (4), 401–428. time performance in the execution of public works. Eur. J. Polit. Econ. 34, 237–252.
Blume, L., Voigt, S., 2011. Federalism and decentralization: a critical survey of frequently Hallward-Driemeier, M., Pritchett, L., 2015. How business is done in the developing
used indicators. Const. Polit. Econ. 22 (3), 238–264. world: deals versus rules. J. Econ. Perspect. 29 (3), 121–140.
Bodman, P., Campbell, H., Le, T., 2012. Public investment, taxation, and long-run output International Monetary Fund, 2009. Macro Policy Lessons for a Sound Design of Fiscal
in economies with multi-level governments. Econ. Model. 29 (5), 1603–1611. Decentralization. International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.
Brueckner, J.K., 2003. Strategic interaction among governments: an overview of Ivanyna, M., Shah, A., 2014. How close is your government to its people? Worldwide
empirical studies. Int. Reg. Sci. Rev. 26 (2), 175–188. indicators on localization and decentralization. Econ.: Open-Access Open-Access. E-
Ebel, R.D., Yilmaz, S., 2003. On the measurement and impact of fiscal decentralization. J. 6, 1–61. http://dx.doi.org/10.5018/economics-ejournal.ja.2014-3.
In: Martinez-Vazquez, J., Alm, J. (Eds.), Public Finance in Developing and Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A., 2014. The Worldwide Governance Indicators (WGI) Project.
Transitional Countries: Essays in Honor of Richard Bird. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, World Bank. 〈http://info.worldbank.org/governance/wgi/index.aspx#home〉.
UK, 101–126. Knack, S., Keefer, P., 1995. Institutions and economic performance: cross-country tests
Elazar, D.J., 1995. From statism to federalism: a paradigm shift. Publius 25 (2), 5–18. using alternative institutional measures. Econ. Polit. 7 (3), 207–227.
Enterprises Surveys Indicators Description (ESID), 2015. Enterprise Surveys Data. Kotera, G., Okada, K., Samreth, S., 2012. Government size, democracy, and corruption:
World Bank. http://www.enterprisesurveys.org/data. an empirical investigation. Econ. Model. 29 (6), 2340–2348.
Faguet, J.-P., 2014. Decentralization and governance. World Dev. 53, 2–13. Kunicová, J., Rose-Ackerman, S., 2005. Electoral rules and constitutional structures as
Fan, C.S., Lin, C., Treisman, D., 2009. Political decentralization and corruption: evidence constraints on corruption. Br. J. Polit. Sci. 35 (4), 573–606.
from around the world. J. Public Econ. 93 (1–2), 14–34. Kyriacou, A.P., Roca-Sagalés, O., 2011a. Fiscal decentralization and government quality
Feld, L.P., Schnellenbach, J., 2011. Fiscal federalism and long-run macroeconomic in the OECD. Econ. Lett. 111 (3), 191–193.
performance: a survey of recent research. Environ. Plan. C: Gov. Policy 29 (2), Kyriacou, A.P., Roca-Sagalés, O., 2011b. Fiscal and political decentralization and
224–243. government quality. Environ. Plan. C: Gov. Policy 29 (2), 204–223.
Fisman, R., Gatti, R., 2002. Decentralization and corruption: evidence across countries. La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., Vishny, R., 1999. The quality of
J. Public Econ. 83 (3), 325–345. government. J. Law Econ. Organ. 15 (1), 222–279.
Gerring, J., Thacker, S.C., 2005. Do neoliberal policies deter political corruption? Int. Lago-Peñas, I., Lago-Peñas, S., Martinez-Vazquez, J., 2011. The political and economic

182
R.K. Goel et al. Economic Modelling 62 (2017) 171–183

consequences of decentralization. Environ. Plan. C: Gov. Policy 29 (2), 197–203. Salmon, P., 1987. Decentralisation as an incentive scheme. Oxf. Rev. Econ. Policy 3 (2),
Lambsdorff, J.G., 2006. Causes and consequences of corruption: what do we know from a 24–43.
cross section of countries. In: Rose-Ackerman, S. (Ed.), International Handbook on Shah, A., Thompson, T., 2004. Implementing Decentralized Local Governance: A
the Economics of Corruption1st ed.. Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham, 3–51. Treacherous Road with Potholes, Detours and Road Closures. World Bank Policy
Maddala, G.S., 1986. Limited-Dependent and Qualitative Variables in Econometrics. Research Working Paper # 3353, June.
Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. Stegarescu, D., 2005. Public sector decentralization: measurement concepts and recent
Martinez-Vazquez, J., Lago-Peñas, S., Sacchi, A., 2016. The impact of fiscal international trends. Fisc. Stud. 26 (3), 301–333.
decentralization: a survey. J. Econ. Surv.. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/joes.12182. Transparency International, 2009. Corruption and Local Government. Working paper
Nelson, M.A., 2013. Corruption and the size of local governments: are they related? In: #05/2009.
Lago-Peñas, S., Martinez-Vazquez, J. (Eds.), The Challenge of Local Government Treisman, D., 2000. The causes of corruption: a cross-national study. J. Public Econ. 76
Size: Theoretical Perspectives, International Experience, and Policy Reform. Edward (3), 399–457.
Elgar, Northampton, MA, 87–124. Treisman, D., 2006. Fiscal decentralization, governance, and economic performance: a
Oates, W.E., 1972. Fiscal Federalism. Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, New York. reconsideration. Econ. Polit. 18 (2), 219–235.
Panizza, U., 1999. On the determinants of fiscal centralization: theory and evidence. J. Treisman, D., 2007. What have we learned about the causes of corruption from ten years
Public Econ. 74 (1), 97–139. of cross-national empirical research? Annu. Rev. Polit. Sci. 10, 211–244.
Prud’homme, R., 1995. The dangers of decentralization. World Bank Res. Obs. 10 (2), United Nations, 2009. International Guidelines on Decentralization and Access to Basic
201–220. Services for All. UN-HABITAT, Nairobi.
Revelli, F., 2010. Spend more, get more? An inquiry into English local government Voigt, S., Blume, L., 2012. The economic effects of federalism and decentralization: a
performance. Oxf. Econ. Pap. 62 (1), 185–207. cross-country assessment. Public Choice 151 (1), 229–254.
Rodden, J., 2004. Comparative federalism and decentralization: on meaning and World Bank, 1999. Decentralization: rethinking governmentWorld Development Report
measurement. Comp. Polit. 36 (4), 481–500. 1999/2000: Entering the 21st Century. Oxford University Press, New York,
Rodríguez-Pose, A., Gill, N., 2003. The global trend towards devolution and its 107–124.
implications. Environ. Plan. C: Gov. Policy 21 (3), 333–351. Yeung, R., 2009. The effects of fiscal decentralization on the size of government: a meta-
Rodríguez-Pose, A., Ezcurra, R., 2011. Is fiscal decentralization harmful for economic analysis. Public Budg. Financ. 29 (4), 1–23.
growth? Evidence from the OECD countries. J. Econ. Geogr. 11 (4), 619–643.

183

View publication stats

You might also like