Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 9

Brazil’s WTO Challenge to U.S.

Cotton
Subsidies:
The Road to Effective Disciplines of
Agricultural Subsidies
By: Scott D. Andersen† and Meredith A. Taylor‡

B
razil’s landmark 2003–2009 challenges before the World precedent that will be highly important for future challenges to
Trade Organization (WTO) targeted massive United agricultural subsidies. As the first challenges under the WTO Sub-
States (U.S.) government subsidies supporting cotton sidies and Countervailing Measures (SCM) Agreement’s8 “actionable
production.1 The five Cotton decisions clarified the breadth and subsidy,” prohibited local content and prohibited export subsidy
limits of agricultural subsidy disciplinary actions through the rules, the Cotton decisions generated a considerable new jurispru-
dispute settlement process of the WTO. The result of the Cotton2 dence and interpretations. As detailed herein, the results gener-
jurisprudence is increased vulnerability of U.S. and European ally illuminated the vulnerability of trade-distorting agricultural
Union (E.U.) agricultural subsidies to future successful WTO subsidies, particularly in the U.S. and the E.U.
challenges. This article sets forth the background and relevancy as Further, from a practitioner’s viewpoint, the strategic
well as key novel legal and evidentiary issues of the case; various choices made and the documentary and expert evidence success-
important lessons learned for future serious prejudice and pro- fully presented by Brazil offer guidance for future challenges to a
hibited subsidy claims; and various examples of potential claims range of agricultural subsidies in the years ahead. More broadly,
in other contexts arising from the Cotton jurisprudence.3 the breadth of the trade distortions established as facts in the vari-
ous Cotton rulings continue to have an important impact on the
Background and Relevancy ongoing Doha Round negotiations to reduce total amounts of
The Cotton case is important because it was the first suc- trade-distorting domestic and agricultural export subsidies. Addi-
cessful challenge to highly trade-distorting, actionable, and tionally, the rulings have encouraged domestic reform efforts in
prohibited agricultural subsidies under the WTO. In September the U.S. and the E.U. by highlighting the severe negative impact
2002, Brazil initiated WTO dispute resolution complaining that of such subsidies on least-developed and developing country pro-
(1) world cotton prices were significantly suppressed as a result ducers of cotton and other agricultural products.
of billions in annual U.S. domestic support subsidies and (2)
prohibited subsidies were granted to facilitate the domestic pur- Key Novel Legal and Evidentiary Issues
chase and export of high-cost U.S. cotton.4 The initiation of the Addressed in the Cotton Decisions
dispute coincided with surging U.S. production and exports of The Cotton dispute involved a number of novel legal and
cotton, plunging world cotton market prices,5 and severe revenue evidentiary issues under the WTO subsidies disciplines relating
losses by Brazilian, African, and other world cotton producers. to various forms of agricultural subsidies. The highlights of some
The sinking revenues were allegedly due, in part, to U.S. WTO- of the key issues are discussed in the brief summaries of the Cot-
inconsistent subsidies.6 ton rulings set forth herein.9 The determinations of these issues
The resulting WTO litigation continued over the period create a legal and evidentiary roadmap for potential future chal-
of 2003–2009 and culminated into the issuance of five Cotton lenges to U.S. and E.U. agricultural subsidies.
WTO decisions.7 Collectively, these decisions created a body of
Serious Prejudice Determination
Of primary importance, these were the first and only WTO
The Cotton case is important because it decisions applying the WTO rules to “actionable” subsidies caus-
ing “serious prejudice” to agricultural products. The WTO SCM
was the first successful challenge to highly Agreement only prohibits a relatively narrow range of export and
trade-distorting, actionable, and prohibited local content subsides10 — all other subsidies are permitted, if
they do not cause various forms of serious prejudice to other
agricultural subsidies under the WTO. WTO Members.11

2 Business Law Brief | Fall/Winter 2009–2010


A major focus of Brazil’s claims was that a variety of U.S. were no material changes to the nature, object, effect, or magni-
subsidies supporting the production and export of cotton caused tude of the U.S. marketing loan18 or counter-cyclical subsidies,19
“serious prejudice” in the form of significant price suppression in which continued during the 2005–2006 period. The panel found
the world cotton market, which that these continuing programs
was in violation of Article 6.3(c) paid the same, if not higher,
of the SCM Agreement.12 The levels of subsidies than those
original panel examined Brazil’s during the 1999–2002 period.20
primary claim that the collective Further, based on considerable
effects of eight different subsi- new evidence concerning the
dies supporting the production, operation of these subsidies dur-
use and export of U.S. upland ing the new reference period
cotton caused significant price of 2005-2006, the compliance
suppression in the world market panel found that the marketing
in violation of Article 6.3(c) loan and countercyclical subsi-
of the SCM Agreement.13 The dies continued to significantly
panel found that three of the impact the planting decisions of
price-contingent subsidies — upland cotton farmers and affect
the marketing loan, the counter- the “level of U.S. upland cotton
cyclical payments (and the predecessor market loss assistance acreage and production as a result of their mandatory and price-
subsidies), and the domestic Step 2 subsidies14 — collectively contingent nature and their revenue-stabilizing effect”21 and
caused significant price suppression in the world market during “insulate revenues of U.S. upland cotton producers when prices
the reference period of 1999-2002.15 are low.”22 The panel’s causation finding also emphasized that it
In response to the original panel and Appellate Body rul- was appropriate to assess the effects of subsidies by examining the
ings, the U.S. eliminated the Step 2 subsidy but did not make longer term impact on farmers entering or exiting the produc-
any changes to the price-contingent marketing loan or counter- tion of cotton, and in covering their total costs of production.23
cyclical subsidies programs. Despite the fact that these remain- In conclusion, the compliance panel found that “without these
ing two price-contingent subsidies constituted the bulk of the subsidies the level of US upland cotton acreage and production
subsidies examined by the original panel, the U.S. argued their would likely be significantly lower.”24
effects were not sufficient to cause significant price suppression On appeal of the second proceedings, the Appellate Body
in the world market.16 Accordingly, Brazil commenced compli- decided against the United States challenge and affirmed all of
ance proceedings in Fall of the major serious preju-
2006 claiming that the dice-related findings and
U.S. had neither com- underlying reasoning of
plied with the require- the compliance panel.25
ment to withdraw the In particular, the Appel-
marketing loan and late Body agreed with
counter-cyclical subsidy the compliance panel’s
programs nor removed rejection of a U.S. juris-
the adverse effects of dictional argument that
those subsidies. would have excluded
Brazil claimed that from the compliance
the effect of the new proceedings any subsidy
“basket” of marketing payments made after
loan and counter-cyclical 2005.26 The effect of
subsidies caused present the decision required the
serious prejudice, inter United States to elimi-
alia,17 in the form of nate or otherwise make
significant price suppres- significant changes to
sion in the world cotton the marketing loan and
market. The compliance counter-cyclical program
panel found that there legislation.27 In addi-

Business Law Brief | Fall/Winter 2009–2010 3


invoke the peace clause as a defense to Brazil’s serious prejudice
This is a pragmatic acknowledgement challenges. Applied more broadly, the decision requires that bil-
lions of U.S. dollars in direct payments must be included in the
that there will be other factors impacting U.S. obligation to reduce its overall levels of trade-distorting
the movement of prices and that a support (“total aggregate measurement of support” or “AMS”). In
practice, this will require the United States to eliminate the fruits
significant price suppression claim may
and vegetables exception to the direct payment program or make
be maintained even if there are other real cuts in its trade-distorting agricultural subsidies in order to
factors influencing world prices. be WTO-consistent.

Arbitration Determinations
tion, the Appellate Body endorsed the use of economic modeling Brazil’s landmark challenge against U.S. subsidies possibly
and other quantitative techniques to “provide a framework to crossed a final threshold in the six-year battle on August 31,
analyze the relationship between subsidies, other factors, and 2009. In light of the continued U.S. failure to implement rem-
price movements.”28 The Appellate Body’s decision criticized the edies consistent with the decisions of the WTO dispute settle-
compliance panel for not examining in detail the parameters of ment panels or Appellate Body, three WTO Arbitrators granted
the competing economic models presented by Brazil and the U.S. Brazil the right to retaliate against U.S. trade in goods, services,
and for not going far enough in its comparative analysis of these and intellectual property rights in amounts that may well reach
models.29 Finally, the Appellate Body clarified that the effect of $800 million.36 The Arbitrators’ calculation of what are effec-
subsidies need not be the only cause of price suppression.30 This tively “trade damages” followed an earlier United States refusal
is a pragmatic acknowledgement that there will be other factors to eliminate billions in annual highly trade-distorting “domestic”
impacting the movement of prices and that a significant price subsidies sustaining the world’s largest exporter of cotton.37 Like
suppression claim may be maintained even if there are other fac- the four previous WTO panel and Appellate Body reports find-
tors influencing world prices.31 ing in favor of Brazil’s claims against these U.S. subsidies over
the period 2004-2008, this new Arbitrator report provides new
“Step 2” Local Content Determination precedents on several novel legal issues that are relevant to future
The Cotton cases were the first WTO decisions examining challenges to agricultural subsidies.
local content (import substitution) subsidies to processors of First, a key aspect of the Arbitrator’s decision was to find
basic agricultural products as well as export subsidies for agricul- that the amount of appropriate suspension of concessions for
tural products contingent upon the export of U.S. agricultural Brazil was limited to the impact on Brazil of the price suppres-
products (cotton under the Step 2 program32). The SCM Agree- sion in the world market resulting from the granting of market-
ment prohibits subsidies granted contingent upon the use of local ing loan and counter-cyclical payments.38 Brazil had argued that
products, such as U.S. grown cotton, or upon the export of prod- it was entitled to suspend concessions of more than one billion
ucts, such as U.S. cotton. Brazil successfully fought off a number U.S. dollars because the adverse effects determined to exist by
of U.S. arguments in demonstrating that the “Step 2” local con- the original panel was significant price suppression in the world
tent and Step 2 export refund subsidies were de jure contingent market price — not significant price suppression for only those
either on the use or export of U.S. cotton in violation of Article transactions involving Brazil.39 Brazil’s share of the world cotton
3.1 of the SCM Agreement. The original panel and the Appellate market was roughly five percent in the reference period used to
Body affirmed Brazil’s challenge and, as stated above, the United calculate countermeasures.40 The Arbitrator valued the damage
States eventually eliminated the Step 2 program in 2006. for which Brazil could continue to impose “countermeasures” of
$147.3 million per year for as long as the United States does not
“Green Box” Direct Payment Determination eliminate the marketing loan and counter-cyclical subsidies or
The cases were also the first WTO decisions clarifying remove all of the $2.905 billion in annual price suppression expe-
WTO rules relating to a special category of “domestic support” rienced by non-U.S. cotton producers in the world market.41
in favor of agricultural producers for which members need not This is an important part of the decision because it means that
reduce the level of their agricultural subsidies, (i.e., commonly Brazil can continue to retaliate against the United States until the
referred to as the “green box”).33 The panel, affirmed by the marketing loan and counter-cyclical subsidies are eliminated or
Appellate Body,34 found that U.S. direct payments to farm- all their worldwide adverse effects removed.42
ers who historically farmed cotton on a particular farm do not Another important aspect of the decision was the Arbitra-
meet the criteria specified in paragraph 6(b) of Annex 2 of the tor’s acceptance of the use of economic models as useful eviden-
Agreement on Agriculture,35 meaning the United States could not tiary tools in conducting a necessary but for analysis of subsidy

4 Business Law Brief | Fall/Winter 2009–2010


effects. The transparent use and ultimate endorsement of such ability to use any form of subsidy to establish serious prejudice
models, submitted by complainants to support their arguments, (prohibited export and local content subsidies, expired subsidies
represents a fairly unique use of this economic tool by WTO with continuing effects, green box subsidies), and the meaning
decision-makers and foreshadows the important advisory role of of significant price suppression and how it can be demonstrated
the WTO Economics Division as reviewers of the models, in any causally.
future WTO challenges to agricultural subsidies. Second, the expiration of the “peace clause” means that
Finally, in view of the ongoing Doha Round negotiations complaining parties can challenge the collective effects of any
concerning reductions in trade-distorting domestic subsidies and form of subsidy to establish serious prejudice–even subsidies
the elimination of export subsidies altogether, another key aspect falling within the so-called “green box.” Nor do complaining
of the Cotton Arbitration is its findings quantifying the amount Members need be concerned with establishing that current levels
of adverse market effects of the U.S. subsidies. For example, of subsidization are greater than historic levels of subsidization
again, in the case of the marketing loan and counter-cyclical sub- for particular product at issue.45
sidies for cotton alone, the Arbitrator found that the total effects Third, the Cotton compliance panel and Appellate Body
of the significant price suppression totaled $2.905 billion43 — a confirmed that the adverse effects of annually recurring agricul-
huge amount by any measure. Such a determination, reflecting tural subsidies can be undertaken using a long-term analysis.46
the extreme size of the effect on the market, can create moral Such an analysis would assess whether the collective effect of a
suasion and generate international outrage at the impact of such number of years of annually recurring subsidies contribute to
illegality, particularly on developing and least developed coun- farmers entering or exiting the production of the crop in ques-
tries.44 An analysis of future potential claims after the Cotton tion. This is a very important because claims based only on
cases is appropriate, especially given the fact that such domestic short-term (one or two years) effects can easily collapse during
subsidy regimes remain and international condemnation of the the WTO proceedings if the level of subsidies contracts signifi-
negative impacts on the trade and development of many develop- cantly (through increases in commodity prices). This rationale
ing country agricultural producers continues. is particularly useful for challenges to subsidies for crops such
as rice or cotton that demand specialized equipment and where
Lessons Learned for Future Litigation of certain land is only economically viable (with subsidies) to grow
Serious Prejudice Claims
a single or only several crops. By contrast, the long-term causa-
A close review of the briefing and evidence used in Brazil’s tion analysis may be less useful for claims involving subsidies for
litigation of its serious prejudice-related claims in the various commodities where it is relatively easy to shift from one crop to
Cotton proceedings demonstrates how document-intensive and many other crops.
expert-intensive a task it is to quantify the effects of subsidies Fourth, the compliance panel rejected U.S. arguments that
and otherwise establish the causal link to serious prejudice in the absence of any temporal link between the lower world prices
agricultural commodity markets. There is no doubt that future and the payment of marketing loan and counter-cyclical subsi-
challenges will require a similar resource-intensive effort to estab- dies meant that the subsidies could not cause price suppression.47
lish causation. Nevertheless, for the reasons set forth, infra, it will The compliance panel’s finding on this point, when read in con-
be considerably easier for future complaining party litigants to junction with its “long-term” approach to examining the effects
plan and prosecute successfully their serious prejudice challenges of subsidies, suggests that future challenges to annual recurring
because of the lessons learned from the Cotton decisions. agricultural subsidies need not demonstrate any temporal link
First, the numerous legal interpretations by the five Cotton between market prices and the provision of subsidies. This appro-
decisions of the SCM Agreement and the Agreement on Agriculture priately limited an obvious defense in situations where subsidies
have clarified issues such as the existence of a world market, the have been provided for decades (as with the U.S. and E.U.) and
where it would thus be difficult to identify a temporal point in
which subsidies have not distorted the market.
[I]t will be considerably easier for future Fifth, while the original panel found that non-price contin-
gent subsidies (direct payments and crop insurance) did not cause
complaining party litigants to plan and
significant price suppression, dicta from the Appellate Body
prosecute successfully their serious suggested that non-price contingent subsidies could contribute
prejudice challenges because of the lessons to price suppression and other forms of serious prejudice.48 In
addition, the rationale behind the use of a long-term effects
learned from the Cotton decisions. analysis is whether the combined effect of the challenged subsi-
dies provides revenue support to farmers that maintain them in
the business of farming the commodity in question.49 Non-price

Business Law Brief | Fall/Winter 2009–2010 5


Eighth, the compliance panel and Appellate Body’s decision
rejecting the distinction between subsidy payments and subsidy
programs will make it much easier for those Members challeng-
ing subsidies to secure implementation by the challenged subsi-
dizing Member. Complaining Members now need only establish
the existence of serious prejudice during a reference period by
the effects of subsidies. A positive finding of serious prejudice
will mean that the losing subsidizing Member will have to make
changes to the subsidy program or legislation and not simply
claim that the effects of the subsidies granted during the reference
period no longer cause serious prejudice.
Finally, an important tactical lesson to be learned from the
Cotton Arbitration decision is that the damages’ focus is only
contingent subsidies that contribute to covering the costs of pro- upon the serious prejudicial effects suffered by a complaining
duction or increasing the wealth of a farmer through facilitating party53 and it would be beneficial to combine as many complain-
the purchase of land or equipment can have a very similar effect ing parties with the largest possible share of world production or
on sustaining production as a price-contingent subsidy. world exports. For example, if China, Brazil, and India — who
Sixth, the Arbitrators confirmed the viability and utility collectively total more than fifty percent of world cotton pro-
of particular types of econometric models50 to assess the effects duction — had joined forces to challenge U.S. upland cotton
of subsidies. Similarly, the Appellate Body in each of its Cotton subsidies, the total amount of retaliation allowed under the Arbi-
decisions criticized the panels for not explaining how it had taken trator’s formula would have been far in excess of $1 billion. As a
the particular models into account, and for failing to evaluate and result, the United States would still have the obligation to remove
compare the parameters used by such models.51 The use of such all of the significant price suppression, but it would also have an
models is crucial given the counterfactual nature of the entire arguably greater incentive to eliminate its WTO-inconsistent
serious prejudice question, i.e. whether, but for the subsidies, conduct.
world prices would have been higher. Future complaining par- In sum, the collective effect of these Cotton decisions will
ties can adopt and adapt as necessary these models in preparing considerably aid complaining parties in future disputes. That is
future challenges. This will significantly facilitate the defense of not to say that it will be easy to establish the causal link between
such models.52 the subsidies and particular market effects that rise to the level of
Seventh, the Cotton decisions highlighted the utility of serious prejudice. Such cases will always be evidence and expert-
a claim of price suppression in challenging such subsidies. intensive and require considerable resources and expertise to liti-
Unlike a claim of price depression, there is no requirement for a gate successfully. However, the clarifications provided by all five
complaining party to explain what may be very wide swings in of the Cotton decisions will allow the structuring and prosecution
commodity prices during the reference period examined. In the of the case in a more efficient and less-resource intensive manner
various Cotton proceedings, the U.S. had the near impossible than Brazil was forced to endure as the first Member to challenge
task of trying to demonstrate that other market factors (such as these subsidies.
China and India’s role in world markets) somehow eliminated
any price suppressing effects of the U.S. subsidies. However,
whether the demand or supply of Chinese cotton (or even sub-
sidies to Chinese producers) may have caused prices to fall was
properly treated as irrelevant by all panels and Appellate Body
decisions. By contrast, it would be relatively easy for a defending
[T]he clarifications provided by all five of the
subsidizing Member to defend against a price depression claim by Cotton decisions will allow the structuring
demonstrating that many non-subsidy factors caused prices to
and prosecution of the case in a more
fall. Similarly, a claim of price undercutting would require proof
that in particular transactions the actual prices of the subsidizing efficient and less-resource intensive manner
Member were lower than the prices of the complaining Member’s than Brazil was forced to endure as the first
producers. This requires evidence that could be very difficult to
obtain and would generally be highly confidential. Member to challenge these subsidies.

6 Business Law Brief | Fall/Winter 2009–2010


Implications of Cotton Decisions for Future Challenges to Finally, subsidies provided by the E.U. would also be vul-
U.S. and E.U. Agricultural Subsidy Programs nerable to serious prejudice challenges under the Cotton rationale.
There are a number of potential challenges to U.S. and E.U. For example, the E.U. provides a wide range of subsidies tied to
agricultural subsidy programs under WTO subsidy disciplines54 the production of E.U. processed dairy products. These include
that could be based on the strategic roadmap and legal precedent export refunds and disposal subsidies, single farm payments, as
of the Cotton dispute. A brief summary of certain examples of well as subsidies provided contingent upon the purchase and use
such potential claims is provided, infra.55 of E.U. dairy products.63 The collective impact of these subsidies
on world market prices is amplified because the E.U. is the larg-
Challenges to U.S. Annual Recurring Domestic est exporter of many commoditized dairy products. To the extent
Support Subsidies that these subsidies over the longer term have covered an impor-
The U.S. 2008 Farm Act56 largely maintained for a number tant portion of the total production costs of milk as well as pro-
of “program” crops representing the bulk of U.S. non-livestock cessed dairy products (and hence allowed producers to maintain
agriculture, include the same “price-contingent” marketing loan and not exit production), it is likely that viable serious prejudice
and counter-cyclical subsidies that were condemned in the Cot- claims could be sustained. Such claims under Article 6.3 of the
ton decisions. The Farm Act also continued the Direct Payment SCM Agreement could include significant price suppression in the
and crop insurance subsidies, and added a new subsidy program world market for butter, cheese, casein, skimmed milk powder,
(ACRE).57 As noted above, the original panel found that Brazil and displacement or impedance of market share of these same
had not sufficiently demonstrated a causal link between the products in various third country export markets.
Direct Payment58 and crop insurance subsidies59 and significant
price suppression.60 However, by employing the “long-term” cau- Challenges to Total Aggregate Measurement of Support
sation focus of the Cotton compliance panel and Appellate Body Another result of the Cotton case is to increase U.S. vul-
decisions, it will be possible under certain market circumstances nerability to challenges under Article 3.2 of the Agreement on
to make strong arguments that the collective effect of all of these Agriculture for failing to restrain the total amount of subsidies
subsidies — including the non-price contingent subsidies — is to provided in favor of U.S. domestic agricultural production to
cause serious prejudice in the world or in third country markets $19.1 billion of AMS. The Congressional Research Service,64
in violation of Article 6.3 of the SCM Agreement. as well as a WTO challenge by Brazil65 and Canada,66 provided
The viability of such claims will depend first on whether analysis suggesting that the inclusion of Direct Payments as
the prices of the particular commodity being challenged are low domestic support meant the United States was in violation for a
enough over some period of time to create payments of at least a number of years over the past decade of its $19.1 billion AMS
modest amount of marketing loan and counter-cyclical subsidies. limit contrary to Article 3.2 of the Agreement on Agriculture. If
Historically, commodity prices have fluctuated considerably and and when commodity prices fall, the United States will again be
if, and when, they do fall from generally current high levels, then vulnerable to future challenges regarding their total aggregate
there will be much larger U.S. marketing loan and counter-cycli- measurement of support.67
cal subsidies that can be challenged under the Cotton rationale.
For example, billions in marketing loan subsidies were provided Challenges to Prohibited Local Content Subsidies
when prices for soybeans fell in the period 2000-2001, and corn Both the U.S. and the E.U. presently provide subsidies to
prices collapsed in the 2005–2006 period.61 Another important processors of agricultural goods contingent de jure or de facto on
factor would be whether the collective amount of the subsidies the use of “local” (U.S. or E.U.) agricultural products. The Cot-
is necessary to cover at least some portion of the total cost of ton decisions confirmed that such local content subsidies (in the
production. Congressional Research Service analysis shows that form of the Step 2 subsidies to U.S. mill users of U.S. cotton)
U.S. subsidy programs have been essential for U.S. farmers of a are covered by the WTO subsidies disciplines. For example, the
number of different commodities to cover their total costs of pro- E.U. provides local content subsidies to E.U. purchasers or users
duction.62 This crucial fact, coupled with the large U.S. world of E.U.-produced skimmed milk, skimmed milk powder, cream,
market share of exports and production of a number of different butter and concentrated butter.68 The E.U. also provides subsi-
commodities, suggests that the U.S. will be vulnerable when dies to purchasers or users of butter and skimmed milk powder
prices fall for those commodities receiving significant domestic contingent upon these products being produced in the E.U.69
support. On the other hand, it will be more difficult to challenge Similarly, the U.S. sugar program requires the U.S. Government
the U.S. domestic support subsidies if over a 4–5 year period to make sugar marketing loan payments70 to sugar processors
prices have been so high that few price-contingent subsidies were contingent on the use of domestic U.S. sugar over imported
provided. goods.71 Under the Cotton decision rationale, all of these forms
of local content subsidies are contingent on the use of domestic

Business Law Brief | Fall/Winter 2009–2010 7


The Cotton decisions provide considerable Endnotes:
clarity to the Byzantine world of WTO Scott D. Andersen and Meredith A. Taylor
agricultural subsidy disciplines. As the first † Scott D. Andersen is a Managing Partner, Sidley Austin, LLP, Geneva, Swit-
decisions under the relatively vague and zerland. The views expressed herein are those of the author and should not be
attributed to Sidley Austin or any of its clients.
general actionable subsidy rules of the SCM ‡ Meredith Taylor is a PhD Candidate, WTO and International Trade Law,
University of Berne, Switzerland; Lecturer in Law and International Business,
Agreement, the decisions offer the analytical Boise State University, Idaho, U.S.A. The authors would like to give special
thanks to Dr. Geoffrey Black, Christian Lau, and Dr. Pietro Poretti, the reviewers
and evidentiary tools for government trade of this article, for taking the time to provide us with feedback and offer editorial
assistance.
officials and their counsel to assess the 1 The focus of this article is on the subsidies challenged by Brazil that provided
only support to upland cotton under both “serious prejudice” and “prohibited”
extent of the negative impact on trade from subsidy disciplines. An equally important aspect of the Cotton decisions that are
not covered by this Article are those relating to export credit guarantee programs
various forms of subsidies. for a number of different products, including cotton.
2 Panel Report, United States — Subsidies on Upland Cotton, WT/DS267/R
(Sept. 8, 2004) [hereinafter PR Cotton]. The decisions concerned upland cotton.
over imported goods, in violation of Article 3.1(b) of the SCM Upland cotton denotes raw upland cotton as well as its primary forms, including
upland cotton fibers and seeds.
Agreement. 3 This Article is intended for the non-WTO expert. For a detailed analysis of
the many procedural and substantive rulings arising from the five Cotton deci-
Conclusion sions during the 2004-2005 period, see Karen Halverson Cross, King Cotton,
Developing Countries and the ‘Peace Clause’: The WTO’s U.S. Cotton Subsidies
The Cotton decisions provide considerable clarity to the Decision, 9 J. Int’l Econ. L. 149 (2006). See generally David Palmeter & Petros
Byzantine world of WTO agricultural subsidy disciplines. As the C. Mavroidis, The WTO Legal System: Sources of Law, 92 Am. J. Int’l L. 398
(1998); Michael Cardwell & Christopher Rodgers, Reforming the WTO Legal
first decisions under the relatively vague and general actionable Order for Agricultural Trade: Issues for European Rural Policy in the Doha Round, 55
subsidy rules of the SCM Agreement, the decisions offer the ana- Int’l & Comp. L.Q. 805 (Oct. 2006) (discussing the broader implications of the
Cotton decisions).
lytical and evidentiary tools for government trade officials and 4 See PR Cotton, supra note 2 at ¶ 7.1108.
their counsel to assess the extent of the negative impact on trade 5 See id. at ¶¶ 7.1288-.1288 (stating that cotton prices plunged in 1999, 2001,
from various forms of subsidies. In the case of domestic cotton and 2002, with prices hitting record lows in the spring of 2002 at 29 cents per
subsidies, that impact is enormous — $2.9 billion in worldwide pound — far below the 20 year average price of 72 cents per pound); see id. at
¶¶ 7.1282-7.1283 (explaining that with record low prices, U.S. share of world
price suppressing effects on cotton each year. The export and market exports increased to 39.9 percent in 2002 and its world share production
local content prohibited subsidy aspects of the decision offer increased to 19.6 percent).
6 See generally Daniel A. Sumner, A Quantitative Simulation Analysis of the
the hope that such highly trade-distorting subsidies can be more
Impacts of U.S. Cotton Subsidies on Cotton Prices and Quantities, (Oct. 2003)
easily identified and successfully challenged in the future — or (unpublished paper, on file with the Department of Agricultural and Resource
simply eliminated by WTO Members seeking to avoid a dispute Economics, University of California, Davis), available at http://www.fao.org/es/
esc/common/ecg/306/en/sumner.pdf (“The analysis and results [of the study]...
settlement challenge. are consistent with a result that common sense and elemental notions of supply
The enormous trade distorting effects quantified by the and demand would compel: that very large subsidies provided to U.S. producers
and users of upland cotton have had and will continue to have large impacts on
most recent Cotton Arbitration decision have the additional quantities of U.S. cotton produced, used and traded and on both U.S. and world
significant benefit of supporting the Doha Round negotiating prices of cotton.”).
7
efforts to further limit the amount of trade distorting domestic The decisions discussed herein are grouped by the “original” Cotton proceed-
ings covering the period 2003-2005 in which the then-existing U.S. measures
support and eliminate entirely highly trade distorting export sub- were found to be WTO-inconsistent. The second phase of the proceedings was
sidies for agricultural products. These multilateral reform efforts comprised of the “compliance” proceedings over the period 2006-2008, in which
Brazil challenged U.S. claims that they had taken sufficient steps to imple-
are crucial to ensure long-lasting and comprehensive reform for ment the rules. The final phase was the determination by the Arbitrators of the
the most trade distorting forms of agricultural subsidies. The Cot- amount and type of retaliation that Brazil could impose against U.S. goods and
intellectual property for failing to sufficiently make its cotton-specific subsidies
ton decisions confirmed and established as a fact the wide-ranging WTO-compliant.
harm inflicted on many WTO Member agricultural producers 8 World Trade Organization, The Legal Texts: Results of the Uruguay

who struggle to compete with their heavily subsidized counter- Round of Multilateral Trade Negotiations 231 (Cambridge University
Press 1994) [hereinafter SCM] (referring to ANNEX 1A: The Agreement on Subsi-
parts in world markets. Based on these established wide-ranging dies and Countervailing Measures (SCM)).
trade distortions, the WTO Cotton decisions compel — and fully 9 As noted, the scope of this article does not permit a comprehensive analysis
support — a successful negotiated result that will alleviate the of all of the important procedural and substantive issues addressed in the more
than one thousand pages constituting the Cotton decisions, let alone the many
severe negative impacts of these highly trade-distorting subsidies. thousands of pages of submissions and exhibits by Brazil and the United States
BLB
and a number of third parties.

8 Business Law Brief | Fall/Winter 2009–2010


10 See SCM, supra note 8, at 232-33. These include prohibited export subsidies 29 Appellate Body Report, United States — Subsidies on Upland Cotton, ¶ 458,
and prohibited local content subsidies as set forth in Article 3.1(a) and (b) of the WT/DS267/AB/R (Mar. 3, 2005) [hereinafter ABR Cotton]. The original Appel-
SCM Agreement). See id. late Body had also criticized the original panel for failing to provide a “more
11 See SCM, supra note 8, at 235 (These various forms of “adverse effects” are set detailed explanation of its analysis of the complex facts and economic arguments
out in Articles 5 and 6 of the Subsidies Agreement. They include significant price arising in this dispute.” Id.
suppression and depression, significant lost sales, significant price undercutting, 30 See ABR Cotton 21.5, supra note 25, at ¶ 374.
displacement or impedance of market share of exports and imports in third coun- 31 It should be noted that the original Appellate Body indicated “it would be
try markets, an increase in the world market share of production, and material difficult to make a judgment on significant price suppression without taking into
injury to the domestic industry of another Member). account the effect of the subsidies.” ABR Cotton, supra note 29, at ¶ 433. Thus,
12 See PR Cotton, supra note 2, at ¶ 7.1108. the “but for” test arguably could require that the only cause of the relevant price
13 See PR Cotton, supra note 2, at ¶¶ 3.1(vi) – (viii), 3.2, 7.337. A key prelimi- suppression is the effect of the subsidies. Prices may well fluctuate up and down
nary threshold legal issue for Brazil’s serious prejudice claim was the so-called for various reasons. But it is only that portion of the restraint on price movements
‘peace clause’ issue, i.e. whether the U.S. had exceeded their 1992 domestic (which objectively can go either up or down) that is linked to the effects of the
support levels during each year of the 1999-2002 reference period. See id. at ¶¶ subsidies that is relevant.
7.1, 7.338 — 7.607. This was found and Brazil was, therefore, not barred from 32 The U.S. Step 2 program was a subsidy unique to cotton. Designed to provide
bringing the claim. See id. at ¶¶ 6.16, 7.608. The peace clause expired in 2004. a constant demand for uncompetitive U.S. cotton, the U.S. government paid
See id. domestic users and exporters of U.S. cotton the difference between the lower
14 See infra p. 4–5 and note 34 for a discussion of the Step 2 program. world market price and the higher U.S. domestic price. As a practical matter, the
15
subsidy enabled U.S. exporters of cotton to buy high-priced U.S. cotton in the
See PR Cotton, supra note 2 at ¶¶ 7.1290-7.1304. The panel was ultimately United States and sell it at a lower price on the export markets. Similarly, the U.S.
unable to find a clear causal link to Brazil’s particular price suppression for the Step 2 program enabled U.S. textile mills to buy higher-priced U.S. cotton, which
non-price contingent subsidies, i.e., Direct Payment, Production Flexibility carries the eligibility to receive Step 2 payments, instead of otherwise lower-priced
Contract Payments, Crop Insurance, and Cottonseed Payments. See id. at ¶¶ imported cotton that is not eligible for Step 2 support.
7.1305-7.1307 (This aspect of the original panel’s decision regarding non-price 33
contingent subsidies and dicta from the original Appellate Body is discussed, infra The “green box” is the working name given to the domestic support measures
p. 11-12, Lessons Learned for Future Litigations Section). falling within the provisions of Annex 2 of the Agreement on Agriculture.
34 In WTO dispute settlement proceedings, a “panel” is a three-person body
16 See PR Cotton, supra note 2 at ¶¶ 7.1255-7.1256 (“For the United States ‘sig-
nificant’ modifies ‘price suppression or depression’ and therefore, it is the effect on that functions as the initial trier of fact.  The “Appellate Body” in the WTO is a
prices that must be ‘significant’ and not the direct effect on producers. Such price standing body that is available, upon request by one of the litigating parties, to
suppression must be demonstrated in respect of Brazilian products alone.”). review questions of law raised by the panel decisions.  In the Cotton case, there
17
were separate panel and Appellate Body proceedings for both the “original” pro-
See PR Cotton, supra note 2 at ¶ 7.1353-7.1354 (asserting that “the U.S. ceedings determining Brazil’s original complaint covering the period 2003-
upland cotton producers would not have been economically capable of remaining 2005 and the 2006-2008 “compliance “ proceedings in which Brazil challenged
in the production of upland cotton had it not been for the United States subsidies the WTO-consistency of the implementation actions taken by the United States
and that the effect of the subsidies was to allow United States producers to sell of the original panel and Appellate Body rulings. A final phase was the 2008-2009
upland cotton at a price lower than would otherwise have been necessary to over Arbitrator proceedings in which the amount and type of suspension of conces-
total costs.”). sions by Brazil against the United States was determined. For a more detailed
18 See Panel Report, United States — Subsidies on Upland Cotton: Recourse to overview see, WTO Secretariat, A Handbook on the WTO Dispute Settlement
Article 21.5 of the DSU by Brazil, ¶ 10.75-10.83, WT/DS267/RW (Dec. 18, System 21-24 (Cambridge University Press) (2004) [hereinafter WTO Hand-
2007) [hereinafter PR Cotton 21.5] (marketing loans). book] (explaining the functions and composition of WTO panels and the Appel-
19 Id. at ¶¶ 10.90-10.103 (discussing counter-cyclical subsides). late Body).
20 35 See PR Cotton, supra note 2, ¶ 7.388. This was based on the finding that such
Id. at ¶ 10.110 (“The evidence before the Panel indicates that in MY 2005
the total amount of marketing loan payments to upland cotton producers and farmers could not receive the Direct Payments if they grew fruits and vegetables.
of counter-cyclical payments allocated to upland cotton was higher than in MY The original panel as affirmed by the Appellate Body rejected U.S. arguments that
2002. We also note that the amount of marketing loan payments and counter- Direct Payment subsidies were “decoupled” from current production as required
cyclical payments in MY 2005 is of the same order of magnitude as the total by Annex 2, paragraph 6(b) because of this “fruit and vegetable” prohibition. See
amount in MY 2002 of the price-contingent subsidies subject to the original’s id. at ¶¶ 7.364-7.388.
panel finding of ‘present’ serious prejudice.”). 36 Decision by the Arbitrator, United States — Subsidies on Upland Cotton:
21 Id. at ¶ 10.104. Recourse to Arbitration by the United States under Article 22.6 of the DSU and
22 Article 7.10 of the SCM Agreement, ¶ 6.1-.5, WT/DS267/ARB/2 (Aug. 31,
Id. at ¶ 10.104; see id. ¶ 10.103 (finding that “a strongly positive relation-
2009) [hereinafter Arbitrator’s Report, Cotton 7.10]. This estimated amount as
ship exists between recipients of upland cotton counter-cyclical payments who
declared publicly by Brazil reflects both the annual amount calculated for serious
hold upland cotton base acres and those who continue to plant upland cotton
prejudice as well as the export credit guarantee amount, which fluctuates on an
and that this factor is an element that provides support for a finding that the
annual basis.
counter-cyclical payments, because of their structure, design and operation, have
37 The Arbitrators also calculated simultaneously additional amounts of trade
price-suppressing effects.”).
23 damages from the U.S. refusal to stop providing prohibited export credit guaran-
Id. at ¶ 10.156.
tee subsidies supporting the export of billions in U.S. agricultural exports cover-
24 Id. at ¶ 10.104. ing a wide variety of agricultural products.
25 Appellate Body Report, United States — Subsidies on Upland Cotton: Recourse 38 See Arbitrator’s Report, Cotton 7.10, supra note 36, at ¶ 4.92.
to Article 21.5 of the DSU by Brazil, ¶ 447, WT/DS267/AB/RW (June 2, 2008) 39 See id. at ¶ 4.1-2, ¶ 4.64-66.
[hereinafter ABR Cotton 21.5]
40 See id. at ¶¶ 4.193-195, Annex 2.
26 Id. at ¶ 248.
41 Id. at ¶ 6.1.
27 Id. at ¶ 248.
42 It should be emphasized that there is no right to appeal decisions of the Arbi-
28 Id. at ¶ 356. See generally Sumner, supra note 6 (using the econometric simula-
trator under WTO rules. For this reason, there is a relatively weak precedential
tion model to demonstrate the significant impacts on U.S. and world cotton
effect of this, or any other Arbitrator’s decision on future Arbitrators. While the
prices that result from very large subsidies provided to U.S. cotton producers).
Arbitrators in Cotton did not take an expansive view of interests of the original
panel’s determination regarding the serious prejudice found to exist — significant
price suppression in the world market — this would not preclude arguments to
future arbitrators asking them to take a different position.

Business Law Brief | Fall/Winter 2009–2010 9


43 See Arbitrator’s Report, Cotton 7.10, supra note 36, at ¶ 4.193. 55 Each of the potential claims is far more complicated than the scope of this
44 E.g., Communiqué, The Cairns Group, The Cairns Group Ministerial Com- article can address or are suggested herein. The Authors offer their summary
muniqué (July 20, 2008), http://www.cairnsgroup.org/media/080720_com- conclusions as an illustration of the types of arguments and claims that could be
munique.html (“major subsidizers have provided….trade distorting support made using the Cotton jurisprudence while fully recognizing the complexity and
— effectively denying the opportunity for others, including low income produc- case-specific nature of each of the claims and defenses that would be applicable to
ers in developing countries, to enter the market.”). each of these potential challenges.
56 P.L. 110-234.
45 Brazil was forced to expend a considerable amount of resources in the original
proceedings to eventually succeed in securing vitally important data to allow the 57 Id. § 1105.
establishment of a peace clause violation. 58 Id. §§ 1101-09.
46 PR Cotton 21.5, supra note 18, at ¶¶ 10.83 (“In our view, the type of effect 59 Id. tit. XII.
of a subsidy on production relevant to the analysis under Article 6.3(c) can also 60
be demonstrated on the basis of a longer-term perspective that focuses on how See Bruce Babcock, Breaking the Link between Food and Biofuels, 14 Iowa Ag
the subsidy affects decisions of producers to enter or to exit a given industry.”), Review 1, 10 (2008), available at http://www.card.iastate.edu/iowa_ag_review/
10.176 (“Thus, it appears to us that the effect of the marketing loan and counter- summer_08/IAR.pdf (finding that the pattern of payments for Iowa corn proved
cyclical payments on cotton farmers’ production decisions could be best assessed “nearly identical to the situation for corn in other states and for wheat and soy-
on the basis of data covering the lifetime of the Act . . . This period of time is of beans in all states . . . [which] suggests that a large proportion of U.S. farmers will
sufficient length to require a medium to long-term analysis.”); see also ABR Cotton find ACRE much more attractive than current commodity programs.”).
61 See Press Release, American Soybean Association, American Soybean Associa-
21.5, supra note 25, at ¶ 422.
47 See PR Cotton, supra note 2, at ¶ 10.146 tion Urges Agriculture Secretary to Maintain Oilseed Loan Rates (Oct. 19,
48
2001) (on file with the American Soybean Association), available at http://www.
Brazil’s Appellant’s submission noted its disagreement with the original soygrowers.com/newsroom/releases/2001%20releases/Loan+RateOct192001.pdf;
panel’s finding that only price-contingent subsidies — but not Direct Payment, Alexei Barrionuevo, Mountains of Corn and a Sea of Farm Subsidies, N.Y. Times,
Crop Insurance, and Cottonseed payments — could be found to contribute to Nov. 9, 2005, at Business, available at http://www.nytimes.com/2005/11/09/
significant price suppression. In affirming the panel’s reliance on only the “price- business/09harvest.html?_r=1&pagewanted=print.
contingent” subsidies, the Appellate Body made the following statement: “We do 62
not exclude the possibility that challenged subsidies that are not ‘price-contingent’ Randy Schnepf & Jasper Womach, Potential Challenges to U.S. Farm Subsidies
(to use the panel’s term) could have some effect on production and exports and in the WTO: A Brief Overview, Congressional Research Service (Oct. 25, 2006).
63 See, e.g., Neil Merrett, Refunds Return as E.C. Reconsiders Dairy Intervention,
contribute to price suppression.” ABR Cotton 21.5, supra note 25, at ¶ 450, n.
589. This statement suggests that the Appellate Body may be receptive to the col- DairyReporter.com, Jan. 20, 2009, http://www.dairyreporter.com/Industry-
lective effect of subsidies “contributing to” production — such as crop insurance markets/Refunds-return-as-EC-reconsiders-dairy-intervention (reporting the
and direct payments — even if those subsidies are not linked to prices and implies reinstatement of dairy export refunds by the E.C.).
that future serious prejudice challenges to agricultural subsidies should not shy 64 See Schnepf & Womach, supra note 62, at 5, Table 2.
away from including non-price contingent subsidies in the mix of subsidies to be 65 Request for Consultation by Brazil, United States–Domestic Support and Export
challenged.
Credit Guarantees for Agricultural Products, WT/DS365/1 (July 17, 2007).
49 PR Cotton 21.5, supra note 18, at ¶¶ 10.83 (“In our view, the type of effect 66 Request for Consultation by Canada, United States–Subsidies and Other
of a subsidy on production relevant to the analysis under Article 6.3(c) can also
Domestic Support for Corn and Other Agricultural Products, WT/DS357/1 (Jan.
be demonstrated on the basis of a longer-term perspective that focuses on how
11, 2007).
the subsidy affects decisions of producers to enter or to exit a given industry.”),
67 See Schnepf & Womach, supra note 62, at 6.
10.176 (“Thus, it appears to us that the effect of the marketing loan and counter-
cyclical payments on cotton farmers’ production decisions could be best assessed 68 See Commission Regulation 1234/2007, Establishing a Common Organiza-
on the basis of data covering the lifetime of the Act . . . This period of time is of tion of Agricultural Markets and on Specific Provisions for Certain Agricultural
sufficient length to require a medium to long-term analysis.”). Products, 2007 O.J. (L 299). A number of provisions of the Single CMO
50 In this case, models were generated and testimony given by Dr. Daniel Sumner Regulation expose the EC to potential local content subsidy claims. They include
of the University of California, Davis. EC intervention purchases of butter and skimmed milk powder, id. art. 15,16,
51 EC storage subsidies for storage of butter, id. art. 28(a)(ii)-(iii), and EC disposal
ABR Cotton, supra note 29, at ¶ 448 (“We note that the Panel indicated
subsidies to the extent they are paid to processors of EC dairy products and not
expressly that it had taken the models in question into account. It would have
paid on the export of such products, id. Recitals 43, 60; art. 99-101 (describing
been helpful had the Panel revealed how it used these models in examining the
measures found in Recitals 43 and 60).
question of third country responses.”); ABR Cotton 21.5, supra note 25, at ¶ 348
69 See, e.g., id. art. 7, 10(1)(e), 10(1)(f ), 100(1) (providing provisions specifically
(“While the Panel appropriately examined the model, the parameters used by
each party, and the arguments made by the parties, and noted the different results indicating if milk or milk products are produced or originated “in the community”).
generated by the simulations conducted by each party, the Panel could have gone 70 Federal Agriculture Improvement and Reform Act of 1996, 7 U.S.C. § 7272
further in its evaluation and comparative analysis of the economic simulations (2008).
and the particular parameters used.”). 71 Agricultural Adjustment Act of 1938, 7 U.S.C. § 1359aa (2008). Similar to a
52 By contrast, a significant portion of Brazil’s briefing before the Cotton panels local content requirement, the current U.S. sugar program in the 2008 Farm Act
and Arbitrator was focused on justifying its econometric model and the various contains a requirement that the size of the overall marketing allotment equal 85
price and elasticity parameters used by that model. percent of U.S. human consumption of sugar. Id. This constitutes a minimum use
53 The Authors believe that this aspect of the Arbitrator’s decision was incorrectly requirement for domestic sugar, in violation of Article III of GATT 1994. See id.
decided and will elaborate on the reasons therefore in a future critique. § 1359bb.
54
This includes claims that could be asserted under Articles 3.1, 5 and 6 of the
SCM Agreement and the claims under Articles 3, 6, 7, 8, 9 and 10 of the Agree-
ment on Agriculture.

10 Business Law Brief | Fall/Winter 2009–2010

You might also like