Is Mining Good For Development?': The Intellectual History of An Unsettled Question

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 34

Progress in Development Studies 8, 2 (2008) pp.

129–62

Ã
‘Is mining good for development?’:
the intellectual history of an
unsettled question
Jeannette Graulau
Lehman College-The City University of New York

Abstract: The paper presents a general overview of the intellectual history of the question of mining
in the development field. It describes the leading development theories and their normative claims
with respect to mining, based upon the work of landmark theorists in the field. The contention of
this paper is that development theories, swinging like a pendulum back and forth with the question
‘Is mining good for development?’, have a troubled relationship with the question about mining.
The theories that embrace a positive view of capitalism in the classical political economy tradition
and mainstream development economics generally support mining for development. The theories
that are critical of the capitalist order, including structuralism, dependency, neodependency, world-
system, feminist and discourse theory, generally have a strong opposition to mining for development.
The unsettled question of mining shows that important questions about the relationship between
development and technology, and the equity requirements of such a relationship, remain unsettled in
the scholarship. The overarching goal of the paper is to provide initial ground upon which to discuss
the normative history of the topic of mining in the development scholarship.

Key Words: development scholarship, mining paradigms, normative history, structuralism

I Introduction was a ‘matter of chance’, or ‘immediate luck’,


Development theories have had a troubled as Mumford (1963) puts it, the issues of
relationship with mining. Business historians mineral discovery and the relationship with
Charles Harvey and Jon Press put it succinctly technological development were automatically
in the phrase ‘the problematic relationship excluded from the exercise of building economic
between mineral wealth and sustained eco- theories. They state:
nomic development’ (Harvey and Press,
1990: 2). There are three reasons for this One question which deserves much attention
is that of how and when resources are
problematic relationship. First, mining is seen,
discovered, and the pace of their subsequent
or was considered to be until very recently, exploitation. Most observers – including
independent from economic development. some eminent economists – have inclined
Harvey and Press (1990) state that because to the view that the discovery of workable
for most economists the discovery of minerals mineral reserves is largely a matter of chance,

© 2008 SAGE Publications 10.1177/146499340700800201


130 ‘Is mining good for development?’

and therefore not susceptible to economic is not a chronological description of the topic
analysis. Certainly, the folklore of mining of mining in development scholarship. Such a
contains many references to chance finds task would require several volumes and the
which triggered mining booms and brought
immense wealth to the lucky prospectors. To
collaboration of scholars, researchers, mineral
date, only a few writers have asserted that planners and governments across the globe.
the discovery of mineral deposits have been Rather, this overview seeks to describe the
economically determined – most notably evolution of the question of mineral resources
Geoffrey Blainey, who argues that discoveries in the most influential development theories.
have tended to coincide with the trough and The overarching goal is to provide solid ground
initial upswing of the business cycle, when upon which to build the normative history
there has been little alternative employment,
and cheap capital has been available to fund
of the topic of mining in the development
exploration (Harvey and Press, 1990: 2). scholarship.
The paper is divided in two sections.
Second, mining was considered to be a The first provides an overview of the major
phenomenon deeply and naturally rooted in works of classical political economy and their
the history of world empires. As Mumford relationship to the topic of mining. The second
states: section discusses the topic of mining in the
Apart from the lure of prospecting, no one leading works of the field of development
entered the mine in civilized states until re- economics, emphasizing the critical schools of
latively modern times except as a prisoner development. It describes today’s normative
of war, a criminal, a slave. Mining was not view favouring mining as built in the neoliberal
regarded as a humane art: it was a form of reforms of the last three decades. The paper
punishment: it combined the terrors of the
concludes with some observations about the
dungeon with the physical exacerbation of
the galley (Mumford, 1963: 67). normative history of the question of mining in
the development field.
Third, theorists of economic development
in the twentieth century who address the II Classical political economy and
topic of mining have not been able to build mining: a normative view of exclusion
a consistent normative view with respect to The tradition of the classical political economy
mining. This normative view has swung like a of the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries
pendulum from omission, to favouring, and to established a normative view of exclusion with
opposing mining. The study of the normative respect to mining. This tradition was interested
view of mining in the development field is in the topic of economic development of the
important because it shows the long-term Western world, and not that of the colonial
‘economic mentality’ of the field, as Özveren and overseas territories (Bhagwati and Eckaus,
elegantly puts it in his study of economic 1990). As such, the topic of mining and metal-
theories under the Ottoman Empire in the lurgy was not a central concern for the early
nineteenth century (Özveren in Psalidopoulos classical political economy thinkers.
and Mata, 2002: 142). The contention of this The philosophical foundations of this
paper is that development theories, swinging tradition are to be found in the works of
like a pendulum back and forth with the ques- Adam Smith, and included important British
tion ‘Is mining good for development?’, have economists such as John Stuart Mill, James
a troubled relationship with mining. The paper Mill and David Ricardo, and French ideologues
presents a general overview of the leading Jean Baptiste-Say, Augustin Cournot and
development theories and their normative Jules Dupuit, among others (Levy and Peart,
claims with respect to mining, based upon the 2005; Screpanti and Zamagni, 2005). In con-
landmark theorists in the field. This overview trast to their mercantilist predecessors, who

Progress in Development Studies 8, 2 (2008) pp. 129–62


Jeannette Graulau 131

promoted an economic nationalist viewpoint, intellectual being; an idea inherited from


classical economists attacked the role of Descartes’ corpuscular theory (Stark, 1943;
the State and embraced Smith’s notion of for Cartesian economics, see Pribram, 1983:
an invisible hand of free market under the 97–114). From Leibniz, Adam Smith inherited
policy of laissez faire (Adelman, 1999). Adam the definition of the problema philosophorum:
Smith was a close friend of philosopher David the question about the relationship between
Hume and a contemporary of Voltaire, Jean- the whole (society) and its parts (individuals)
Jacques Rousseau, François Quesnay and (Stark, 1943).
Robert-Jacques Turgot. His reputation is based Adam Smith did not write about mining or
upon the tremendous impact and influence metallurgy; however, he was not unaware of
of The Wealth of Nations (1776). The book the intellectual developments in the field. One
is devoted to investigating the nature and of his closest friends was Scottish geologist
causes of a nation’s prosperity. In this work, James Hutton (Stephen and Lee, 1949). In
Smith stated that the division of labour was a paper entitled Theory of the Earth, or an
the main cause of prosperity. His discussion on Investigation of the Laws Observable in the
individuals’ allocation of labour and resources Composition, Dissolution and Restoration of
based on rates of return; his explanation for Land upon the Globe (1785), Hutton developed
differentiated wage rates; his strong opposition
the theory of gradualism, or the view that
to mercantilism; and the role he assigned to
the Earth changed because of the work of
government in a free market economy (that
slow forces (Cutler, 2003). This work would
of provider of infrastructure and enforcer of
have a tremendous impact in the science
contracts, grant patents and copyrights to en-
of metallurgy, and it put Hutton in close
courage inventions) – all contained in the five
contact with Scottish philosophers of the
books that constitute The Wealth of Nations –
Enlightenment.
are considered the pillars of modern liberal
economic theory (Adelman, 1999). The specific linkage between Hutton’s
The ideas of Adam Smith reflect a and Adam Smith’s writings is a subject timidly
broader concern of the generation of classical explored by historians of political economy.
philosophers with the growth of industrial The book of John Rae, Life of Adam Smith,
capitalism in England, France and Germany, first published in 1895, seems to be the most
the uneven reappearance of mercantilism in complete source on the subject. In it, Rae
countries such as Germany, and the battle states that Hutton was one of Smith’s closest
against what Roll calls the ‘structure of mer- associates and literary executors during the
cantilist foreign trade policy’ (Roll, 1973: 149). latter part of Smith’s career at Edinburgh
Commenting on the importance of laissez faire (Rae, 1895, reprinted by Liberty Fund Inc.,
in the writings of Adam Smith, economist 1999–2005).
Jacob Viner says that ‘the one social issue on In the writings of John Locke, one can see
which Adam Smith was a zealot was the issue more clearly the normative view of exclusion
of freedom of trade vs. mercantilism’. Stark has of the topic of mining in classical political
described Smith’s work as the philosophical economy. In Two Treatises of Government
inquiry about ‘the intellectual clarity of man- (1689), Locke makes reference to precious
kind’, which would characterize classical metals and describes their usefulness. In Book
theorists starting with John Locke; a quest II, Chapter Five, Locke describes the intro-
that found its strongest explanatory power duction of metal coins into the state of nature,
in The Wealth of Nations (Stark, 1943: 16). which in his theory of the social contract refers
Stark states that Adam Smith inherited to the money economy. In Book II, Locke
from Locke the idea of the individual as an states:

Progress in Development Studies 8, 2 (2008) pp. 129–62


132 ‘Is mining good for development?’

This is certain that in the beginning, before accumulation (Adelman, 1999). This was
the desire of having more than men needed probably the case of mining activities in Central
had altered the intrinsic value of things, Europe, the Mediterranean and Spain by the
which depends only on their usefulness to the
life of a man, or had agreed that a little piece
seventeenth century. Mining and quarrying
of yellow metal, which would keep without relied upon building shafts and galleries, for
wasting or decay, should be worth a great which a variety of tools and techniques were
piece of flesh or a whole heap of corn, though used, even when they depended upon an abun-
men had a right to appropriate by their labour, dant supply of cheap labour (Singer et al.,
each one to himself, as much of the things of 1954–78).
nature as he could use, yet this could not be Interestingly, the idea of technical progress
much, nor to the prejudice of others, where
the same plenty was still left to those who
in mining was already developed in Europe. The
would use the same industry (Locke quoted classical political economy tradition emerged at
from Laslett, 1988). a time when works about mining, minerals and
geology appeared in the famous French and
Since the Earth was produced by the English encyclopaedias and dictionaries, such
‘spontaneous hand of Nature’, it was there to as the following: Encyclopédiea, ou Dictionnaire
satisfy humans’ needs. It is reasonable to infer Raisonné des Sciences, des Arts, et des Métiers,
from Locke that mining and metallurgy were by Denis Diderot (1751–80); Lexicon Technicum
the result of individuals’ work upon minerals or the Universal English Dictionary of Arts
and relations of barter. and Sciences, published in London in 1704 by
The amount of ground encompassed by Daniel Brown (and others); and the Universal
the classical political economy tradition cannot Dictionary of Arts and Sciences in two volumes
be covered in a single paper. It encompasses written by Ephraim Chambers (Horblit, 1964;
radically different historical periods that pro- Dibner, 1981). The Encyclopédiea by Diderot
vided the context for highly diverse theories of is considered the greatest encyclopaedia of
economic development. However, one of its science, and it covered all the aspects of the
central ideas, technical progress as the motor technology of metallurgy, mining and smelting
to create wealth, had important implications (Horblit, 1964). It also contained pictures of
for the normative view of exclusion of the mining technology. Of the Lexicon Technicum,
topic of mining. If the essence of capitalist Horblit states that it is the earliest modern en-
development lay in the accumulation of capital cyclopaedia of science, and contained several
and the increase in labour productivity, mining entries about mining, smelting and metallurgy
activities that are based upon increasing the (Horblit, 1964).
supply of a cheap labour force are not con- The most important works on the topic
ducive to wealth and development. The clas- of minerals and metallurgy, in particular De
sical political economy view maintained that Ortu et Causis Subterraneorum… De Natura
increase in labour productivity was mainly Fossilium (1546) and De Re Metallica (1556),
due to the incorporation of technological were written by German physician Georgius
innovations and to growing specialization. Agricola Bauer. These works are considered
Both allowed for an increase in income, the first handbook of modern systematic min-
and expanded the possibility of savings and eralogy, and the early standard treatise on
investment increases. Adelman states that the mining and metallurgy, respectively (Horblit
underlying idea of classical political economy 1964). The books contain pictures of machines
was in tune with the essence of capitalism: that pumping, ventilating, smelting, assaying, trans-
it was possible to expand the accumulation porting and hoisting equipment, and the
process, incorporate technical progress, and methods of his time (Dibner, 1981: 43–44).
utilize its ‘benefits’ for new processes of Agricola analysed mining and metallurgy in

Progress in Development Studies 8, 2 (2008) pp. 129–62


Jeannette Graulau 133

connection with diseases, the pharmaceutical armament and tools in Europe. Today, the
use of minerals and smelting products, and permanent exhibition of European military
labour and production. According to the Dic- tools at the Gallery of Arms and Armors
tionary of Scientific Biographies, Agricola was of the Philadelphia Museum of Art serves
heavily inspired by his journey to the mining to corroborate the importance of iron and
districts of Carinthia, Styria, and the Tyrol. The copper mining for the military and economic
mining district of Saint Joachimsthal (today development of Europe. An impressive col-
Jáchymov in the Czech Republic) became his lection of iron helmets, swords, horse armours,
town (Dictionary of Scientific Biographies, n.d.). elbow gauntlets, and processional crosses from
This was the most important mining centre of the mid-fourteenth century onwards bears
Europe. It was in Joachimsthal that the first witness to a flourishing science of mining and
labour markets appeared, when miners in metallurgy.
the fifteenth and sixteenth centuries offered The omission of the topic of mining in the
themselves to the people who owned the ma- early classical political economy tradition is
chines in the mines (Braudel, 1992). disconcerting, considering the development
Agricola’s work is unprecedented in that of what Dibner calls ‘renaissance engineering’
it linked mining with the social and economic (Dibner, 1981) and its application to extractive
aspects of development. It also came to be a economies in Europe. The information the
landmark in the scholarship of Subterranean books provide about technical progress in
Geometry, the Euclidean Geometry applied to mining indicates that mining was at the forefront
the building of shafts and mines that was the of technological development. Historian
common practice in Central Europe during the Lewis Mumford arrives at this conclusion
fourteenth, fifteenth and sixteenth centuries when commenting on the observations by
(Gamboa, 1761). Agricola in De Re Metallica about the modern
Another important work about mining improvements of mining. In his superb history
of technology entitled Technics and Civilization,
and smelting in Europe was that of Lazarus
Mumford states:
Ercker, entitled Beschreibung: Allerfürnemisten
Mkineralischen Ertzt Unnd Berckwercks Arten The great need of commercial enterprise
(1574). According to Dibner (1981), Ercker was in the fifteenth century was for a sound
but expansible currency, and for capital to
inspector-general of the mines of Hungary,
provide the necessary capital goods – boats,
Transylvania and the Tyrol, and his work is sec- mills, mine-shafts, docks, cranes-for industry.
ond only to Agricola in the number of original The mines of Europe began to supply this
contributions to the literature of mining and need even before the mines of Mexico and
metallurgy (Dibner, 1981: 44). Ercker’s book Peru. Sombart calculates that in the XV and
was so important in the field that it became a XVI centuries German mining earned as
much in ten years as trade in the old style was
textbook in the late 1500s (Dibner, 1981).
able to accomplish in a hundred. As two of
Another book that exercised great influence the greatest fortunes of modern times have
in the ideas of technical progress in mining was been founded upon monopolies of petroleum
Le Diverse Et Artificiose Machine (1588) by and aluminum, so the great fortune of the
Agostino Ramelli. Ramelli was a captain of Fuggers in the XVI century was founded
engineers to the kings of France and Poland. upon the silver and lead mines of Styria and
the Tyrol and Spain (Mumford, 1963: 75).
He prepared this book to show the uses of
logging mills, metal-working machines, pumps For historian Fernand Braudel, mining
and other machines (Dibner, 1981: 80). The was also responsible for the origins of labour
machines described in Ramelli’s work played markets in Europe. In Central Europe, Braudel
a crucial role in the development of military gives accounts of how miners had to offer

Progress in Development Studies 8, 2 (2008) pp. 129–62


134 ‘Is mining good for development?’

themselves to the people with machines in criarse prácticos de Ciencias’ (Gamboa, 1761:
the mines, and became among the first wage 232). Gamboa refers to the letter that Madame
earners of Europe in the fifteenth and sixteenth de Beau oleil sent to Cardinal of Richelieu, to
centuries (Braudel, 1992). Moreover, mining describe the scientific knowledge that mining
was also at the centre of the development requires. Gamboa adds: ‘Re titucion de Plutòn
of foreign exchange bursars (Braudel, 1992). dirigida al Cardenal de Richelieu, [Madame de
Braudel narrates the history of exchange Beau oleil] pide en el Gefe, y Director de Minas
bursars in the late sixteenth century, and el conjunto de muchas Ciencias. La A trologìa,
asserts that they could only function if sufficient para conocer los temperamentos. Arquitectura,
silver from American territories reached Genoa Geometrìa, Arithmetica, Per pectiva, Pintura,
(Braudel, 1992). The development of fairs in la Hydraulica, y otras, que largamente expre a’
the Spanish-American territories, such as the (The letter pleading for the restitution of Pluto,
Nombre de Dios, was also linked to mining. directed to the cardinal of Richelieu, asks that
They were modelled after the European fairs, the Director of Mines be instructed in several
and served as places for exchanging minerals sciences. Astrology, for the knowledge of
(mostly silver) for European goods (Braudel, temperaments, Architecture, Geometry, Arith-
1992). Indeed, the mineral legal tradition of metic, Perspective, Drawing, and Hydraulic
the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries in Sciences, and the other sciences that are exten-
the Spanish-American territories was inspired sively described in the restitution.) (Gamboa,
from the classic European treatises about 1761: 232).
metallurgy. The citation from Madame de Beau oleil’s
In Comentarios a las Ordenanzas de Minas, letter reveals that mining and metallurgy had
Dedicados al Catholico Rey, Don Francisco established themselves as part of the sciences
Xavier Gamboa, lawyer of the Real Audiencia of the Enlightenment. Their importance in
of Mexico, describes the importance of several Europe is also evidenced by the French editions
European treatises about metallurgy, in of mining treatises during the eighteenth
particular the German scholarship represented century. For example, the French Royal Aca-
in the following works: Vom Markscheiden demy of Science translated and published
Kurzer und Gründlicher Unterricht by Era mus in 1750–53 and 1753–64 the book entitled
Reinhold (1574); Berg Informasion by Abr. à Grundlicher Unterricht von Hütte-Werken…
S’choremberg (1693); Balthan Roe ler by Berg- nebst einer vollständigen Probier-Buch, daren
ban-Spiegel (n.d.); Markscheidekun t by Nicol enthalten wie allerley. Ertze auf alle Metalle zu
Voigtel (1686); and Gründlicher und Deutlicher probieren… by Christophe A. Schlüter (1738).
Begriff Vom Berg-ban S’chmelzwe en, und Molloy cites C.S. Smith in his description of
Markscheiden by Joa Gottfried Jugel (1744), Schlüter’s book as ‘one of the most important
among others (Gamboa, 1761: 246–73). works on assaying and metallurgy to appear
Gamboa also acknowledges the contribution since Ercker’ (Molloy, 1986: 176).
of Latin scholarship on mining, in particular the Mumford has an explanation for the im-
works of San I idoro, Po sidonio, Diodoro de portant role that mining and metallurgy played
Sicilia, Polibio, Strabòn, Plinio, Cardano and in Europe during the eighteenth and nineteenth
Caryophilo (Gamboa, 1761).1 centuries. He states that it was the mining of
Gamboa’s work is pertinent because it puts precious metals in previous centuries that gave
mining and metallurgy within the context of rise to new technologies for the transportation
the scientific revolutions of the Enlightenment; and processing of metals during the eighteenth
in his words, ‘En cada Real de Minas deben and nineteenth centuries. Mumford states:

Progress in Development Studies 8, 2 (2008) pp. 129–62


Jeannette Graulau 135

The use of the rare metals and the metallic Iron and Steel, Iron Ores and Fuels by Thomas
earths is another characteristic advance of Bayley (1884), and Assaying (two volumes) by
this phase: tantalum, tungsten, thorium, and Charles H. Aaron (1885), among others.
cerium in lamps, iridium and platinum in mech-
anical contact points – the tips of fountain
The titles show a deeper inquiry into the
pens or the attachments in removable institutionalization of science, the application of
dentures – and of nickel, vanadium, tungsten, scientific knowledge to mining, and the utility
manganese, and chromium in steel. (…) As a of mining. Important schools of geology were
result of systematic experiment in metallurgy established during the nineteenth century,
a revolution took place here comparable to such as the following: Société Géologique de
that which was involved in the change from France (1830), École Nationale Supérieure
the steam-engine to the dynamo. For the rare
metals now have a special place in industry
des Mines (1816), the Geological Society of
(…) (Mumford, 1963: 231). London (1807), the Royal School of Mines
(1851), and the Bergakademie Freiberg (which
Mumford is referring to the Industrial established the first fellowship for students of
Revolution. This period produced an extra-
mining and assaying, or the Stipendienkasse in
ordinary amount of work about assaying,
1702), which had attracted foreign students
mining, metallurgic chemistry, and the pro-
since the early eighteenth century, and where
specting of minerals throughout Europe, as
Alexander von Humboldt was permitted to
revealed in Molloy’s The History of Metal Mining
study in 1790.
and Metallurgy: An Annotated Bibligoraphy
These concerns were ignored by the classical
(1986). Molloy lists two editions of Johann A.
political economy tradition. Preoccupied with
Cramer’s Elements of the Art of Assaying Metals
the philosophical foundations of free trade,
(1741), which were published in London in 1741
the classical political economy tradition left the
and 1764 (Molloy, 1986: 172). John Budge’s
The Practical Miner’s Guide…Also a Treatise question of mining mainly in the hands of the
on the Art and Practice of Assaying Silver, German scholarship on mining and metallurgy.
Copper, Lead and Tin… was published in three The omission of the topic of mining in the
editions between 1825 and 1854 (Molloy, 1986: British classical political economy tradition
172). The work of Christlieb E. Gellert was brings to mind the metaphor that Braudel uses
translated as Metallurgic Chemistry and pub- to describe the two sides of historical change:
lished in London in 1776 (Molloy, 1986: 173). the conspicuous and the submerged (Braudel,
The mining literature of the nineteenth 1987). It seems that the intellectual circles
century would be concerned with the economic of Great Britain were more concerned with
aspects of mining, as in An Historical Inquiry the ‘conspicuous’ changes of the Industrial
into the Production and Consumption of the Revolution – trade and economic relations be-
Precious Metals by William Jacob (1831), tween nations – while those of Germany were
which, according to Molloy, was published more concerned with its ‘submerged’ changes –
in Philadelphia in 1832 (Molloy, 1982: 152). the centuries of innovation and technological
This period would also be concerned with development in mining and metallurgy in Cen-
the techniques for assaying precious metals, tral Europe.
as indicated in the following titles: Manuel de As the international trade in raw ma-
l’essayeur by Louis N. Vauquelin (1799), A terials increased in the nineteenth century,
Practical Handbook for Miners, Metallurgists, the classical political economy tradition
and Assayers by Julius Silversmith (1866), addressed the topic of mining. The normative
Sulphurets; What They Are, How Concentrated, view of exclusion of mining would change
How Assayed, and How Worked… by William with the tradition initiated by the works of
Barstow (1867), The Assay and Analysis of David Ricardo. The next section discusses

Progress in Development Studies 8, 2 (2008) pp. 129–62


136 ‘Is mining good for development?’

the emergence of a normative view favouring and Thomas Hodgskin; Alfred Marshall and
mining in the development scholarship. his influential Principles of Economics (1890);
and the population theory of Robert Malthus
III The pendulum swings: from a (Stark, 1943; Cairnes in Spiegel, 1952: 227;
normative view favouring mining Roll, 1973). Second, as Viner states, British
to one opposing mining classical political economy was bound up with
English politics, the dominant power in global
1 Mainstream development economics: ‘mining politics (Viner in Speigel, 1952: 719). As part of
is good for development’ the legacy of what historian Hobsbawm (1987)
The topic of minerals and mining was going to calls ‘the age of empire’, British literature en-
be addressed, if not explicitly, then indirectly, joyed a central place in the nineteenth-century
by British economist David Ricardo. Among intellectual history of development.2
his most important works was Principles of In the 1930s, economists Eli Heckscher
Political Economy and Taxation (1817), where and Bertil Gotthard Ohlin redefined Ricardo’s
he developed the theory of comparative ad- theory of comparative advantage. According
vantages, from which a new justification for to The Concise Encyclopedia of Economics,
international free trade emerged. It stated Heckscher’s and Ohlin’s work showed that
that every country had an ability to find a par- goods can move more easily than their factors
ticular good it could produce at a lower cost of production (Liberty Fund Inc., 1999-
relative to other goods, or its comparative ad- 2006). Principally, Ohlin’s work concluded
vantage (Screpanti and Zamagni, 2005). The that a country should export commodities
exportation of such a good in exchange for for which there are relatively abundant
other goods would result in welfare increases domestic production factors. The export of
for every country, given that countries produce such commodities was the comparative ad-
and export those commodities they can pro- vantage of the country (see also Screpanti and
duce more efficiently. Ricardo assumed that Zamagni, 2005).
as long as the cost ratios differ among coun- The idea of comparative advantages
tries in the absence of trade, every country was used to justify the specialization of
has a comparative advantage (Screpanti and European colonial territories in mining and
Zamagni, 2005). extractive products (Furtado, 1982). Today,
The ideas of David Ricardo would dominate there is abundant scholarship on the topic
the intellectual debates about international of comparative advantages in mining (see,
trade and development in Great Britain over for example, for the comparative advant-
the next century. In the first place, his works age of the copper industry in the US, Aydin
provided rigorous theoretical and mathemat- and Tilton, 2000; for copper in Chile, García
ical explanations that would capture the et al., 2001; for mining technology, Porter and
economic mentality of the period: labour as a Cunningham, 2005).
factor of production, the impact of machinery The concern with the international trade of
in production, wages, surplus product, value minerals and raw materials became a common
and distribution (Roll, 1973). This was the theme of the development literature that was
era of the ‘Radical Reformers’ John Stuart born in the inter-war period (1915–38). Arndt
Mill and Jeremy Bentham; the Sophismes finds that many studies specialized in world
Économiques of Frédéric Bastiat in France, commodity trade. He writes:
whom Cairnes called ‘a generous defender World commodity problems were of interest
of English policy’; the socialism of Robert as part of the wider problem of economic
Owen, Fourier and Saint-Simon; the Ricardian stability; Brazil, Malaya, West Africa and the
socialists Charles Hall, William Thompson East Indies were studied, because and to the

Progress in Development Studies 8, 2 (2008) pp. 129–62


Jeannette Graulau 137

extent that they were exporters of coffee, instruments in Western Europe. Historians
rubber, cocoa, and sugar and as such part of have shown how the lines of credit of Charles
the international trading system (Arndt in V with bankers from Augsburg, Genoa and
Bhagwati and Eckaus, 1973: 19).
Antwerp were sustained with precious metals
Since economists of the period were not from the Americas, or, as Henry Kamen states,
concerned with the topic of underdevelop- with ‘the promise of their arrival’ (Kamen,
ment,3,4 mining was not explicitly discussed 2004: 88):
in connection to national economic growth. The Bankers, in turn, set up or expanded their
This was part of the normative view of the operations in Seville and the rest of Castile,
scholarship of the period, for which the eco- in order to have direct access to their profit.
nomic growth of colonial territories was not This meant, inevitably, that a high proportion
an important concern. As a case in point, of the gold and silver from America became
economist Eugene Staley, in a report on raw pledged to foreign bankers, often years in
advance. Charles, obviously, used that part
materials and markets prepared for the Inter-
of the precious metals he was entitled to, the
national Studies Conference of 1937, states: ‘fifth’ levied as a tax on all mine production in
The importance of colonies to their present America. But from 1523, and more frequently
possessors as sources of raw materials or as from 1535, he also began to ‘borrow’ (that is,
markets has usually been grossly overrated seize as involuntary loans) shipments that
(Staley, 1937: 7). came for the Castilian merchants of Seville.
The latter complained bitterly in 1536 that
In a footnote, Staley mentions some influ- this effectively gave the advantage to for-
ential scholars who inspired such a line of eign merchants: ‘they control all the money’
thinking: (Kamen, 2004: 88-89).

We are in agreement on this point with Sir The development of industrial capital
Norman Angell (Raw Materials, Population in Western Europe and the United States
Pressure, and War), and with the study recently during the eighteenth to the early twentieth
published by the Carnegie Endowment in the centuries intensified and expanded the mineral
United States (Grover Clark, The Balance
Sheets of Imperialism), as well as with the
commodity trades with former European
United Kingdom Memorandum No. I, which colonial territories of the developing world
concludes that ‘In fact, the problem of access (see, for example, Prebisch, 1949; Coquery-
could never be sold by transfer of territory Vidrovitch, 2002).
unless whole continents were transferred; In the second place, the experience of World
the only real possibility of improvement War I (and later World War II) had brought to
lies in a greater freedom of trade’ (Staley, the field two novel concerns that would impact
1937: 7).
ideas about mining: war economics and peace
Instead, the topic of mining was addressed economics. As Staley puts it, raw materials
by mainstream scholarship in its concerns were studied in connection with ‘the aims,
with international trade. One can infer several methods and needs of war economy on the
reasons for the interest in mining in relation one hand, and of peace economy on the other’
to international trade. In the first place, the (Staley, 1937: 19; See also Redmayne, 1923;
history of mineral commodity markets from the Clark, 1932; Rawles, 1933; Emeny and Ely,
fifteenth to the eighteenth centuries showed 1934; Mendershausen, 1941; Holmes, 1942).
that these were the most profitable commodity This scholarship addressed the topic of minerals
trades operating over enormous distances and mining in connection with the needs of the
(Arndt in Bhagwati and Eckaus, 1973). In fact, ‘war economics’ of developed countries. As
these trades were so profitable that they had a such, minerals and mining in colonial territories
profound impact in the development of credit and developing countries were studied as part

Progress in Development Studies 8, 2 (2008) pp. 129–62


138 ‘Is mining good for development?’

of the international relations of developed international institutions reflected the idea that
countries. This idea is well-illustrated in the underdevelopment was caused by a deficiency
following quotation from Military Geology and in capital (Adelman, 1999). This notion came
Topography: A Presentation of Certain Phases of out of the many rich debates about under-
Geology, Geography and Topography for Military development that were taking place at the time,
Purposes: mainly in the field of economics. Multilateral
Our dependence upon minerals is even
and bilateral aid programmes concentrated on
greater in times of war. No nation could hope providing the loans to be used for domestic
to carry on war under present conditions investments on concessionary terms and fi-
without abundant resources of certain nancing large infrastructure works (almost
essential mineral materials. The lack or exclusively in transport and energy). The idea
the insufficient supply of certain metals behind the programmes was creating economic
would inevitably bring disaster. One thinks growth based on a ‘big push’ of simultaneous
first of iron and steel, coal, copper, and
investments that would generate rapid and
the nitrates and sulphur used in making
munitions, yet equally necessary is mica self-sustained growth (Rosenstein-Rodan,
for wireless and other electrical insulation 1961). The ‘big push’ was to be achieved
work; tungsten, vanadium, chromium, through private enterprise and the market
and manganese, necessary in making steel; economy. Adler states that private enterprise
platinum, necessary for chemical work in became the dogmatic preference of the World
the manufacture of munitions; graphite, Bank, ‘the single most important component
necessary for crucibles used to produce
of the Bank’s development “philososophy”’
brass, crucible steel, and various alloys; and
antimony to harden bullets. Consequently (Adler in Bhagwati and Eckaus, 1973: 34).
the military uses of minerals, the location This ‘dogmatic preference’ was going to have
of their deposits, the amounts available, a profound impact in shaping an anti-normative
the difficulties of their transportation, the view about mining later on.
possible development of substitutes if the Probably the most influential work of the
supply is deficient — all these are vitally im- dominant development economics tradition
portant subjects of study at the present time
was Walter W. Rostow’s Stages of Economic
(Gregory, 1918: 253).
Growth: A Non-Communist Manifesto (1960).
Mining would be studied in connection Based on the discussion of the ‘preconditions
with underdevelopment in the scholarship of to take off ’ in this work, one can infer this trad-
development economics that emerged during ition’s normative views on mining. He states:
the post-war period, particularly in the critical
And, above all, the concept must be spread
schools of development. that man need not regard his physical
environment as virtually a factor given by
Post-war period The field of development nature and providence, but as an ordered
during the post-war period was dominated world which, if rationally understood, can be
by scholars reviving classical economics (see, manipulated in ways which yield productive
for example, Nurkse, 1953; Lewis, 1955; change and, in one dimension at least, pro-
Hahn, 1960; Meade, 1961; Rosenstein- gress. All this and more is involved in the
passage of a traditional to a modern growing
Rodan, 1961; Solow, 1970; Hirschman, 1971; society (Rostow, 1962: 19).
Firestone, 1972). Theories about ‘disguised
unemployment’, ‘balanced growth’, and Rostow adds that the general requirement
‘demonstration effect’ prepared the context is to ‘apply quick-yielding changes in pro-
for the policies of development of the World ductivity’ to ‘natural productive resources’;
Bank and the International Monetary Fund.5 and to achieve this, ‘capital imports can
According to Adelman, the charter of the help, of course, but in the end, loans must be

Progress in Development Studies 8, 2 (2008) pp. 129–62


Jeannette Graulau 139

serviced; and the servicing of loans requires devoted a vast amount of work to analysing
enlarged exports’ (Rostow, 1962: 22). In this the impact of Latin American structuralism
view, mining is a sector capable of attracting on US social science thinking and academia.
international finance (investments and loans). (For an overview, see, for example, Haberler,
This presupposes opening the mining sector 1957; Aronowitz, 1979; Almond, 1990;
to foreign capital. Only in this way could Packenham, 1992). No other development
traditional societies transform their natural paradigm gained such wide attention from
productive resources into their comparative mainstream development theorists as Latin
advantage (Rostow, 1962). American structuralism and its descendant,
This view of mining was going to be con- the dependency movement – a criticism
tested by Latin American structuralism and that involved an attack on ECLA’s policies
the dependency movement. Latin American and from where Gabriel Palma reminds us
structuralism plays a central role in the that ECLA gained the pejorative name the
intellectual and social history of development. ‘Trojan horse of Marxism’ (Palma, 1978). This
First, the ideas of Raúl Prebisch, the father furious attention to and surveillance of the
of Latin American structuralism, provided new economic mentality of Latin American
the founding principles for establishing, in structuralism on the part of mainstream clas-
1964, the United Nations Conference on sical theorists probably occurred because,
Trade and Development (UNCTAD) – as Copper prudently reminds us, Smith and
of which Raúl Prebisch became its first Ricardo were the ancestors of structuralism –
Secretary-General. The goal of UNCTAD ‘a pedigree which the dependency theorists do
today is inspired by Prebisch’s structuralist not claim’ (Copper, 1981: 9).
analysis: to study, in the words of former With the development of Latin American
Secretary-General Rubens Ricupeiro, the structuralism, the topic of mining would be
‘systematic biases and asymmetries that addressed like never before in the field of
impede trade and development prospects development. The importance of structuralism
in poorer countries’ (Ricupeiro, 2002). The
for the question of mining in development
prominent and distinguished career of the
scholarship deserves to be discussed at length
Argentinean economist also put him right in
in the next section.
the direction of the United Nations Economic
Commission for Latin America (For more on
2 Critical development economics: ‘mining is
the life of Prebisch, see Iglesias, 1994; Malan,
bad for development’
et al., 1999; Ricupeiro, 2004).6 Second, critical
ECLA, structuralism and the dependency move-
development theories were influenced by
ment With the advent of the international
the Latin American structrualist debate.
crisis triggered by the Great Depression and
According to Africanist scholar Frederick
World War II, many social scientists questioned
Copper, by the time ‘Africanists were jump-
whether the integration of Latin American
ing on the bandwagon of underdevelop-
ment and world system theories, many Latin economies into the international markets
Americanists were getting off …’ (Copper, benefited these countries, as the theory of
1981: 10; see also Bello, 2002). Third, Latin comparative advantages proclaimed.7 By the
American structuralism was at the core of late 1940s, and as a response to the crisis, a
the intellectual debates between the Centro current of thought appeared, which claimed
de Estudios Económicos (Chile), the Fernand that the theoretical stream of comparative
Braudel Center (US), and the Samir Amin advantages corresponded to the needs and
group in Africa (Entrevista a Theotônio Dos characteristics of the expansion of capitalism
Santos, n.d.). Fourth, mainstream theorists in the last quarter of the nineteenth century,

Progress in Development Studies 8, 2 (2008) pp. 129–62


140 ‘Is mining good for development?’

up to the mid-twentieth century. It saw for primary product exporters in the 1920s, and
the economic constraints of non-industrial despite the slight recovery the data showed for
countries as structural failures of the export- the 1930s, he concludes that primary resource
oriented model of economic growth. It was exporting countries, such as Argentina, had
going to be known as structuralism, and its to export an increasing amount of raw ma-
leading figure was Argentinean economist terial products in order to continue importing
Raúl Prebisch. His work formed the working the same amount of industrial commodities
agenda, research goals, theoretical ambitions, (Ffrench-Davis and Tironi, 1982). Prebisch
and intellectual pillars of the newly-created concludes that countries specializing in primary
Economic Commission for Latin America products could never expect to follow a path
(ECLA) (Bielschowsky, in Malan, et al., 1999). of export-led growth.8
Raúl Prebisch’s work created a major Prebisch’s work was a radical departure
revolution within the prevailing economic from evolutionist international trade theories,
thinking represented in the classical economic which maintained that the international
view of international trade based on Ricardo’s division of labour worked to the mutual benefit
doctrine of comparative advantages. Prebisch’s of centre and peripheral countries as they
seminal essay, El Desarrollo Económico de la enjoyed comparative advantages in different
América Latina y Algunos de sus Principales areas. Bielschowsky elegantly describes
Problemas, analysed the economic growth and Prebisch’s importance in the following words:
development of Latin America as a structural ‘Prebisch e ousadia intelectual são sinônimos
problem of the specialization of the ‘periphery’ na América Latina’(‘Prebisch is the synomym
in raw materials and the industrial centres in of intellectual courage in Latin America.’)
manufactures within the context of unequal (Bielschowsky, in Malan, et al., 1999).
international trade relationships. Bielschowsky Kay observes that Prebisch’s terms-of-
comments that Prebisch employed the trade thesis was consonant with the findings of
term ‘periphery’ in his writings prior to his another United Nations functionary, Hans W.
appointment as ECLA’s Executive Director, Singer, who, working independently in the UN’s
to emphasize the vulnerability of Latin New York office, found statistical evidence to
American countries to the economic cycles support the idea of declining terms of trade for
of the international economy (Bielschowsky, primary products (Singer, 1950). The thesis
in Malan, et al., 1999: 124). Prebisch argued on the deterioration of commodity terms of
that the international division of labour, based trade is known in development literature as
on comparative advantages, operated to the Prebisch-Singer thesis (Kay, 1989). These
the detriment of the countries specializing ideas provided the first generation of ECLA
in the production of agricultural and mineral intellectuals with conceptual, analytical,
commodities because of an inherent tendency theoretical and ideological referents for
towards diminishing terms of trade for raw understanding the Latin American experience
material exports (Prebisch, 1949). (Ffrench-Davis and Tironi, 1989). It also
Primarily seeking responses to Argentina’s established the landmarks for the anti-mining
balance of payments problems, Prebisch intellectual, research and policy tradition of
studied British trade data for the period 1876- development economics (Davis, 1995).9
1947 under the suspicion that there was a long-
term tendency for prices of primary products Dependency theory Following the inductive
(the periphery’s exports) to deteriorate re- method, contrary to Rostow’s modernization
lative to the prices of manufactured goods theory which followed the deductive method,
(the centre’s exports) (Davis, 1995). After the historical-structural approach of the
observing a sharp drop in the terms of trade new school of thought used the theoretical

Progress in Development Studies 8, 2 (2008) pp. 129–62


Jeannette Graulau 141

concepts of Prebisch’s writings, in particular be greatly prolonged through institutional


‘periphery’ and ‘centre’ (for more on the obstacles (Furtado, 1970: 92–93).
method of structuralism, see Bath and James, He stated that underdevelopment, con-
1976; Bielschowsky, in Malan, et al., 1990: trary to what classical economists argued,
116–21). was not a phase of the development process,
Among the leading figures of the new de- because such ‘a phase would be overcome if
pendency movement was Brazilian economist certain factors of production came into play’
Celso Furtado. Drawing on Prebisch’s concepts, (Furtado, 1970: xvi). The origins of underde-
Furtado argued in his early writings that the velopment are to be found in the differentiated
classical international division of labour, which distribution and diffusion of the technical
confined the periphery to the production of progress commanded by the Industrial Re-
raw materials and the centre to the production volution. Under this historical process, the
of industrial goods, perpetuated the process economy of the periphery evolved in a dis-
and condition of underdevelopment of the articulated and dualistic way, and had as its
periphery (Furtado, 1961, 1970, 1982). In his main distinguishing feature the existence of
book Obstacles to Development in Latin America what Furtado called a ‘pre-capitalist sector’.
(Furtado, 1970), Furtado advocates strong Its disarticulated character resulted from the
government intervention to enhance industrial fact that these countries imported advanced
capacities for the production of manufactures, technology from industrial centres, borrowed
and to foment in this way a growth pattern heavily to raise their basic social capital (that
through the domestic markets. He argues that is, roads, ports, railroads, infrastructure),
the transformation of industry into the most most of which concentrated along the export
dynamic economic sector through a process of activities, had a restricted state apparatus
substitution for imports would lead to a higher based upon rigid, oligarchic land-ownership
rate of economic growth than that achieved structures and political loyalties (Furtado,
by the export agricultural and mineral sectors. 1961). Its dualistic character was in response
He defines the process of import substitution to the gap in productivity that developed
as follows: between the export agricultural and mineral
sectors and the subsistence sectors (Furtado,
It is, in reality, a process of change in the 1970). The dualism was more evident and
productive structure, allowing a reduction in stronger in mineral-export countries, given
the share of imports of the aggregate supply
the external character of the factors explaining
without reversion of labor to precapitalist
economy. The import of certain goods is
the integration of Latin America to the
reduced, or eliminated; other goods are world mineral trade. Imports of capital, the
substituted in the domestic market by local introduction of new techniques of production
products, while the imports of those items and organization based on the technical
that are hard to substitute are enlarged. know-how of the industrial centres, and the
Since per capita income is increasing and creation of external economies through the
the coefficient of imports is diminishing, the construction of roads, installation of ports,
composition of aggregate demand tends
railroads and urban public services facilitated
to change, requiring greater alterations
in the structure of aggregate supply than
the expansion and concentration of foreign
those foreseen at the beginning of the sub- economic power in the mineral sector at the
stitution process. The period of time re- expense of the development of the national
quired for aggregate supply to adapt to the economy.
modifications in the pattern of demand is a In Furtado’s view, mineral and agricultural
primary force responsible for the creation export sectors impeded the formation of
of infl ationary pressures. This period can strong domestic markets for goods and

Progress in Development Studies 8, 2 (2008) pp. 129–62


142 ‘Is mining good for development?’

services (Furtado, 1961, 1970). The fact that For Dos Santos, the process of the inte-
mining, unlike agriculture, concentrated its gration of Latin American economies into
export activities in geographically isolated world markets was fuelled and channelled
areas further deepened the dualism between through US monopolist capital (Dos Santos,
centre and periphery. More importantly, 1969). Until the 1940s, foreign monopolist
the development of mining required heavy capital was concentrated in agricultural and
investments, and the remuneration of the mineral export sectors. After the end of
labour force could not be obtained from the World War II, monopolist capital had changed
lands incorporated into mining activities (in its sector of production, and expanded to
contrast to agriculture, where the principal manufacturing and other industrial sectors
part of the remuneration of the labour force (Dos Santos, 1969). The dominance of foreign
was paid with the produce obtained from the capital in manufacturing activities had shaped
agricultural lands, as in the case of perennial a new dimension to the international division
crops like coffee, cacao and castor beans) of labour. Imperialism had turned its attention
(Furtado, 1970). to the industrial sector in response to the
Another source of dualism in mining re- protectionist measures of the 1930s and 1940s
ferred, according to Furtado, to the capital that the Latin American governments adopted
in the wake of the international crisis of the
coefficient per worker of the mineral industry
Great Depression.
(Furtado, 1970). While mining industries
In the process, a fundamental contradiction
represented a high coefficient of capital per
had emerged to the detriment of peripheral
worker and a high level of productivity, these
countries: on the one hand, capitalism had a
absorb no more than a small fraction of the
great need to expand its markets so that more
labour force. Finally, while agriculture evolved
investments could take place, and on the other,
through the impetus of individuals testing the
monopolist multinational enterprises had a
absorption capacities of external markets and need to control and expand their markets (Dos
stimulating groups cultivating a product with Santos, in Matos-Mar, comp., 1969). Due to
favourable conditions in the foreign markets, this contradiction, monopolist multinational
mining developed in response to the need for enterprises had aligned with the oligarchic
mineral inputs of the industrial centre countries regimes of rural areas, under which mining
(Furtado, 1970; 1961). and agricultural export sectors developed
The enlargement of a pre-capitalist, (Dos Santos, in Matos-Mar, comp., 1969).
backward, rural economy and the concentration Industrialization on the basis of monopolist
of the economy under foreign capital are the capital had fomented, in the peripheral
main concerns of the Dependency school. economies, a concentration of power in
Brazilian economist Theotônio Dos Santos, the hands of foreign groups, a tendency to-
for example, elaborates a critique of the lack wards authoritarianism, bureaucratic state
of analysis in early structuralist thought of the regimes, consolidation and integration of Latin
dominion of foreign, imperialist, oligopolistic American foreign policies with US foreign
capital of the periphery’s industrial sectors policy, a tendency towards militarization, and
(Dos Santos, 1969). His main thesis is that the perpetuation of backwardness in rural
Latin America’s fundamental problems of extractivist areas (Dos Santos, in Matos-Mar,
development (manifested in the conditions comp., 1969).
of marginality, poverty, stagnant economic The works of Marxist economist Paul
growth, backward agrarian institutions) are Baran, despite his not being a dependentista
intimately related to the process of industrial- (dependency theorist), had a tremendous in-
ization of capitalism. fluence on the structuralist and dependency

Progress in Development Studies 8, 2 (2008) pp. 129–62


Jeannette Graulau 143

debates about mining. Baran’s most important industries in different economic sectors or the
contribution is his Marxist analysis of the expansion of new markets.
relationship between imperialist capital and Moreover, Baran cites Paul Singer to
underdevelopment, based on the examination assert that the service economy that supplies
of a vast amount of literature from early the mineral export sector is generally a con-
structuralism, official publications from the sequence of foreign investments, and never
US, Great Britain, Brazil, India and other becomes an integral part of the economic
governments, UN publications, and the structure of the underdeveloped country,
academic debates between structuralism, except in a purely geographic and physical
Marxism, and orthodox political economic sense (Baran, 1957: 273-74). Even when these
thought (Baran, 1957; Baran and Sweezy, service sectors and industries are planned to
1966). In The Political Economy of Growth satisfy the developmental needs of the isolated
(1957), Baran argued that the conditions regions in which they are located, Baran argues
assumed by neoclassical economics for the that their effects are null or negative, given
‘well functioning’ of markets and full em- the foreign, alien character of the ‘artificially
ployment of factors of production were introduced services’. In this sense, these
not present in underdeveloped countries potential sources of external economies,
situated in countries where capitalism has
(Baran, 1957). Contrary to the assumption
not overcome its mercantilist phase, feed the
of classical political economy, he asserted
mercantilist capitalism and do not contribute
that low or extremely low levels of income
to a transition to industrial capitalism. He
characterized all underdeveloped countries.
argues that historically, economic surplus in
The main characteristics of underdeveloped
underdeveloped countries has been obtained
economies were the low consumption levels
by a monopolist consortium of industries – very
of their populations, heavy dependence on
much the case in mining industries – and is
agricultural and mineral production, including not invested in other economic sectors of the
subsistence agriculture, the sub-utilization of country, not even in opening new firms (Baran,
capital, natural and human resources, and the 1957: 254). The surplus is invested by the
heavy concentration of land under landowners wealthy in luxury items or is repatriated. For
(Baran, 1957: 240). Baran, this is the character of the imperialism
Industrial sectors in underdeveloped coun- that operates through foreign mineral and
tries were characterized by limited and even agricultural export-oriented industries (Baran,
stagnant investments. Mining investments, 1957).
in particular, had a ‘paralyzing impact’ in Mining enterprises are seen as the
underdeveloped countries (Baran, 1957). quintessential manifestation of the exploitation
Like structuralist thinkers, he argued that and dominion of foreign monopolist capital.
foreign mineral industries lacked ‘amplifying For Baran, mining companies’ investments
investment effects’, and had a limited capacity in their host national economies are limited
to increase the volume of and diversify their to creating the necessary infrastructure for
investments and the general economic growth their own operations: civil work such as the
(Baran, 1957). He explained that mineral opening of roads, construction of bridges,
industries’ investments in infrastructure, the ports, railroad, etc., which primarily serve
opening of roads, ports, electrical plants, etc., the external-export sector (Baran, 1957).
were aimed at supplying themselves with the Control of the natural resources that provide
necessary power sources, rather than fostering the input for industrial operations is obtained
potential sources of external economies. by expropriating the lands of the local and
They did not encourage the dissemination of native populations, or through a ‘symbolic’

Progress in Development Studies 8, 2 (2008) pp. 129–62


144 ‘Is mining good for development?’

acquisition from governments, feudal lords, or Fernando Henrique Cardoso and Enzo
Indian chiefs. Investments in new machinery, Faletto analysed these as development failures
equipment, and even human resources are of the advanced stages of ISS. Their work
made back in the developed countries, as heavy served to guide the development debates of the
capital goods are not produced in the periphery following generations; and it provided the basis
(Baran, 1957). for the development of leftist political agendas
Baran also criticizes foreign mining and Marxist approaches among Latin American
enterprises for the low salaries paid to the intellectuals. In Dependencia y Desarrollo en
unspecialized local labour force. The labour América Latina (1969), Cardoso and Faletto
force receiving high-income salaries is mostly analysed the extent to which structuralist
of foreign origin, employed in administrative theory was plagued by misconceptions and
tasks. This, according to Baran, is the erroneous perspectives.10 In particular, they
problem that underdeveloped countries face: criticized the naïve expectation that dominant
expropriation of their surplus by foreign mining national elites would push for policies of self-
enterprises and foreign capital’s reinvestments sustained economic growth (Cardoso and
in the host countries (Baran, 1957: 263). The Faletto, 1969; see also Cardoso, 1978).11 The
state cooperates with foreign enterprises lack of an ‘integral analysis’ of development
by allowing them to extract the periphery’s was responsible for an incomplete social
resources and surpluses without any significant science rationalization and policy-making
compensation. that rendered unimportant institutional, so-
Interestingly, Baran is the first Marxist cial and political processes that used to be
scholar to question the idea that the natural relevant, such as the power and dominion
market for foreign mineral industries is the of traditional political groups, the national
export market. Even if this is the case, he industrial bourgeoisie, and the alliances among
argues, there is no justification for the destruc- them.
tion of national soils commanded by the Cardoso and Faletto’s work placed strong
operations of foreign mining industries, emphasis on the need to study the connections
their predatory exploration, the systematic between the economic system and the social
pauperization of local populations, and the and political organization of underdeveloped
physical destruction of native populations societies, and its relationship to developed
(Baran, 1957: 265). The idea that development countries. Like the early structuralists, they
implies sacrifices is, for Baran, an absurdity, argued that the historical specificity of the
considering that the exportable production situation of underdevelopment emerged
of foreign industries is mostly composed of from the unequal relationship between
minerals, petroleum, and other extractivist peripheral and core countries. For a global
resources. interpretation of development, dependency
Baran’s discussion of the exploitative theorists had to distinguish the differences
character of foreign mining enterprises is a in the ‘real historical process’ underlying the
fierce critique of what he terms the ‘myopia conditions of non-development and under-
of Western economists’ who, by defending development. They also had to identify the
the virtues and advantages of mineral pro- particular relationships characterizing the
duction on the periphery commanded by linkages between countries in any of those
the technologically advanced industries and situations, and the hegemonic economic and
processes of the US, are unable to see the political powers. The inquiry into ‘real historical
ramifications of the exploitation of monopolist processes’ produced an impressive amount
capital on the periphery’s economic and pol- of literature analysing what Norman Girvan
itical life (Baran, 1957). called the dependency economics of the mining

Progress in Development Studies 8, 2 (2008) pp. 129–62


Jeannette Graulau 145

regions of the Caribbean, Latin America and but were the manifestation of a relationship
Africa (see, for example Girvan, 1973, 1978; characterized by an unequal exchange of
González, 1973; Widstran, 1975; Persaud, products containing unequal amounts of social
1980; Yachir, 1988. For an extensive review of labour (Wallerstein, 1985). They correspond to
the literature, see Palma, 1978). the capital/labour relationship of appropriation
Since dependency theory draws upon and extraction of surplus value in spaces where
the structuralist analysis of mineral export productive activities are grouped according to
economies, defined as oligarchic, imperialist, the imperatives of the entrepreneurs seeking to
and backward, it is unable to analyse mining maximize their profits, or the ‘anarchy of pro-
production independent from the position duction’ (Wallerstein, 1985). Consequently,
and function of foreign capital. Naturally, Dos spaces, productive processes and relationships
Santos, Cardoso, Faletto and Baran cannot are ‘core-like’, ‘periphery-like’ and ‘semi-
envisage, not even in the wake of the failure periphery-like’.12
of ISS in many Latin American countries, any Another departure from structuralism and
potential for mineral production. dependency theory was the understanding of
states as expressions of power. States are not
World-system theor y The world-system given political structures, but are the result
theory of Immanuel Wallerstein proposes a of the imperatives of capital accumulation
novel understanding of capitalism, which is also by the system and, as such, are the political
pertinent to the discussion of the normative manifestation of the operations of commodity
views against mining in development literature. chains.
Wallerstein sees capitalism as a ‘world- Wallerstein’s theory was nurtured and
economy’, ‘a network of integrated production expanded by the work of Egyptian economist
processes united in a single division of labor’ Samir Amin, German economist André
(Wallerstein, 1985: 88). He emphasizes that Gunder Frank, and Italian economist Giovanni
there is an ‘economy’ wherever there is an ‘on- Arrighi. Known to many as the gang of
going extensive and relative complete social four, they brought to the development field
division of labor’ (Wallerstein, 1985: 13). solid work on underdevelopment in Africa,
To this, Wallerstein adds that a capitalist Southern Europe and Latin America. Some
mode of production must be characteristic of their most important works are: Imperialism
of a world economy for it to survive; and, and Unequal Development (Amin, 1973), The
inversely, that capitalism cannot be the Long Twentieth Century: Money, Power and the
mode of production except in a system that Origins of Our Times (Arrighi, 1994), World
has the form of a world economy, that is, Accumulation 1492–1789 (Frank, 1978), and
an extensive division of labour transcending The Dynamics of Global Crisis (Amin, Arrighi,
any political and territorial unit (Wallerstein, Frank and Wallerstein, eds, 1982). World-
1979). The set of integrated commodity chains system theorists nurtured a rich dialogue
characterizing the world economy is based between Latin American dependentistas and
upon and organized according to the capitalist European and African intellectuals (Entrevista
principle of accumulation. a Theotônio Dos Santos (n.d.); see also Zerán,
This rationalization was a radical departure 2004, in an interview by Enzo Faletto).
from structuralism and dependency theory. While Wallerstein does not explicitly discuss
By taking the ‘world economy’ as the main the implications of world-system theory for
unit of analysis, Wallerstein proposed that mineral economies and mining production, one
development and underdevelopment are not can infer that the structuralist and dependency
just two phases of the same phenomenon as assumptions about mining remain virtually
structuralists and dependency writers argued, unaltered. In the first place, Wallerstein states

Progress in Development Studies 8, 2 (2008) pp. 129–62


146 ‘Is mining good for development?’

that the role of raw material producing countries periphery and the ‘condition of peripherality’
was to provide labour, minerals and sugar to (Wallerstein, 1985: 24–27).
Europe. The consolidation of the ‘Atlantic
triangular trade’ in the sixteenth century Neo-structuralism Neo-structuralist theory
shaped the peripheral zones of the capitalist analyses the historical linkage among nature,
world economy, whereby slaves were shipped the environment and underdevelopment
from West Africa to work the mines and (Sunkel, 1993). Its aim is to study the long-
sugar plantations in the Caribbean and South term structural relationship between the
America; sugar was exported to Europe; and development of the productive capacity
manufactured goods and guns were exported of natural resources and the potential of
to West Africa (Wallerstein, 1974).13 Later, the Latin American countries to pursue new
advent of the Industrial Revolution gave way forms of insertion into the international
to an extensive international division of labour, economy (Sunkel, 1993: 2). Sunkel defines
and the full incorporation of peripheral zones neo-structuralism as:
into the capitalist world economy (Wallerstein, [A] renewed development strategy from
1979). within, as compared to the previous inward-
Second, peripheries become the territories looking and current outward-looking develop-
ment strategies (…) This strategic option
where economic processes requiring a less
represents a Latin American attempt at
skilled and more extensive manpower, which is formulating an alternative to neoliberalism
easily retained at low rates of income – such as (…) based on a critical review of the contribu-
mining work – are concentrated (Wallerstein, tion of the traditional structuralism of the
1985). Third, given that the capitalist world 1950s and 1960s and the neostructuralism
economy is a chain of productive processes of the 1980s (Sunkel, 1993: 2–3).
that supersede and transcend any other Neostructruralist theorists analyse the
political identity, the strong bourgeois core structures, institutions, and dynamics of global-
exerts pressure over the weaker periphery, ization that widen and expand the gap between
resulting in the economic polarization of the industrial and industrializing regions of the
productive processes of the core and those world economy (see, for example, Ocampo,
of the periphery. Fourth, given that unequal 1998; Coatsworth, 2004; Taylor, 2004; Irogbe,
exchange between the core and periphery 2005). The work of Italian agronomist Nicolo
takes place through the political process of Gligo is relevant in discussions on this theory’s
imperialism, the periphery is in an inferior pos- normative views about mining.
ition (politically and otherwise) with respect Gligo’s main idea is that with the development
to the core (Wallerstein, 1985: 1–13). Fifth, of peripheral societies, the growing social and
assuming that the system develops in wave- economic polarization was encouraged,
like spurts of expansion and contraction, over which was manifested in the emergence of
the history of the capitalist world economy informal economies, peasant migration to
there has always been a periphery, a core and agricultural frontiers, dualistic agricultural
a semi-periphery whose positions, productive development (an export, technologically
processes and relations change with the con- advanced sector versus a peasant subsistence
tinuous restructuring of the system.14 Finally, sector), high demographic pressures, and
the devaluation of work under historical cap- high demands on water and energy (Gligo,
italism, which is ‘a global empirical reality’ of 1980, 1986). Under dependent development
the operations of enterprises that regiment and a highly stratified social structure, people
the development of resource-rich regions of the exert pressure on the environment, causing
periphery, perpetuates the existence of the depressed environmental situations that mostly

Progress in Development Studies 8, 2 (2008) pp. 129–62


Jeannette Graulau 147

affect urban and rural marginal populations. an ownership structure based on large, landed
This began with the colonization process estates, and supported by ‘seigniorial monopoly
in Latin America, where the widespread over agricultural land, the paternalistic ideology
idea that Spanish American resources were inherent to the encomienda and the hegemonic
virtually infinite led to high deforestation, soil control over power-sharing and representation
erosion, and social, demographic and structural mechanisms’ (Gligo, in Sunkel, 1993: 188). Due
disorganization of Latin America (Gligo, 1980). to the organization of mining as an enclave,
Agricultural production was severely affected no significant pressure was exerted in favour
in several ways: increasing food demand of the expansion and penetration of inland
trends; increasing need for imports of energy territories.
inputs and agro-production; and artificial Gligo asserts that the pattern of defor-
agricultural ecosystems, which were made to estation, soil erosion and land restructuring
depend heavily on energy subsidizes (Gligo, inherent to the economies of extraction
1980, 1986). continued well into the late 1930s, when the
Gligo’s neostructuralist analysis of develop- international crisis triggered by the Great
ment and natural resources starts from the Depression provoked the restructuring of Latin
fundamental premise that: American economies (Gligo, 1980). With the
The system through which poor societies
advent of ISS, Latin American governments
relate to their physical environment has cre- relegated mining and agricultural enterprises to
ated the descending spirals generated by the second place. Indeed, there were no significant
survival efforts of populations trying to make regional policies of economic development
the best possible use of available resources for mining or agriculture during this period.
(Gligo, in Sunkel, 1993: 186). Gligo adds that these enterprises were left
With respect to mining, Gligo states that unprotected. Although his analysis is not clear
mining operations have historically encouraged as to the state of mining during the many
patterns of severe deforestation and erosion phases of ISS, it is logical to presuppose that
of soils (Gligo, 1980). The need to clean and mining became in those decades an arena
break large stretches of land, the need to where foreign and national interests merged
produce the wood and energy required by and collided (Gligo, 1980).
foundries, and the maintenance of the system Contemporary neostructuralist theorists
of animal traction that provided transportation have added to the question of mining in
are the structural requirements of mining development a wealth of empirical evidence
operations. For example, historically mules, to support the claim that neoliberal reform
donkeys and horses have been used to trans- and globalization entail the intensification of
port minerals to the ports; these were domes- patterns of uneven development. The work
ticated and grazed in vast stretches of land of Gavin Bridge, for example, analyses what
that became overgrazed (Gligo, 1980). Land he calls the ‘new geographies of resource
was reorganized according to the empire’s extraction’, which are created by neoliberal
interest in populating regions that had greater reforms in investment, trade and production
prospects for mining operations. Native cul- (Bridge, 2004a, 2004b; Jonas and Bridge,
tures were forced to work in agricultural 2003). According to Bridge, the mining boom
and mining enclaves. Moreover, agricultural of the mid-1990s shows the spatial expansion
production was oriented initially to serve of mining capital in the developing world.
mining purposes, and new agricultural and Under neoliberal reforms, mining companies
livestock products were incorporated based on have created the strategic targets for new
the needs of mining extraction (Gligo, 1980). investment opportunities in the global South
Territorial space was organized according to (Bridge, 2004a). Drawing upon spatial analyses

Progress in Development Studies 8, 2 (2008) pp. 129–62


148 ‘Is mining good for development?’

of mining investments in the developing world Jan Nederveen Pieterse calls it, attempted to
in the last decade, Bridge concludes that an uncover the mechanisms through which the
evolution in patterns of investments has not construction of ideas becomes the production
been accompanied by a structural shift in the and organization of power (Pieterse, 2000). In
geography of development. He says: this view, development was criticized for its
Western, liberal, positivist credo that glorifies
[R]ecent patterns of investment have ac-
tively contributed to a process of uneven rationality, individualism, modernity, and the
development as both existing spatial in- market (Escobar, 1996).
equalities in investment are consolidated and According to Pieterse (2000), this debate
new patterns and scales of inequality emerge had a solid forum in the journal Development:
(Bridge, 2004b: 411). Seeds for Change. Many authors who appeared
Bridge’s work provides solid data on the in the first issues of the journal seemed to
‘unevenness of development’. His work is share a strong political commitment to the
rejection of every aspect of development
sympathetic to and supportive of the neo-
(Pieterse, 2000). For example, Gustavo Esteva,
structuralist normative view against mining.
identifying development with a ‘malignant
The timid theoretical claims of Bridge’s work
myth’, stated: ‘[T]he development decades
are not a shortcoming; he provides a solid
were a huge, irresponsible experiment that,
methodological framework within which to
in the experience of a world-majority, failed
study flows of mining investments as a spatial
miserably’ (Esteva, 1985: 78).
mechanism that reproduces the relationship
Esteva’s characterization of development
between the core and the periphery. entailed a fierce critique of the impoverishment
of the masses brought about by the rapid
Development as a discourse In the 1980s, the
modernization of Latin American economies
intellectual debate about development turned its
which only responded to the imperatives
attention away from structures of production,
of Western markets (Esteva, 1985). In this
industrialization of national economies, and the
view, modernization of the Third World
international markets and trade, to the analysis
necessarily implied the adoption and impos-
of development as a discourse. One of the most
ition of exogenous forms of production that
influential intellectuals of this new perspec- were based on the needs of the industrialized
tive is Arturo Escobar. His work is an incisive world, and the exclusion of native forms of
scrutiny of the language, ideas, methods of production. For Esteva, development, ra-
inquiry, and assumptions and ideologies of ther than being an economic agenda or a set
development scholarship (Escobar, 1985, 1995, of policies, was a myth, a metaphor, and a
1996). Escobar argues that development is a threat of colonization and Westernization of
mechanism for producing truth about the Third the Third World (Esteva, 1985). Thus, the
World. As he says, necessary consequences of development were
Development can best be described as an exploitation, subordination, marginalization,
apparatus that links forms of knowledge homogenization and poverty in the Third
about the Third World, with the deployment World.
of forms of power and intervention, resulting The study of development as a discourse
in the mapping and production of Third
provided the first analytical framework within
World societies (Escobar, 1996: 213).
which to study ideologies of development.
Escobar stated that development is a colon- It brought to the development field an in-
izing form of knowledge, which colonized re- quiry unexplored by its structuralist prede-
ality, and became reality itself (Escobar, 1996). cessors: the extent to which knowledge
The ‘linguistic turn’ provided by discourse, as about development entailed relationships of

Progress in Development Studies 8, 2 (2008) pp. 129–62


Jeannette Graulau 149

domination, representation, ideology and Maria Mies is worth mentioning. In Patriarchy


power. For the first time, intellectuals were and Accumulation on a World Scale: Women in
pushed to explore their own discourses of the International Division of Labor (Mies, 1986),
development, and scrutinize the development Mies argues that women’s work in peripheral
epistemology from within the scholarship. areas allows the ‘ongoing primitive accumulation
Many works promptly followed, exploring the and colonization’ necessary for capitalist
discourses of uniformity, cultural imperialism, expansion and development. Drawing upon
consumerism, poverty, and native peoples, Rose Luxemburg’s analysis of the process
among others (see, for example, Sachs, 1992; of capital accumulation, she argues that the
Crush, 1996; also, ‘Post-Marxist Aporias’ by contemporary international division of labour
Siar, 1998). Moreover, theorizations of alter- rests upon the maintenance and recreation
natives to development and post-development of an asymmetrical sexual division of labour
emerged as a response to the failures and within and outside the family.
crimes that have been the steady companions The few works that exist on women in
of development (Sachs, 1992). mining have emphasized, with one notable
Notwithstanding its significant contribu- exception, women’s subordinate roles in the
tion, this critique has not led to any fruitful sexual service sectors of mining economies,
framework within which to study the topic household economy and the provision of
of mining. It has set itself apart from any security, women’s reproductive work, and
theoretical and political effort to give con- women’s productive work as an appendage
crete answers to contemporary dilemmas of to that of men (Barrios de Chungara, 1978;
development. Nash, 1979). An analysis of linkages between
Feminist development scholarship and mining women’s labour in mining and national eco-
The feminist scholarship in development called nomic development do not abound in the
attention to the gendered division of labour in field. Two notable works along this line are
mining production (’Atu Emberson Akin, in an essay by ’Atu Emberson Akin on women’s
Harcourt, 1994); women’s struggles against labour in nickel mining in the Pacific (’Atu
economic exploitation in mining (Barrios De Emberson Akin, in Harcourt, 1994), and the
Chungara, 1978); the notion of femininity book by Lahiri-Dutt and Macintyre on women
and the role of women in peasant miners’ miners in developing countries (Lahiri-Dutt and
cultural rituals (Nash, 1979); and women’s Macintyre, 2006).
subordination to the sexual and patriarchal This scholarship has not challenged the
structures of mining (Rodrigues, 1994).15 It put normative view against mining of critical
at the forefront of the gender and development development theories. While providing a rich
debate the need to study women’s activities in body of work about women in development,
mining economies of the developing world.16 it reifies the anti-mining normative view of
Feminist political economy made a significant structuralism, dependency and world-system
contribution to the study of women’s work in theories.
primary and peasant production. It has offered
an insightful collection of fieldwork on this topic 3 The pendulum swings back in favour of
that provided empirical grounds to demand mining: neoliberalism and the ‘Extractive
gender-sensitive policy-decision tools from Industries Review Report’
development aid agencies (see, for example, The development debate today is dominated
Momsen and Townsend, 1987; Pietilä and by a positive view with respect to mining.
Vickers, 1990; Deere, 1995). In this tradition, This view has its roots in a diverse group
the early work of German anthropologist of theories that view mining as promoting

Progress in Development Studies 8, 2 (2008) pp. 129–62


150 ‘Is mining good for development?’

‘clusters’ of industrial growth, technology- Washington Consensus approach to inter-


intensive production and commercialization national development in the early 1990s,
of knowledge (for a brief overview of theories and the recent Extractive Industries Review
along this line, see WBG/IFC, 2002; Pedro, initiative. These would build an economic
2006). These theories are part of a broader mentality that favours the withdrawal of the
intellectual and policy paradigm that one can state from traditional mineral policy areas. The
identify with neoliberalism. Gilpin’s definition increasing dispersion of international financial
of neoliberalism is useful here: ‘[It] refers to and credit networks to the developing world
the application of principles of neoclassical have given an extraordinary impetus to this
economics to economic development and mentality.
other aspects of economic affairs’ (Gilpin, SALPs were designed by the International
2001: 306). Monetary Fund as a response to the debt crisis
Neoliberal theories about mining con- of the Third World.17 In the area of mining,
verge in the idea that mining produces SALPs put in place a set of fiscal and legal
competitive advantages for mineral-rich incentives to transfer to foreign capital the
developing countries. The theoretical shift allocation, tenure and operation of mineral rights
from comparative to competitive advantage (Campbell and Clapp, 1995; SAPRIN, 2002;
Campbell, et al., 2003). The following areas
emphasizes the increasing importance of
were targeted by SALPs: no-discrimination
technology, companies’ specialization and
against foreign capital; flexible concessionaire
economies of scale in international trade,
regimes; guarantees to remittances abroad;
rather than natural resources endowments
provisions for international arbitration; and
(Gilpin, 2001). It establishes a normative
protection for investors (Campbell, et al.,
rationale that favours mining based on (and
2003; Sánchez, et al., 2001).
under conditions of) transnational capital
The second wave, identified as Washington
intervention in developing countries. It seems Consensus (a term coined by John Williamson),
that the idea of competitive advantages em- aimed at deepening the liberalization reforms
phasizes the networks of trade, production that started with SALPs. The fall in commodity
and marketing of mining companies over factor prices at a time of expansion in the supply of
endowments. Hansen describes how the primary products, the recession of North
theory of competitive advantages provided an American and Western European mar-
environmental dimension to the normative view kets, and the loss of access to foreign credit
in favour of mining (Hansen, 1998). It refers to prompted a rapid intervention by Washington-
the idea that developing countries are ‘pollution based institutions in developing countries
heavens’ with abundant ‘contamination en- (Schaeffer, 2005). The intervention of the US
dowments’, which means that they have a Treasury, Federal Reserve Board, the IMF and
natural pollution absorption capacity given World Bank aimed at promoting reforms in the
their low levels of industrialization (Hansen, following areas: fiscal discipline, reordering
1998). public expenditure priorities, tax reform,
The neoliberal policy paradigm is the most liberalization of trade, interest rates and in-
recent episode – in the Braudelian sense – in ward foreign direct investment, privatization,
the longer history of neoclassical economics. deregulation and property rights (Williamson,
It is the product of the last three decades 2002).
of international financial intervention in the In a paper entitled ‘Strategies for African
developing world. It started officially with Mining’ from the Mining Unit of the Industry
the Structural Adjustment Program Loans and Energy Division of the World Bank (IBRD/
(SAPLs) of the early 1980s, followed by the WB 1992), the World Bank described a set of

Progress in Development Studies 8, 2 (2008) pp. 129–62


Jeannette Graulau 151

policy criteria to be applied to mining as part e) ‘guarantees of access to foreign exchange


of the Washington Consensus (Campbell, at market rates for repayment of debts,
et al., 2003). An enterprise survey conducted capital and profit repatriation, and
among 80 international mining companies, purchase of essential inputs’;
asking ‘what influences their investment f ) ‘institutions which are well-equipped,
decisions in developing countries’ provided able to respond to private investors in
the basis for the strategies for African mining a professional and timely manner and
(IBRD/WB 1992: 16). The sample included which prevent or minimize corruption’
junior and multinational mining companies (IBRD/WB 1992: 20).
with exploration budgets ranging from US$ 1–
2 million to US$ 50–100 million. The follow- The economic mentality embraced by the
ing criteria – in order of importance – were Washington Consensus is that governments
identified in the survey: (a) mineral potential are facilitators of foreign investments. The
and infrastructure; (b) guarantee of mining States are important for building conditions of
rights as a precondition prior to exploration; institutional stability, reduce foreign investors’
(c) ownership and control of mining operations; risks, and improve economic management by
(d) minimal political and economic risks; (e) risk transferring mineral rights in the five areas
premiums; and (f) solid information about the targeted by SALPs to corporatist capital.
country – financial, political, geological, etc. A Report commissioned by the Joint
(IBRD/WB 1992: 16-18). World Bank/Civil Society/Government
The World Bank paper identifies a group Structural Adjustment Participatory Review
of countries that have put in place legis- Initiative (SAPRI) indicates that during
lation to build ‘an environment conducive to this period, Washington-based institutions
investment’ – Chile, Indonesia, Papua New granted the highest amount of credit to
Guinea, Botswana and Ghana (IBRD/WB mining: US$ 5,950,000,000 by the World
1992: 20). Following the experience of mining Bank Group; US$ 946,000,000 by the
investments in these countries, the World European Bank for Reconstruction and
Bank defines key lessons for the rest of the Development; US$ 2,025,000,000 by the
developing world. These are as follows: Asian Development Bank; US$ 1,073,000,000
by the Inter-American Development Bank;
a) ‘sound macro-economic and trade and US$ 40,500,000,000 by Export Credit
policies with few restrictions or controls Agency Financing of Upstream Oil and Gas
on mineral exports or needed imports of Development – Not Mining – for the period
plant, equipment, services and supplies’; 1994–99 (SAPRI 2002).
b) ‘a legal framework, which adequately The most recent neoliberal policy wave is
defines the investor’s rights and represented by the World Bank in its report,
obligations. This includes legal safeguards Striking a Better Balance: Extractive Industries
which set forth important details Review Report (WBG, 2003). The Extractive
like operational control, marketing Industries Review (EIR) Report seeks to pro-
arrangements, dispute resolution, and mote mining activities in the context of the
so on’; increasing liberalization of the mineral sectors
c) ‘security of tenure to give the investor of industrializing regions. The novel normative
assurance of being able to enjoy the fruits view about mining represented by the EIR
of success’; Report is its emphasis on promoting corporatist
d) ‘a fiscal package which shares equitably mining as a way of achieving poverty alleviation
the rent of profitable production among and sustainable development. This includes
the various parties concerned’; normative stances about the environmental

Progress in Development Studies 8, 2 (2008) pp. 129–62


152 ‘Is mining good for development?’

impacts of mining, human rights, and the for which transparency is ‘the building
rights of indigenous peoples. These come block’ (McPherson, 2006). In the words of
from the World Commission on Environment Mr Rashad-Rudolf Kaldany, Director of the
and Development (1987)18 also known as the Oil, Gas, Mining and Chemicals department
Brundtland Commission, the UN Conference of the World Bank, ‘the objective is to increase
on Environment and Development (1992),19 transparency over payments and revenues
and the UN Committee on Economic, Social in the extractives sector in countries heavily
and Cultural Rights.20 In this regard, the EIR dependent on these resources in line with the
Report states: Statement of Principles and Agreed Actions
If the WBG is to have a role in the extractive agreed at the London Conference on EITI
industries, it must be one of contributing to on June 17, 2003’ (Kaldany, 2005: Annex 1,
the objective of poverty alleviation through par. 1.1).
sustainable development. Accordingly, WBG This normative view of mining is supported
operations in the extractive industry sector
by a wide number of scholars in the field of
should meet strict criteria to ensure that
they contribute to equitable and sustainable development (see, for example, Auty and
development, promote sustainable livelihoods, Mikesell, 1998; Hilson, 2004; Hilson and
and alleviate poverty. (…) Extractive industry Potter, 2005). They argue that neoliberal
projects considered for World Bank Group reforms increase the volumes of mineral pro-
support should be evaluated to ensure that duction, strengthen export market niches,
their expected benefits – especially for the
poor – are sufficiently higher than their
and intensifies linkages between domestic
estimated costs, including environmental mineral economies and global mineral markets
and social costs. Further, local communities (Hilson, 2004). Empirical work, such as
bearing the costs should clearly benefit from that of Auty and Mikesell (1998), is built to
such development. The outcome will often support the idea that good governance can
depend on helping countries to create the promote sustainable mineral-driven growth
policy and institutional frameworks needed
for extractive industries to contribute to
by preventing the ‘external and internal dis-
sustainable development (WBG, 2003, turbances’ incompatible with sustained growth
Vol. I: 4). (Auty and Mikesell, 1998).
The challenges to this normative view
The most conspicuous antecedent of
come from a wide range of theories that com-
the EIR Report is the Extractive Industries
bine environmental, ecological, neo-Marxist,
Transparency Initiative (EITI). This initiative
feminist and neostructuralist frameworks
seeks to build an international regime to pro-
(see, for example Clüsener-Godt and Sachs,
mote ‘good governance’ and ‘transparency’
1995; Davis, 1995; Leamer, et al., 1999;
in resource-rich developing countries. It is
aimed at addressing questions about political Godoy, 2001; SAPRIN, 2002). The intellectual
and institutional failures of the State in man- arguments of these theorists are supported
aging its mineral accounts. The speech of by the political pressure of transnational net-
Germany State Secretary Erich Stather at works of communities and interested parties
the meeting of the International Advisory that are forming to lobby against mining at
Group of EITI describes it as ‘an overarching regional, national and international levels,
information unit’, for the ‘establishment of such as Fatal Transactions, Partizans, and
internationally binding standards’ (Stather, the Minewatch Asia-Pacific Project. The
2006: 2–3).21 The problems of Dutch disease intellectual and political pressure levied by
and revenue volatility, according to World critics of neoliberalism does not seem powerful
Bank Senior Advisor Charles McPherson, enough to inspire a new economic mentality,
are to be addressed by ‘good governance’, or normative view, with respect to mining.

Progress in Development Studies 8, 2 (2008) pp. 129–62


Jeannette Graulau 153

Hence, the pendulum today remains on the The problema philosophorum of the new
side favouring mining for development. economic mentality seems to be of a technical
order: how to apply a given set of theories to
III Conclusions mining. The concerns with muchas Ciencias,
The brief exploration of the history of the as expressed by D. Francisco Gamboa, seems
normative views on mining in development to be a matter from the past. This might be
scholarship reveals that the question ‘Is mining a ‘necessary evil’ inherent to the neoliberal
good for development?’ has followed a difficult historical episode of the question of mining in
road, from the omission of the topic in the early development. It is worth recalling the words
classical political economy tradition, to moving of Malthus from an anecdote by Jacob Viner:
back and forth between favouring and opposing in a speech of introduction to Senior’s lectures
mining. It is clear that every time the pendulum on population, Malthus said that ‘it was among
moves, new questions, ideas and theories the disadvantages of public lectures, that the
are in the making. The scientific revolution lecturer sometimes thought he was called
of Renaissance Europe, in particular that of upon to say something new, where there
renaissance mining engineering, described by was nothing new to be said’ (Viner in Spiegel,
Smith as ‘larger than the struggle against the 1952: 719).
Turks or the doctrinal differences of Catholic It is clear that the normative understanding
and Protestant’ (Smith in Grünhaldt Sisco and of mining in development scholarship is not
Smith, 1951: ix); the intellectual revolution tied to ideas about the geology of the Earth.
of Adam Smith, David Ricardo, and later on, As seen in this paper, the nineteenth-century
that of Latin American structuralism; the genealogy of the topic of mining starts with
fruitful debates about Western ideologies; and international trade theories, in particular
women’s labour in mining all created new ideas the theory of comparative advantages. If, as
about development, which are the foundations Braudel asserts, ‘material life is at the root of
for today’s debates about mining. everything’ (Braudel, 1992), the debate about
The last movement of the pendulum in development must ‘get more physical’, as
favour of mining brings new elements to the geographer William Doolittle puts it (Doolittle,
intellectual history of development. First, it 2006, personal communication). It means
conveys the idea that there is a global con- incorporating the scholarship about mining,
sensus on the desirability (and superiority) metallurgy and geology in the theorizations
of neoliberal reforms for mining. This is done for development.
by spreading the core values of what Cerny Understanding the troubled relationship
(2000) elegantly calls the ‘Anglo-Saxon between mining and development is useful
spirit’ of capitalism (ideas about flexibility, when it comes to understanding the mistakes,
competitiveness, diversification of portfolio, failures and disasters in the history of mineral
transparency, accountability). These values policies. Consider, for example, the ways
are built as the material basis of the flows in which Germany defined national health
of investment and finance promoted by the and nutritional policies based on the mineral
World Bank. Second, it is devoid of philo- needs of its war economy during World
sophical questions about development, at War I. These policies attempted to reduce
least when compared and contrasted with domestic consumption and the import of
its intellectual predecessors in the long-term certain foodstuff, to encourage the imports
history of ideas about development. The of mineral and metal-related products to
problema philosophorum of its predecessors defy the raw materials blockade of 1914–18
were the origins of wealth, the nature of (Staley, 1937). Another historical failure was
international trade, and the nature of capital. the prohibition of small-scale iron ore mining

Progress in Development Studies 8, 2 (2008) pp. 129–62


154 ‘Is mining good for development?’

in Brazil during the 1940s. This prohibition an obstacle for building mineral policies over
transformed Brazil into an importer of iron the long run? To what extent is the incoherent
ore from international markets (after being normative history inherent to development
able to sustain its domestic demand with its theorization? It is worthwhile to remember
own national production) (Cleary, 1990). The Adler’s words, when he stated that the lack
greatest disaster in mineral development is still of a ‘definite concept of the development
unfolding: the resource wars and their legacy in process or philosophy was inherent to the
the African countries of Angola, Sierra Leone, business of the World Bank in its early decades
Liberia and the Democratic Republic of Congo (Adler, in Bhagwati and Eckaus, 1990: 30).
(see, for example, Innes, 1984; Zack-Williams, Even when one can infer that any aspect of
1995). Examining and using historical analogies development will have the same limitations,
in mineral development is an urgent task in the environmental, geological, and economic
order to avoid the mistakes of the past. aspects of mining deserve further theoretical
Other mistakes and failures are more subtle. inquiry and policy examination. The increasing
They refer to the way ideas about mining in the conflicts between peasants and small-scale
development field allow for certain institutions, miners and mining companies, and the ex-
university programmes, and research centres haustion of mineral deposits, are problems that
to dominate the public policy arena. Mirowski
cannot wait any longer.
and Van Horn (2005) have called attention
In the short term, the normative history of
to this question in their exploration of the
mining ultimately reveals that the question ‘Is
history of economic theories of the Chicago
mining good for development?’ is important
School of Economics. This is a question that
because of the further questions it throws
also applies to theories of mining and develop-
up. These questions include the meaning
ment, and deserves further analysis: What is
of development, the relationship between
the relationship between dominant normative
views about mining and funding for research development and technology, and the equity
programmes? This is a question about the ma- requirements of this relationship. Unless
terial basis of the political economy of mining those questions are settled, my forecast is
in the field of development. that mining will continue to have a troubled
Today, the dominance of the World Bank relationship with development scholarship.
Group, the International Monetary Fund, and Today’s debate about mining and develop-
multinational mining corporations in building ment seems to be a century-long product of,
a normative rationale favouring mining must and response to, the dismantling of the myth
come under scrutiny. A topic with an incoherent of El Dorado. Is it also the disillusionment of
normative history and a troubled relationship the new century with the dismantling of this
with development theories (with, indeed, myth, a myth that had the power to attract, as
very short periods of tranquillity in such a Italian Jesuit Antonio Andreoni saw it in 1711,
relationship), has today become an integral personas de todas condiciones? To replace the
part of mineral policies in industrializing myth of El Dorado, the nineteenth-century
countries. What are the outcomes of mineral classical political economy produced a new
policies that have swung between favouring myth, which today underlies the economic
and opposing mining? This question deserves mentality about mining: a myth that one
a long-term, multidisciplinary engagement. It can call El Dorado Technicum. Powerful ideas
also requires that social scientists scrutinize about technology dominate the debates about
our tools, methods, techniques, and ideas mining, including the development of peasant
about mineral policies. To what extent does the and artisanal mining, where rural violence,
incoherent normative history of mining create mercury pollution, and the environmental

Progress in Development Studies 8, 2 (2008) pp. 129–62


Jeannette Graulau 155

impacts of what British anthropologist David mainstream of economics and, to a degree which is
Cleary called ‘ethnogeology’ are problems astonishing in retrospect, Western economists ignored
the under-developed world’ (Arndt in Bhagwati and
that still wait for solution (see Cleary, 1990; Eckaus, 1973: 16).
Chaparro Ávila, 2003; Hilson, 2003). Will 5. For a revision of the theories of economic growth,
the key to a new movement of the pendulum see Adelman (1961), Falkus (1968) and Hoselitz
lie in the debate about technology? For the (1960). An excellent source is also the Handbook
of Development Economics, particularly Volume 1
answer, development scholarship will have to
(Chenery and Srinivasan, 1988) and Volume 3B
wait patiently for new generations to come and (Behrman and Srinivasan, 1995).
bring a future ‘father of innovation’, as Jeremy 6. ECLA, which later included the Caribbean and
Betham was once called, a new ‘apostle of came to be known as ECLAC, was a United Nations
Adam Smith’, as Speigel reminds us about Jean agency established in 1948 with its headquarters in
Santiago, Chile, following a decision taken by the
Baptiste Say, and a new economist with the General Assembly of the United Nations in 1947
‘intellectual courage’ of Raúl Prebisch. (Kay, 1989). The criticisms made by many Latin
American delegates to the United Nations that the
Notes region was excluded from the Marshall Plan and
1. Gamboa recognizes the Latin scholarship because it had no access to much-needed financial resources
explains ‘la Philo ophia natural y secreta de los metales’ prompted the Assembly to favour the creation of a
(the natural and hidden philosophy of metals), even regional commission for Latin America (Bielschowsky,
when Gamboa says that the Latin works are difficult in Malan, et al., 1999).
to understand (Gamboa, 1761: 2). Taking as an 7. The impact of the Great Depression on the
example the Latin edition of Agricola, he says, ‘Con international markets for raw materials has been ex-
Agricola no se puede contar para el uso común de los tensively studied (Matos-Mar, comp., 1968; Prebisch,
Metalicos por ser latino su idioma (…) y en materia 1971; Furtado, 1982). It suffices to say that with the
tan extraña que su comprensión necesita ciencia como Great Depression, raw material products of Latin
lo lamenta Monfieur Helot, de la Academia Real de American countries lost an important export market.
las Ciencias’ (The work of Agricola is of little help to These countries promptly found themselves facing
the common Miners. Monsieur Helot, of the Royal a surplus of raw material, rapidly falling prices, and
Academy of Sciences, laments that only with the aid an increasing demand for manufactures (Prebisch,
of science one could understand its Latin language.) 1971). Their capacity to import was reduced by
(Gamboa, 1761: 2). 50 percent, and the crisis provoked a return of the
2. New research on economic theories in nineteenth- labour force engaged in activities for the external
century Russia, Poland, Rumania, the Middle East sector to the so-called pre- or semi-capitalist sectors
and the Ottoman Empire promises to address the (Sunkel, 1993). Countries that, prior to 1929, had
historiographical gap between the West and the agricultural and mineral exports equivalent to a fifth
East (see, for example, Ïnalcik 1993; Dasgupta 1993; of their gross internal product, suddenly experienced
Psalidopoulos and Mata 2002). a lowering of export prices and a drastic shrinkage of
3. Arndt calls attention to notable exceptions, such the quantum exported (Sunkel and Paz, 1970).
as Dutch colonial economist J.H. Boeke and 8. Such data was criticized as being misleading by
British economists J.S. Furnivall, Lord Hailey and many economists contemporaneous to Prebisch,
W.K. Hancock. In particular, Boeke developed the who advocated the comparative advantages theory
theory of ‘social dualism’ based on his experience (Higgins, 1959; Levin, 1960). He finally published
as a colonial administrator in the Dutch Antilles. It the report in 1949, arguing against trade based on
referred to ‘the clashing of an imported social system comparative advantages and advocating government
with an indigenous social system of another style’ intervention to promote government-protected in-
(Arndt in Bhagwati and Eckaus, 1973: 20). These dustrialization in Latin American countries.
economists attempted to conceptualize the problem 9. Important names, such as Celso Furtado, José Medina
of underdevelopment with special emphasis on the Echevarría, Regino Botti, Jorge Ahumada, Juan
problems of the Southeast Asian colonies (Arndt in Noyola Vázquez, Aníbal Pinto, Osvaldo Sunkel and
Bhagwati and Eckaus, 1973). Maria Da Conceição Tavares, identified themselves
4. For this scholarship’s silence on the topic of under- with Prebisch’s arguments against specialization in
development, Arndt calls the inter-war years the primary production, consolidating the ECLA school
mainstream. In his own words, ‘the problems of long- of thought (for more on ECLA’s writings, see Malan,
term economic growth all but disappeared from the et al., 1999).

Progress in Development Studies 8, 2 (2008) pp. 129–62


156 ‘Is mining good for development?’

10. Christobal Kay observes that an English translation of mechanized labour value, and are highly profitable.
the book appeared 10 years after its first publication The term ‘periphery-like’ is employed to designate
in the Spanish language (Kay, 1989: 230). the ‘dependent zones’ that were incorporated into
11. Specifically, Cardoso and Faletto addressed three the international division of labour with the expansion
aspects of the structuralist and dependency thinking of of the world economy over historical time, and as
the 1940s, 1950s and 1960s, which might have distorted a consequence of its internal needs (Wallerstein,
in some ways the vision of and expectations about 1985). The colonies and semi-colonies, where the
Latin American development. The first aspect was system operated to facilitate the flows of surplus to
the ‘typological analysis’, or the analysis of ‘traditional’ core regions via unequal exchange, are characterized
and ‘modern’ societies. They criticized the analytical by ‘periphery-like’ relationships of production. The
and methodological approach to development as an operation of the system in these zones is referred
evolutionary trend towards industrialization, with to as the peripheralization of the incorporated ter-
stages running from traditional to modern societies. ritories. ‘Semi-periphery like’ is used to describe
The flaws of this approach were its lack of analysis the simultaneous coexistence of ‘core-like’ and
of the socio-historical specificities of each transitional ‘periphery-like’ productive processes in zones that can
phase, as manifested in Latin American countries be attached as satellites to one core power in specific
(Cardoso and Faletto, 1969). Along this line, they historical periods and circumstances (Wallerstein,
questioned the poor understanding of the social, 1985: 80–91).
political and institutional aspects of the ‘structural 13. This idea reflects the tremendous influence of the
dualism’ that characterized many Latin American work of Caribbean historian Eric E. Williams in early
countries in their transitions towards modernity. world-system theory (see, for example, Williams,
Second, Cardoso and Faletto raised objections 1944).
to the notion of social change in structuralist and 14. As production expands in the search for accumulation,
dependency theories. The methodological assumption the amounts produced throughout the world-
that the political, social and economic characteristics economy exceed the effective demand resulting from
of the core represent the future stage of development the existing distribution of world income (as fixed by
of the periphery overlooked the historical variations the resolutions of prior, acute sociopolitical conflicts).
and singularities of each case of underdevelopment. Consequent periods of stagnation reduce overall
In particular, they criticized the ‘demonstration ef- production and lead to class struggles, which forces
fect’ analysis, whereby modernization is taken as the a redistribution of the world income to the lower
manifestation of a single, isolated variable, such as strata within the world economy. This redistribution
mass mobilization. For example, the ways in which an expands the market, at least in the core zones, and this
accelerated rate of urbanization in Brazil was viewed can be most effectively compensated for, in terms of
as the single causal variable to explain and predict the interest of the upper strata, by the incorporation
patterns of social and political orientations similar to of new zones within the world economy, adding a
those of centre countries was problematic. Similarly, new component of ultra-low-income-receiving direct
high social mobilization and the early experience of producers.
syndicalization in Argentina were not factors suf- 15. This concern was also influenced by debates in
ficient to demonstrate that this country was at the the field of anthropology about the methods and
edge of modernization in a manner similar to that of techniques for conducting fieldwork and gathering
centre countries (Cardoso and Faletto, 1969). The data about the object of study (see, for example,
third aspect they discuss is related to what they call Apffel-Marglin and Marglin, 1996; Wolf, 1996).
‘reciprocal determinations between structure and 16. Along the lines of critical development theory, other
process’. The concept refers to an analytical per- feminists have also made extraordinary contributions
spective that links the structuralist analysis of the to the study of the positions, options and constraints
economic and social aspects of development to the of women’s work in peripheral countries, and their
analysis of historical processes (Cardoso and Faletto, relation to global capitalist dynamics of accumulation,
1969). The problem of the social control of production appropriation, production, consumption and growth
and consumption is, for them, the starting point for a (Friedmann, et al., 1996; Mies, et al., 1988). These
historical and sociological analysis. scholars have challenged the male-biased normative
12. In Wallerstein’s theory, the term ‘core-like’ is used position and patriarchal epistemological assumptions
to denote the locations of ‘ceaseless’ accumulation underlying the notions of industrialization, modern-
and concentration of capital and continuous appro- ization, labour, production and economics. They
priation of surplus-value, originated by states that have also questioned the paternalistic character of
represent the interests of enterprises, and the pro- First World feminism towards Third World women
cesses that incorporate strong-state machineries, (Mohanty, et al., 1991).

Progress in Development Studies 8, 2 (2008) pp. 129–62


Jeannette Graulau 157

17. The debt crisis officially started on 27 March 1981, Apffel-Marglin, F. and Marglin, S.A. 1996: Decolonizing
when the Polish government declared that Poland Knowledge. From Development to Dialogue. Clarendon
could not meet its debt obligations with Western Press.
banks (which amounted to US$ 27 billion). Other Arndt, H.W. 1973: Development economics before
countries promptly followed Poland’s statement: the 1945. In Bhagwati, J. and Eckaus, R.S., editors,
Rumanian government suspended its payments on its Development and Planning Essays in Honour of Paul
US$ 7 billion, and in 1982, the Mexican government Rosenstein Rodan. MIT Press.
declared its suspension of payments on its US$ 90 Aronowitz, S. 1979: The End of Political Economy.
billion foreign debt (for the causes of the debt crisis, Social Text 2, 3–52.
see Schaeffer, 2004: 79-120). Arrighi, G. 1994: The long twentieth century: Money,
18. From the Bruntdland Commission, the Report takes power and the origins of our times. Verso.
the famous definition of sustainable development as Auty, R.M. and R.F. Mikesell. 1998: Sustainable Devel-
‘development that meets the needs of the present opment in Mineral EconomiesI. Clarendon Press.
without compromising the ability of future generations Aydin, H. and Tilton, J.E. 2000: Mineral endow-
to meet their own needs’ (WBG, 2003: 3). ment, labor productivity, and comparative advantage
19. From this Commission, the Report takes the need in mining. Resource and Energy Economics 22(4),
to achieve sustainable development on a global basis 281–93.
(WBG, 2003). Bath, C.R. and James, D.D. 1976: Dependency Analysis
20. From this Commission, the Report takes the definition of Latin America: Some Criticisms, Some Sugges-
of poverty as ‘a human condition characterized by tions. Latin American Research Review XI(3), 3–54.
sustained or chronic deprivation of the resources, Baran, P. 1957: The Political Economy of Growth. Monthly
capabilities, choices, security and power necessary Review Press.
for the enjoyment of an adequate standard of living Baran, P. and Sweezy, P. 1966: Monopoly Capitalism.
and other civil, cultural, economic, political and social Monthly Review Press.
rights’ (WBG, 2003: 3). Barrios de Chungara, D. 1978: Let me speak! Testimony
21. Germany’s Ministry of Economic Cooperation and of Domitila, a woman from the Bolivian mines.
Development, the Department for International Monthly Review Press.
Development of United Kingdom, the Ministry of Bee, A. 2000: Globalization, grapes and gender: Women’s
Foreign Affairs of The Netherlands, and the Royal work in traditional and agroexport production in
Ministry of Foreign Affairs and the Norwegian northern Chile. Geographical Journal September,
Agency for Development Cooperation of Norway 255–65.
are the architects of the EITI principles. They are the Behrman, J. and Srinivasan, T.N. 1995: Handbook
donors of EITI’s fund, called the EITI-Multi-Donor of Development Economics, Volume 3B. Elsevier
Trust Fund. Science B.V.
Bello, W. 2002: Pacific Panopticon. New Left Review
References 16, 68–85.
Ackerman, R. 1998: Is Mining Compatible with Sus- Bhagwati, J. and Eckaus, R.S., editors. 1990: Devel-
tainable Development? A World Bank Perspective. opment and Planning Essays in Honor of Paul Rosenstein
International Council on Mining and the Environment Rodan. The MIT Press.
Newsletter 6(1), 1–3. Braudel, F. 1995: The Mediterranean And the Mediterranean
Adelman, I. 1999: Fallacies in Development Theory World in the Age of Philip II, Volume I. University of
and Their Implications for Policy. Department of California Press.
Agricultural and Resource Economics at Berkeley, ——— 1992: Civilization and Capitalism 15th–18th Century,
University of California. Volume II The Wheels of Commerce. University of
——— 1961: Theories of Economic Growth and Development. California Press.
Stanford University Press. ——— 1987: A History of Civilizations. Penguin Books.
Adelman, I. and Morris, T. 1997: Development History Bridge, G. 2004a: Contested terrain: Mining and the
and Its Implications for Development Theory: An environment. Annual Reviews of Environmental Re-
Editorial. World Development 25(6), 831–40. sources 29, 205–59.
Almond, G.A. 1990: A Discipline Divided: Schools and ——— 2004b: Mapping the bonanza: geographies of
Sects in Political Science. Sage Publications. mining investment in an era of neoliberal reform. The
Amin, S., Arrighi, G., Frank, A.G. and Wallerstein, I., Professional Geographer 56(3), 406–21.
editors. 1982: The Dynamics of Global Crisis. Monthly Campbell, B. and Clapp, J. 1995: Guinea’s economic
Review Press. performance under the structural adjustment: import-
——— 1973: Imperialism and Unequal Development. ance of mining and agriculture. The Journal of Modern
Monthly Review Press. African Studies 33(3), 425–49.

Progress in Development Studies 8, 2 (2008) pp. 129–62


158 ‘Is mining good for development?’

Campbell, B., Hatcher, P. and Sarrasin, B. 2003: Culver, W.W. and Greaves, T.C. 1985: Miners and
Factoring in governance is not enough. Mining Codes Mining in the Americas. Manchester University Press.
in Africa, policy response and corporatist responsibility. Cutler, A. 2003: The seashell on the mountaintop: a story
Minerals and Energy 18(1), 2–13. of science, sainthood, and the humble genius who dis-
Cardoso, F.H. 1978: Ideología de la burguesía industrial en covered a new history of the Earth. Penguin Books.
sociedades dependientes. Siglo XXI Editores. Dasgupta, A. 1993: A History of Indian Economic
Cardoso, F.H. and Faletto, E. 1969: Dependencia y Thought. Routledge.
Desarrollo en América Latina. Editorial Siglo Veintiuno. Davenport-Hines, R.P.T. and Van Helten, J.J. 1986:
CEPAL. 1995: La inversión extranjera y las empresas Edgar Vincent, Viscount D’Abernon, and the Eastern
transnacionales en América Latina. Notas sobre la Investment Company in London, Constantinople and
economía y el desarrollo 576–77. Johannesburg. Business History 28(1), 35–61.
——— 1989: Development of Mining Resources of Latin Davis, G. 1995: Learning to Love the Dutch Disease:
America. Estudios e Informes de la CEPAL 48. Evidence from the Mineral Economies. World Devel-
——— 1982a: Report of the meeting on horizontal opment 23(10), 1765–79.
cooperation for the development of the mineral Deere, C.D. 1995: What difference does gender make?
resources of Latin America, 14–18 June, Bogotá, Rethinking peasant studies.. Feminist Economics 1(1),
Colombia. 53–72.
——— 1982b: El crecimiento económico y la política de Dictionary of Scientific Biography. n.d.: Agricola,
recursos mineros en los países en desarrollo, 24 de Georgius. Dictionary of Scientific Biography. [online].
marzo de 1982. Published by the Cultural Heritage Language
——— 1982c: Seminar on policies and negotiations with Technologies, Linda Hall Library, History of Science
TNCs in the mining-metallurgic sector of Bolivia. Collection. Available from http://www.chlt.org/
CEPAL. sandbox/lhl/dsb/page.77.php [accessed 3 June 2006].
Cerny, P.G. 2000: Restructuring the Political Arena: Dibner, B. 1981: Heralds of Science as represented by two
Globalization and the Paradoxes of the Competition hundred epochal books and pamphlets in the Dibner
State. In Randall D. Germain, editor. Globalization Library, Smithsonian Institution. Burndy Library and
and Its Critics: Perspectives from Political Economy. Smithsonian Institution.
Macmillan Press Ltd, pp. 117–38. Dobb, M. 1963: Economic Growth and Underdeveloped
Chaparro Ávila, E. 2003: Small-scale mining: A new Countries. International Publishers.
entrepreneurial approach. ECLAC Document LC/ Dore, E. 2000: Environment and Society: Long-Term
L.1834-P/I. August 2003. CEPAL. Trends in Latin American Mining. Environment and
Chenery, H.B. and Kretschmer, K.S. 1956: Resource History 6(1), 1–29.
Allocation for Economic Development. Econometrica Dos Santos, T. 1969: The crisis of development theory
24(4), 365–99. and the problem of dependence in Latin America. In
Chenery, H.B. and Srinivasan, T.N., editors, 1988 Berstein, H., editor, Underdevelopment and Devel-
Handbook of Development Economics, Volume 1. opment. Penguin, pp. 57–80.
Elsevier Science B.V. Emeny, B. and Ely, J.E. 1934: The Strategy of Raw
Chilcote, R.H. 2000: Comparative Inquiry in Politics and Materials: A Study of America in Peace and War.
Political Economy. Westview Press. MacMillan.
Clark, E., editor. 1932: Boycotts and Peace. A Report by Firestone, O.J. ed., 1972: Economic Growth Reassessed.
the Committee on Economic Sanctions. Harper and Ottawa: University of Ottawa Press.
Brothers. Kaldany, R.R. 2005: Administration arrangement be-
Cleary, D. 1990: Anatomy of the Gold Rush. University tween the Royal Ministry of Foreign Affairs of the
of Iowa Press. Kingdom of Norway and the Norwegian agency for
Clüsener-Godt, M. and Sachs, I., editors. 1995: Brazilian Development Cooperation, and the International
Perspectives on Sustainable Development. UNESCO. Bank for Reconstruction and Development and the
Coatsworth, J.H. 2004: Structures, Endowments and International Development Association Concerning
Institutions in the Economic History of Latin America. the Multi-Donor Trust Fund for the Extractive In-
Latin American Research Review 40(3), 126–44. dustries Transparency Initiative. Washington, D.C.,
Coquery-Vidrovitch, C. 2002: Afrique noier: De la 5 April.
colonisation a la recolonisation? Economie Appliquee Escobar, A. 1996: Imagining a post-development era.
55(2), 207–24. In Crush, J., editor, The Power of Development.
Copper, F. 1981: Africa and the World Economy. African Routledge, pp. 211–27.
Studies Review 24(2/3), 1–86. ——— 1995: Encountering Development: The Making and
Crush, J., editor. 1996: The Power of Development. Unmaking of the Third World. Princeton University
Routledge. Press.

Progress in Development Studies 8, 2 (2008) pp. 129–62


Jeannette Graulau 159

Escobar, A. 1985: Discourse and power in development: Geography and Topography for Military Purposes. Yale
Michel Foucault and the relevance of his work to the University Press.
Third World. Alternatives (10), 377–400. Grünhaldt Sisco, A. and Smith, C.S. 1951: Lazarus
Esteva, G. 1992: Development. In Sachs, W., editor, The Ercker’s Treatise on Ores and Assaying, Translated by
Development Dictionary. Zed Books, pp. 6–25. Anneliese Grünhaldt Sisco and Cyril Stanley Smith.
Falkus, M., editor. 1968: Readings in the History of University of Chicago Press.
Economic Growth. Oxford University Press. Haberler, G. 1957: Los términos del intercambio y
Ffrench-Davis, R. and Tironi, E., editor. 1982: Latin el desarrollo económico. In Ellis, H.S., editor, El
America and the New International Economic Order. desarrollo económico y América Latina. Fondo de
St. Martin’s Press. Cultura Económica.
Frank, A.G. 1978: World Accumulation 1492–1789. Hahn, F.H. 1960: The Stability of Growth Equilibrium.
Monthly Review Press. Quarterly Journal of Economics 74, 206–26.
Friedmann, J., Abers, R. and Autler, L. 1996: Hansen, M. 1998: Economic Theories of Transnational
Emergences: Women’s Struggles for Livelihoods in Corporations, Environment and Development,
Latin America. UCLA Center for Latin American Copenhagen Business School.
Publications. Harcourt, W.A., editor. 1994: Feminist Perspectives on
Furtado, C. 1982: El subdesarrollo lationamericano: Sustainable Development. Lynne Rienner Publishers.
Ensayos de Celso Fur tado. Fondo de Cultura Harvey, C. and Press, J. 1990: Issues in the history of
Económica. mining and metallurgy. Business History 32(3), 1–14.
——— 1970: Obstacles to Development in Latin America. Higgins, B. 1959: Economic Development. Principles,
Problems and Policies. W.W. Norton & Co., Inc.
Anchor Books.
Hilson, G.M. 2004: Structural adjustment in Ghana:
——— 1961: Desenvolvimento e subdesenvolvimento.
Assessing the impacts of mining-sector reform. Africa
Editora Fondo de Cultura Econômica.
Today 51(2), 53–77.
Gamboa, D.F.X. 1761: Comentarios a las Ordenanzas de
——— editor. 2003: The Socio-Economic Impacts of
Minas Dedicados al Catholico Rey… En la Oficina de
Small-Scale Mining in Developing Countries. Taylor
Joachin Ibarra, calle de las Urofas. Año MDCCLXI.
and Francis.
García, P., Knight, P.F. and Tilton, J.E. 2001: Labor
Hilson, G.M. and Potter, C. 2005: Structural Adjustment
productivity and comparative advantage in mining:
and Subsistence Industry: Artisanal Gold Mining in
the copper industry in Chile. Resources Policy 27(2),
Ghana. Development and Change 36(1), 103–31.
97–105.
Hirschman, A.O. 1971: A Bias for Hope Essays on Devel-
Gilpin, R. 2001: Global Political Economy Understanding opment and Latin America. Yale University Press.
the International Economic Order. Princeton University Hobsbawm, E.J. 1987: The Age of Empire 1875–1914.
Press. Vintage Books.
Girvan, N. 1978: Corporate Imperialism: Conflict and Holmes, H.N. 1942: Strategic materials and national
Expropriation Transnational Corporations and Economic strength. Macmillan.
Nationalism in the Third World. Monthly Review Horblit, H.D. 1964: One Hundred Books Famous in
Press. Science Based on an Exhibition Held at the Grolier Club.
——— 1973: The development of dependency economics The Grolier Club.
in the Caribbean and Latin America. Social and Hoselitz, B.F., editor. 1960: Theories of Economic Growth.
Economic Studies 22(1), 1–33. Free Press.
Gligo, N. 1986: Agricultura y medio ambiente en América Iglesias, E.V. 1994: The Legacy of Raúl Prebisch. Inter-
Latina. Editorial Universitaria Centroamericana & American Development Bank.
Sociedad Interamericana de Planificación. Ïnalcik, H. 1993: The Middle East and the Balkans Under
——— 1980: Notas sobre la historia ecológica de América the Ottoman Empire: Essays on Economy and Society.
Latina. In Gligo, N. and Sunkel, O., editors, Estilos de Indiana University Press.
Desarrollo y Medio Ambiente en América Latina. Fondo Innes, D. 1984: Anglo American and the Rise of Modern
de Cultura Económica. South Africa. Monthly Review Press.
Godoy, R. 2001: Indians, Markets and Rainforests: Theor- Irogbe, K. 2005: Globalization and the development of
etical, Comparative and Quantitative Explorations in underdevelopment of the Third World. Journal of
the Neotropics. Columbia University Press. Third World Studies XXII(1), 41–68.
González, E. 1973: Venezuela: nueva política petrolera Johnson, W.L. and Kamerschen, D.R. 1972: Readings
y dependencia. Social and Economic Studies XXII in Economic Development. South-Western Publishing
(March). Company.
Gregory, H.E., editor. 1918: Military Geology and Topog- Jonas, A.E.G. and Bridge, G. 2003: Governing nature:
raphy: A Presentation of Certain Phases of Geology, The re-regulation of resources, land use-planning,

Progress in Development Studies 8, 2 (2008) pp. 129–62


160 ‘Is mining good for development?’

and nature conservation. Social Science Quarterly Meade, J.E. 1961: A Neo-Classical Theory of Economic
84(4), 958–62. Growth. Greenwood.
Kamen, H. 2004: Empire How Spain Became a World Mendershausen, H. 1941: The Economics of War.
Power 1492–1763. Perennial. Prentice Hall.
Kay, C. 1989: Latin American Theories of Development and Mies, M., Benholdt-Thomsen, V. and Werlhof, C.
Underdevelopment. Routledge. 1988: Women: The last colony. Kali for Women.
Lahiri-Dutt, K. and Macintyre, M., editors. 2006: ——— 1986: Patriarchy and Accumulation on a World
Women Miners in Developing Countries Pit Women Scale: Women in the International Division of Labour.
and Others. Ashgate Publishing Ltd. Zed Books.
Leamer, E., Maul, H., Rodríguez, S. and Schott, P.K. Ministry of Foreign Affairs of Denmark. 2005: Nicolaus
1999: Does Natural Resource Abundance Increase Steno. Available from http://www.ambwashington.
Latin American Income Inequality? Journal of um.dk/en/menu/InformationaboutDenmark/
Development Economics 59, 3–42. EducationandTraining/FamousDanishScientists/
Levin, J. 1960: Export Economies: Their pattern of devel- NicolausSteno.htm [accessed 3 June 2006].
opment in historical perspective. Harvard University Mohanty, C.T., Russo, A. and Torres, L., editors.
Press. 1991: Third World Women and the Politics of Feminism.
Levy, D.M. and Peart, S.J. 2005: The Theory of Eco- Indiana University Press.
nomic Policy in British Classical Political Economy: Molloy, P.M. 1986: The History of Metal Mining and
A Sympathetic Reading. History of Political Economy Metallurgy An Annotated Bibliography. Garland
37(1), 120–42. Publishing, Inc.
Momsen, J.H. and Townsend, J.G., editors. 1987:
Lewellen, T.C. 1995: Dependency and Development: An
Geography of Gender in the Third World. SUNY
Introduction to the Third World. Begin & Garvey.
Press.
Lewis, W.A. 1955: The Theory of Economic Growth.
Moreno, K. and Gandarrilla Salgado, J.G. n.d.:
Richard D. Irwin, Inc.
La teoría de la dependencia y el sistema mundial
——— 1954: Economic Development with Unlimited Sup-
Entrevista a Theotônio Dos Santos. Available from
plies of Labor. The Manchester School of Economics and
http://www.herramienta.com.ar/varios/8/8-7.html
Social Studies 22 (May), 139–91.
[accessed 16 January 2006].
Liberty Fund Inc. 1999–2006: The Concise Encyclopedia
Mumford, L. 1963 [1934]: Technics and Civilization.
of Economics. By Henderson, David R., editor, first
Harcourt Brace & Company.
published in 1993 as The Fortunate Encyclopedia
Nash, J. 1979: We eat the mines and the mines eat us:
of Economics by Warner Books. Available from: dependency and exploitation in Bolivian tin mines.
http://www.econlib.org/library/Enc/bios/Ohlin.html Columbia University Press.
[accessed 8 August 2006]. Nurkse, R. 1953: Problems of Capital-Formation in Under-
——— 1999-2005: Life of Adam Smith. John Rae, first developed Countries. Oxford Univeristy Press.
published in 1895, by Macmillan and Co., Available Ocampo, J.A. 1998: Más allá del Consenso de
from http://econlib.org/LIBRARY/YPDBooks/Rae/ Washington: Una visión desde la CEPAL. Revista de
raeLS21.html [accessed 15 May 2006]. la CEPAL 66 (December), 7–28.
Laslett, P., editor. 1988: Two Treatises of Government By Packenham, R. 1992: The Dependency Movement:
John Locke. Cambridge University Press. Scholarship and Politics in Development Studies.
McPherson, C. 2006: Extractive Industries Trans- Harvard University Press.
parency Initiative. World Bank Energy Week. Palma, G. 1978: Dependency: A Formal Theory of Under-
Washington, D.C., 6 March. Available from: development or a Methodology for the Analysis of
http://www.eitransparency.org/section/abouteiti/ Concrete Situations of Underdevelopment? World
speechespresentations [accessed 5 November Development 6, 881–924.
2006]. Pedro, A.M.A. 2006: Mianstreaming Mineral Wealth in
Malan, P. Maria da Conceição Tavares, Antonio Growth and Poverty Reduction Strategies. Minerals
Barros de Castro, Carlos Lessa, Fabio Sá Earp, and Energy Raw Materials Report 21(1), 2–16.
Ricardo Bielschowsky, Sulamis Dain, José M. Pegg, S. 2003: Globalization and natural-resource
Camargo, Reinaldo Gonçalves, João P. and De conflicts. Naval War College Review 56(4), 82–96.
Almeida Magalhães. 1999: Vinte anos de política Persaud, T. 1980: Conflicts between multinational cor-
econômica. Contraponto. porations and less developed countries: The case of
Matos-Mar, J., com. 1969: La crisis del desarrollismo y la bauxite mining in the Caribbean with special reference
nueva dependencia. Amorrortu Editores. to Guyana. Arno Press.
——— com. 1968: La dominación de América Latina. Pieterse, J.N. 2000: After post-development. Third
Amorrortu Editores. World Quarterly 21(2), 175–91.

Progress in Development Studies 8, 2 (2008) pp. 129–62


Jeannette Graulau 161

Pietilä, H. and Vickers, J. 1990: Making Women Matter. Siar, D., editor. 1998: Post-Marxist Aporias. Special
The Role of the United Nations. Zed Books. Topic. Cultural Logic: An Electronic Journal of
Prebisch, R. 1971: Latin America: A problem in develop- Marxist Theory and Practice 1 (2). Available from
ment. Institute of Latin American Studies. http://clogic.eserver.org/1-2/1-2index.html [accessed
——— 1949: El Desarrollo Económico de la América Latina 13 November 2006].
y Algunos de sus Principales Problemas. CEPAL. Singer, C., Holmyard, E.J. and Hall, A.R. 1954–78:
Pribram, K. 1983: A History of Economic Reasoning. The A History of Technology Vol. I. From Early Times to Fall
Johns Hopkins University Press. of Ancient Empires. Clarendon Press.
Porter, A.L. and Cunningham, S.W. 2005: Tech mining: Singer, H.W. 1950: The Distribution of Gains Between
exploiting new technologies for competitive advantage. Investing and Borrowing Countries. American Eco-
Wiley. nomic Review 40(2), 473–85.
Psalidopoulos, M. and Mata, M.E. 2002: Economic Solow, R.M. 1970: Growth Theory: An exposition. Oxford
Thought and Policy in Less Developed Europe: The University Press.
Nineteenth Century. Routledge. Staley, E. 1937: Raw Materials in Peace and War. Council
Rawles, W.P. 1933: The nationality of commercial control on Foreign Relations.
of world minerals. American Institute of Mining and Stark, W. 1943: The Ideal Foundations of Economic
Metallurgical Engineers. Thought: Three Essays on the Philosophy of Economics.
Redford, K.H. and Mansour, J.A., editors. 1996: Routledge.
Traditional peoples and biodiverity conservation in large Stather, E. 2006: Achieving transparency in resource
tropical landscapes. Island Press. extraction and trade – harnessing our partner coun-
Redmayne, R.A.S. 1923: The British Coal Mining Industry tries’ natural wealth for poverty reduction and devel-
During the War. Clarendon Press. opment. Bonn, Germany, 31 August. http://www.
Ricupeiro, R. 2004: La renovada contemporaneidad de eitransparency.org/section/abouteiti/speeches
Raúl Prebisch. Revista de la CEPAL 1ro de diciembre. presentations [accessed 14 November 2006].
——— 2002: Statements by Rubens Ricupeiro, Secretary- Stephen, S.L. and Lee, S.S., editors. 1949: Dictionary of
General of UNCTAD (1995-2004). Available from National Biography. Oxford University Press.
http://www.unctad.org/templates/webflyer.asp? Sunkel, O., editor. 1993: Development from Within:
docid=2545&intItemID=3552&lang=1 [accessed Toward a Neostructuralist Approach for Latin America.
18 December 2005]. Lynne Rienner Publishers.
Rodrigues, R.M. 1994: Mulheres do Ouro: O Trabalho Sunkel, O. and Paz, P. 1970: El subdesarrollo latino-
Femenino nos Garimpos do Tapajós. Secretaria de americano y la teoría del desarrollo. Editora Siglo
Estado de Indústria, Comércio e Mineração. Veintiuno.
Roll, E. 1973 [1938]: A History of Economic Thought. Surin, K. 1998: Dependency Theory’s Reanimation in
Faber and Faber Ltd. the Era of Financial Capital. Available from http://
Rosenstein-Rodan, P. 1961: Notes on the Theory of the www.duke.edu/literature/dependency.htm [accessed
Big Push. In Ellis, H.S. and Wallich, H.C., editors, 18 February 2003].
Economic Development in Latin America. Macmillan. Taylor, L. 2004: Reconstructing Macroeconomics Struc-
Rostow, W.W. 1962 [1960]: Stages of Economic Growth. turalist Proposals and Critiques of the Mainstream.
A Non-Communist Manifesto. Cambridge University Harvard University Press.
Press. United Nations. 1998: Problema básico de aumentar la
Sachs, W., editor. 1992: The Development Dictionary: A capacidad de los países en desarrollo y las economías
Guide to Knowledge as Power. Zed Books Ltd. en transición de obtener ventajas económicas y
Sánchez, F., Ortíz, G. and Moussa, N. 2001: Mining sociales máximas de su potencial de producción
in Latin America in the late 1990s. CEPAL Natural minera. Consejo Económico y Social, Comité de
Resources and Infrastructure Division. Recursos Naturales. United Nations.
SAPRIN. 2002: The Policy Roots of Economic Crisis and ——— 1980a: The role of TNCs in the production and
Poverty, A Multi-Country Participatory Assessment of export of minerals. Proceedings of the 6th Session of the
Structural Adjustment. Prepared by the Structural Committee on Natural Resources, Mineral Resources
Adjustment Participatory Review International Development Series, No. 47, pp. 33–64.
Network (SAPRIN). ——— 1972: Small-scale Mining in Developing Countries.
Sautter, H. 1978: Underdevelopment and dependence: United Nations.
An Economic Evaluation of Dependency Theory. ——— 1970: Mineral Resources Development with Par-
Economics 18. ticular Reference to Developing Countries. United
Screpanti, E. and Zamagni, S. 2005: An Outline of Nations.
the History of Economic Thought. Oxford University ——— 1953: Role of minerals in the development of East
Press. Asia and the Far East. United Nations.

Progress in Development Studies 8, 2 (2008) pp. 129–62


162 ‘Is mining good for development?’

Wallerstein, I. 1985: The politics of the world economy: World Bank Group. 2003: Striking a Better Balance: The
The states, the movements and the civilizations. EIR. World Bank.
Cambridge University Press. World Bank Group/International Finance Corpor-
——— 1980: The Modern World-System, Volume II: Mer- ation. 2002: Treasure or Trouble? Mining in Developing
cantilism and the Consolidation of the European World- Countries. International Finance Corporation.
Economy. Academic Press. World Gold Council. 2001: The New El Dorado: The
——— 1979: The Capitalist World-Economy. Cambridge Importance of Gold Mining to Latin America. Avail-
University Press. able from http://www.gold.org/pub_archive/pdf/
——— 1974: The Modern World-System, Volume I: Cap- eldorado.pdf [accessed 3 April 2003].
italist Agriculture and the Origins of the European
Yachir, F. 1988: Mining in Africa Today: Strategies and
World-Economy in the Sixteenth Century. Academic
Prospects. Zed Books.
Press.
Zack-Williams, A. 1995: Tributors, Supporters and Mer-
Widstrand, C., editor. 1975: Multinationals firms in
Africa. Scandinavian Institute of African Studies. chant Capital. Avebury.
Williams, E.E. 1944: Capitalism and Slavery. University Zerán, F. 2004: Enzo Faletto rompe tres décadas de
of North Carolina Press. silencio, Necesitamos una nueva ética de com-
Wolf, D., editor. 1996: Feminist Dilemmas in Fieldwork. portamiento. Cuadernos del CENDES 21(56),
Westview Press. 131–40.

Progress in Development Studies 8, 2 (2008) pp. 129–62

You might also like