Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 20

Industrialization: trends and transformations

Trade and industrialization have reinforced each ences in the period before World War II. The chap-
other. At the international level, trade has allowed ter serves as historical background for the analyses
countries to specialize between industry and other of industrialization since World War II in later
sectors, between different branches of industry, chapters. Although industry, broadly defined, in-
and increasingly even between different stages in cludes mining, construction, electricity, gas, and
production. Trade has provided access to critical water, in addition to manufacturing, this chapter
industrial inputs, including technology, for coun- focuses more on manufacturingthe most dy-
tries incapable of producing them. Expanded de- namic and usually the largest industrial subsector.
mand for exports has spurred technological devel-
opment and industrial production. In turn, the ad- Global industrialization in historical
vent of new industrial technologies has shaped the perspective
pattern of specialization and hence the pattern of
trade. International specialization has evolved beyond
At the national level, domestic trade has allowed the old pattern by which industrialized countries
specialization between economic sectors and exported manufactures to the developing coun-
within industry. Again, new technologies and in- tries in exchange for primary commodities. Today,
dustrial progress have altered the internal pattern some of the world's most successful exporters of
of specialization and trade. In the other direction, manufactures are developing countries; many of
increased domestic trade has provided the de- their exports go to industrialized countries, from
mand to stimulate the introduction of new technol- which they in turn import manufactures. Among
ogies and further industrialization. industrialized countries, this two-way trade in
The first two parts of this chapter trace some key manufacturesintraindustry trade as it is com-
developments in technology, international special- monly calledhas reached the point where com-
ization, and international trade. Together, these parisons of comparative advantage are meaningful
have led to today's integrated system of global only at the level of finely disaggregated product
trade and industrial production. This historical re- categories. Much of this intraindustry trade re-
view highlights the influence of government poli- flects the specialization that has accompanied in-
cies toward trade and ends by discussing the per- dustrialization. Production of a single good now
formance of developing countries in this global commonly spans several countries, with each
system since the 1960s. The third part of the chap- country in this "global factory" performing tasks
ter discusses the changes in economic structure in which it has a cost advantage (see Figure 3.1).
that have typically resulted from the interaction of Some of these changes in international speciali-
technology, specialization, and trade over the zation and trade are no doubt responses to govern-
course of industrialization. The fourth part dis- ment policy. But, on the whole, they reflect the
cusses the factors that appear to have contributed natural economic processes that have shaped in-
to the more successful industrialization experi- dustrialization from the start.

38
Figure 3.1 Global manufacturing: the component network for the Ford Escort (Europe)

United Kingdom Federal


,/" Sweden"\ Republic of Germany
Carburetor, rocker arm, clutch,
ignition, exhaust, oil pump, Hose clamps,
cylinder bolt, Locks, pistons, exhaust, ignition,
distributor, cylinder bolt, cylinder switches, front disc, distributor,
head, flywheel ring gear, heater, exhaust down
pipes, pressings, weatherstrips, rocker arm,
speedometer, battery, rear wheel speedometer, fuel tank, cylinder
spindle, intake manifold, fuet hardware
bolt, cylinder head gasket, front
tank, switches, tamps, front disc,
steering wheel, steering column,
glass, wealherstrips, locks /
Netherlands
wheel knuckles, rear wheel
spindle, transmission cases,
clutch cases, clutch, steering
column, battery, glass

Tires, paints,
France hardware Norway"\
Exhaust flanges,
Alternator, cylinder head, master tires
cylinder, brakes, underbody
coating, weatherstrips, clutch
release bearings, steering shaft
and joints, seat pads and frames, Belgium
transmission cases, clutch cases,
tires, suspension bushes, Tires,
ventilation units, heater, hose tubes, seat
clamps, scalers, hardware pads,
brakes, trim Denmark
Fan bell

Austria

Tires, radiator
and heater
hoses

United States

EGR valves, wheel


nuts, hydraulic
tappet, glass Japan
Italy Switzerland Starter, alternator,
Spain Underbody cone and roller
Cylinder head, coating, bearings, wind-
Wiring harness, carburetor, glass, speedometer screen washer
radiator and heater lamps, defroster gears pump
hoses, fork clutch grills
release, air filter,
battery, mirrors

Note: Final assembly takes place in Halewood (United Kingdom) and Saarlouis (Federal Republic of Germany).
Source: Dicken 1986, figure 9.9, p. 304.

The rise of modern industrialization: the middle of the eighteenth century. Innovations
the mid-i 700s to 1820 in the spinning and weaving of cotton greatly
boosted productivity; cotton output increased a
Although historians differ on details, the consen- hundredfold from about 1760 to 1827, and cotton
sus is that industrialization began in Britain around textiles overtook wool manufacturing to become

39
These innovations are now generally thought to
Figure 3.2 Historical trends in the growth of have sparked the Industrial Revolution, but it is
real GDP and exports in selected countries, unlikely that people at that time would have re-
1720-1985 garded them as revolutionary. Output in British
agriculture and handicrafts had been expanding
Percent
for about 300 years. In contrast with continental
10
Europe, Britain had eliminated internal customs
barriers as well as most guild and state monopoly
o restrictions on production by the early 1700s. The
Exports bill of exchange, deposit banking, and insurance
8
were well developed, and there had also been
steady improvements in roads, rivers, and canals.
6
Rising agricultural productivity had increased in-
comes and expanded the domestic market for
other goods. The enclosure of common village
lands had pushed labor from the farms and in-
creased the number of people who depended on
the market for food.
2
Throughout the period, domestic trade boomed,
and an additional boost in demand came from in-
creasing foreign trade. The expansion of demand
FL1 gave impetus, within the relatively free enterprise
1720- 1820- 1870- 1913- 1950- 1973- 1979-
environment that prevailed, to a series of innova-
1820 1870 1913 1950 1973 1979 1985 tions in production. An important pre-Industrial
Revolution example was the putting-out system in
textiles. Merchant-entrepreneurs supplied materi-
Note: Accurate historical data for world exports and GDP are als to textile weavers in the villages, bought back
difficult to obtain, so the chart shows average growth rates for six
major industrial countries: France, Germany, Italy, Japan, the the finished cloth, and sold it to domestic con-
United Kingdom, and the United States. For exports, the growth sumers or to export merchants. Ultimately, as the
rate for 1720- 1820 includes only France and the United Kingdom;
the average for 1820-70 includes France, Germany, the United growth of demand for manufactures exceeded the
Kingdom, and the United States. The GDP growth rates have the growth of the labor force, the specialization and
same coverage, except that the first period is 1700-1820 instead of
1720-1820, and the United States is excluded from both the first labor-saving inventions that are generally ac-
and second periods. More comprehensive world data are pro- knowledged to have constituted the first industrial
vided for the period since World War H in Figure 3.3.
Source: For 1720-1979: Maddison 1982, tables 3.2 and 3.7. For revolution followed.
1979-85: for GDP, World Bank data; for exports, IMF, Interna-
tional Financial Statistics.
The transport revolutions, the spread of
industrialization, and the emergence of a global
market: 1820 to 1870

the leading manufacturing product. Most of this After the innovations in cotton textiles, iron smelt-
growth may be attributed to specialization com- ing, and the steam engine, industrialization cen-
bined with simple modifications to existing pro- tered on steel, railways, and steamships from
cesses. Adam Smith, writing The Wealth of Nations about 1820 to 1870. Railways integrated national
in the 1770s, emphasized specialization and the di- markets and stimulated demand for iron and steel.
vision of labor, not the introduction of machines, With steel and steam power, bigger and more reli-
as the basis for higher productivity. The innova- able ships could be built. Freight costs dropped,
tion that allowed coal to be used in smelting iron which enabled such previously remote areas as the
and James Watt's improvement of the Newcomen American Midwest to produce bulky agricultural
steam engine between 1776 and 1781 were mile- products for distant markets in Europe. Belgium,
stones in the development of industrial machinery. France, Germany, and the United States began to
But it took several decades for these innovations to industrialize in this period. Europe, the United
be incorporated into production on a wide scale States, Canada, Argentina, and Australia were
and to make the factory the symbol of manufactur- linked by international trade in agricultural pro-
ing industry. duce, raw materials, and manufactured products.

40
The spread of industrialization to the European Kingdom. This treaty liberated French industrial
continent was facilitated by important institutional development from reliance on expensive domestic
reforms and the removal of many of the restric- coal and iron. French industry and railways, which
tions that had hindered domestic commerce. By now had access to cheaper and better coal, iron,
1820, Europe had emerged from the French Revo- and steelthe basic industrial raw materials of that
lution and the Napoleonic wars that followed it. In erawere able to develop rapidly. In Germany, the
France, tariffs and tolls on domestic trade, as well import duties levied by the Zoliverein in 1834 were
as guild restrictions on the choice of occupation, much lower than those in other European coun-
were abolished immediately after the Revolution. tries at the time. Duties on manufactured imports,
These reforms were soon followed by a standard- for example, were about 10 percent in Germany.
ized system of weights and measures (the metric But these were steadily increased in the 1840s. The
system) and new legal codes protecting property Cobden-Chevalier treaty between France and the
rights. The Napoleonic wars helped diffuse this United Kingdom and agitation by German free
wave of liberalism and reform to other parts of traders prompted a series of tariff reductions in
EuropeBelgium, the Netherlands, Switzerland, Germany in the 1860s. By 1873 all duties levied for
Italy, and much of Germany. In Germany, after protective purposes had been removed in favor of
years of effort, barriers to domestic trade were moderate duties levied for revenue purposes.
greatly reduced in 1834 by the creation of the Economic liberalism between 1820 and 1870, to-
Zoilverein, a customs union among the different gether with the transport revolutions wrought by
German states. railways and steamships, boosted world output
The United Kingdom, the United States, and and international trade (see Figure 3.2). Still, more
many of the European countries also adopted than three quarters of the world's industrial pro-
more liberal external trade policies between 1820 duction in 1870 was accounted for by four coun-
and 1870. Initially, the United Kingdom, the leader tries: the United Kingdom (about 32 percent), the
in industrial technology, prohibited exports of ma- United States (about 23 percent), Germany (about
chinery and the emigration of skilled workers. But 13 percent), and France (about 10 percent).
British entrepreneurs and craftsmen could be
found in Belgium, France, and other European The second industrial revolution
countries, often using smuggled machinery to pro- and the waning of liberalism: 1870 to 1913
duce textiles and engineering products. Realizing
the futility of the prohibition, the United Kingdom The next forty-three years-1870 to 1913saw ma-
removed the legal barriers against emigration of jor advances in science and technology. The inven-
skilled workers (in 1825) and against exports of tion of the Gilchrist-Thomas process, which al-
machinery (in 1842). Thereafter, British entrepre- lowed steel to be made from iron ore of high
neurs, workers, and financiers helped to develop phosphorus content, propelled the industrial de-
railways and coal mining in Europe and elsewhere. velopment of countries with extensive deposits of
Subsequently, the United Kingdom abolished the phosphoric ores, such as Germany and Sweden.
Navigation Acts, which had restricted interna- Other innovations in this periodelectricity, re-
tional shipping; and with the repeal of the restric- frigeration, organic chemicals, the internal com-
tions on grain imports (the Corn Laws) in 1846, it bustion engine, the transatlantic telegraph, and
moved to free trade. Protective tariffs were re- the radioare commonly regarded as the basis of a
placed with revenue tariffs, which were gradually "second industrial revolution." Some of them re-
reduced to an average of 5.8 percent by 1880. inforced the trend toward greater physical integra-
The United States began a series of tariff reduc- tion of world markets: refrigeration, for example,
tions in 1840, and by 1857 most rates were at or made it possible to ship frozen meat from Australia
below 24 percent. But an increasing need for gov- to London by the 1880s.
ernment revenue, especially during the Civil War, This second revolution differed from the earlier
led to several tariff increases. After the Civil War one in two important ways. Technological ad-
ended in 1865, tariff increases continued for pro- vances became more dependent on scientific re-
tection purposes. search that was systematically organized in firms
France embarked on a policy of reducing tariffs and universities for commercial application. Ger-
and eliminating import prohibitions around 1852, many, later joined by the United States, led the
which culminated in the Cobden-Chevalier free way. Also, for the first time, industrial growth in
trade treaty of 1860 between France and the United the industrialized countries became partly depen-

41
dent on supplies from elsewhere: raw materials was forced in the 1850s to open up to foreign trade.
needed by the new technologies (for example, The country was compelled to sign a treaty that for
bauxite, petroleum, and rubber) and ingredients years (1858-98) put a 5 percent ceiling on the tariffs
for new alloys (for example, tungsten, nickel, and that it could levy on imports. Partly in reaction to
chromium) now had to be supplemented with sup- this, the old Tokugawa Shogunate that had ruled
plies from outside the group of industrialized Japan for centuries was overthrown, the Meiji Em-
countries. As a result, many countries were ush- peror was restored in 1868 as head of a centralized
ered into global industrialization as suppliers of state, and a series of reforms was begun. Guilds
industrial raw materials. Since many of these were eliminated, feudalism was abolished, and
products had no economic value until the new private property rights to land were established.
technologies created demand for them, people in People were now free to choose their trade or occu-
these areas were now presented with additional pation: they could produce any crop or commodity
income opportunities. But along with these in- and could buy and sell land freely. Taxation was
come opportunities came colonization for many of reformed and made uniform across the country.
the new suppliers in Africa and Asia. This histori- Internal tolls on the movement of goods and re-
cal link between participation in international strictions on the movement of people were abol-
trade and colonization influenced the choice of in- ished; so too were prohibitions on the exports of
dustrialization and trade strategies in many of the rice, wheat, copper, and raw silk. These reforms
former colonies after World War II. are generally acknowledged to have been major
Despite advances in technology, output in the catalysts in early Japanese industrialization.
industrialized countries grew only slightly faster
than it had between 1820 and 1870, and the growth The collapse of liberalism and of the global
rate of exports fell (Figure 3.2). One reason for this market: 1913 to 1950
was the onset of protectionism in the late 1870s.
The United States had increased tariffs to help fi- Economic liberalism, waxing from 1820 to around
nance its Civil War. After the war the tariffs were 1870, and waning between 1870 and 1913, was
maintained and even increased to protect both ag- practically moribund from 1913 to about 1950. Dur-
riculture and industry. In Germany, where tariffs ing these years there were two world wars and
on most imports had been abolished by 1877, agri- frequent trade wars, the severest economic depres-
cultural producers complaining of "cheap" wheat sion in history occurred, the socialist approach to
from America and iron and steel producers facing industrialization emerged, and several countries
declining prices caused free trade to be abandoned that had previously served the world trading sys-
in 1879. Protectionist forces in France quickly fol- tem as suppliers of primary products (Argentina
lowed Germany's example, led again by farmers and Brazil to name just two) adopted an industrial-
complaining about imports of cheap American ization strategy that emphasized import substitu-
wheat. Other countries did the same, which led to tion behind high protective barriers.
a series of tariff wars in Europe. Even within some of the major capitalist indus-
A number of countries joined the "industrial trialized countries, the market lost ground. The
league" between 1870 and 1913, including Russia cartelization of German industry, which had
and Japan. The state played a more active role in started around the last quarter of the nineteenth
the industrialization of these two countries, partic- century, greatly intensified in the years between
ularly in the development of infrastructure, than it the two world wars. Industrial cartels started in
did in the countries that had industrialized earlier. the United States at about the same time as in Ger-
Nevertheless, the experience of Russia and Japan many, but unlike in Germany were promptly out-
paralleled Western Europe's in some respects. lawed. Nevertheless, a wave of mergers resulted
Both countries embarked on major reforms that in significant concentration in U.S. industry. Inter-
removed restrictions on domestic markets and national trade also became restricted as the indus-
helped spur domestic commerce. Serfdom was trialized countries adopted restrictive and preda-
abolished in Russia in 1861, and judicial, adminis- tory commercial policies around the Great
trative, tax, and monetary reforms followed in the Depression years of the 1930s. Tariff wars and
late 1860s. In the mid-1880s the domestic market quantitative restrictions became common. The
was integrated by the expansion of the railways. United States passed the Smoot-Hawley Tariff Act,
Reforms in Japan were even more far-reaching. which created high protective tariffs. The United
After more than 260 years in virtual autarky, Japan Kingdom and France retreated from multilateral

42
trade, each emphasizing trade within its colonial
empire at the expense of outside countries. Ger- F;.gure 3.3 Postwar growth in world output
many created an elaborate mechanism of bilater- and exports
al payments and exchange controls for its trade
with central and southern Europe and with South
America. Growth rate by sector
Although the period from 1913 to 1950 inherited Agriculture
many technological innovations from the earlier Output
period of industrialization and contributed many 1965-73
Exports
of its own, their diffusion was delayed by the polit-
ical and economic turmoil. The growth of output 1973-85
dropped, and there was an even greater fall in the
growth of international trade (Figure 3.2).
Manufacturing

Global industrialization after World War II 1965-73

By the mid-1950s postwar reconstruction was vir-


1973-85
tually complete, and the world economy entered a
period of unprecedented output and trade expan-
sion (Figure 3.2). Manufacturing led the way in Mining
both output and export growth (see Figure 3.3). As
1965-73
in the nineteenth century, exports grew faster than
output.
Postwar growth in manufacturing was fueled by 1973-85
an explosion of new products, new technologies,
liberalization of international trade, and increasing 2 0 2 4 6 8 10
integration of the world economy. Assembly line Percent
production, the internal combustion engine and Manufacturing output and exports
the automobile, electricity and the consumer dura- Index (1950 = 100)
bles that came with itall of them predating the 1,500
warwere given a push by the postwar release of
postponed consumer spending. There were en-
tirely new technological advances as well: syn-
thetic materials, petrochemicals, nuclear energy,
jet aircraft, and computers and electronic products
(notably television). And great strides were made
in telecommunications technologies, microelec-
tronics, and robotics. The impact of microelec-
tronics and robots on production processes is po-
tentially so great that many observers believe the
world is now on the threshold of a "third indus-
trial revolution."
As before, some of the new technologies assisted Source: GATT 1986b.
the physical integration of world markets. The jet
aircraft cut travel time. Telecommunications made
it easier for multinational corporations to coordi-
nate subsidiaries in different countries. The associ- Three other developments marked the pattern of
ated electronic media helped shape a world market global industrialization in the postwar period.
with increasingly similar consumer tastes. Trade First, the appearance of a nonmarket alternative to
liberalization among industrialized market econo- industrialization in Eastern Europe and elsewhere
mies under the General Agreement on Tariffs and (see Box 3.1); second, decolonization in Asia, Af-
Trade (see Chapter 8) helped to create a global en- rica, and the Caribbean; and third, the rise of the
vironment that was conducive to the development multinational corporation to prominence in world
and diffusion of the new technologies. production and trade in manufactures.

43
Box 3.1 Industrialization and trade in nonmarket economies
Industrialization in the Soviet Union and other non- cluding imports) so as to reduce costs. At the same
market economies has evolved differently from the time, however, each firm is generally assured of a mar-
other cases reviewed in this chapter. These countries ket regardless of quality, since other firms are required
have suppressed market transactions domestically and by the plan to take its outputs and final consumers
have engaged in relatively little foreign trade, even have no options. Hence, there is little incentive for
among themselves. Spontaneous responses to eco- most firms, especially those producing nonmilitary
nomic incentives have contributed little to either tech- products, to improve upon their products, to maintain
nological change or specialization among economic the goodwill of customers, or to develop new markets
units. The Central Plan prepared by the government (including export markets).
has attempted to determine most economic activities. Some Western experts claim that total factor produc-
State control of the means of production has been a key tivity growth (see explanation in Box 3.3) in the Soviet
feature of this economic system. The Soviet Union pio- Union has been negative since the mid-1970s. Given
neered it in 1928, and after World War lIthe socialist the difficulty of getting access to detailed and accurate
countries of Eastern Europe and elsewhere adopted it. data on the Soviet economy, however, this assessment
Statistics on these economies are difficult to obtain. of total productivity growth is not beyond dispute.
In addition, because relative prices in these economies What is beyond dispute is the fact that by the mid-
do not reflect relative scarcities, data on GDP, total in- 1970s many economists and policymakers within the
vestment, domestic consumption, industrial output, Soviet Union and other nonmarket economies had
and so forthall of which must rely on relative prices openly recognized the inefficiencies in their industrial
for aggregationare difficult to interpret. Neverthe- sectors. Most of the countries then began opening up
less, it is quite clear that the Soviet Union and some of more to foreign trade with the industrial market econo-
the nonmarket economies have made tremendous mies, with technology acquisition the primary motive.
progress in industrialization, especially since World Poland entered into a number of industrial cooperation
War II. According to calculations by Western econo- agreements with Western firms (such as International
mists, Soviet GNP grew at an average annual rate of Harvester). Other East European nonmarket econo-
6.7 percent from 1929 to the mid-1950s; 6.1 percent in mies, as well as China, entered into similar agree-
1953-65; 5.3 percent in 1966-70; 3.8 percent in 1971-75; ments, although in most cases more conservatively.
2.7 percent in 1976-80; and 2.4 percent in 1981-85. In The Soviet Union eventually also began increasing
view of the statistical problems, these estimates are de- trade with the industrial market economies. Soviet im-
batable. But, if they are reasonably accurate, they sug- ports from the industrial market economies expanded
gest that in the two decades following World War II at about 17 percent a year in the first half of the 1970s.
(1950 to 1970), only Japan and Germany, among the Some experts estimate that technological imports in the
industrial market economies, grew faster. Growth in 1970s may have added about 0.5 percent a year to the
the other nonmarket economies during this period was Soviet industrial growth rate. Recently (1987) the So-
also rapid, although generally not so rapid as that in viet Union adopted a policy that allows joint ventures
the Soviet Union and not sustained over such long with foreign firms inside the Soviet Union.
periods. There are, however, potential problems with a policy
Much of this growth occurred in industry. Govern- of opening up more to foreign trade while still main-
ment control of the means of production allowed these taining a rigid system of central planning. Increased
countries to channel large shares of output to invest- imports ultimately require more exports to pay for
ment in industry. The large investment efforts involved them, and so domestic firms should have the flexibility
meant that in many of the countries consumption per to seek and respond quickly to export opportunities.
capita had to be constrained by the state for long pe- Lack of such flexibility and also of a price system that
riods. Nevertheless, the heavy investments together reflects relative scarcity has already contributed to bal-
with the large pools of labor available initially resulted ance of payments difficulties in some of the nonmarket
in rapid industrial expansion. economies that have opened up their foreign trade,
But the industrial sectors that appeared in these especially Poland. Several countries (for example,
economies quickly lost dynamism, owing to the inher- Hungary and China) are now trying to relax some of
ent rigidities in central planning. For instance, for most their restrictions on domestic market transactions in
firms the Central Plan specifies what to produce, which order to promote efficiency and innovation. These re-
inputs to use, where to obtain them, and where to send forms are complicated and delicate, but the potential
the outputs. Hence, most firms have had little liberty economic gains appear to be considerable.
or incentive to innovate or diversify input sources (in-

44
terms of trade against primary products were com-
Figure 3.4 Share of offshore assembly mon, and many of the newly independent coun-
products in total manufactured imports by tries thought it sensible to shift quickly to indus-
the United States from selected developing tries. Second, many people in the new countries
economies, 1973-85 associated specialization in primary commodities
(percent)
with their previous colonial status. To them, inde-
pendence called for breaking away from the colo-
nial economic system. Many also believed that
protection granted through government restric-
tions on imports had played a significant role in
the early industrialization of Europe, North Amer-
ica, and Japan. In addition, inspired by the Soviet
Union's rapid industrialization, several of the
newly independent countries combined import
substitution with government ownership, plan-
ning, and production. In these countries, govern-
ments sought to restrict domestic trade, unlike in
Europe and Japan where early industrialization
had been assisted by the easing of restrictions on
domestic trade.
Countries pursuing the import substitution strat-
egy typically started by producing final manufac-
tures to replace imports. Many enjoyed initial
bursts in the growth of manufacturing. But since
production usually required imported intermedi-
ate and capital goods, sustained industrial growth
depended on the expansion of exports to provide
Note: Data are averages for the period. Manufactured products the necessary foreign exchange. Countries that
are defined here as Standard International Trade Classification made an early transition to export expansion, such
(SITC) categories 5,6,7,8, and 9, less 68.
Total value of the finished product. as the Republic of Korea, sustained their industrial
Gross value minus the value of material components that growth. Many others did not make the transition.
originated in the United States.
Source: U.S. International Trade Commission and United They stayed in the protective import substitution
Nations. phase and their industrial development was re-
tarded.

Multinationals
Decolonization
Multinational corporations in manufacturing date
Many of the countries emerging from colonialism back as far as the nineteenth century (Singer, a
in the postwar period chose an industrial develop- U.S. firm, established a factory in Glasgow in 1867
ment strategy that emphasized import substitution to manufacture sewing machines), and those in
behind high government protectionsimilar to the primary commodities date back even farther. But it
strategy adopted by Argentina, Brazil, Turkey, and is only since the 1960s that multinationals have
other independent developing countries in the become major actors in shaping world industrial-
1930s. Several factors contributed to the appeal of ization. Today, between 25 and 30 percent of the
this approach. First, during the turbulent years world's stock of foreign direct investmentthe
spanning the world wars, countries that had spe- channel for multinationals' investmentsis in de-
cialized as exporters of primary products found veloping countries; about 40 percent of this is in
their access to export markets and to manufactured the manufacturing sector. Manufacturing multina-
imports reduced. Their terms of trade fell drasti- tionals have been attracted to some of the large
cally. This is what had prompted Argentina and developing countries, especially in Latin America,
others to take the protective import substitution because of trade policies that restricted imports of
course in the 1930s. In the first two decades after final manufactures. But in many other countries,
World War II, predictions of a secular decline in the especially those in Southeast Asia, the attraction

45
has been the availability of semiskilled industrial specifications to producers in developing coun-
labor at low cost. Some developing countries de- tries, purchase the finished products, then sell
rive a significant part of their manufacturing ex- them at home and abroad. This is akin to the
ports from local subsidiaries of multinationals. Al- putting-out system in textiles which was adopted
though data for recent years are not available, in in preindustrial England. With modern transport
the middle and late 1970s the share of multina- and communications, it probably is no more diffi-
tionals in manufactured exports from Korea and cult for today's merchants to organize a putting-
Mexico was around 30 percent. In Brazil the share out system between New York and Hong Kong, or
was more than 40 percent, and in Singapore more between Tokyo and Seoul, than it was for the early
than 90 percent. English merchants to organize their putting-out
Multinationals have made it easier for some de- system between London and the surrounding vil-
veloping countries to begin exporting manufac- lages.
tures without going through an initial phase of im-
port substitution. Some of these corporations have Postwar performance of developing countries
located in developing countries with the principal As a group, the developing countries still have
aim of producing in order to export to their home only a small share in world manufacturing output,
and other markets. Typically, this has occurred but their output and exports of manufactures have
when the production processes have become rou- nonetheless grown more rapidly than those of the
tine and thus require large inputs of semiskilled industrial countries since the 1960s (see Tables 3.1
labor. Locating in developing countries then allows and 3.2). No developing economy figured among
the multinational firms to reduce labor costs. the world's top thirty exporters of manufactured
Beginning in the late 1960s several multina- products in 1965. Twenty years later Hong Kong
tionals began rationalizing their global production. and the Republic of Korea were among the top
Whereas before, most foreign subsidiaries had fifteen, with export shares close to those of Swe-
produced finished products, often with technolog- den and Switzerland. Singapore and Brazil were
ical and intermediate inputs from the parent com- among the top twenty, with export shares close to
pany, now all the subsidiaries were increasingly those of Denmark and Finland. Although this per-
linked into a unified production process. Each per- formance occurred during a period of unprece-
formed only those aspects of the manufacturing dented real growth in world output and trade in
process in which it had a comparative advantage. manufactured products, it is remarkable that de-
New subsidiaries were in some cases set up in de- veloping countries sustained their progress even
veloping countries to perform the labor-intensive when the world economy slowed after 1973. More-
activities. This system is not always confined to over, manufactured exports from developing
transactions among subsidiaries of the same countries have become more sophisticated (see Ta-
multinational. Sometimes the arrangements are ble 3.3). Developing countries have diversified
between locally owned companies and foreign- from traditional labor-intensive products (such as
owned companies. The foreign-owned companies textiles) or those based on natural resources (such
are not always multinationals, and sometimes they as crude petrochemicals, cork, and paper) to chem-
may not even be based in the domestic economy. icals and engineering products.
The arrangement is known as international sub- There are now fears that microelectronics and
contracting. Sometimes the terms "offshore as- robotics will reduce the labor-cost advantage
sembly" and "sourcing" are used. Figure 3.4 which the developing countries have exploited to
shows the share of offshore assembly products in expand their role in world manufacturing. Similar
total manufactured imports by the United States fears about the effects of machinery on employ-
from four developing economies. Exemption from ment in earlier times proved unfounded. Increas-
duties of the value of U.S. components in the off- ing mechanization displaced some workers, but it
shore assembly imports has encouraged U.S. firms also introduced new opportunities that led in the
to use this arrangement. Similar arrangements oc- long run to higher employment. The same could
cur between manufacturing firms in other industri- be true of the long-run impact of microelectronics
alized countries and producers in developing and robotics on industrialization in developing
countries. countries. Box 3.2 discusses the effect of techno-
An important form of subcontracting, especially logical change in textiles and clothingtwo indus-
in textiles, is an arrangement whereby firms based tries that are of special importance to industrializa-
in the industrialized countries provide design tion in developing countries.

46
Table 3.1 Shares of production and exports of manufactures by country group, 1965, 1973, and 1985
(percent)

Share in production Share in exports


Country group 1965 1973 1985 1965 1973 1985
Industrialmarketeconomies 85.4 83.9 81.6 92.5 90.0 82.3
Developing countries 14.5 16.0 18.1 7.3 9.9 17.4
Low-income 7.5 7.0 6.9 2.3 1.8 2.1
Middle-income 7.0 9.0 11.2 5.0 8.1 15.3
High-income oil exporters 0.1 0.1 0.3 0.2 0.1 0.3
Total 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0

Table 3.2 Growth in production and exports of manufactures by country group, 1965-73,
1973-85, and 1965-85
(percent)

Growth in production Growth in exports


Country group 1965-73 1973 -85 1965-85 1965-73 1973-85 1965-85
Industrial market economies 5.3 3.0 3.8 10.6 4.4 6.8
Developing countries 9.0 6.0 7.2 11.6 12.3 12.2
Low-income 8.9 7.9 7.5 2.4 8.7 6.0
Middle-income 9.1 5.0 6.6 14.9 12.9 13.8
High-income oil exporters 10.6 75a 8.4 16.2 11.5 16.0
Total 5.8 3.5 4.5 10.7 5.3 7.4
a. End period is 1984 instead of 1985.

Table 3.3 Structure of manufactured exports from developing countries, 1970-84


Share of developing Growth
countries' exports rate'
Description 1970 1984 1970-84
Traditional manufactured exports
Labor-intensive
Textiles and apparel (84 and 65) 31.3 24.8 11.8
Footwear (85) 1.8 2.9 18.2
Other labor-intensive (61 and 83) 2.9 2.3 11.6
Total 36.0 30.0 12.4
Resource-based
Wood and cork (63) 3.6 1.5 6.9
Paper manufactures (64) 0.8 1.1 17.6
Other resource-based (52 and 56) 0.8 0.9 14.5
Total 5.2 3.5 12.2

Nontraditional manufactured exports


Electrical machinery (72) 16.1 16.7 14.1
Chemicals (51) 8.3 9.9 15.3
Nonelectrical machinery (71) 4.2 8.7 20.1
Transport equipment (73) 2.6 5.2 20.0
Iron and steel (67) 6.2 6.5 14.2
Other nontraditional" 21.4 19.5 12.9
Total 58.8 66.5 15.1

Total 100.0 100.0 14.0


Note: Figures in parentheses are the SITC categories for the respective product group.
Developing countries' exports of the listed product as a share of developing countries' total exports of manufactured products defined as SITC categories
5, 6, 7, and 8, less 68.
The rate of growth of developing countries' exports of the listed product during 1970-84 in constant dollars.
Total manufacturing exports less traditional manufactured exports.
Rest of nontraditional exports.
Source: Murray (background paper).

47
Box 3.2 Technical change and comparative advantage: the case of textiles and clothing
Developing countries that have embarked on a path of economies and the developing economies remained so
efficient industrialization have often done so partly large that a broad range of techniques could exist side
through the export of simple, labor-intensive manufac- by side.
tures, in particular clothing and textiles, to industrial The clothing industry was never able to make similar
market economies. But rapid technical change in such strides in productivity because of the inherent obsta-
industries has led to a new form of export pessimism. cles to automating the functions of a machinist manip-
Surprisingly, perhaps, the textile industrynot nor- ulating a soft, limp fabric. But thanks to the promise of
mally considered a leading industryhas consistently microelectronics, clothing industrialists are now begin-
registered higher-than-average labor productivity ning to echo the textile industrialists of the 1960s.
gains in the industrial market economies in recent dec- A recent study sought to assess the likely impact of
ades. These gains have been brought about by a series microelectronics on developing countries' comparative
of labor-saving innovations since World War II: the ra- advantage in clothing (Hoffman 1985). This study
tionalization of production in more specialized factor- found signs of an increasing rate of innovations in
ies, dramatically higher speeds in spinning, weaving, clothing machinery, most of them based on microelec-
and knitting (helped in part by the growing use of syn- tronics. Recent innovations promised substantial sav-
thetic fibers), and the introduction of radical, new tech- ings in material and labor costs, as well as other advan-
niques (open-end spinning, shuttleless weaving, non- tages (such as time saving) in the preassembly phase of
woven fabrics, tufted carpets, and so on). In the 1960s production (when fabrics are cut). In the assembly
many textile industrialists predicted a sharp reversal of (or sewing) phasewhich accounts for a significantly
comparative advantage in favor of the advanced indus- larger share of total costs than preassembly-
trialized countries. productivity gains from microelectronics were also pos-
These predictions turned out to be not entirely right, sible, but on a less dramatic scale. The productivity
but not entirely wrong. By and large, innovations in gains in both stages required costly capital investment,
textiles did succeed in halting the further loss of com- a minimum scale of efficient operation larger than that
parative advantage in the high-wage industrialized of the normal size of firm in this industry, increasing
countriesby means of a substantial reduction in labor managerial sophistication, andin some casesa loss
content. The textile industries of Germany, Italy, and of flexibility. The study judged that, given the prob-
the United States are, unlike their clothing industries, lems in adopting the new technology, its rate of diffu-
broadly competitive (although they still cling to protec- sion would be slow in the coming decade, and the new
tion). The reversal in comparative advantage was in- technologies might not reach their maximum impact
complete for several reasons. Firmsespecially in until the first years of the next century. The study con-
Europefound that the market would not allow them cluded that protection by the industrial countries
to produce standardized textiles on the scale that would remain the more immediate threat to develop-
would justify the most capital-intensive equipment. In ing countries' exports.
addition, the wage gap between the industrial market
/

Not all of the developing countries have pro- have been common to most industrializations and
gressed at the same rate, however. Some have tries to draw some lessons from the period before
done far better than others. Figure 3.5 compares World War II.
production and exports of manufactures for forty-
three economies before and after 1973. Because of Industrialization and structural change
differences in the degree of distortion in exchange
rates and in relative sectorál prices, comparisons Typically, the share of manufacturing in GDP has
based on the dollar value of manufactured produc- risen in the early phase of industrialization. After a
tion mean little. Export shares are more revealing. time, however, it has tended to fall, while the
By 1985, the forty-three economies accounted for basic underlying forces of industrialization
two-thirds of manufactured exports from develop- technological change, specialization, and trade
ing countries; the first fifteen alone accounted for have continued to propel output per capita up-
about 60 percent. Chapters 4 through 7 attempt to ward. Thus, for most countries, the ratio of (a) the
explain why recent performance has varied so share of manufacturing (or of industry) in GDP to
widely from country to country. The rest of this (b) GDP per capita follows an inverted U as indus-
chapter discusses the economic processes that trialization proceeds (see Figure 3.6). This same

48
relationship emerges, although not as clearly, dustry and services. Similar trends occur in the
when the ratio is compared across different coun- sectoral distribution of employment.
tries at a single point in time (see Figure 3.7). The Initial discussion of these long-term trends
share of services has also tended to rise over time; (Cohn Clark in 1940 and Simon Kuznets in the
its upward trend lasts longer than that of manufac- 1950s and 1960s) were confined mainly to the in-
turing. Agriculture's share in output gradually de- dustrialized countries. Since then, a number of
clines to accommodate the increased share of in- scholars, notably Hollis Chenery, have studied

Figure 3.5 Indicators of industrial performance of developing economies


1966-73 1973 -85
Share Share Change in
Growth Growth of manu- Growth Growth of manu- share of
in manu- in man u- factu red in manu- in manu- factu red manufactured
factu ring factu red exports facturing factu red exports exports from
1973 Rankings value added exports (1973)b 1985 Ranking' value added exports (1985)' 1973 to 1985
Hong Kong U 0 0 1. Hong Kong U U 0
Republic of Korea U U U 2. Republic of Korea U U 0 +
Yugoslavia U U 0 3. Singapore 0 U U +
Singapore U U U 4. Brazil U U U +
India U U 0 5. Yugoslavia U U U
Brazil U U 6.India U U U
Mexico U U 7. Malaysia U U U
Argentina U D U 8. Mexico 0 U U
Pakistan U 0 U 9. Turkey O U U
Greece U 0 U 10. Philippines U U U
Malaysia o 0 U 11. Thailand U 0 U
Thailand O U U 12. Indonesia U U U
Colombia 0 U U 13. Greece O U U
Philippines o 0 U 14. Pakistan U U U
Egypt 0 U 0 15. Argentina U U 0
Turkey o 0 U 16. Morocco U 0 U
Jamaica U 0 U 17. Tunisia U U U
Morocco 0 U U 18. Colombia U U U
Zimbabwe U U U 19. Egypt U U U
Guatemala U U U 20.Peru U U U
El Salvador U U U 21. Sri Lanka U U U
Dominican Republic U 0 U 22. Botswana U U U
Tunisia U U U 23. Venezuela U U U
Sierra Leone U U U 24. Zimbabwe U U U
Costa Rica U U U 25. Jamaica o U U
Venezuela U U U 26. Trinidad and Tobago o U 0
Zaire U U U 27. Uruguay U 0 U
Trinidad and Tobago U U U 28. Costa Rica O 0 U
Côte d'Ivoire U U 29. Chile O U U
Indonesia U U 0 30. Guatemala U U 0
Algeria U U U 31. Cyprus 0 0 0 +
Kenya U 0 U 32. Côte d'Ivoire U U U
Uruguay U 0 U 33. Dominican Republic U U U
Nigeria o 0 U 34. El Salvador U 0 U
Tanzania O U U 35. Kenya U U 0
Sn Lanka o U 36. Cameroon U U U
Chile U 0 U 37. Senegal U U U
Senegal U U U 38. Zaire U U U
Ghana U U U 39. Algeria U U 0
Cyprus 0 U U 40. Sierra Leone U U U
Cameroon O U U 41. Tanzania U U U
Peru U U U 42. Nigeria U U U
Botswana U 0 U 43. Ghana U U U
Based on the share in manufactured exports from developing economies.
Share of manufactured exports from developing economies.
The + sign indicates that the share in 1985 is greater than in 1973, and the - symbol indicates that the share in 1985 is smaller than in 1973.

Growth rates (percent) Export share (percent)


o equal to or more than 15.0 equal to or more than 10.0
o 10.0 to less than 15.0 o 5.0 to less than 10.0
0 7.5 to less than 10.0 o 2.5 to less than 5.0
o 5.0 to less than 7.5 o 0.5tolessthan2.5
O 0.0 to less than 5.0 U 0.2tolessthan0.5
U less than 0.0 U less than 0.2

49
growth in agricultural employment; in the later
Figure 3.6 Historical relationship between phases, high growth of employment in services is
GDP per capita and the share of industry made possible by lower growth in industrial and
in GDP in selected industrial countries, agricultural employment.
1870-1984
Agricultural productivity and industrialization
Share of industry in GDP (percent)a
60 Agriculture's reduced share in GDP has, in many
countries, coincided with higher agricultural out-
put and productivity. Britain experienced large in-
50 Germany" creases in agricultural productivity in the second
half of the eighteenth century, before its industrial
40 Japan revolution. Europe and North America went
France
through a similar process later. Japan substantially
increased its agricultural yields around the second
United Kingdom
30 half of the 1800s.
United States Increasing agricultural productivity facilitates in-
20
dustrialization in at least four ways:
Higher rural incomes raise the demand for
manufactures along with the demand for other
10 goods. Moreover, because the share of food in total
expenditure tends to decline as income rises, rising
0
rural incomes also lead to a larger proportion of in-
comes being spent on manufactures.
0 50 100 150 200 250 300
Index of real GDP per capita (1965 = 100)
Rising agricultural productivity increases the
supply of agricultural raw materials for industry.
Note: The six data points shown for each country represent the
Additional foreign exchange made possible by
following approximate time periods: (from left to right) 1870, increased agricultural exports can be used to im-
1913, 1950, 1965, 1975, and 1984.
Industry includes manufacturing, mining, and construction.
port inputs for industry. Higher farm incomes
Data for 1950 onward refer to the Federal Republic of Ger- from increased agricultural productivity can also
many. generate additional savings, which can then be
Source: Kuznets 1957, appendix table 2; Maddison 1982, tables A4
and B2; and World Bank data. made available for investment in industry. Japan's
success in its transition to rapid industrial growth
in the early twentieth century was partly due to its
success in mobilizing agricultural savings. Agricul-
ture financed 27 percent of nonagricultural invest-
post-World War II trends in developing countries, ment from 1888 to 1902, and 23 percent from 1903
extending the analyses to trends within industry to 1922. In the earlier period two-thirds of the in-
(see Box 3.3.). The economic explanations behind vestment was channeled through the public sector,
the long-term trends rest, on the supply side, on courtesy of the land tax. In the later period this
technological change and its differential impacts share fell to a quarter (the private sector accounted
on economic sectors, the induced specializations, for the rest).
and the resulting trade and flow of resources Rising farm productivity initially allows new
among and within sectors. On the demand side, entrants to the labor force to be employed outside
the pattern of consumption changes with income agriculture. Later, it allows labor to be released
growth, and this induces changes in the structure from agriculture and to be fed without sharp rises
of production. in domestic food prices or recourse to large and
In the early phases of industrialization, greater unsustainable imports of food.
use of machinery, especially in manufacturing, in-
creases labor productivity and output. As industri- The sen.'ice sector and industrialization
alization continues, further increases in labor pro-
ductivity reduce the growth of industry's demand Growth in the share of services tends to persist
for labor. In the early phases, high growth of em- longer than growth in the share of manufacturing
ployment in industry is made possible by low as industrialization proceeds. Much of the growth

50
Figure 3.7 Relationship between GD? per capita and the share of manufacturing value added in GD!'
in selected economies, 1984

Philippines
Egypt / Uruguay
Zimbabwe// Brazil
Turkey \
4
Bolivia Peru
Chile
Zambia)
- Thailand
Pakistan Developing economy
S
Senegal Colombia
S
. Industrial economy
Morocco
India Share of manufacturing value added in GDP (percent)
S Sri Lanka Jordan 40
S
Kenya Tunisia Republic Federal Republic of Germany
Indonesia of Korea
- Bangladesh Belgium
/ s Nigeria 30 Areentina Singapore
Aistria
s Japan
Côte d'Ivoire Mexico Italy.
Sudan / Hong Kong , France
Finland United States S
Tanzania , Spain
Netherlands Sweden
T
Ghana 20 - Venezuela Israel
Somalia j
Denmark Australia
Greece New Zealand * Canada
Zaire Malaysia Norway
United Kingdom
10
Algeria

0
0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14
GDP per capita (thousands of dollars)

in the share of services reflects the increasing spe- in later phases of industrialization. Fourth, in-
cialization and urbanization that come with indus- creasing labor demand leads to the commercializa-
trialization. First, the factorythe symbol of tion of domestic services, as housewives and other
industrializationrequires a vast, but less visible domestic workers join the formal labor force. Ac-
service infrastructure to function effectively. Trans- tivities that previously fell outside the statistics
portation, distribution, communications, finance, thus begin to boost the recorded output of ser-
and insurance, to name just a few, are all services vices. Fifth, urbanization, which accompanies in-
that have to expand to facilitate industrial growth. dustrialization, requires additional services: police,
Second, some services (for example, cleaning, in- sanitation, city administration, and so forth.
formation processing, advertising, and so forth) Since service occupations, on the whole, are less
that previously were performed in-house by in- amenable to automation, an increase in the value
dustrial firms have progressively been contracted of service output would normally require more la-
to firms in the service sector. Third, just as the bor input than an increase of equal value in the
higher income demand elasticity for manufactures output of industry. This explains why the share of
(compared with agricultural products) spurs the services in employment rises faster than the share
rapid growth of manufacturing output in the early of services in GDP.
phases of industrialization, so the higher income These factors account for the shift toward ser-
demand elasticity for services (compared with vices within the individual economy. Growing
manufactures) encourages the growth of services integration in the world economy has added

51
Box 3.3 Statistical studies of economic growth and industrialization
Statistical studies of economic growth fall into two mostly food products, first to industrial products and
broad categories. One category extends the celebrated then to services and leisure. In response to these de-
Clark-Kuznets studies to a large number of industrial mand changes, the share of agriculture in production is
and developing countries. The aim is to describe stan- expected to fall, the share of industry to rise, and later
dard patterns of growth in economic sectors and across the share of services to rise. In addition to income per
different branches of manufacturing. Another category capita, many of the studies also examine the role of
tries to account for the different sources of economic population size and the endowment of natural re-
growth and to isolate the contribution of rising produc- sources (or the availability of foreign resources).
tivity. Strictly speaking, the structural features, such as the
The studies that seek to establish standard patterns share of manufacturing in GDP, and the principal "ex-
focus on income per capita. They postulate that as con- planatory" variable, income per capita, are joint out-
sumers' incomes increase, their demands shift from comes of underlying economic processes that are not
explained in the statistical model. Hence, no causality
can be inferred. Nevertheless, the standard patterns
Box figure 3.3A Per capita GDP and the share produced by these studies provide useful statistical
benchmarks for inquiries into a very complex process
of manufacturing
(see Box figure 3.3A).
Some studies attempt to provide similar standard
patterns for the various branches of manufacturing.
Share of manufacturing in commodity GDP (percent)a
For instance, it is postulated that at low per capita in-
70 comes, demand for manufactures is concentrated on
Large countries food and other light manufactures, but as per capita
Small countries incomes increase, demand shifts to consumer durables
60
with ample and other heavy manufactures. The demand stimulus
resources, thus provided is supposed to be translated into pro-
industrial orientation duction, in part with the help of higher savings made
possible by the higher per capita incomes. While all
this may be true in general, rapid change in industrial
40 technology and in international specialization reduces
the relevance for policy of statistical patterns at the
Small countries detailed level of industrial subsectors.
with ample The studies that seek to account for the sources of
resources, growth start from the premise that countries can grow
20
primary orientation either through the accumulation of factor inputs (ex-
tensive growth) or through the more productive use of
inputs (intensive growth). For fast growth, sustained
Small countries through time, both are necessary. Rapid growth rates
with modest can usually be achieved with expansion in factor inputs
resources at early stages of industrialization, but with time it be-
0
comes more difficult to expand factor inputs, especially
100 200 400 7001,000 2,000 3,000 labor, and efficiency in the use of all economic re-
Per capita GDP (1970 dollars) sources becomes critical to further growth in GDP. To-
tal factor productivity growth is a concept that tries to
capture productivity growth in the use of all physical
Note: A country was classified as large if its population in 1970 was
20 million or more; otherwise, it was classified as small. A small inputs. It is usually derived as a residual, after subtract-
country was classified as having modest resources if its average per ing the contribution attributable to growth in the use of
capita production of primaries (defined as GDP less services and labor, land, and capital from GDP growth. Since land
manufacturing) in 1960-73 was less than $84 (in 1970 prices); other- grows slowly, if at all, in most countries, a good ap-
wise, it was classified as having ample resources. A small country
with ample resources was classified as having an industrial orienta- proximation is the residual obtained after subtracting
tion if in most years during the period 1969-73 its value added in the contributions of labor and capital growth from GDP
manufacturing was above the regression plane that predicts manu- growth. Box figure 3.3B shows estimates of the growth
facturing value added using per capita GDP and population (for rates of real GDP, total factor (capital and labor) inputs,
small countries with ample resources); if in most years the actual
manufacturing value added was below the regression plane, the and total factor productivity.
country was classified as having a primary orientation. The estimates were obtained by examining the
The horizontal axis is in log scale. The curves are plots of a logistic growth of countries at different levels of industrializa-
function with the population variable held constant at the average tion for the period 1960-75. Changes in the quality of
value for each group. The number of observations at higher income
levels was insufficient to estend the curve for small countries with capital and labor that occur over time have been taken
modest resources beyond $400 per capita income. into account in deriving the estimates for each country.
a. Commodity GDP is GDI' minus the value of services. Differences in the stage of industrialization may ac-
Source: UNIDO 1979, figure VI, p. 47, and Annex I.
count for some of the differences in performance
among the countries shown. Nevertheless, the general

52
picture conveyed by the figure is valid. Japan and the than Argentina'sthe result of differences in produc-
Republic of Korea have achieved high GDP growth tivity growth.
rates through higher growth rates in both factor inputs Like the patterns-of-growth approach, the sources-
and factor productivity. In contrast, the high GDP of-growth approach does not provide explanations;
growth rates of Brazil and Venezuela have been based rather it provides a useful way of viewing the outcome
mainly on the growth of factor inputs. Furthermore, of the complex process of economic growth. Some re-
the figure shows that although factor inputs grew at cent studies (Chenery, Robinson, and Syrquin 1986)
about the same rate in Argentina and Colombia, the have attempted to encompass the two methodologies
latter's real GDP growth was about 2 percent higher within a single framework.

Box figure 3.3B Total factor productivity and real GDP growth in selected countries, 1960-75

Real GDP growth (percent)


12

11

10

4
7
3
6
2
5
I
4
0
3

I
0

Note: Real GDP growth is the sum of the contributions from total factor input growth and total factor productivity growth. The closer a point isto
the total factor productivity growth axis, the greater the relative contribution of productivity to real GDP growth. As one moves horizontally
toward the total factor input growth axis, the relative contribution of productivity to real GDP growth falls and that of factor inputs rises.
Source: Adapted from Chenery, Robinson, and Syrquin 1986, figure 2-2.

53
an international dimension. Several developing tiles to heavier industries, they had to rely on big-
countries (for example, Brazil, Mexico, the Repub- ger plants to reap economies of scale. This too is
lic of Korea, and Singapore) have been able to sup- changing. It is now profitable to produce steel in
ply the relatively labor-scarce industrialized coun- mills with a capacity of around half a million tons;
tries with labor-intensive manufactures at lower in the old integrated steel mills, plants of less than
prices. Although the industrialized countries have 2 million tons were inefficient. In the microelec-
sometimes tried to resist this trend, they have also tronics industry, efficient plants can be much
adjusted to it, partly by increasing their exports of smaller than in the older branches of manufac-
services such as banking, insurance, engineering, turing.
computer software, and marketing.
Lessons from industrialization experiences
Structural change within manufacturing before World War II

World industrialization initially centered on tex- What are the lessons to be drawn from the experi-
tiles, later moved to iron, steel, and engineering ences of countries which have followed a success-
products based on steel, then to chemicals, electri- ful path to industrialization? This section examines
cal products, and, finally, to today's electronic and five of the most important issues: the initial
microelectronic products. Most of the countries conditionscountry size, population size, and re-
that industrialized before World War II followed source endowment; policies toward domestic and
this product sequence, at least as far as electrical foreign trade; education; transportation and com-
products. Is this pattern of change within the sin- munications infrastructure; and the institutional
gle sector of manufacturing as inevitable as the one and macroeconomic background.
by which agriculture first gives way to manufactur-
ing and then manufacturing itself gives way to Initial conditions
services?
Textiles are preeminent in the early phase of in- A country with a large domestic market is in a
dustrialization mainly because clothing is a good better position to establish industrial plants that
for which there is growing demand in countries take advantage of economies of scale. Since dis-
with low, but rising, income levels. In addition, tance between countries in many cases confers nat-
most countries have a long history of textile pro- ural protection to domestic firms, everything else
duction by artisans. Moreover, until quite recently, being equal, a country with a larger domestic mar-
textiles technologies have been simple and stable. ket can begin industrializing earlier than one with
All in all, then, it was natural for most countries to a smaller domestic market. A large geographical
begin industrializing by producing textiles (Box size and a large population can, together, produce
3.2). The same factors also explain the early im- a large domestic market, unless agricultural pro-
portance of leather goods, food processing, furni- ductivity is exceptionally low. Hence, a large coun-
ture, ceramics, building materials, and household try with a large population can industrialize earlier.
utensils. But this has not always been the case.
By the time most of today's developing countries Although the United Kingdom is a small coun-
started to industrialize (in the postwar period), the try, its growing agricultural productivity in the
choice of products and processes in manufacturing early 1700s supported an increasing population
was much wider and the world much more inte- and provided an expanded domestic market that
grated. Countries could choose not to follow the helped spur the Industrial Revolution. Japan, a
product sequence that had occurred in the prewar small country with a relatively large population,
period. For example, it was possible to create an went through a similar process. Switzerland has
engineering industry without producing iron and industrialized successfully despite its smallness in
steel and to produce chemicals without refining size and population. By contrast, Australia and Ar-
petroleum. Nonetheless, some developing coun- gentina are both large countries. In the late nine-
tries, emulating the previous generation of indus- teenth and early twentieth centuries, their popula-
trializers, built steel mills, refineries, factories pro- tions were expanding. In 1895, the per capita
ducing consumer durables, and other heavy (or income of Argentina was as high as that of Ger-
"late") industries. Some of these enterprises sur- many, Holland, and Belgium; Australia's was
vive only with the aid of high protective barriers. higher, exceeding that of the United States. Yet
As the industrialized countries moved from tex- neither country industrialized in the nineteenth

54
century, and neither is among today's major in- It is unclear how these shifts of foreign trade
dustrial countries. policyliberal followed by protectionist, and vice
A rich endowment of natural resources may pro- versashaped industrialization before World War
vide a country with the financial means to import II. Domestic markets were generally competitive,
foreign technology and with the high incomes to so inefficiencies arising from protectionism may
support a large domestic market for industrial have been reduced, particularly in countries with
products. But several of the countries that became large internal markets such as Germany and the
rich from natural resources were slow to industri- United States. What is clear is that imports were
alize. In the sixteenth century, Spain was the rich- the main channel of new technology in the initial
est country in Europe, thanks mainly to the min- stages of industrialization in each country except
eral resources of South America. But Spain did not the United Kingdom. Furthermore, exports pro-
initiate the Industrial Revolution, and the great vided a powerful demand stimulus; the countries
surge in industrialization in eighteenth- and whose exports grew rapidly achieved the fastest
nineteenth-century Europe largely passed it by. overall economic growth.

Domestic and foreign trade policies Education, skills formation, and technology adaptation

Many of the countries that industrialized success- The transition from a primarily agricultural and
fully in the nineteenth century first acquired tech- trading economy to an industrial economy has re-
nology through imports, then rapidly moved to quired, at least in the initial stages, an increase in
producing manufactures for export. Policies that the skills of the labor force. To use foreign technol-
allowed opportunities on foreign markets to be ogy effectively, producers must examine the
communicated to domestic producers, that al- choices available, make intelligent selections, and
lowed domestic resources to move freely in re- adapt them to local conditions (see Box 3.4). All of
sponse to the opportunities, and that comple- this calls for education.
mented existing resources through education, More than general education is required, but
training, and infrastructure all contributed to the high achievements at the frontiers of science are
success. not. Science played a minor role in the first indus-
Unrestricted domestic trade was a precursor of trial revolution in Britain. Scientific excellence
Britain's industrial revolution. Many other Euro- played an important role in Germany's rise to in-
pean countries and Japan began their industrializa- dustrial prominence in the nineteenth century, but
tion with reforms that liberalized their domestic its system of polytechnical institutes, which taught
trade. Foreign trade policies, however, were incon- basic industrial skills, probably mattered more.
sistent. Episodes of free tradesuch as those in the The United States and Japan both rose to world
United Kingdom after 1846, in France during the industrial leadership by copying and modifying
1860s, in Germany in the 1830s and 1860s, and in foreign technologies. (Until the early 1900s the
the United States during the 1840s and 1850s United States trailed behind the United Kingdom,
were mixed with periods of restrictions on trade. France, and Germany in major scientific discov-
The aims of foreign trade policy varied widely, too. eries, but not in practical innovations and inven-
In some cases foreign trade restrictions arose from tions.)
a desire to protect domestic industry. Examples in- State support for technical education made sig-
clude British restrictions on machinery exports un- nificant contributions to French and German in-
til 1842 and tariff increases in Germany in the 1840s dustrialization. The United States broadly emu-
and in the United States after the Civil War. At lated the German system of technical education. In
other times, import restrictions were prompted by addition, its government established a system of
the desire to protect agriculture. This was the moti- financial support for research in universities. Pri-
vation behind Britain's Corn Laws, the increases in vate industry also maintained research laboratories
German and French tariffs in the 1870s, and the that sometimes received public support. Although
Smoot-Hawley tariffs in the United States in 1930. some of these laboratories conducted original re-
In Germany, France, and the United States, how- search, one of their main tasks has been to spot
ever, the tariffs were also extended to cover manu- innovations elsewhere and provide the expertise
factured imports. In other cases, import restric- that makes rapid imitation possible. Japan has also
tions were adopted with the balance of payments shown a strong and continuing commitment to ed-
in mind. ucation. By 1870 it had achieved a literacy rate that

55
Box 3.4 Technology acquisition and adaptation: the experiences of Japan
and the United States
In a variety of ways the Japanese deliberately adapted the need to adapt foreign technology to domestic cir-
Western technology to preserve scarce capital re- cumstances. Dutch water control technology, for in-
sources and use abundant labor. In textiles, for exam- stance, was introduced without considering that, in ad-
ple, they purchased older, secondhand machines often dition to tidal forces, mountain runoff was a major
discarded as obsolete by the Lancashire mills. Once source of flooding. Similarly, the Japanese government
installed, the machines were operated at high speeds in 1871 imported a vast mechanized silk-reeling plant
and for longer hours than was the prevailing practice in from France. Although it was intended as a model fac-
the United Kingdom or the United States. Greater tory, private business discovered that it could not prof-
quantities of labor were lavished in servicing the ma- itably operate such capital-intensive plants.
chines and maintaining them in a decent state of repair. The United States' earlier adaptation of technology
When the Japanese eventually reached the point of in the nineteenth century was very different from that
building their own textile machines, they substituted of Japan, but as successful. Endowed with an abun-
wood for iron wherever possible. They also introduced dance of natural resources, but with a scarcity of labor,
cheaper raw materials into production, as in the case of the United States adapted its technology accordingly.
cotton spinning, and added more labor to each spin- Technology imported from Britain was adapted, when-
fling machine to handle the increased frequency of bro- ever possible, to the extensive exploitation of natural
ken threads. They also employed ring-spinning tech- resources. For example, although the United States
nology when virtually every other textile giant, apart had a later industrial start than Britain, it quickly estab-
from the United States and Brazil, was using mule- lished a worldwide leadership in the design, produc-
spinning machines. When continued improvements in tion, and use of woodworking machinery. It was char-
ring-spinning technology and changes in global factor acteristic of these machines that they were wasteful of
prices made ring spinning the dominant technology in wood, which was abundant in the United States.
the world, Japan was well positioned to increase its These examples show that, ultimately, "appropri-
market share (Rosenberg, background paper; Saxon- ate" technology is what a country creates for itself,
house 1985). using all the means available to itincluding "inappro-
It is noteworthy that Japan at first did not understand priate" foreign technologyefficiently.

compared favorably with those in Western Europe. many, Italy, and Japan, the financing was often
Today, industrial research is carried out mostly direct. In others, it was indirectfor instance, land
within private firms, but in the early period of in- grants (as in the United States) and guarantees of
dustrialization the government helped to promote debt issues of private companies (as in France).
technological change, for example by setting up
demonstration factories which were later sold to Stable institutional and macroeconomic environment
the private sector. Laws and institutions that allow markets to func-
Transportation and communications networks tion efficientlyproperty rights, standardized
weights and measures, patent laws and so forth
One of the better known aspects of nineteenth- have helped to promote rapid and efficient indus-
century industrialization is the importance of rail- trialization. Laws and institutions should provide
ways. Transportation and communications net- a stable environment that promotes long-term in-
works integrated and expanded domestic markets vestments and risk taking. Yet they should also be
and increased their efficiency. They also integrated flexible enough to allow institutional innovations.
domestic markets into the global economy, making For example, faced with the problem of financing
it easier for exporters to compete. But transporta- the capital-intensive railway system in the early
tion and communications networks are capital- 1800s, Britain lifted its earlier prohibition on the
intensive, and therefore expensive, especially dur- formation of joint-stock companies. Late industri-
ing the early stages of industrialization. Except for alizing countries in Europe, particularly Germany,
Britain, governments of countries industrializing pioneered such innovations as the joint-stock bank
in the nineteenth century helped to finance the and the investment bank in the second half of the
construction of transportation and communica- 1800s, and the United States devised the modern
tions networks. In some countries, such as Ger- corporation in the 1920s. Such flexibility greatly

56
assisted industrialization. early industrialization, but further progress along
Industrialization requires large investments in the path is greatly influenced by government pol-
machines and infrastructure, especially in its early icy. Provision of infrastructure and education has
stages. Moreover, one of the most important been important. A stable institutional and macro-
means by which technological innovations have economic environment and domestic and foreign
been incorporated in production has been invest- trade policies which allowed producers and factors
ment in new machines. Macroeconomic policies in of production to respond to incentives have been
the countries industrializing in the nineteenth cen- crucial. Much has changed since World War II, but
tury encouraged domestic savings and thus pro- the essence of industrialization is as it was before:
vided the funds required for investment. They also the interaction of technological change, specializa-
made foreigners, especially the British and the tion, and trade. Some of the policies that proved
French, willing to provide loans and direct invest- successful in the years before World War II may
ments. not be applicable today. But the key to success is
stifi to choose policies that allow economies to uti-
Conclusion
lize this interaction fully to their advantage. The
Initial conditions of size, population, and natural chapters that follow discuss what this means for
resources may influence the timing and pattern of today's developing countries.

57

You might also like