Kawamura, The Formation of Global Economic Law Under Aspects of The Autopoietic System, 2012

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 30

Working Paper Series

Studies on Multicultural Societies No.7

The Formation of Global Economic Law:


Under Aspects of the Autopoietic System

Satoko Kawamura

Afrasian Research Centre, Ryukoku University


Phase 2
Mission of the Afrasian Research Centre

Today's globalised world has witnessed astonishing political and economic growth in
the regions of Asia and Africa. Such progress has been accompanied, however, with a
high frequency of various types of conflicts and disputes. The Afrasian Research Centre
aims to build on the achievements of its predecessor, the Afrasian Centre for Peace and
Development Studies (ACPDS), by applying its great tradition of research towards Asia
with the goal of building a new foundation for interdisciplinary research into
multicultural societies in the fields of Immigration Studies, International Relations and
Communication Theory. In addition, we seek to clarify the processes through which
conflicts are resolved, reconciliation is achieved and multicultural societies are
established. Building on the expertise and networks that have been accumulated in
Ryukoku University in the past (listed below), we will organise research projects to
tackle new and emerging issues in the age of globalisation. We aim to disseminate the
results of our research internationally, through academic publications and engagement
in public discourse.

㸯㸬A Tradition of Religious and Cultural Studies


㸰㸬Expertise in Participatory Research/ Inter-Civic Relation Studies
㸱㸬Expertise in Asian and Africa Studies
㸲㸬Expertise in Communication and Education Studies
㸳㸬New Approaches to the Understanding of Other Cultures in Japan
㸴㸬Domestic and International Networks with Major Research Institutes
Afrasian Research Centre, Ryukoku University

The Formation of Global Economic Law:


Under Aspects of the Autopoietic System

Satoko Kawamura

Working Paper Series


Studies on Multicultural Societies No.7

2012
978-4-904945-07-0
The Formation of Global Economic Law:
Under Aspects of the Autopoietic System

Satoko Kawamura*

Introduction

In the global world, a society called “the global civil society” is being formed. In the global
civil society, not only states and public International Organizations but also private actors
such as multinational enterprises, non-governmental organizations (NGOs) and international
expert groups which have been regarded, for a long time, as ancillary actors to the traditional
International Relations field, are playing a very important role now. The operations of such
private international associations are active. The tendency is welcomed. On the other hand,
the arbitrary behaviours of the private power cause new problems. In order to integrate those
private international associations into and to therefore reinforce global governance, States and
Interstate organizations are required to making norms and to cooperate with them (Held
2004).

On the other hand, in the fields of economy, teleinformatics, health care and advanced
science and technology, in which public legalization has not been advanced, private
international associations make voluntary rules by themselves. These rules, known as “global
law,” have attracted the attention of practitioners and scholars in International Relations and
International Law (Lenoble and Maesschalck 2003). Especially in the field of international
economy, it is undesirable for private actors to be restricted by rules made by the government,
and necessary for them to be allowed to operate freely, therefore, the global economic law
which is formed voluntarily by the free activities of private actors is expected to play an
effective role in global governance. However, global economic law has problems. It is made
by private actors, so its validity as law is doubtful because it lacks democratic procedures and
it tends to be purpose-built (Hall and Biersteker 2002). To solve this problem, one needs to
analyze global law and to find theories and systems which give global law legal validity.

The aim of this paper is to clarify the formation process of the global economic law and
suggest some theories which support its validity as legal norms by means of autopoietic
*Ph. D. in International Relations, Assistant Professor of International Relations and International Law, Faculty
of Law, Toyo University.

1
system analysis. Under autopoietic system theory, the global society is analyzed as an
autopoietic system of communication. Communication has been differentiated into its
functions in the social system and they have formed many sub-systems which have been
specialized by their functions, for example the political system, the economic system, the
legal system, etc. Communication about global economic law is involved in three systems;
the economic system, the global political system, and the legal system. Today’s global society,
while recognized as being formed by interstate relations, can be understood as a collection of
global societies which are differentiated into law, politics, economy, etc. Such a global
society does not have a central organization. Therefore, the autopoietic system theory
becomes a valid methodology that can be applied to the global society as a multi-centred
society. This theoretical model made possible through autopoietic system analysis enables
one to clearly explain the function and the possibilities of global economic law in the global
society.

In its first section, this paper deals with the characteristics of the autopoietic system, and
explains three systems; the economic system, the political system, and the legal system,
which are related to global economic law as viewed from the autopoietic system. The second
section of this paper discusses the legal sources of global economic law to clarify the
formation of global economic law on the basis of the autopoietic system and, hence, describes
the outline of global economic law. This paper also deals with problems of global economic
law and tries to suggest solutions for them.

1. Global Economic Law in the Context of the Autopoietic System

1.1. Characteristics of autopoietic system theory


Autopoietic system theory borrows the theory of a self-produced system of life, in which
component parts are cells (Maturana and Varela 1979). The autopoietic system theory in this
paper is based on the social system theory of Niklas Luhmann and Gunther Teubner in the
field of Sociology of Law (Kawamura 2008, 144-147). Stated quite simply, there are five
characteristics of the theory.

(1) The essence of “a system” is the reduction of complexity by distinguishing the system
from its environment. Each System has “a code” which distinguishes between the
inside and outside of the system. The code decides what kinds of things exist in the
system and the “programs” are the criteria for the code. Each system has an
“eigenvalue” which stabilizes the system.1

1
Heinz von Foerster who researches cybernetics introduced the concept of the eigenvalue in his book Sicht und
Einsicht in 1985 (Von Foerster 1985/2006).

2
(2) The system is not a united organization, but the difference between the system and the
environment. The system draws a boundary between what is inside and outside of it
through its operations. This means that the operations of the system are producing
component parts of the system. The operation makes the structure of the system, not
vice-versa. The mechanism of self-reference forms the circulation of the
self-preservation of the system.

(3) The system is closed against its environment, so that there is neither direct input nor
output from the environment. There are four concepts of the relation between the
system and the environment. First is “external observation,” by which the system
observes the environment according to its code. Second is “resonance,” by which a
system is stimulated by the environment through the external observation of the system.
Third is “operational coupling,” which means that some operations of one system are
also some operations of another system, simultaneously (Luhmann 2004, 381). Fourth
is “structural coupling,” which means that a part of the structure of a system depends
on the other system. Even though two systems are in the condition of structural
coupling, each system reacts to an event at a different pace. There is the synchronicity
of each operation of two systems, but it does not guarantee the synchronization of each
operation of them (Ibid. 383). These four concepts of relationship between the system
and the environment are regarded as “performance” by the observation of the whole
social system (Kawamura 2008, 147).

(4) The system differentiates into some sub-systems by its function. Inside a system, there
are sub-systems. The system refers to elements which are produced by its sub-systems
for its operation, and sub-systems refer to elements which are produced by the system
for its operations. Referring to elements which are produced by the other sub-systems,
a hyper-cycle between the system and sub-systems is constructed.

(5) Functionally differentiated systems operate individually, without seeing the operation
of the whole social system. From the view of the social system, operations of each
system are regarded as the function of each system.

By using the autopoietic system theory which has such characteristics, the society is
visualized as a social system which is constituted by communication network. In the context
of this theory, communication means a combination between selections of what information
is to be communicated, which way it is communicated and how it is understood by someone
being communicated with (Luhmann 1984, 147). The communication as a combination
between these three selections always contains the contingency, so it is always complicated.
Therefore, the social system which is constructed by communication is also complicated and
differentiated into sub-systems. It should be noted that the subject of the communication is

3
not a person, but a personality. Of course, a person is indispensable for the social
communication. However, the system of mind and the system of consciousness of a person
are not social facts. In the context of autopoietic system theory, an individual person means a
generic name for multilayered personalities, and each communication belongs to each
personality.2

The global society attains the stage of functional differentiation, through the stage of
segmental differentiation, by which the social system has been differentiated into equal
groups, and of stratificational differentiation, by which the social system has been
differentiated into non-equal groups. Inside the social system, each sub-system of it, for
example the legal system, the political system, and the economic system, is closed against the
environment and self-referential, and performs its own operation without seeing the purpose
of the whole social system.3

1.2. Three functional differentiated systems related to global economic law


I will deal with three functionally differentiated systems related to global economic law in
this paper. First is the economic system. The economic system has been differentiated from
such other systems as the political system or the religious system, and has been closed since
there are limitations on what can be bought with money. In the medieval period, people were
able to purchase salvation, political posts, citizenships, etc. Then the economic system was
not closed (Luhmann 1989, 51).

The code of the economic system is “to pay/not to pay.” Money is the media which helps
communication inside the system. Communication about “to pay/not to pay” is the operation
of the system. Continuing communication, this system produces the cycle of self-reference
(Ibid. 52). The program of this system is “value.” If a price has been considered an
appropriate value to pay, communication in which people pay that price will occur, and it will
become the operation of the economic system (Ibid. 53). Through these operations, the
economic system provides the guarantee of the distribution of economic goods as its function
for the whole social system. The eigenvalue of it is “profitability.” The system needs actors
which have abilities to pay and reproduce (Ibid. 56), and profitability secures those abilities
for them, so that the profitability stabilizes the economic system.

The economic system is closed; events in the environment cannot influence the system
directly. The restraint which comes into existence in the environment is translated into the
fluctuation of the price in the economic system. For example, a government intervention to

2
A person is consisted by multi-layered personalities. For example, a person can be simultaneously “a student”
in the educational system, “a consumer” in the economic system and “a creditor” in the legal system.
3
The autopoietic system theory faces criticism for its method for the analysis of International Studies. See
Kawamura (2009, 203-209).

4
regulate price is not the operation of the economic system but the communication of the
political system which changes an economic event into a political event through resonance
with the economic system (Ibid. 54). The economic system doesn’t care about any events in
the environment so far as they do not concern its code “to pay/not to pay.” The intervention
of the central bank to guarantee the credit of money is also one of data which helps in making
the cycle of the self-reference of the system (Ibid. 57). “Every intervention acquires the
character of an event, an impulse, a provocation, a stimulation or destimulation of change in
the system itself” (Ibid. 55). However, the economic system still has a strong possibility to
resonate with other systems, because a price always tries to meet needs which reflect events
happening in the environment (Ibid. 53), and effects of these changes bring new changes.
Though the economic system can resonate with other systems, there is a limit to the external
observation of the system.

Inside the economic system, competition has been highly differentiated from the exchanges
and the cooperation, so that actors can compete against rivals without communication
between them. This is one of the ways in which complexity is reduced. Internal restraints of
the system work to communicate about making unreasonable prices and pursuit of gain
greedy. The economic system “can be called ‘capitalistic’ only to the extent that it connects
payments with the reproduction of the capacity to make further payments, above all from the
point of view of the profitability of investments,” and “a capitalistic self-control exists only
as a possibility” (Ibid. 55).

Second is the political system. The code of the political system is “government/
non-government” and political principles and policies which are the programs whereby the
system decides what comes into the system or not. The program of the political system is
always a purpose-oriented norm. For the whole social system, the function of the political
system is to make decisions which bind any groups, and, in producing these decisions by
itself, the political system forms a self-referential circle. The validity of these decisions is the
eigenvalue which has played an important role as stabilizer for the system. Since modern
times, the democratic political system, meaning that a person who is bound by a decision
participates in the making of that decision, has given validity to the decision. Therefore,
communication as the operation of the political system does not only belong to the
governmental authority but also to other actors. The principle of the division of powers has
made the political system differentiated into three sub-systems; the system of politics which
consists of the communication about decision-making by politicians, the administrational
system, and the system of public. These sub-systems consider each other “the environment,”
and make a hyper-cycle.

Because the political system is closed, the system cannot operate outside itself. However the
system has the ability to resonate with the environment. The political system is very sensitive

5
to events which happen in the environment and the demands of the environment which
extend beyond the possibility of the political system. Actually, because the operation of the
political system is the communication about making decisions which bind groups, the system
cannot control the whole social system. However, the environment of the political system
expects the system to start communication to solve problems of the other systems and the
political system also pretends to operate beyond its ability.

The global political system is one of the sub-systems of the political system. The code of the
global political system is not “government/non-government,” but “governance/
non-governance.” In the meaning of the code “governance,” the relation between the
governor and governed is not fixed and sometimes an actor becomes not only the governor
but also is governed at the same time. In this code, it tends to have discussions between actors
when they make a decision and to achieve a consensus on the decision. There is no central
decision-making system and there is no fixed relationship between governor and governed in
global politics, so that the code of the global political system can be understood as
“governance/non-governance.” Because of the sub-system of the political system, the global
political system follows the program and the eigenvalue of the political system, and what’s
more, it is differentiated into three sub-systems; the interstate system which started with the
Westphalia Treaty, the international institutionalized system which has been differentiated
from the interstate system since the First World War,4 and the global civil society system
which consists of transnational communications by private actors who are becoming more
and more important in the process of globalization. From the analysis of autopoietic system
theory, global governance is understood as a condition of the hyper-cycle between these three
sub-systems.

Third is the legal system. The code of this system is “legal/illegal.” Inside this system, the
code judges that a case is legal or illegal (Luhmann 1989, 64). When it is judged legal, it
means the case is not illegal. The code guarantees the legal justification for the case. Only the
legal system can make a decision which is legal or not in the legal system itself. Even if it is
true that the decision of the system can influence other systems through resonance, it may
happen only within the legal system. Programs of the legal system are legal norms; viz., laws,
ordinances, statutes, procedural rules, judicial rulings and contractual agreements, judicial
precedents (Ibid. 64). These programs decide the content of the communication as the
operation of the system. The system only communicates about legal norms which are
regarded as valid. The validity of legal norms is also given by legal norms. To put it shortly,
superior legal norms are applied by the inferior ones. It doesn’t mean that norms produce

4
This system contains not only the communication of interstate organizations, but also the communication of
private actors which as subsidiary actors in the system. Communications of the interstates system are in a
haphazard way, on the other hand, communications of the international institutionalized system are persistent
and stable.

6
other norms, because norms are produced from the operation of the political system (that is
legislative communication). So that the communication of the legal system is how to apply
norms to a case, the validity of the norms is the eigenvalue that stabilizes the legal system. In
continuing communication within the system, the legal system is closed. The court is an
apparatus that makes sure that conditions continue making such communication which
produces another communication for self-reference inside the legal system (Idem). The
function of the legal system for the whole social system is to make it possible for people to
predict their action in the society, especially to predict what happens when a legal dispute
occurs, and to keep society in order. The communication of the legal system has formed “a
social desire for order,” and the legal communications of order are related to freedom which
can be protected or restricted by legal norms (Ibid. 65). The legal system “can be developed
only as a social regulative” (Ibid. 67).

The legal system easily resonates with the political system, so that the system needs decisions
which bind any groups made by the political system. The legal system requests the political
system to do much more than it can provide (Ibid. 63). The legal system is closed, however
the system has to observe the environment to apply an appropriate norm to a case or to check
the appropriateness of norms or to judge the necessity to change the norms, and it causes the
resonance with the environment. In this meaning, the legal system is open (Ibid. 65). Only in
this way, can the legal system understand events of the environment. When a legal dispute
occurs, the legal system tries to resonate with the environment by transforming an economic
event or a political event into a legal event. Any communication which is excluded from the
legal system, for example the estimation of risks, is always regarded as communication of the
political system. Although the expectations of the political system give the illusion that that
system can control matters for the whole social system, the legal system has in fact more
occasions to decide arbitrarily on environmental matters (Ibid. 68).

2. Formation of Global Law and its Possibility

2.1. Legal sources of global economic law on the basis of the autopoietic system
The arguments for legal sources of global law (Teubner 1997, 11) refer to the customary law
theory (Khan 1982, 97-107; Loquin 1986, 67-122), institutionalist theory (Fouchard 1983,
81-114), and contract theory (Cremades and Plehn 1984, 317-348). In any way, one cannot
explain the phenomena of the legal sources of global law by a sole theory. According to the
customary law theory, the formation of legal conviction between traders through the
establishment of worldwide commercial practices leads to the elaboration of customary law.
In this case, the contract which establishes the rights and obligations between the parties in
each case becomes standardized and contributes in such a way to encouraging the
establishment of such practices. The institutionalist theory presupposes a sort of
institutionalized world community of merchants (a societas mercatorum) which has the

7
natural inclination of establishing its order by producing internal legal rules framing
themselves so as to avoid chaos or the imposition of authoritative order by others. Such rules
have the effect of a disciplinary code of a closed club and “organizational sanctions such as
blacklisting and exclusion from membership” are imposed against a violator. As for the
contract theory, there are two sorts of explanation. One is the self-regulatory contract theory
and the other, the autopoietic self-referential contract theory. The former explains that, on the
basis of the freedom of contract as a general principle of law, private parties can freely
establish self-regulatory law rules between them without any basis in national or international
law. According to Teubner, “National Laws are supposed to grant freedom of contract in the
form of the choice of non-national global law” (Teubner 1997, 9; Schmitthoff 1964, 47).

As for the autopoietic self-referential theory, we should understand first of all that the
contracts we deal with are international contracts, viz., moving goods and values beyond
frontiers, having plural links (for example, installation of services, the territory of the
provision of services, the provider of services, the client of services, etc.) in plural countries,
and concerning the international trade interest, and, hence, that these contracts are placed in
the global context. The contracts themselves are the primary sources of law like legislations
or judicial precedents and provide the primary basis for quasi-judgment and legislation. The
fact is that a contract producing a legal norm governing the contract itself is a paradox.
Therefore, the autopoietic contract theory must make a deparadoxification. According to G.
Teubner, there are three ways of deparadoxification; internal hierarchy of contractual rules,
temporalization of the paradox, and externalization of contractual self-validation (Teubner
1997, 16). Teubner wrote that these ways “mutually support each other and make it possible,
without help of the state, for a global law of the economic periphery to create its own legal
centre” (Idem).

First, by the internal hierarchical organization of contractual rules into primary rules which
regulate the behaviour of the parties and into secondary rules which regulate the recognition
of primary rules in the sense established by H. L. A. Hart, “the paradox of self-validation still
exists, but it is concealed in the separation of hierarchical levels, the levels of rules, and Meta
rules” (Idem). “The hierarchy is tangled, but this does not hinder” the higher rules from
regulating the lower ones. Second, a contract temporarizes “the paradox and transforms the
circularity of contractual self-validation into an iterative process of legal acts, into a sequence
of the recursive mutual constitution of legal acts and legal structures” (Idem). A contract
refers to “pre-existing standardization of rules” and to “the future of conflict regulation”
(Idem). Therefore, it becomes an element of “an on-going self-production process in which
the network of elements creates the very elements of the system” (Idem). Third, a
self-referential contract uses the technique of externalization for deparadoxification. The
validity of a contract and the future conflicts are submitted to the judgment of the external
non-contractual institutions which are nevertheless contractual because they themselves are

8
the internal product of the contract, and hence, the self-validation of a contract is externalized.
The typical action of such institutions is arbitration which has the task of judging the dispute
concerning the contract. The fact that the validity of the arbitration is based on the contract of
which the arbitration itself judges the validity is still a paradox. “Hence, the vicious circle of
contractual self-validation is transformed into the virtuous circle of two legal processes̿
contracting and arbitration. An internal circular relationship is transformed into an external
one” (Ibid. 17). Rules spontaneously created by a contract can be self-referential by
combining the organized production of rules by arbitration.

In my opinion, this autopoietic self-referential contract theory seems to be the most


persuasive one for understanding why the rules established by a contract can be the sources
of global law.

2.2. The characteristics of global economic law viewed from the autopoietic system
Global laws are regarded as self-regulations which are made by private actors. Essentially,
the activities of private actors have been regulated by laws of each state. But, in certain fields,
states or interstate organizations have some difficulty in regulating transnational activities
caused by or involving private actors which are becoming more and more important in the
global society. In such fields as economics, activities are essentially transnational. For
example, trade is impossible without transnational activities of persons, goods, services and
capital. The private legislation is made by private international associations which carry out
structural coupling with the economic system so as to keep order in their mutual activities.
They try to regulate by themselves without relying on the public process of making rules.
These self-regulations are regarded as global economic law (Tatsuzawa 2009, 115-119).5
They are regarded as operations of the political system, because communication about
regulations or making rules is primarily communication belonging to such personalities as
“citizens”6 or “politicians.” In the case of global law, the associations of such as “consumers,”
“producers,” “business agents” and “multinational corporations” who are primarily
personalities belonging to the economic system, participate in the governance and act in order
to make regulations. These communications can be regarded as communications of the global
civil society system. These communications generate global economic laws.

For example, the Internet Society is a private association which makes rules and regulates the
evolution of Internet protocol of all over the world (Ibid. 124). eBay supplies an online
market for people to use. eBay decides detailed and formalized rules for users and has
established a mechanism to resolve disputes among users. It also made a system which

5
The global economic law as the self-regulation of private actors is not the modern phenomenon. For example,
“jus mercatorum” which was made by merchants in Europe and had been observed as same as rules which were
regulated by governors in medieval time (Lévy-Bruhl 1961).
6
Here citizens means active political actors.

9
evaluates performance of buyers and sellers on the online market. The systems and the rules
of eBay became a model of other online markets. The assignments of domain names and IP
addresses are regulated by rules made by Uniform Domain Name Dispute Resolution Policy
(UDRP) which is an private non-profit organization built on the Internet Corporation for
Assigned Names and Numbers (ICANN). ICANN is an American private association.7

Another model is the International Air Transport Association, which consists of airlines and
conveys 94 percent of the world’s air passengers, travel agents, and freight shippers. It
decides rules for the transportation of passengers. It can affect the decision-making of the
International Civil Aviation Organization (ICAO) (Koppell 2010, 254-255).

The International Accounting Standards Board (IASB) is a private non-profit association. It


was founded for the harmonization or uniformication of international rules of accounting.
The standards of IASB have influenced the accounting rules of almost every state. It has
contributed to the development of world accounting standards (Ibid. 62-63).

The International Organization of Standardization consists of 161 national standards bodies,


that manage processes that “generate standards in a wide range of areas from screw threads to
petroleum products to corporate social responsibility” (Ibid. 7).

The International Chamber of Commerce (ICC) was founded after the First World War to
help reconstruct European economies and industries and establish free trade. The purposes of
the ICC are to promote international trade and investment, develop the economic system
based on the principle of free and fair trade, and to propose suggestions for the world
economy. It makes common rules for international trade and provides an international court
system for arbitration (International Chamber of Commerce 2010).

When global economic law is formed, the subjects of global economic law, viz., private
associations, have to observe the rule. Once legal disputes arise, it gives them a chance to
refer to commercial arbitration. Although it is quite difficult to have systems which indemnify
them against violation of global economic law or help to solve legal disputes, it appears to be
such an adjudicative body.

It is indicated that global law is useful for the governance of transnational economic activities,
because the global economic law is not formed by government intervention but by
self-regulation of private actors. The global economic law has some problems. The first
problem is that it is lacking the democratic elements in the process of making the global
economic law. The function of the political system is to make decisions which bind groups.

7
About eBay and ICANN, see Schultz (2007, 157-163; 2010, 1-19).

10
Making norms are one of outcomes of this function. 8 Global economic law is also a
manifestation of the function of the global civil society system. The validity of these
decisions is the eigenvalue which plays an important role as stabilizer of the global political
system. Since modern times, the democratic political system that people who are bound by
political decisions participate in the decision-making process, has given validity to the
decision. For example, a national law obtains validity through the system in which people’s
representatives who win seats in an election participate in the decision-making process.
International laws or decisions are made by communications of the interstate system or the
international institutionalized system. They also get their validity from the system that the
governments of states representing peoples join in their decision-making. However, the
global economic law is not made by democratically-elected people’s representatives.
Therefore we can say that there is democratic deficit in the validity of the global law (Nölke
2006, 139). This is essentially tied to the question of legitimacy of global law, if we consider
law as “l’expression de la volonté générale du peuple” (De Malberg 1920/1962, 330).

Then new types of democratic mechanism for the legislative process of global economic law
have occurred in the communications of the global civil society system. For example,
Participatory democracy; this is a political theory that tries to maximize the participation of
people in decision-making by means of developed information technology. Deliberative
democracy; it regards “deliberation” as necessary condition of decision making and of getting
its’ validity. Functional democracy; it is the theory which ensures the system of the freedom
of information, of accountability and of contestation giving the validity to decisions
(Cunningham 2001, 123-141, 142-161, 163-183).

However, the global civil society system has difficulty in having a democratic decision
making process (Dahl 1999, 19-36). Even the interstate system and the international
institutionalized system which have indirect democratic processes of decision-making hold
such problems as “Democratic deficit” (Zweifel 2002, 12) and the lack of accountability
(Bono 2004, 175-177).

In this situation, republicanism has the possibility to complement democratic processes in the
global civil society, and gives validity and legitimacy to the global economic law.
Republicanism is a political philosophy based on the following elements; the principle of
freedom from arbitrary domination, citizens as the common denominator of various people,
and the realization of the common good in a community. Under the republicanism, arbitrary
powers are not allowed. Reference to experts in each field to restore law and order is needed
in a decision-making process in the global civil society. Even if it is not a democratic

8
Making norms is performances of the political system. Once norms are formed, communications about norms
are regarded as operations of the legal system. The political system and the legal system form the structural
coupling through norms.

11
decision-making process, it is better than no law and order (Pettit 1997, 265-266). It is very
important for republicanism to restrict arbitrary power rather than the holder of power.
“Virtuous experts” who have advanced knowledge, who have the ability to understand the
common good and its duty for the society, and take moderate actions (Ibid. 290-292), can be
regarded as valid representatives of the people even if they are not elected by the people.
They are required to make rules for order. The principle of republicanism has the possibility
to compensate for the lack of democratic decision-making process in the global civil society
(Ibid. 261-262, 267-270).

In the interstate system and international institutionalized system, the personalities who can
join in communications thereof still have been limited to “politicians” and to “officials.”
Individuals have been limitedly involved in these communications.9 In the global civil
society system, more personalities can join in these communications because of the system
which is forming coupling with other systems. In the case of the global economic law, the
representatives of “employers,” “employees,” “producers” and “consumers” who are
essentially actors of the economic system communicate about making norms for themselves
to keep order in their activities. If a person does not join directly in the decision for norms, he
could take part in the communications of the decision-making. For example, saying
something about food security as a consumer to a company is included in these
“participations.” Thus, there is possibility to obtain the validity of global economic law
through the challenge of the above-mentioned three new democracies and application of
republicanism principles (Cutler et al. 1999, 19).

The second problem is that global economic law tends to be purpose-built because, it is
established to stabilize communications of actors in the economic system. Even if the global
economic law is made by “virtuous experts,” it may have arbitrariness. It is self-regulation
which is made by private actors. It has more risk of corruption (Nölke 2006, 135-140). This is
a reason why global law has difficulty in being valid law.

To solve this problem, it is necessary for legislators (private actors) of global economic law to
make “secondary rules” in the global economic law in the sense established by Hart.
Secondary rules are regulations of the recognition of primary rules. They have the
characteristic of fundamental norms or constitutional rules which decide the enforcement,
abolition, procedures, and alteration of primary rules (Tsagourias 2007, 1-2; Sciulli 1992).
They also decide how to deal with protest against primary rules (Hart 1997, 79-123; Bobbio
1971, 113-115, 119). In fact, some global economic laws have already had secondary rules as
fundamental norms. For example, ICANN, eBay and ISO established secondary rules (Nölke
2006, 137; Haufler 2002, 6-9). In fact, ICC has already set up an adjudicative institution

9
An example of this is the representatives of workers having their seats in the ILO.

12
which deals with commercial disputes among members. The ICC International Court of
Arbitration is a permanent organ of international commercial arbitration which was founded
to solve business disputes of an international character. Most business contracts refer to the
ICC rules of Arbitration and ICC Rules of Conciliation recently (International Chamber of
Commerce 1997a, 1997b).

Conclusion

The aim of this paper is to clarify the formation process of global economic law and to
suggest some theories which support its validity as legal norms by using the autopoietic
system theory. The autopoietic system which I deal with in this paper is a closed system
which produces its own components by self-reference. In addition, inside the system, there
are some closed sub-systems which form a hyper-cycle. According to the theory, society is
analyzed as a self-referential system of communications. The social system has many
sub-systems which have been differentiated by their functions. There are three systems
concerning global economic law; the economic system, the political system, and the legal
system.

The global law is an amalgamation of self-regulations which are made by private


international actors. Private international actors include “consumers,” “producers,” “business
agents” and “multinational corporations” carrying out transnational activities which states or
interstate organizations have difficulty in regulating. Especially in the economic field, these
actors try to self-regulate without relying on the public rule-making process. This
self-regulation generates global economic law. The former means communication in the
global civil society system. As such, global economic law is formed by personalities
primarily belonging to the economic system.

The global economic law has two problems to its validity, first is the lack of the democratic
legislative process, and second is its arbitrariness. This paper suggests some solutions for
these problems. As for the first problem, it suggested adopting the principle of republicanism
to complement democratic legislative process. As for the second problem, it suggested that
private international actors have to make not only primary rules but also secondary rules and
institutions like the court of arbitration, which deals with disputes of global economic law.

From now on, it will be very important for the success of global economic law that the
interstate system and the international institutionalized system involve global economic law
in their communications. In other words, the resonance among the global civil society system,
the interstate system, and the international institutionalized system to form a hyper-cycle is a
key for the success of global economic law (Teubner 2004, 27).

13
References

Bobbio, Norberto. 1971. Esssais de Théorie du Droit [The Essay of the Theory of Law].
Paris: Bruylant-L. G. D. J.

Bono, Giovanna. 2004. The European Union as an International Security Actor: Challenges
for Democratic Accountability. In The Double Democratic Deficit, eds. Hans Born
and Heiner Hänggi, 163-181. Burlington: Ashgate.

Cremades, Bernardo M. and Steven L. Plehn. 1984. The New Lex Mercatoria and the
Harmonization of the Laws of International Commercial Transactions. Boston
University International Law Journal 2: 317-348.

Cunningham, Frank. 2001. Theories of Democracy: A Critical Introduction. London:


Routledge.

Cutler, Claire A., Virginia Haufler and Tony Porter, eds. 1999. Private Authority and
International Affairs. Albany: State University of New York Press.

Dahl, Robert A. 1999. Can International Organizations Be Democratic? A Skeptic’s View. In


Democracy’s Edges, eds. Casiano Hacker-Cordón and Ian Shapiro, 19-36.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

De Malberg, Raymon Carré. 1920/1962. Contribution à la Théorie Générale de l’Etat


[Contribution to the General Theory of the State]. T. I. Paris: C. N. R. S.

Fouchard, Philipe. 1983. La loi Régissant les Obligations Contractuelles en Droit


International Privé Français [The Law Regulating Contractual Obligations in
International Private Law]. In le Colloque de Bâle sur la loi Régissant les
Obligations Contractuelles [The Colloquium of Basel on the Law Regulating
Contractual Obligations], eds. F. Klein and F. Vischer, 81-114. Bâle: Frank Vischer
Publisher.

Hall, Rodney B. and T. J. Biersteker, eds. 2002. The Emergence of Private Authority in
Global Governance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Hart, Herbert L. A. 1997. The Concept of Law. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Haufler, Virginia. 2002. Public and Private Authority in International Governance: Historical
Continuity and Change. Paper prepared for the conference on New Technologies
and International Governance, Washington DC.

Von Foerster, Heinz. 1985/2006. Sicht und Einsicht [Perspective and Insight]. Heidelberg:
Carl-Auer-System Verlag.

14
Held, David, 2004. Global Covenant. Cambridge: Polity Press.

International Chamber of Commerce. 1997a. ICC Rules of Arbitration in force as of January


1, 1998. ICC Publication 581.

International Chamber of Commerce. 1997b. ICC Rules of Conciliation in force as of January


1, 1998. ICC Publication 581.

International Chamber of Commerce. 2010. International Chamber of Commerce: The World


Business Organization.
http://www.iccwbo.org/ (accessed 17 October 2010).

Kawamura, Satoko. 2008. Guroubaru na seiji ni okeru seiji shisou no ichi to kinou:
Ohtopoiehtikku shisutemu riron bunseki no tekiyou kanousei ni kansuru kousatsu
[The Position and the Function of the Political Thought in the Global Politics: A
Prospect in the Applicability of the Theoretical Concept of Autopoietic System as a
Methodology to International Politics]. Ritsumeikan Kokusai Kenkyu [The
Ritsumeikan Journal of International Studies] 21(2): 141-163.

Kawamura, Satoko. 2009. Guroubaru shakai ni okeru kyouwa shugi no kinou to kanousei:
Shisutemu bunseki ni yoru riron moderu no teiji [The Function and the Possibility
of Republicanism in the Global Society: A Proposal of a Theoretic Model Through
Autopoietic System Analysis]. Ritsumeikan Kokusai Kenkyu [The Ritsumeikan
Journal of International Studies] 22(2): 201-219.

Khan, Philippe. 1982. Droit International Économique, Droit du Développement, lex


Mercatoria: Concept Unique ou Pluralism des Orders Juridiques? [International
Economic Law, Right to Development, lex Mercatoria: Unique Concept or
Pluralism of Legal Orders?] In Le Doit des Relations Économiques Internationals:
Etudes Offertes à Berthold [The Law of International Economic Relations: Studies
Offered to Berthold], ed. B. Goldman, 97-107. Paris: Litec.

Koppell, Jonathan G. S. 2010. World Rules: Accountability, Legitimacy, and the Design of
Global Governance. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Lenoble, Jacques, and Marc Maesschalck, eds. 2003. Toward a Theory of Governance.
Hague: Kluwer Law International.

Lévy-Bruhl, Henri. 1961. Sociologie du Droit [Sociology of Law]. Paris: Universitairs de


France.

Loquin, Eric. 1986. L’application des Règles Anationales Dans L’arbitrage Commercial
International [Application of Anational Rules in the International Commercial
Arbitrage]. In L’apport de la Jurisprudence Arbitrale [Input of Arbitral Precidence],

15
67-122. Paris: C. C. I.

Luhmann, Niklas. 1984. Social Systems. Stanford: Stanford University Press.

Luhmann, Niklas. 1989. Ecological Communication. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Luhmann, Niklas. 2004. Law as a Social System, Trans. Klaus A. Ziegert, eds. Fatima
Kastner, Richard Nobles, David Schiff and Rosamund Ziegert. Oxford: Oxford
University Press.

Maturana, Humbert, and Francisco J. Varela. 1979. Autopoiesis and Cognition: The
Realization of the Living. Dordrechit: Boston Studies in the Philosophy of Science.

Nölke, Andreas. 2006. Private Norms in the Global Political Economy. In Global Norms in
the Twenty-First Century, eds. Klaus-Gerd Giesen and Kees van der Pijl, 134-149.
Cambridge: Cambridge Scholars Press.

Pettit, Philip. 1997. Republicanism. Oxford: Clarendon Press.

Schmitthoff, Clive M. 1964. Das neue Recht des Welthandels [The New Law of World
Trade]. Rabels Zeitschrift für ausländisches und internationales Privatrecht [The
Rabel Journal of Comparative and International Private Law] 28: 47-77.

Schultz, Thomas. 2007. Private Legal Systems: What Cyberspace Might Teach Legal
Theorists. Yale Journal of Law & Technology 10: 151-193.

Schultz, Thomas. 2010. Le Critère de la Moralité Interne du Droit Comme Réponse aux
Enjeux Éthico-politiques du Règlement des Différends Hors de L’etat [The Criteria
of the Internal Morality of Law as Answer to Ethico-political Game of the
Regulation of Dispute Outside the State].
http://www.thomasschultz.org/documents/Schultz-Etat-de-droit.pdf (accessed 17
January 2010).

Sciulli, David. 1992. Theory of Societal Constitutionalism: Foundation of a Non-Marxist


Critical Theory. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Tatsuzawa, Kunihiko. 2009. Guroubaru hou to toransu nashonaru (minsaitekina) kenpou


shugi [The Global Law and the Transnational Constitutionalism]. Kenpou Kenkyu
[The Journal of Constitutional Law] 41: 113-131.

Teubner, Gunther. 1997. ‘Global Bukowina’: Legal Pluralism in the World Society. In Global
Law without a State, ed. Gunther Teubner, 3-28. Burlington: Ashgate.

Teubner, Gunther. 2004. Societal Constitutionalism: Alternatives to State-centred


Constitutional Theory? In Transnational Governance and Constitutionalism, eds.

16
Christian Jorges, Inger-Johanne Sand and Gunther Teubner, 3-28. Oxford: Hart
Publishing.

Tsagourias, Nikolas. 2007. Introduction-Constitutionalism: A Theoretical Roadmap.


In Transnational Constitutionalism, ed. Nikolas Tsagourias, 1-13. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.

Zweifel, Thomas D. 2002. Democratic Deficit?: Institutions and Relation in the European
Union, Switzerland and the United States. Lanham: Lexington Books.

17
Working Paper Series

Peace and Development Studies (Phase1)


No.1 (2005)
James R. Simpson, Future of the Dairy Industries in China, Japan and the United States:
Conflict Resolution in the Doha Round of WTO Agricultural Trade Negotiations
No.2 (2005)
K. Palanisami, Sustainable Management of Tank Irrigation Systems in South India
No.3 (2006)
Nobuko Nagasaki, Satyagraha as a Non-violent Means of Conflict Resolution
No.4 (2006)
Yoshio Kawamura and Zhan Jin, WTO/FTA and the Issues of Regional Disparity
No.5 (2006)
Shin’ichi Takeuchi, Political Liberalization or Armed Conflicts? Political Changes in
Post-Cold War Africa
No.6 (2006)
Daniel C. Bach, Regional Governance and State Reconstruction in Africa
No.7 (2006)
Eghosa E. Osaghae, Ethnicity and the State in Africa
No.8 (2006)
Kazuo Takahashi, The Kurdish Situation in Iraq
No.9 (2006)
Kaoru Sugihara, East Asia, Middle East and the World Economy: Further Notes on the Oil
Triangle
No.10 (2006)
Kosuke Shimizu, Discourses of Leadership and Japanese Political Economy: Three
Phallus-centrists
No.11 (2006)
Nao Sato, The Composition and Job Structure of Female-Headed Households: A Case Study of
a Rural Village in Siemreap Province, Cambodia
No.12 (2006)
Takuya Misu, The United States and the United Nations Operation in the Congo (ONUC)
No.13 (2006)
Om Prakash, Asia and the Rise of the Early Modern World Economy
No.14 (2006)
Takehiko Ochiai, Regional Security in Africa
No.15 (2006)
Masahisa Kawabata, An Overview of the Debate on the African State
No.16 (2006)
Kazuo Takahashi, The Middle East, the Middle Kingdom and Japan
No.17 (2006)
Tomoya Suzuki, Macroeconomic Impacts of Terrorism: Evidence from Indonesia in the
Post-Suharto Era
No.18 (2007)
Kenichi Matsui, International Energy Regime: Role of Knowledge and Energy and Climate
Change Issues
No.19 (2007)
Kazuo Takahashi, Not the Most Popular Decision: Japan’s Ground Self Defense Force Goes to
Iraq
No.20 (2007)
Shinya Ishizaka, Leader-Follower Relations in the Foot Marches in Gandhian Environmental
Movements in India
No.21 (2007)
Yoshio Kawamura, Participatory Community Development and a Role of Social Statistical
Analysis: Case of the JICA-Indonesia Project—Takalar Model
No.22 (2007)
Takashi Inoguchi, The Place of the United States in the Triangle of Japan, China and India
No.23 (forthcoming)
Kosuke Shimizu, Asian Regionalism and Japan’s Unforgettable Past
No.24 (2007)
Kosuke Shimizu, Human Security, Universality, and National Interest: A Critical Inquiry
No.25 (2007)
François Debrix, The Hegemony of Tabloid Geopolitics: How America and the West Cannot
Think International Relations beyond Conflict, Identity, and Cultural Imposition
No.26 (2007)
Naomi Hosoda, The Social Process of Migration from the Eastern Visayas to Manila
No.27 (2007)
Chizuko Sato, Forced Removals, Land Struggles and Restoration of Land in South Africa: A
Case of Roosboom
No.28 (2007)
Michael Furmanovsky, Reconciliation, Restitution and Healing: The Role of Vietnam Veterans
in Facilitating a New Era in U.S.-Vietnam Relations, 1985-2005
No.29 (2007)
Hiroyuki Torigoe, Land Ownership for the Preservation of Environment and Livelihood
No.30 (2007)
Kokki Goto (Edited, Annotated, and with an Introduction by Motoko Shimagami), Iriai
Forests Have Sustained the Livelihood and Autonomy of Villagers: Experience of Commons in
Ishimushiro Hamlet in Northeastern Japan
No.31 (2007)
Kazuo Kobayashi, The “Invention of Tradition” in Java under the Japanese Occupation: The
Tonarigumi System and Gotong Royon
No.32 (2007)
Benedict Anderson, Useful or Useless Relics: Today’s Strange Monarchies㸦ຍ⸨ ๛ヂࠗ᭷⏝
࡞㑇ไ࠿↓⏝࡞㑇≀㸽⌧௦࡟࠾ࡅࡿྩ୺ไ࡜࠸࠺୙ᛮ㆟࡞Ꮡᅾ࠘ 㸧
No.33 (2008)
Pauline Kent, The Chrysanthemum and the Sword: The Use of Radical Comparisons to
Enhance Mutual Understanding
No.34 (2008)
Naomi Hosoda, Towards a Cultural Interpretation of Migration in the Philippines: Focusing
on Value-Rationality and Capitalism
No.35 (2008)
Anan Ganjanapan, Multiplicity of Community Forestry as Knowledge Space in the Northern
Thai Highlands
No.36 (2008)
Shinji Suzuki, The Increasing Enclosure of Mangrove Wetlands: Towards Resource
Management in Development Frontiers
No.37 (2008)
Akiko Watanabe, Migration and Mosques: The Evolution and Transformation of Muslim
Communities in Manila, the Philippines
No.38 (2009)
Acharawan Isarangkura Na Ayuthaya and Senjo Nakai, The Emergence and Development of
Interfaith Cooperation: A Case Study of the Theravada Buddhist Advocacy for People Living
with HIV/AIDS (PWA) in Upper Northern Thailand
No.39 (2009)
Jeremy Rappleye, Decline of the Tokyo Technocrats in Educational Policy Formation?
Exploring the Loss of Ministry Autonomy and Recent Policy Trends with Reference to
‘Globalisation’ and Educational Transfer
No.40 (2009)
Robert Aspinall, The New ‘Three Rs’ of Education in Japan: Rights, Risk, and Responsibility
No.41 (2009)
Takehiko Ochiai, Personal Rule in Nigeria
No.42 (2009)
Toru Sagawa, Why Do People “Renounce War”? The War Experience of the Daasanach of the
Conflict-ridden Region of Northeast Africa
No.43 (2009)
Aysun Uyar, Political Configuration of Thailand’s Free Trade Agreements within the
Framework of Southeast Asian Regional Economic Cooperation
No.44 (2009)
Kosuke Shimizu, Nishida Kitaro and Japan’s Interwar Foreign Policy: War Involvement and
Culturalist Political Discourse
No.45 (2009)
Julian Chapple, Increasing Migration and Diversity in Japan: The Need for Dialogue and
Collaboration in Education, Language and Identity Policies
No.46 (2009)
Motoko Shimagami, An Iriai Interchange Linking Japan and Indonesia: An Experiment in Practical
Collaborative Research leading toward Community-Based Forest Management
No.47 (2009)
Nakamura Hisashi, Social Development and Conflict Resolution; as Seen by an Unorthodox Economist
No.48 (2009)
Tomoko Matsui, The Narrative Strategies and Multilayered Realities of Returnee Workers: A Case Study
of Thai Returnee Workers from Japan
No.49 (2009)
Yoshio Kawamura, Framework on Socio-economic Mechanism of Emigration in the Pre-war Japan
No.50 (2009)
Yoshio Kawamura, Socioeconomic Factor Structure of Japanese Emigrant Communities: A Statistical
Case Study at Inukami County, Shiga Prefecture, in the Meiji Era
No.51 (2009)
David Blake Willis, A Nation at Risk, A Nation in Need of Dialogue: Citizenship, Denizenship, and
Beyond in Japanese Education
No.52 (2009)
Shinya Ishizaka, Non-violent Means of Conflict Resolution in the Chipko (Forest Protection) Movement
in India
No.53 (2009)
Shinji Suzuki, Illegal Logging in Southeast Asia
No.54 (2009)
Fuping Li, The Current Issues and Development Process of Poverty in China
No.55 (2009)
Shin’ichi Takeuchi, Conflict and Land Tenure in Rwanda
No.56 (2009)
Katsumi Ishizuka, The Impact of UN Peace-building Efforts on the Justice System of Timor-Leste:
Western versus Traditional Cultures
No.57 (2009)
Kazuo Funahashi, Changes in Income among Peasants in Northeast Thailand: Poverty Reduction Seen
Through a Panel Analysis
No.58 (2009)
Kazue Demachi, Japanese Foreign Assistance to Africa: Aid and Trade
No.59 (2009)
Akio Nishiura, Determinants of South African Outward Direct Investment in Africa
No.60 (2009)
Ryosuke Sato, Discontinuity of International Law with the ‘National Reconciliation’ Process — An
analysis of the transitional ‘amnesty’ mechanism of the Truth and Reconciliation Commission in South
Africa —
No.61 (2009)
Kazuya Masuda, The Reconstitution of Adat in a Dual Level Land Conflict: A case study of a village
community under forest development schemes in Sumatra, Indonesia
No.62 (2009)
Kyoko Cross, Harmonizing Local with Global Justice: Emergence of a Hybrid Institutional Mechanism
for Reconciliation in East Timor
No.63 (2009)
Tomoaki Ueda, Institution and Ideal in Indian Nationalist Thoughts: G. K. Gokhale in Comparison with
M. K. Gandhi
No.64 (2010)
William Bradley, Educational Policy in 21st Century Japan: Neoliberalism and Beyond?
No.65 (2010)
Kosuke Shimizu, Structural Violence and Human Security
No.66 (2010)
Misa Shojiya, Democratization in Divided Society – Outcomes and Issues in International Assistance㸫

 Studies on Multicultural Societies (Phase2)


No.1 (2012)
Katsumi Ishizuka, Is US and NATO-led Security Policy Compatible with the Multiple Frameworks
Model of Peace-building in Afghanistan?
No.2 (2012)
Rieko Karatani, Unravelling the Security and Insecurity of Female Overseas Domestic Workers:
‘Global Householding’ and ‘Global De-Householding’ Examined
No.3 (2012)
Katsumi Ishizuka, Japan’s Policy towards the War on Terror in Afghanistan
No.4 (2012)
Soo im Lee, Japanese Learners’ Underlying Beliefs Affecting Foreign Language Leaners’ Motivation:
New Perspectives of Affective Factors Mechanism
No.5 (2012)
Kelvin Chi-Kin Cheung, Historicizing Taiwan’s Democracy: Recovering the Identity Politics Behind the
New Civic Nation in Taiwan
No.6 (2012)
Kawamura Yoshio, Characteristics of Agricultural Production Structures Determined by Capital Inputs
and Productivities in Contemporary China: Based on 2010 Annual Statistical Data at the Provincial
Level
No.7 (2012)
Satoko Kawamura, The Formation of Global Economic Law: Under Aspects of the Autopoietic System
No.8 (2012)
Soo im Lee, Diversity of Zainichi Koreans and Their Ties to Japan and Korea
Afrasian Research Centre, Ryukoku University
1-5 Yokotani, Seta Oe-cho, Otsu,
Shiga, JAPAN
ISBN 978-4-904945-07-0

You might also like