Technovation: Marc Cowling, Josh Siepel

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 11

Technovation 33 (2013) 265–275

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Technovation
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/technovation

Public intervention in UK small firm credit markets: Value-for-money


or waste of scarce resources?
Marc Cowling a,n, Josh Siepel b
a
Exeter Business School, Exeter, Devon EX4 4PU, United Kingdom
b
Science Policy Research Unit, University of Sussex, Brighton BN1 9QE, United Kingdom

a r t i c l e i n f o abstract

Available online 21 December 2012 Loan guarantee schemes are used in many countries to provide financial support to small firms by
Keywords: guaranteeing loans from commercial banks, but questions remain about whether public intervention in
Small business private credit markets to support entrepreneurial firms is justified. This paper examines whether the
Government programs UK Small Firms Loan Guarantee Scheme (SFLG) provides value-for-money to the UK tax payer,
Financing presenting a regression based performance approach which then feeds into a formal cost–benefit
Loan guarantees analysis. Specifically, we consider whether firm performance post-investment is such that it justifies
the governments’ presence in the lending market and the costs associated with it. Our findings suggest
that entrepreneurial firms that are able to access new finance through SFLG achieve superior
performance in the form of improved sales, job creation and exports and that this justifies public
intervention in private credit markets.
& 2012 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

1. Introduction research agenda by emphasising the key role that government


policy could play in supporting or diminishing the ability of smaller
Bruce Kirchhoff was one of the first scholars in the post-Birch firms to maximise their potential. In this paper we focus on the most
Job Generation Study period to not only update the job generation widely used, and long-standing, public policy mechanism world-
findings of Birch (1979), but add to our understanding of the wide for supporting small firms: the (partial) credit guarantee
relative dynamics of job creation across different size classes of scheme. Examples of these schemes include the SBA 7(a) loan
firm. As a result of his early work (Kirchhoff and Phillips, 1988), programme in the US, founded in 1953; the Canadian core guaran-
and the consistent evidence that small, and specifically new, firms tee programme (CSBFP), founded in 1961; and the UK Small Firm
create a disproportionately high number of net new jobs, he Loan Guarantee programme, founded in 1981, as well as pro-
became more widely interested in questions around how policy- grammes in many other countries, including France, Germany, India
makers could support smaller and younger entrepreneurial firms and Korea.
to maximise their potential to the wider benefit of the economy. Why are credit guarantee programmes such a widely used
Of particular concern to Kirchhoff was (a) that policy had up form of policy intervention in developed and developing coun-
until that point ignored smaller firms, and explicitly the creation tries, and is there an empirical basis for their use? Given that the
of new firms (Kirchhoff, 1996, p. 628), (b) that rigidities in the growth of small firms is generally constrained by access to
labour market had created barriers that prevented entrepreneur- internal capital (Carpenter and Peterson, 2002; Beck and
ial firms from hiring more workers (Kirchhoff and Phillips, 1988, Demirguc-Kunt, 2006), a common concern raised in the small
pp. 271–272), and (c) that the removal of barriers to new firm business literature is that capital market imperfections exist and
entry was critical to future economic dynamism and growth limit the availability of finance to small firms (Laeven, 2003; Love,
(Kirchhoff, 1994, p. 199). 2003; Gelos and Werner, 2002). Beck and Demirguc-Kunt (2006)
Given the centrality of new firms and smaller firms in general state that small firm financing obstacles have almost twice the
to job creation and economic growth, Kirchhoff (and his co-authors) effect on annual growth than large firm financing obstacles.
not only empirically justified the role of small firms as an important Headd and Kirchhoff (2007) express the importance of ‘available
agent of economic development, but explicitly shaped the future financing’ in allowing small businesses to maintain their role as
major actors in the economic system. This allows them to
continue as a major source of net new job generation (Phillips
n
Corresponding author. Tel.: þ44 78 4186 6228. and Kirchhoff, 1989). Access to finance is particularly relevant for
E-mail address: M.Cowling@exeter.ac.uk (M. Cowling). innovative firms, which have considerable job creation potential

0166-4972/$ - see front matter & 2012 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2012.11.002
266 M. Cowling, J. Siepel / Technovation 33 (2013) 265–275

but suffer from gaps in knowledge and provision of capital, potential entrepreneurs and/or small businesses get access to
leading to underfunding (Peneder, 2008). Given that innovation loans is a necessary, but not a sufficient condition, for justifying
is a costly (Saemundsson, 2005) and uncertain (Wang et al., 2008) public intervention in credit markets.
process, innovative firms tend to be persistently financially Crucial to loan guarantee schemes is that bank screening
constrained (Westhead and Storey, 1997; Carpenter and processes remain in place to avoid risky investments. Riding
Peterson, 2002). (1998) argues that the objective of loan guarantee schemes is to
The sources of capital that firms use to address their financial assist small firms, not to subsidise risky firms. Further, Fraser
needs are therefore important. The ‘pecking order hypothesis’ of (2009) suggests that it is the task of the credit markets to
Myers and Majluf (1984) suggests that firms will prefer debt to discriminate according to quality of borrower. For example, firm
equity capital. While forms of equity investment such as venture size and firm age are often taken to be good proxies for firm risk
capital are commonly discussed in the literature (Cornelius and (see Beck and Demirguc-Kunt, 2006; Cowling, 1999a respec-
Persson, 2006), in practice venture capital-backed firms represent tively). In a world of imperfect (or incomplete) information,
only a small fraction of the total population of firms—in the US lending institutions often look for easily verifiable factors when
approximately 0.625% of firms founded in any year will receive making lending decisions. Empirical evidence reported by
VC (Puri and Zarutskie, 2008), while 55% of firms access debt Hyytinen and Pajarinen (2007) finds that when a small business
capital (Bitler et al., 2001). Consequently, given the high demand ages 1 year, its cost of debt decreases by 1–2 basis points.
for capital from growing firms, credit is a crucial part of the Importantly, they also find that within firms’ growth of collater-
funding ecosystem for small firms, including those with innova- alisable wealth is not driving this age–cost of debt relationship.
tion activities (Colombo and Grilli, 2007; Aaboen et al., 2006). For Gregory et al. (2005) find that only firm size is a predictor of
innovative firms, the availability of credit reduces the reluctance capital structure decisions. Whilst both may be true in a wider
to adopt new technologies that raise mean income levels (Ghosh sense, it is also true that within each size and age category of firm
et al., 2000), allowing firms to use new technologies that then there is a distribution of risk across firms within that group. Thus
facilitate further growth. the objective of loan guarantee schemes is to facilitate capital
This leads us to the key issue surrounding the rationale for formation for small firms, a contention supported by Green
loan guarantee schemes, that of credit rationing. Credit rationing (2003) and Graham (2004). To this end, the offer of a loan
refers to the phenomenon where some borrowers receive loans guarantee by a potential lending bank is made after due diligence
while others do not, all else being equal (Bester, 1985). Given the is conducted according to conventional lending criteria.
importance of credit for firms and their growth, much attention
(see Cowling, 1997) has been paid to credit rationing in the form
of loan denial, what Ghosh et al. (2000) refer to as macro credit 2. Credit guarantee schemes
rationing (As opposed to micro credit rationing, which refers to
credit limits (i.e. the amount that firms can raise).). Loan guaran- In this section we briefly review the empirical literature on
tee schemes are predicated on the notion small firms cannot gain several international loan guarantee programmes, discussing
access to (proportionally) as much credit, or credit on equally their effectiveness and impact on small businesses and regional
favourable terms, as larger firms of equal risk. Concerns about or national economies. Key to the literature evaluating loan
credit rationing for small firms have led to the widespread use of guarantee schemes is what is termed additionality in the UK,
loan guarantee programmes throughout the developed (Cowling and incrementality in North America. Additionality refers to the
and Mitchell, 2003; Riding, 1998) and developing (Klapper et al., requirement that guaranteed loans are only issued to borrowers
2006; Honaghan, 2008) world. Almost without exception this who had exhausted all other potential sources of loan funding,
type of intervention in the capital market has sought to provide and studies addressing this topic generally seek to identify
loan security to smaller firms who would not otherwise be able to the additional economic benefit provided by these additional
obtain debt finance through conventional means (Riding, 1998; guaranteed loans.
Cowling and Clay, 1995). The major benefits of public financing
initiatives have been identified as supporting the validation of 2.1. Canadian small business financing (CSBF) programme
technology (Freel, 1999) and acting as a catalyst for broader
economic development (Wonglimpiyarat, 2006). The Canadian Small Business Financing program (CSBF)
Despite this, the existence of credit rationing (and conse- evolved from the original 1961 Small Business Loans Act primary
quently the rationale for loan guarantee schemes) has remained loan guarantee program. In its current form, the program is
difficult to clearly identify. The challenge behind public interven- available for any (non-farm) profit oriented business with sales
tion may be viewed in light of Astebro and Bernhardt’s (2003) less than $5 m Canadian, and loans up to $250,000 can be issued.
framework of Type 1 and Type 2 errors: if a loan guarantee Loans are limited to term loans, and for the purchase of premises
programme advances a loan to a firm that subsequently fails, this and equipment, land, or leasing but not working capital. The
represents a Type 1 error, indicating that banks made the correct guarantee is for 80% of the outstanding balance. Lenders have
decision in the first instance not to lend to the firm in the absence complete discretion over the loan approval process.
of a loan guarantee scheme. By contrast, government backed Riding (1998) focuses on additionality in CSBF, estimating a
loans which are successfully repaid would, in the absence of a loan ‘outcomes’ model to identify which firms successfully
guarantee scheme, represent a missed opportunity for the bank. applied for loans and which were turned down based on obser-
This would be termed a type 2 error. Broadly speaking, if defaults vable characteristics. They then apply this approval/turn-down
increase as constrained firms become unconstrained via the loan model to a sample of loan guarantee program borrowers. Their
guarantee, then banks are, under certain conditions, better off key finding was that 81% of their loan guarantee sample would
without a scheme. This occurs as loan guarantees raise the have been turned down for conventional loans, and after further
equilibrium price (via the government interest rate premium) testing (Riding et al. 2007) amounted to 74.8% additionality.
and volume (number of loans and the total value of loans) traded Further analysis for jobs created suggested that of the 10,000
in the market. This can lead to a situation where banks are guaranteed loans per annum, CSBF contributed to an additional
lending at levels above their profit maximising level (Cressy, 22,000 full-time jobs in Canada each year. This builds on previous
1996; Devinney, 1986; Cowling, 2010). The fact that not all research (Riding and Haines, 2001) showing the guarantee
M. Cowling, J. Siepel / Technovation 33 (2013) 265–275 267

scheme to be very efficient in job creation, with a cost of rationing (i.e. limits to amounts firms can access) as identified
approximately $2000 per job created (most of which reflects cost by Ghosh et al. (2000). He estimated the determinants of agreed
of default). overdraft limits in a framework related to the theoretical volume
rationing model of De Meza (2002), whereby banks ration firms
2.2. US small business association loan schemes by restricting loan amounts rather than explicitly denying lending
proposals, and the credit allocation model of Melnik and Plaut
The US SBA loan guarantee is a large-scale programme cur- (1986) under which contract terms can be traded off against one
rently holding USD 50 billion in assets in over 360,000 loans since another. The key findings were that ex post default had no bearing
1991. Under its general 7(a) loan programme and its ‘504’ on initial credit volumes advanced, nor was there an obvious
programme more focused on building fixed assets, the pro- trade-off between loan margins (risk premia) and loan amount.
gramme provides partial guarantees to loans from banks. But the availability of collateral for firms which wish to borrow
A series of papers by Craig et al. (2005, 2006, 2007a, 2007b) debt under commitment contracts is absolutely crucial to their
from the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland focused on how the ability to raise substantial amounts of funding. Holding all else
US SBA loan guarantee affected local economic growth and constant, not having any collateral reduces a firm’s maximum
employment. Using panel data at the Metropolitan Statistical borrowing by half. This is supportive of the role of SFLG in
Area (MSA) level, they test whether the 360,000 SBA and ‘504’ allowing certain types of small firm borrowers to access bank
loans were associated with higher per capital incomes and higher funding.
local employment. On incomes, they find that SBA loans are In a further two papers, Cowling (2008, 2010) replicated the
associated with a positive (but small) increase in future per capita Berger and Udell (1992) US loan market study using UK SFLG
income growth. On employment, they find that ‘if you increased data. Broadly, there were nine explicit tests of credit rationing,
per capita SBA guaranteed lending in a local market byy divided into two strands. The first strand were categorised as
approximately $100 the predicted result is an increase in the ‘stickiness’ tests and involved testing how bank margins moved
level of employment by 0.8 percentage points’ (p. 26). In localities when base rates moved, or how margins differed with loans of
with less developed financial markets the effect is higher, and different types. The second strand was categorised as ‘propor-
specifically, ‘guaranteed lending will have a larger positive impact tions’ tests, and involved testing how banks rationed loans of
on social welfare if it is targeted to certain high-minority areas’ different types when base rates changed. On the six stickiness
(p. 28). tests, four results were broadly supportive of credit rationing,
particularly for firms without collateral. But the results on the
2.3. UK small firm loan guarantee scheme (SFLG) three ‘proportions’ tests were inconclusive. The author concluded
that in the presence of the SFLG, credit rationing in not an
The empirical context for our paper is the UK Small Firm Loan explanation consistent with the loan market for most small
Guarantee scheme. The SFLG, established in 1981, was the businesses in the UK. However, there is a small pool of borrowers
government’s primary debt finance instrument until its name who, due to information problems, will always find it more
change in 2009. SFLG addressed the market failure in the provi- difficult to raise bank funds when credit markets are tightening,
sion of debt finance by providing a Government guarantee to even in the presence of SFLG.
banks in cases where a business with a viable business plan is We have drawn upon a wide range of theoretical and empirical
unable to raise finance because they cannot offer security for their literature, including some longstanding seminal contributions
debt and/ or lack a track record. This rationale still underpinned and some recent theoretical and empirical advances, to establish
the SFLG at the time of the collection and evaluation of data. In what we know about key aspects of credit rationing and how it
the SFLG, the government covers 75% of the loan value and impacts on the financing of entrepreneurial businesses. In doing
borrowing businesses pay a premium which is 2% over the so we have considered what the economic effects of finance
commercial bank rate. Over the last decade, take up of the scheme constraints might be, how banks deal with risk and how this
has averaged around 4500 loans per year, although there have might lead to missed opportunities for viable lending to smaller
been fluctuations between individual years. In January 2009, SFLG businesses. We have also made a case for public intervention
was replaced by the Enterprise Finance Guarantee (EFG), which in the form of loan guarantee programmes under certain
opened the scheme to a wider number of businesses, with the circumstances.
specific objective to facilitate new bank lending in response to the
decrease in credit availability associated with the financial crisis.
The SFLG has been analysed in a series of empirical papers by 3. Objectives and methodology
Cowling (2007a, 2007b, 2008, 2010) and Cowling and Mitchell
(2003). They add some interesting insights into the operation of While the rationale behind loan guarantee programmes is
the UK SFLG. The latter paper uses data for the 42,316 loans clear (as discussed above), what is less clear is whether this form
issued from 1984 to 1998 to estimate the determinants of default of intervention –while logical – is economically justified in terms
and the timing of it in the context of the theoretical credit of the benefits provided to the broader economy, particularly in
rationing model set out by Stiglitz and Weiss (1981). The key challenging times for the public sector. The remainder of the
findings were that default increases with the banks’ cost of capital paper explores this topic in the case of the UK SFLG. The main
(the loan rate) but not with the government premium. In addition, objective of this research is to provide an assessment of the SFLG’s
default was also found to increase in periods of macroeconomic impact arising from supported businesses being able to access
growth, suggesting that in economic upturns the marginal SFLG loans that they would otherwise not have received. Our examina-
borrower is of lower quality as banks relax their lending criteria. tion has two parts: first we examine the survival and performance
Collateralisable wealth was found to have no effect, which implies of firms receiving SFLG guarantees, and then we consider the
that entrepreneurial ability is randomly distributed throughout relative costs and benefits of the scheme to the UK economy.
the population and not confined to the wealthy. We first explore the relative survival and performance of SFLG-
Cowling (2007a) explored the role of loan commitments backed firms. As discussed above, credit rationing assumes that
(overdrafts) on the UK SFLG as a means of insuring borrowers there are firms who are able to repay loans but are not able to obtain
against future credit rationing. This relates to micro credit capital. We seek to examine this by considering the short-term and
268 M. Cowling, J. Siepel / Technovation 33 (2013) 265–275

long-term survival of SFLG backed firms. We do this using measures (sales and employment), the self-reported data was
descriptive analysis for investments from 2006 to 2008, and cross-referenced against the Office for National Statistics Annual
regression analysis for long-run survival for loans made from Business Register figures. Telephone interviews were conducted
2000 to 2005. Under conditions of credit rationing we would by a specialist survey company during August to September 2008
expect relatively high survival rates as this would represent firms with businesses who had received an SFLG loan in 2006, alongside
that were otherwise unable to raise debt but were otherwise a matched sample of non-users from the general business
sound. Building on this, we then compare the performance of population. The comparison sample group was matched to the
SFLG-backed firms against a matched control group. This regres- SFLG group in terms of company legal status and broad industry
sion analysis allows us to assess the performance of SFLG in terms sector (to one level SIC). In total, 1488 businesses were surveyed
of a number of business outcomes including employment change, including 441 SFLG supported businesses and 1047 unassisted
sales change and likelihood to export, as a means to under- businesses. The survey was designed to collect information on
standing the impact of the firm. additionality including finance deadweight and market displace-
Research Question 1 (RQ1): Do SFLG backed firms perform ment amongst SFLG supported businesses and more generally,
better or worse than otherwise similar firms? growth orientation, employment and sales growth, product and
Using this information we then seek to examine whether the process innovation, prior labour market history of the business
performance of SFLG represents good value for the public sector. We owner, geographic market focus and internationalisation.
do this by first using the information about survival from the prior In order to identify the ‘true’ impact of SFLG, it was necessary
analysis to derive information about cost, and then examine the to take into account key differences in characteristics between the
overall cost effectiveness of the SFLG to the Exchequer and the sample groups. Although the survey comparison groups were
economy in terms of additional Gross value added (GVA). These originally matched to SFLG recipient group it was necessary to
estimates take account of the extent to which businesses would have also statistically adjust for this using a three-way weight which
obtained finance in the absence of the scheme (finance additionality) took account of sector, age and initial size of businesses. This
and business deadweight and displacement effects in markets. enable businesses that accessed SFLG supported loans to be
Research Question 2 (RQ2): Given default rates and observed ‘matched’ to businesses with similar characteristics that did not
performance of SFLG backed firms, does the SFLG scheme repre- receive an SFLG loan.
sent value-for-money or a waste of scarce resources? When assessing finance additionality, the SFLG recipient group
Answering these two research questions will therefore allow is compared against businesses who received a conventional bank
us to gain an understanding of the value and impact of public loan. To assess the wider contribution of the scheme, the SFLG
sector intervention in the credit market. group is compared to two comparison groups; conventional
borrowers and non-borrowers (Although an additional number
3.1. Data of comparison groups were identified, it was not possible to
analyse these in practice due to small sample numbers.).
To address our first research question, we draw upon two sets The cost–benefit analysis (CBA) is carried out using UK
of data. For our long-run survival analysis we use the full SFLG Treasury Best Practice as highlighted in the Green Book (http://
population of firms for loans taken out between 2000 and 2005. In www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/data_greenbook_index.html.). The cost–
total this constitutes 31,425 SFLG backed loans. Using data from benefit analysis was conducted using findings gathered from
this period allows us to have a fuller longitudinal understanding the evaluation survey as well as from Management Information
of the survival of SFLG-backed firms. However, this dataset is not provided by the Enterprise Directorate of the Department of
sufficient to understand issues of relative performance outlined Business, Innovation and Skills (BIS), and other, secondary,
above. In order to address the question of relative performance sources for tax and benefit data and gross value added figures.
and value-for-money we need to address the counterfactual and
therefore use a different sample that allows us to compare SFLG
backed and non-SFLG firms. 4. Survival and performance of SFLG
Therefore, for the other analysis of RQ1 and RQ2 we use a
comparison group methodology to assess the counterfactual As discussed above, the key concern of loan guarantee
issues by drawing on a sample of SFLG backed and non-SFLG schemes is to provide capital to otherwise quality firms who are
firms over a 2 year window from 2006 to 2008. This data was not able to access the credit market. In this section we analyse
collected as part of a formal evaluation commissioned by the UK short-term and long-term survival of SFLG firms and examine
Department for Business Innovation and Skills (DBIS) and it these firms’ performance against a control group.
assessed the outcomes achieved by assisted businesses compared
to what would have happened to those businesses in the absence
of SFLG. The counterfactual was established by constructing a 4.1. Short-term survival
matched sample to compare the performance outcomes of those
accessing SFLG supported loan as against a sample of similar It is difficult to use the data available to estimate short-term
businesses not accessing SFLG loans. Matching was done on the survival of firms receiving loans, which is not aided by the fact
age of business, sector and size at the point of loan issue in 2006. that annual reports list annual figures rather than full cohorts.
In total, 1488 businesses including 441 SFLG supported busi- Using data from BIS Management Information we were able to
nesses and 1047 unassisted businesses were surveyed. The SFLG examine a cohort of loans drawn down in Q2 2006 to assess the
sample was drawn as a quota sample so as to be representative of proportion defaulting over each quarter of the life of the loan.
the full SFLG population at that point in time. The effective Fig. 1 shows the cumulative survival profile of SFLG loans
sample is 10% of the total SFLG population from 2006. Survey drawn down in Q2 2006. After 2 years (eight quarters) 73.9% of
responses were analysed using a mixture of statistical approaches the loans issued in Q2 2006 had not defaulted, suggesting 26.1%
including econometric modelling to control for any sample had defaulted. From this profile it is possible to estimate the cost
differences. of SFLG loans drawn down in 2006, in the first 2 years of the
This evaluation used businesses’ self-reported assessment of scheme, which we will do in Section 5 as part of the cost–benefit
business performance and scheme impact. For two key output analysis.
M. Cowling, J. Siepel / Technovation 33 (2013) 265–275 269

firm). Differences in lending institution were also apparent with


the default probability varying by 16.1% between the ‘worst’ and
‘best’ banks. But the impacts of loan bundling (SFLG as part of a
multiple loan package including a collateralised conventional
loan) did not influence default. Taken as a whole, our findings
suggest that the government has the potential to significantly
affect default rates, the prime determinant of the schemes cost, by
altering the eligibility criteria and hence the types of firms who
use the scheme Table 1).

Fig. 1. SFLG loan default profile.


Source: BIS Management Data. 4.3. Comparative performance analysis

4.2. Long-run risk of default Next we focus on comparative short-run performance of SFLG
backed firms and our control group firms. Given that we do not
An issue with the data described above is that at the time of have access to the range of variables for the long-term analysis
collection, a high proportion of the loans issued under SFLG had above, we focus on the short-term impact. We use three core
not reached maturity and of those that would not reach their final measures to capture general performance over the 2 years follow-
term many still had not defaulted. But understanding what drives ing loan issue, 2006–2008. These are (a) employment change,
default is important as this substantially affects the cost to (b) sale change, and (c) exporting propensity. These first two
government of running the scheme. Lessons from default can measures are central to our subsequent cost–benefit analysis. The
provide further guidance for scheme enhancement in the future. final measure captures potential additional benefits to the UK
To tackle this issue we refer to the full SFLG population data for economy derived from selling goods and services in international
the loan issue period 2000–2005. As the data is drawn from
government management information records (MI), we do not
have the additional set of variables collected as part of the full Table 1
evaluation, but core firm level demographics are available for Loan default model.

analysis including loan purpose, loan term, loan size, industry, age Loan default (marginal effects)
of firm, sales, employment, geographic region, lending bank, legal
form, and a measure of labour productivity. dF/dx z-stat Sig.
The default probability model is estimated by a probit model
Loan amount, £s 0.0000  0.06
as default is a binary outcome coded 1 if the loan ended in default
Loan term (months) 0.0005 5.23 nnn
and zero otherwise. For the total SFLG population over this period, Legal form (ref. ¼co-op)
2000–2005, the default rate is 28.1%. For ease of interpretation Ltd 0.7363 8.09 nnn
the marginal effects are reported. The basic default model is thus Ltd partnership 0.7639 7.54 nnn

Default [1,0] ¼F(loan amount, loan purpose, loan term, loan Partnership 0.8801 7.31 nnn
PLC 0.7629 6.45 nnn
year, collateralised loan bundle, base rates, GDP growth, lending Sole trader 0.9336 7.77 nnn
institution, labour productivity, industry sector, geographic Loan purpose (ref. ¼working capital)
region, age of firm, legal form) Plant/fixed assets  0.0574  5.57 nnn
The ‘typical’ SFLG backed firm in the sample period has a loan Premises  0.1284  12.67 nnn
Other  0.0711  9.88 nnn
of £78,109 with a term of 70 months. The majority of firms have
Region (ref. ¼North East)
limited liability status, 75.7%, and 27.9% are newly established North West 0.0238 1.19
firms. Average labour productivity is £69,790 per employee. More Merseyside 0.0358 1.29
than half of all firms have a bundle of loans associated with their Yorks & Humber 0.0181 0.91
SFLG loan and in total 30.3% of firms have a collateralised West Midlands 0.0254 1.29
East Midlands 0.0424 2.09 nn
conventional loan running alongside their SFLG backed loan. At South East 0.0313 1.66 n
the sector level, manufacturing, 27.9%, and construction firms, East 0.0369 1.87 n
27.1%, tend to have a disproportionate share of SFLG loans. Base Greater London 0.0373 1.88 n
rates averaged 4.62% over the period. South West 0.0011 0.06
Scotland 0.0106 0.51
The key findings from the default model are that there is a
Wales 0.0240 1.11
positive relationship between the initial loan term (expressed in Northern Ireland  0.0478  0.65
months) and subsequent default, but no relationship between Stage of firm (ref. ¼ new)
loan amount and default. Longer term loans increase the prob- Existing  0.0899  4.85 nnn
ability of default by 0.6% for every additional year until loan Established 0.0083 0.45
GDP growth  0.0154  1.16
maturity. In contrast, firms with higher labour productivity (i.e. Base rate  0.0084  0.84
more efficient firms), on average had lower default rates. The Conventional loan  0.0116  1.57
marginal effect implies that for every 1% increase in labour Secured loan 0.0052 0.80
productivity, the probability of default declines by 0.5%. Neither Year of loan (ref. ¼2000)
2001  0.0126  0.87
the state of the macroeconomy or the general cost of borrowing
2002  0.0535  2.41 nn
impacted on default. This, in itself, suggests that firm character- 2003  0.0823  3.55 nnn
istics fundamentally determine loan default. On firm age, we find 2004  0.1176  6.68 nnn
that existing, but young, firms (1–2 years old) were the least 2005  0.2038  13.35 nnn
likely to default. The probability was 9.0% lower than that for new Labour productivity, £ 0.0000  2.28 nn
No. obs 21.967
start-ups and older firms. Sole traders and partnerships (i.e. those
Pseudo R2 0.0766
firms without limited liability) had the highest default rates
(19.7% and 14.4% higher probabilities than a limited liability Significance: n ¼ 0.1; nn
¼0.05; nnn
¼ 0.01.
270 M. Cowling, J. Siepel / Technovation 33 (2013) 265–275

markets. The key variables to be included in our performance Performance (2006–2008) ¼F (firm characteristics, entrepre-
models are as follows: neur characteristics, ownership characteristicsþSFLG dummy).
On employment change between 2006 and 2008 we find that
 Firm characteristics—legal status, age, industry sector, size, region. the median SFLG firm grew its employment by 0.42% compared to
 Entrepreneur characteristics—previous labour market status,  0.13% (i.e. a loss of jobs) in the comparison group firms Table 2).
management qualifications, financial qualifications, prior busi- In contrast, the average employment growth for SFLG and control
ness experience, prior entrepreneurial experience, gender, and firms was 1.51% and 2.15% respectively. This implies that employ-
ethnicity. ment growth is less concentrated (more equally distributed)
 Ownership characteristics—board size, non-executive directors. amongst SFLG firms over time, and generally higher. For real sales
change (i.e. adjusted for general increases in price levels), between
2006 and 2008 we find that the median SFLG firm grew its
The ‘typical’ firm in the sample was 6.5 years old in 2006 and employment by 0.31% compared to 0.0% (i.e. no change) in the
had 6.2 employees. About 37.1% of entrepreneurs had previously comparison group firms. In contrast, the average for SFLG and
started a business and this experience averaged 5 years. About control firms was 1.82% and 2.23% respectively. This implies that
88.9% were previously in waged employment or self-employed. sales growth is less concentrated (more equally distributed)
Boards of directors were typically small, averaging 2.2 directors, amongst SFLG firms over time, and generally higher. Finally, we
although 15.4% of boards had a non-executive director. 44.3% of note that SFLG firms had a higher propensity to export than
boards had a female director and 13.1% a director from an ethnic control firms, 23% compared to 16%. Thus the raw evidence
minority. Only 16.3% of directors had a financial qualification and suggests that SFLG is associated with generally superior perfor-
22.1% a management qualification. mance on key measures such as employment (job creation), sales
For the employment and sales change models we estimate our growth and internationalisation. This is consistent with two
models by OLS using robust standard errors. The exporting model, general concluding points of Bruce Kirchhoff’s body of work in
as it is expressed in binary form [1,0] for whether a firm exports, that small firms do create jobs and contribute to general economic
is estimated as a probit model, for which we report the marginal growth, and also that policy intervention to promote jobs and
effects. The SFLG scheme effect is estimated by a simple dummy growth can generate positive outcomes. It is also important here
variable coded 1 if the firm has an SFLG loan and zero otherwise. to remember that the final year of performance was the start of
The basic model can be written thus the deepest economic crisis for 70 years.

Table 2
Comparative performance models.

Employment change Real sales change Exporting propensity

b t-stat Sig. b t-stat Sig. b z-stat Sig.

Start employment size  0.0819  7.0100 nnn 0.0000 0.0000 nnn 0.0001 0.0700
SFLG 0.4064 7.1200 nnn 0.1589 5.0100 nnn 0.0878 3.6400 nnn
Firm age 0.0081 2.9200 nn  0.0017  1.3200 0.0016 1.4600
Ltd liability 0.0528 0.7900 0.0075 0.1900 0.1357 4.8200 nnn
Sector
Construction  0.0059  0.0500 0.2198 3.2700 nnn  0.1368  3.7900 nnn
Services 0.0615 0.9300 0.0255 0.6800  0.1727  6.2600 nnn
Region (ref¼ North East)
North West  0.0261  0.2000 0.0572 0.8200  0.0066  0.1200
Yorkshire & Humberside 0.1739 1.1300 0.0336 0.4000 0.0870 1.2300
West Midlands 0.0461 0.3400  0.0626  0.8700 0.0613 0.9800
East Midlands 0.0973 0.6400  0.0889  1.1000 0.0258 0.4000
East 0.0420 0.2700 0.0815 0.9400 0.0920 1.2000
South West 0.0631 0.5000 0.0450 0.6500 0.0100 0.1800
South East 0.1365 1.1000 0.0001 0.0000 0.0731 1.2600
Greater London 0.1316 0.9900  0.0219  0.3100 0.0316 0.5300
Wales 0.2528 1.6500 n 0.0274 0.3200  0.0536  0.8300
Scotland 0.2281 1.5500 0.0346 0.4400 0.1396 1.9300 n
Northern Ireland 0.0960 0.4100  0.1359  0.8700 0.0373 0.3600
Other  0.0612  0.1800 0.1732 0.8200 0.1803 1.2300
Ownership
Number of directors 0.2992 13.3000 nnn 0.0213 1.7800 n 0.0115 1.0400
Non  executive director 0.4309 5.6200 nnn 0.0758 1.8100 n 0.0571 1.7800 n
Female directors  0.2420  6.7400 nnn 0.0025 0.1200  0.0204  1.3100
Ethnic directors  0.0466  1.0100 0.0243 0.7200  0.0376  1.7100 n
Management qualifications  0.0661  1.0000 0.0176 0.4800 0.0161 0.5600
Finance qualifications 0.0161 0.2200 0.0253 0.6100 0.1167 3.4800 nnn
Business experience years 0.0429 2.5000 nn  0.0185  1.7800 n 0.0109 1.5000
Previous Start  up  0.0303  0.5200  0.0459  1.3900 0.0385 1.5800
Prior labour market status
Working  0.0522  0.8000 0.0046 0.1200  0.0253  0.9200
Self-employed  0.2272  1.3000 0.1738 1.4900  0.1162  2.0300 nn
Unemployed 0.0295 0.1900 0.0766 0.8300  0.0053  0.0900
Inactive 0.2514 1.8200 n 0.0757 0.8800  0.0015  0.0300
Constant  0.4190  2.7500 nnn 0.2924 3.4900 nnn
No. obs. 1248 788 1258
Prob 4 F 0.0001 0.0001 0.0001

Significance: n ¼0.1; nn
¼0.05; nnn
¼0.01.
M. Cowling, J. Siepel / Technovation 33 (2013) 265–275 271

The first point of note from our employment and sales change defaults was £69.3 million in 2007/2008. This resulted from 1759
models is that the SFLG dummy variable is positive and signifi- loans that defaulted with an average cost of £39,410. Recoveries
cant in both. The respective coefficients (0.41 and 0.16) imply that arise when a lender’s demand against the SFLG guarantee has
the SFLG has a stronger effect on employment change than sales been settled and the lender subsequently recovers funds from the
change. There is also a substantial degree of consistency in terms borrower, which may occur following liquidation of businesses
of what are the key variables associated with employment and assets. During 2007/2008 BIS recovered previous demands with a
sales change. For example, initial firm size is negatively associated total value of £1.2 million, or around 2% of the demand settlement
with subsequent growth in both models. This implies that smaller payments made in the year. However, as mentioned in Section 4.1
firms grow faster. On sales change, it was also the case that it is difficult to calculate the annual impact, so it is useful to
construction firms grew more than firms in any other sectors. examine 1 year’s investments.
Employment change was also positive associated with initial age The exact number of new SFLG loans made in 2006 (calendar
of firm. In terms of entrepreneurs’ characteristics, we observe that year) was 3100, with an average value of SFLG loans made in 2006
previous labour market status had no effect, nor did managerial or of £79,500 (US$120,000). The estimated gross default cost of the
financial qualifications (measures of formal human capital). Prior 810 SFLG loans drawn down in 2006 that did not survive up to
business experience had different effects, being positively asso- quarter 9 (i.e. more than 2 years) is £41.8 million (The Govern-
ciated with employment growth, but negatively associated with ment guarantee covers 75% of the value of the remaining loan
sales growth. Ownership characteristics were found to be impor- value.). To estimate the net cost of default, administration costs
tant, with a positive growth association for firms with larger incurred by BIS need to be taken into account and the costs need
board size and non-executive directors. These two variables could to be offset from the revenue generated by the BIS premium
capture informal human capital elements and aspects of social income (2% of the outstanding balance paid quarterly.). Adminis-
capital. Again the association with employment change was of tration costs are estimated to be around £1 million, whilst the
greater relative magnitude than was the case for sales change. premium income is £7.8 million. This suggests the net costs of
The exporting propensity model has a richer set of associations SFLG to BIS are £35 million (US$53 million) over the first 2 years
between firm, entrepreneur and ownership characteristics than of the programme of loans taken out in 2006 Table 3).
was the case for sales and employment change. However, we also These costs can be considered as interim as they relate to the
find that SFLG firms, in general, had a significantly higher first 1.5–2.5 years of the duration of the SFLG loan received in
probability ( þ8.8%) of exporting. Firms with limited liability 2006. SFLG loans can last up to 10 years with the mean average
had a 13.7% higher probability of exporting, whilst service sector loan being 8 years and median loan term 6 years. Therefore, the
and construction firms had a 17.3% and 13.7% lower probability costs that are estimated are not the entire costs. In practice, this
(than manufacturing firms). Entrepreneurs who were previously disadvantages the benefits from the scheme as defaults are likely
unemployed were 11.6% less likely to be exporters, but those with to peak in the first 2 years of the programme but benefits are
a financial qualification were 11.7% more likely to be exporters. In likely to continue going forward.
terms of ownership characteristics, firms with non-executive
directors had a 5.7% higher probability of being exporters. In 5.2. Cost–benefit analysis
general, these findings are consistent with human capital based
factors (both formal and informal measures) being important to The benefits of SFLG to recipient firms relate to (1) net jobs
internationalisation captured here by exporting propensity. created, (2) net increase in sales (and GVA), (3) net gains in
We began our empirical analysis by seeking to establish how productivity, and (4) net increase in export earnings. The full costs
many SFLG loans default and what drives this default rate. We of the government providing this form of support relate to
then sought to provide evidence to support or refute the question administration and cost of defaults. Table 4 provides a summary
of whether SFLG backed firms perform better or worse than of the main findings.
otherwise similar firms on objective criteria. On our first research However, the economic benefits are likely to be an under-
question we have established that (a) default rates are high, and estimate of the full benefits because: (1) the evaluation only
(b) we can identify specific types of firms that are more likely to considers the benefits and costs over the first 2 years since
default. We have broadly established that SFLG backed firms have businesses received an SFLG loan. Costs are likely to peak in year
recorded better performance, at the univariate and multivariate two but benefits are likely to be ongoing into the future; (2) only
level, across three alternative measures, employment, sales and conservative assumptions are used, for instance median rather
exporting. We now consider our second research question, which than mean average effects, and programme costs reflect net cost
asks whether or not this firm level performance translates into to BIS rather than net cost to government. Revenue flow backs to
value-for-money for the UK economy given the costs. This is the Exchequer attributed to additional jobs created are substan-
addressed by a formal cost-benefit analysis in the next section. tial and are estimated at around £7 million per annum; (3) any
benefits from businesses that defaulted within the first 2 years
are ignored; (4) wider benefits such as the positive externalities
5. Cost–benefits analysis of SFLG arising from using cutting-edge technology are not quantified;

In this section we explore the value-for-money proposition Table 3


posed by SFLG, specifically whether the overall benefit from the Summary table of net SFLG costs to Exchequer
scheme outweighs the costs of default. We begin this section by (financial figures in parentheses indicate a cost to
calculating the costs for the scheme, and then perform cost– government).
benefit analysis using a number of variables.
Item £

5.1. Costs of SFLG Cost of called in guarantees (41,799,000)


Administration costs (1, 000,000)
Premium income 7,772,000
The main cost to Government of SFLG is meeting the cost of
Net SFLG costs (35,027,000)
loan defaults. The 2007/2008 SFLG annual report showed the total
amount paid out by the Government on demands from SFLG loan Source: BIS Management Data.
272 M. Cowling, J. Siepel / Technovation 33 (2013) 265–275

Table 4
Economic cost and benefits.

Item Estimated unit Benefits per £1 incurred


and cost per job created

Costs
Net Exchequer cost of default and scheme administration adjusted £35,027,400
for premium income
Benefits
Net jobs created (excluding entrepreneur) 3550–6340 £5560–£9933 per job
Net additional sales £74,812,000–£149,625,000 £2.12–£4.14
Net additional gross value added multiplier (0.329) £24,613,000–£49,103,000 £0.70–£1.40
Net additional labour productivity £10,958,000–£21,917,000 £0.32–£0.62
Net exporting (per annum) £32,695,000 £0.93
gross economic benefit £36,779,000 £1.05
Net economic benefit (based on the midpoint of £1.05 for net additional £1.75 million £1.05
GVA multiplied by the net exchequer cost of SFLG adjusted for this net
exchequer cost) equivalent to a net return of þ 5%

Table 5 trading immediately, all of their sales would be taken up by a UK


Employment change. based company within 1 year) and their activities are not
displacing other businesses, which leaves benefits accruing on a
Variable Mean per Median per
business business total of 1268 businesses.

Total employment change per additional þ 7.1 4.0


non-displacing business 5.2.2. Net jobs created
Per cent attributed to SFLG: The mean and median change in the number of jobs between
60 4.3 2.4 2006 and 2008 was estimated for additional businesses (i.e.
70 5.0 2.8
finance additional and non-displacing businesses). The mean
80 5.7 3.2
Annualised at midpoints 2.5 1.4 average employment change is 7.1 (full-time equivalent jobs),
whilst the median employment change is 4.0 (full-time equiva-
lent jobs) per SFLG supported business over the 2 year period.
However, not all the job creation can be attributed to the SFLG
and (5) the evaluation relates to a time when the ‘‘5 year rule’’
loan. To adjust for this the survey asked businesses to indicate the
was in operation which restricted SFLG to businesses aged less
relative contribution they felt that their SFLG loan made to their
than 5 years old. Younger businesses have a higher probability to
performance change over the period. The relative contribution
default than older businesses, leading to higher scheme costs. The
was found to be in the bounded category of 60–80%. The net
5-year rule was reversed by the 2008 Enterprise Strategy.
contribution is calculated at the lower bound, midpoint, and
It is also important to note that this evaluation relies on
upper bound of the relative contribution band Table 5).
business owners’ self-reported outcomes and assessment of the
From the employment change table, the net contribution to
scheme’s impact rather than using administrative measurements
employment growth between 2006 and 2008 of SFLG backed
of business performance. It is acknowledged that business owners
loans can be estimated and is within the bounds of 2.80 and 5.00
may not be able to give a completely accurate assessment, but this
(full-time equivalent) jobs. This figure can then be multiplied by
issue is common in all business support evaluations and careful
the 1268 businesses in the total SFLG portfolio for 2006 which are
questionnaire design attempts to minimise this. Further, the key
finance additional and non-displacing. This gives an estimate of
survey data for employment and sales was cross-references against
between 3550 and 6340 extra jobs (or 1775–3170 extra jobs per
official Company House Annual Reporting data and the raw
annum).
correlation was 0.92. The default data is derived from official
To provide some context, the last full SFLG evaluation (KPMG,
sources and represents a call by a lending bank on the UK Treasury.
1999) estimated mean additional employment as falling within a
range of 0.3 (assuming very high displacement) to 2.4 (assuming
no displacement). Other employment growth studies have
5.2.1. Economic additionality methodology
reported annualised jobs created per business ranging from 0.64
It is important to acknowledge that the economic evaluation
in deprived areas to 7.0 in instrument electronics, although the
assesses the effectiveness of the scheme by assessing the addi-
typical value lies between 1.15 and 2.75 (see Westhead and
tional benefits that would not have occurred in the absence of the
Cowling (1995) for a review of early studies and Meager et al.
programme and off sets them against the gross costs of running
(2003), for a more recent review). This might suggest that SFLG is
the scheme. In actual numbers, of the 3102 SFLG supported loans
attracting more growth-orientated businesses.
made in 2006, 26% (810) defaulted within 2 years of issue. This
leaves a ‘live’ business total of 2292 businesses. Of these busi-
nesses only 55% are finance additional. (Not all SFLG supported 5.2.3. Net sales change
businesses could be categorised as finance additional as some Median sales change (in finance additional and non-displacing
indicated that other alternative sources of funding were available businesses) over the 2 years is estimated at £295,000 per SFLG
to them at the point at which they accessed their SFLG loan. The supported business, but not all this sales growth can be attributed
actual proportion of non-finance additional SFLG borrowers was to the SFLG loan. In this case the relative contribution was found
16.5% and so these businesses are excluded from the benefit side to be in the bounded class of 20–40%. Three figures are presented
of the calculations. The estimates also excluded cases of market using 20% for the lower boundary, 30% as the midpoint and 40%
displacement if SFLG businesses indicated that if they ceased contribution for the upper boundary.
M. Cowling, J. Siepel / Technovation 33 (2013) 265–275 273

Table 6
Table 8
Sales change.
Labour productivity change.
Variable Median per
Variable Median per business
business

Total labour productivity change per additional £43,211


Total sales change per additional þ non-displacing £295,000
þ non-displacing business
business
Per cent attributed to SFLG:
Per cent attributed to SFLG:
20% £8642
20% £59,000
30% £12,963
30% £88,000
40% £17,285
40% £118,000
Annualised at midpoints £6482
Annualised at midpoints £44,000

Table 7 The net contribution to labour productivity growth between


GVA change. 2006 and 2008 of SFLG backed loans is estimated to be within the
bounds of £8642 and £17,285 per additional business. This figure
Net additional sales £74,812,000–£149,625,000
Net additional gross value added multiplier £24,613,000–£49,103,000 can then be multiplied by the 1268 finance additional and non
(0.329) displacing businesses in the SFLG portfolio for 2006, which gives a
bounded estimate of between £10,958,000 and £21,917,000 extra
labour productivity (or £5,479,000 to £10,958,000 extra labour
productivity per annum). This general productivity enhancing
effect of financial capital is consistent with earlier, UK based,
From the sales change table, the net contribution to sales empirical work on small business production functions (see
growth between 2006 and 2008 of SFLG backed loans is estimated Cowling and Mitchell, 2003) which showed that the majority of
to be within the bounds of £59,000 and £118,000 per business. small businesses need to grow to become more efficient Table 8).
This can be multiplied by the number of businesses that are
financial additional and non-displacing (1268). This gives an
estimate of between £74,812,000 and £149,624,800 extra sales 6. Conclusion
for SFLG over 2 years from loans taken out in 2006 (or
£37,406,000–£74,624,800 extra sales per annum). Two of Bruce Kirchhoff’s major contributions were to
To provide context, the previous evaluation (KPMG, 1999) (a) justify and quantify the important contribution of smaller
generated an additional sales estimate of between £16,900 and and younger firms to job creation and general economic devel-
£29,500 per business, less than the annualised estimate of opment, and (b) argue that government had a key role in
£44,000 reported in Table 6. maximising the potential of entrepreneurial activity. In the light
of this, most developed and developing countries have some form
of loan guarantee scheme to support private sector commercial
5.2.4. Gross value added (GVA)
lending to smaller entrepreneurial businesses. The underlying
From the sales change table, it is also possible to derive and
rationale for providing such schemes is to promote and support
estimate GVA (GVA represents the incomes generated by eco-
economic development through maximising the potential of the
nomic activity and comprises: (a) compensation of employees
entrepreneurial sector of the economy. In itself this is surprising
(wages and salaries, national insurance contributions, pension
given that commercial credit markets are often perceived to be
contributions, redundancy payments etc); (b) gross operating
the most efficient form of capitalist market. Implicitly, bankers
surplus (self-employment income, gross trading profits of part-
are often assumed to be efficient processors of business informa-
nerships and corporations, gross trading surplus of public cor-
tion and it follows that loans only flow to entrepreneurs with
porations, rental income, etc).) based on ratios drawn from the
viable business propositions. In reality, as we can observe in the
Annual Business Inquiry which are disaggregated by size class of
current financial crisis and in previous crises, this is not always
business. (Although it is possible to estimate GVA directly by
true. But even if it were, there is still a case to be made for public
asking businesses about wage costs and profits, this evaluation
sector intervention if the wider economic (and sometimes social)
used a simpler approach by deriving it from reported sales
benefits outweigh the net costs of an intervention. And, impor-
turnover. This is consistent with other evaluations in this area.
tantly, a government’s objective function can differ from the
It is not known which approach may be more accurate.) The
bank’s narrower objective function, and this can create a ‘gap’ in
relevant ratio (of GVA to sales turnover) is estimated at 0.329 for
the lending market. The UK SFLG is one such example of a public
SMEs, and the bounded additional sales figures are adjusted
sector intervention in the commercial loan market to address this
accordingly.
gap. It then becomes an empirical question whether or not we can
justify this intervention on the basis that the net benefits to the
5.2.5. Net gains in productivity UK as a whole outweigh the costs of intervention. Our paper
The median change in labour productivity between 2006 and examines this question in detail.
2008 (in finance additional and non-displacing businesses) is We find evidence that loan guarantee schemes, if designed
£43,211 per SFLG supported business. Again not all performance well, can have considerable positive impact on firm performance
changes can be attributed to the SFLG loan but as labour and the broader economy. Even with conservative assumptions,
productivity is a derived variable, this information was not SFLG is found to have a net benefit to the economy over the first
generated from the evaluation survey. In this case the relative 2 years of businesses receiving an SFLG loan. There will be
contribution for sales change, which was found to be in the additional benefits lasting beyond the initial 2 year time period,
bounded class of 20–40% was used. So of the total labour and consequently this assessment underestimates the potential
productivity change per business, only 20–40% was attributed to benefits from the scheme. We are led to conclude that the UK
the SFLG Table 7). SFLG is well targeted, with more than three-quarters (76%) of
274 M. Cowling, J. Siepel / Technovation 33 (2013) 265–275

SFLG supported loans being finance additional in the sense that Ackowledgements
these businesses could not have accessed conventional bank loans.
Aggregated to the whole SFLG population, this would imply that This paper is based on work that was originally funded by the
around 2400 additional small businesses got loans in 2006 than UK Department of Business Innovation and Skills (2010). The
they would have in the absence of the scheme. In the absence of authors are grateful to James Phipps and Daniel van der Schans,
SFLG, this would have resulted in around half of their intended UK Department for Business Innovation and Skills, the Editor of
investment projects not proceeding, and significant numbers this journal, and the referres for insight and comments. The usual
being scaled down or delayed. This suggests that SFLG has disclaimers apply.
removed the credit constraint from previously constrained busi-
nesses, levelling the playing field and allowing them to compete
References
and perform as well as (or superior to, in terms of introducing new
technologies) unconstrained businesses. Furthermore, we find that
Aaboen, L., Lindelöf, P., von Koch, C., Löfsten, H., 2006. Corporate governance and
SFLG businesses are more likely to be looking to grow, suggesting
performance of small high-tech firms in Sweden. Technovation 26 (8),
that further benefits may accrue in the future. 955–968.
However, the provision of SFLG has costs associated with it, in Astebro, T., Bernhardt, E., 2003. The winners curse of human capital. Small
particular the cost of loan defaults covered by the Government Business Economics 24, 1–16.
Beck, T., Demirguc-Kunt, A., 2006. SMEs: access to finance as a growth constraint.
guarantee. These are substantial (£35 million over the first 2 years Journal of Banking and Finance 30, 2931–2943.
of the programme of loans taken out in 2006). To quantify Berger, A., Udell, G., 1992. Some evidence on the empirical significance of credit
whether the economic benefits outweigh the costs of the scheme rationing. Journal of Political Economy 100 (5), 1047–1077.
Bester, H., 1985. Screening vs rationing in credit markets with imperfect informa-
a detailed cost–benefit analysis was conducted. The evidence tion. American Economic Review 75 (4), 850–855.
presented using this approach suggests that SFLG supported Birch, D., 1979. The Job Generation Process. MIT Program on Neighborhood and
businesses generate substantial levels of additional sales and jobs Regional Change, Cambridge, MA.
Bitler, M., Robb, A., Wolken, J., 2001. Financial services used by small businesses:
compared to what would have happened in the absence of the evidence from the 1998 survey of small business finances. Federal Reserve
programme. Bulletin, 183–204.
Central estimates suggest that for every £1 spent on SFLG the Carpenter, R., Peterson, B., 2002. Is the growth of small firms constrained by
internal finance? Review of Economics and Statistics 84 (2), 298–309.
additional sales attributable directly to SFLG would be around £3.13
Colombo, M., Grilli, L., 2007. Funding gaps? Access to bank loans by high-tech
(totalling £112 million), of which £1.05 would be gross value added start-ups. Small Business Economics 29, 25–46.
(totalling £37 million). This is positive suggesting there is an overall Cornelius, B., Persson, O., 2006. Who’s who in venture capital research. Technova-
tion 26 (2), 142–150.
benefit to the economy of operating the SFLG scheme.
Cowling, M., 1997. Small Business Loan Requests: Who Gets the Cash? SME Centre
The directly attributable increase in net employment is around Working Paper, No. 53. Warwick Business School, England.
2292 at a cost of £7750 per job. Although the costs to BIS of Cowling, M., 1999a. The determination of bank-small business loan premia.
running SFLG over the first 2 years are estimated to be £35 mil- Applied Economics Letters 6 (4), 291–293.
Cowling, M., 2007a. The Role of Loan Commitments in Credit Allocation. IES
lion, taking into account revenue flow back from additional Working Paper, No.11. Institute for Employment Studies, University of Sussex.
taxation, the net cost to government of running the scheme is Cowling, M., 2007b. The Role of Loan Guarantee Schemes in Alleviating Credit
£23 million. Rationing in the UK. Institute for Employment Studies Working Paper WP 7.
Cowling, M., 2008. An Empirical Test of the Significance of Credit Rationing on the
Ultimately our findings mirror Bruce Kirchhoff’s contributions UK Small Firms Loan Guarantee Scheme. Session IV. Partial Credit Guarantees:
by presenting the important role that government can play in Experiences and Lessons. World Bank, Financial & Private Sector Development,
small firm growth. Our evidence from SFLG suggest that the Washington DC.
Cowling, M., 2010. The role of loan guarantee schemes in alleviating credit
scheme is successfully targeted at smaller businesses who, on the rationing in the UK. Journal of Financial Stability 6 (1), 36–44.
whole, have viable lending propositions and who could not access Cowling, M., Clay, N., 1995. An analysis of factors influencing take-up rates on the
conventional bank loans due to problems of collateral and, to a loan guarantee scheme. Small Business Economics 7 (2), 141–152.
Cowling, M., Mitchell, P., 2003. Is the small firms loan guarantee scheme
lesser degree, track record. This suggests that loan guarantee hazardous for banks or helpful to small business? Small Business Economics
programmes represent viable options that promote access to debt 21, 63–72.
finance to constrained smaller businesses. Craig, B., Jackson III, W., Thomson, J., 2005. SBA Loan Guarantees and Local
Economic Growth. Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland Working Paper, 05–03.
The specific lessons that may be learnt from this analysis
Craig, B., Jackson III, W., Thomson, J., 2006. Small Firm Credit Market Discrimina-
depend on the policy objectives. If the government’s primary tion, SBA Guaranteed Lending, and Local Market Economic Performance.
objective was reducing the default rate (the main element of Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland Working Paper, 06–13.
scheme cost) then excluding firms who are using loan for cash- Craig, B., Jackson III, W., Thomson, J., 2007a. Small firm credit market discrimina-
tion, SBA guaranteed lending, and local market economic performance. Annals
flow and working capital purposes would have a large and of the American Association of Political and Social Science 613, 73–94.
beneficial effect as firms that are using loans to invest in tangible Craig, B., Jackson III, W., Thomson, J., 2007b. Small firm finance, credit rationing,
productive assets have a much lower default rate, and a greater and the impact of SBA guaranteed lending on local economic growth. Journal
of Small Business Management 45 (1), 116–132.
potential to generate long-term benefits to productivity and Cressy, R., 1996. Are business start-ups debt rationed? Economic Journal 106,
positive economic multipliers down the supply-chain and in 1253–1270.
capital goods manufacturers. They would equally have more Devinney, T., 1986. Rationing in the Theory of the Banking Firm. Springer-Verlag,
Berlin.
assets to secure against future loans. If the government’s main De Meza, D., 2002. Overlending? Economic Journal 112 (477), F17–F31.
objective is job creation then directing SFLG towards the smallest Fraser, S., 2009. Is there ethnic discrimination in the UK market for small business
firms is the best option. But if the over-riding policy objective is credit? International Small Business Journal 27 (5, October), 583–607.
Freel, M., 1999. The financing of small firm product innovation within the UK.
directed at growth and balance of payments through exporting, Technovation 19, 707–719.
then the scheme should be explicitly targeted at larger SMEs. In Gelos, G., Werner, A., 2002. Financial liberalization, credit constraints and
the current environment with a general fall in asset prices, loan collateral: investment in the Mexican manufacturing sector. Journal of Devel-
opment Economics 67 (1), 1–27.
guarantee schemes are likely to become a more important
Ghosh, P., Mookherjee, D., Ray, D., 2000. Credit rationing in developing countries.
component of general bank lending to smaller firms. The more In: Mookherjee, D., Ray, D. (Eds.), A Reader in Development Economics.
wide ranging conclusion is that the scheme in general creates Blackwell, London.
positive economic effects, but with more fine-tuning it can be Graham, T., 2004. Graham Review of the Small Firms Loan Guarantee – Final
Report. HM Treasury, London.
adjusted to deliver different policy objectives as the government’s Green, A., 2003. Credit Guarantee Schemes for Small Enterprises: An Effective
objectives change in response to different economic conditions. Instrument to Promote Private Sector Led Growth? SME Technical Working
M. Cowling, J. Siepel / Technovation 33 (2013) 265–275 275

Paper No.10. UNIDO. Vienna /http://www.unido.org/file-storage/download/ Myers, S., Majluf, N., 1984. Corporate financing and investment decisions when
?file_id=18223S. firms have information that investors do not have. Journal of Financial
Gregory, B., Rutherford, M., Oswald, S., Gardiner, L., 2005. An empirical investiga- Economics 13 (2), 187–221.
tion of the growth cycle theory of small business financing. Journal of Small Peneder, M., 2008. The problem of private under-investment in innovation:
Business Management 43 (4), 382–392. A policy mind map. Technovation 28 (8), 518–530.
Headd, B., Kirchhoff, B., 2007. Small Business Growth: Searching for Stylized Facts. Phillips, B., Kirchhoff, B., 1989. Formation, growth and survival; Small firm
US Small Business Administration, Office of Advocacy. dynamics in the US economy. Small Business Economics 1, 65–74.
Honaghan, P., 2008. Partial credit guarantees: Principles and practice. Session I. Puri, M. Zarutskie, R., 2008. On the Lifecycle Dynamics of Venture Capital- and
Partial Credit Guarantees: experiences and lessons. World Bank, Financial & Nonventure Capital-Financed Firms. NBER Working Paper 14250.
Private Sector Development. Washington DC. Riding, A., 1998. On the Care and Nurture of Loan Guarantee Programmes. Carleton
Hyytinen, A., Pajarinen, M., 2007. Is the cost of debt capital higher for younger University, Canada.
firms? Scottish Journal of Political Economy 54 (1), 55–71. Riding, A., Haines, G., 2001. Loan guarantees: cost of default and benefits to small
Kirchhoff, B., 1994. Entrepreneurship and Dynamic Capitalism: The Economics of firms. Journal of Business Venturing 16 (2), 595–612.
Riding, A., Madill, J., Haines, G., 2007. Incrementality of SME loan guarantees. Small
Business Firm Formation and Growth. Praeger, Westport, CT.
Business Economics 29, 47–61.
Kirchhoff, B., 1996. Self-employment and dynamic capitalism. Journal of Labor
Saemundsson, R., 2005. On the interaction between the growth process and the
Research 17 (4), 627–644.
development of technical knowledge in young and growing technology-based
Kirchhoff, B., Phillips, B., 1988. The effect of firm creation and growth on
firms. Technovation 25 (3), 223–235.
job creation in the United States. Journal of Business Venturing 3 (4),
Stiglitz, J., Weiss, A., 1981. Credit rationing in markets with imperfect information.
261–272. American Economic Review 71 (3), 393–410.
Klapper, L., Laeven, L., Rajan, R., 2006. Barriers to entrepreneurship. Journal of Wang, C., Lu, I., Chen, C., 2008. Evaluating firm technological innovation capability
Financial Economics 82 (3), 591–629. under uncertainty. Technovation 28 (6), 349–363.
Laeven, L., 2003. Does financial liberalisation reduce financing constraints? Westhead, P., Cowling, M., 1995. Employment change in independent owner-
Financial Management 32 (1), 5–34. managed high-technology firms in Great Britain. Small Business Economics 7,
Love, I., 2003. Financial development and financing constraints: international 111–140.
evidence from the structural investment model. Review of Financial Studies 16 Westhead, P., Storey, D., 1997. Financial constraints on the growth of high
(3), 765–791. technology small firms in the United Kingdom. Applied Financial Economics
Meager, N., Bates, P., Cowling, M., 2003. An evaluation of business start-up support 7 (2), 197–201.
for young people. National Institute Economic Review 186 (4), 59–72. Wonglimpiyarat, J., 2006. The dynamic economic engine at Silicon Valley and US
Melnik, A., Plaut, S., 1986. Loan commitment contracts, terms of lending, and government programs in financing innovations. Technovation 26 (September),
credit allocation. The Journal of Finance 45, 1069–1087. 1081–1089.

You might also like