Policymakers and Providers: Compacts, Management, and The "Long Route" of Accountability

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 16

13_WDR_Ch06.

qxd 8/14/03 9:07 AM Page 95

Policymakers and providers

6
Educated children. Good health. Clean, reli- be clear and backed with sufficient resources
able, and convenient water. Safe neighbor- for adequate and regular compensation.
chapter hoods. Lighted homes. That is what citi-
zens, poor and rich, want from services. If
Good information on the actions of
providers and the outcomes of those actions
policymakers take responsibility for deliver- must get to the policymaker. And remunera-
ing services, they must also care about these tion must be tied as closely to these outcomes
outcomes and be sure that services as possible. Accountability is improved by:
providers care about them, too. Chapter 5
discussed the first challenge: inducing poli- • Clarifying responsibilities—by separat-
cymakers to reflect the interests of poor ing the role of policymaker, accountable
people. This chapter takes up the second: to poor citizens, from that of provider
inducing providers to achieve the outcomes organizations, accountable to policy-
of interest to poor people. How? By choos- makers.
ing appropriate providers. By aligning • Choosing the appropriate provider—
incentives with those outcomes. And by civil servants, autonomous public agen-
ensuring that policymakers do at least as cies, NGOs, or private contractors. Com-
well as the clients themselves in creating petition can often help in this choice.
those incentives. • Providing good information—an essen-
tial step. Just monitoring the performance
Compacts, management, and the of contracts requires more and better
“long route” of accountability measures. Keeping an eye on the prize of
The “compact” introduced in chapter 3 is better outcomes also requires more regu-
composed of relationships of accountability lar measurement. It also requires finding
necessary for increasing the power of incen- out what works by rigorously evaluating
tives for good performance (figure 6.1). programs and their effects.
Instructions to provider organizations must
These steps are neither easy nor straight-
Figure 6.1 Compact and management in the service delivery framework forward. Political pressures often make it
impossible for policymakers to claim inde-
The state pendence from the performance of service
Politicians Policymakers providers. Compacts for the kind of services
discussed here cannot be complete or have
of accounta
ro u te bili
Com
perfectly measured outcomes. Finding
ng ty pa
Lo c
enough staff, regardless of their precise
t

employment agreements, is a real challenge


S h o rt r o u t e
Providers for many developing countries because of
international migration and, for Sub-Saharan
Management
Africa, HIV/AIDS. And finding out what
Frontline Organizations works—determining the link between poli-
cies and inputs and outcomes—is difficult,
not just for technical reasons. Governments,
Services
donors, and provider organizations fre-
95
13_WDR_Ch06.qxd 8/14/03 9:07 AM Page 96

96 WORLD DEVELOPMENT REPORT 2004

quently don’t want to know—or don’t want private goods. Private providers may be con-
to take the risk of finding out—what does- tracted by the public sector for services to
n’t work.281 poor people or for true public goods (where a
It may be difficult to measure the out- private sector is impossible, even in princi-
comes of health, education, and infrastruc- ple). But they cannot be relied on to provide
ture services, but it is possible. Improve- them on their own. That is why the public
ments cannot be measured as precisely as sector should assume responsibility for basic
tons of steel. But the outcomes of these ser- services, especially for poor people.
vices are far more amenable to measurement The public sector has its problems, too.
than many core functions of government. Chapter 5 asked whether, in fulfilling this
Mortality rates, literacy rates, and the purity responsibility, policymakers have the incen-
of water are observable in ways that “advanc- tive to “do the right thing.” The answer is
ing the international interests of the nation,” often “no.” But even if policies are properly
the goal of a foreign ministry for example, designed, it is difficult to get personnel to
are not.282 And technical knowledge for staff facilities in poor or remote areas.
rigorous evaluation of programs to reach Vacancy rates for doctors in Indonesia range
the poor is certainly available. from near zero in Bali to as high as 60 percent
A word on “compacts” versus “manage- in West Papua (formerly Irian Jaya), the
ment.” The focus of this chapter is the com- province farthest from Java (box 6.1).
pact between the policymaker and the The difficulty in staffing such places varies
provider organizations, not the details of the by job. It is greatest for the most highly edu-
management of frontline providers by a cated people with the best alternative
provider organization. Appropriate manage- employment prospects. Educated people in
ment needs to be tailored to local circum- countries with few such people are almost
stances. Focusing on the details of manage- always urban born and bred. In Niger 43 per-
ment detracts from the more crucial cent of the parents of nurses and midwives
relationship of the compact and indulges the were civil servants, and 70 percent of them
tendency to micromanage. Here the empha-
sis is on the principles for designing incen-
tives. But management cannot be ignored BOX 6.1 A good doctor is hard
entirely. Much of the (very thin) literature on
to find
what works and what doesn’t—on provider
responses to changes in incentives—deals Public health centers in desirable locations
with management reforms, so these experi- have modest vacancy rates, as low as 1.2 per-
cent in Bali and near 5 percent in most of the
ences must form the limited empirical base.
provinces in the population centers of Java and
Sumatra. For such remote areas as West Papua
Misaligned incentives the vacancy rate reaches 60 percent, and for
and service failures central Kalimantan more than 40 percent.
Failures to reach poor people with effective Percentage of health centers without
services can usually be attributed to a mis- doctors, by province, Indonesia 1992
alignment between the incentives facing 60
providers and outcomes. A private market Remote provinces
left to itself cannot provide appropriate ser-
vices to poor people. It will tend to serve 40 Poorer
clients who possess the purchasing power for provinces

a fairly narrow set of services. Modern, pri-


20
vate medical care by skilled professionals and
private education are largely used by the bet-
ter off. Water is an exception, with substantial 0
middle-class capture of public water, leaving Bali West
Papua
poor people to buy from expensive private
sellers. The range of services the private sec- Source: World Bank (1994b).
tor will provide on its own is limited to, well,
13_WDR_Ch06.qxd 8/14/03 9:08 AM Page 97

Policymakers and providers 97

had been raised in the city.283 It is only nat- for poor people. The lack of conscientious-
ural for them to want the same for their chil- ness, the mistreatment of students and
dren. And it is naïve to simply say “pay them patients, and the loss of skills with time
more.” Doctors in Indonesia would require (chapter 1)—all can be attributed to a com-
multiples of current pay levels to live in West bination of the failure of incentives and a
Papua.284 And giving providers too much dis- service ethos. Salaried workers with no
cretion over where they serve may hurt the opportunity to advance and no fear of pun-
poor, as in rural schools in Zambia (box 6.2). ishment have little incentive to perform well.
Even when people accept jobs in poor Chapter 4 argued that discourtesy depended
areas, their absenteeism is often astonishing on incentives, not training. If income does
(see tables 1.2 and 1.3 in chapter 1). The rea- not come from clients, the policymaker must
sons vary, but alternative earning opportu- hold providers accountable, particularly in
nities are a major one for professions with monitoring and rewarding good behavior.
easily marketable skills.285 This applies to Corruption—unauthorized private gain
doctors and other medical personnel and to from public resources—is common in many
teachers offering independent tutoring. services and also attributable to competing
Again, the day-to-day imperatives for people incentives. In Eastern Europe under-the-table
to make a living run counter to increasing payments to public servants and general cor-
services to poor people. This is particularly ruption undermine the legitimacy of all gov-
true where civil service pay is much less ernment services. They are particularly costly
than private sector pay for the same skills. to poor people (box 6.3). Pharmaceutical
Even when people are on the job, their mismanagement is everywhere: thefts from
performance can compromise the outcomes public stores supply much of the private mar-
ket in Côte d’Ivoire, India, Jordan, Thailand,
and Zambia. Corruption responds to mone-
tary incentives, but it also requires a lack of
BOX 6.2 Provider discretion
information on hidden activities and an
can hurt the poor inability to impose sanctions. As Captain
Shotover in George Bernard Shaw’s Heart-
Funding of rural primary schools in Zambia break House put it,“Give me deeper darkness.
from different sources
Money is not made in the light.” Open infor-
Funding per student (kwacha, thousands) mation can reduce both the incidence of cor-
30 Discretionary
ruption and its corrosiveness.286
25
Community pressure can also subvert
20 the incentives to fulfill the primary respon-
15 Staff
sibilities of public providers. In many places
10 remuneration the public servant is a permanent member
According of the community, facing substantial social
5 to strict pressures to bend rules to the benefit of
0 rules
local preferences. Sometimes this is good—
Poorest 2 3 4 Richest
it shows the flexibility to respond to local
Wealth by fifths
needs. But for some services, particularly
those with punitive characteristics, it can
Rural schools in Zambia obtain resources in
cash and in kind (personnel). Cash transfers compromise the core duties of the provider.
allocated by strict rules of per capita funding For example, forestry agents who are part of
are distinctly progressive. Rural areas give sig- a community may be reluctant to report
nificantly higher discretionary cash allocations
illegal logging by their neighbors.287 A form
to rich schools. Per-pupil teacher compensa-
tion increases with the wealth of children of community pressure particularly harm-
attending the school, reflecting higher staffing ful to the poor is the capture of services by
ratios and the gravitation of senior staff to local elites. In Northern Ghana young, inex-
richer areas.
perienced, and poorly paid facilitators for
Source: Das and others (2003). participatory projects found such pressure a
major impediment.288
13_WDR_Ch06.qxd 8/14/03 9:08 AM Page 98

98 WORLD DEVELOPMENT REPORT 2004

BOX 6.3 Bribery hurts the poor


To gain access to health, education, and the justice system in Kazakhstan, poor people pay bribes simply to
receive services they are entitled to (and to avoid “problems” getting them) while richer people pay to speed
up service.
In Romania, the poor pay substantially higher fractions of income in bribes.

Kazakhstan: reasons for paying bribes Romania: Percent of income paid in bribes
to health, education, and justice systems (of those paying bribes)
Percent responses per income group Percent
140 12
Other
120 10
To avoid
100 problems
8
To receive
80 benefits
6
60 Speed
4
40

20 2

0 0
Poorest Middle Richest Poorest Middle Richest
third third third third third third
Note: Numbers add to more than 100 percent due to multiple responses.

Source: Anderson, Kaufmann, and Recanatini (2003).

Many, and usually most, providers in the for delivering services. In many cases, the pol-
public sector are dedicated people whose icymaker is the legislature or a central min-
interests are largely compatible with the pub- istry, the provider organization a line min-
lic good. But their own needs of looking after istry. So many of the activities of the head of
a family, ensuring their well being, having the “provider organization” will look like pol-
friendly relations with neighbors—all pre- icymaking. But these are “internal policies” of
vent them from providing sufficient services the organization to achieve the overall goals
to benefit poor people. If the scale of opera- focused on here. (The literature on public
tions needs to be increased to reach the poor, management explicitly cautions against sepa-
even more incentives need to be changed at rating290 policymaking from implementa-
the margin, whether monetary or not.289 tion, but that literature is concerned with
management within the “provider organiza-
tion” and not the separation proposed here.)
Increasing accountability: Clear separation lends itself to much sim-
separating the policymaker pler and less ambiguous accountability for
from the provider the provider organization. When the policy-
The many incentives that providers face blur maker is the provider organization, day-to-
the focus on outcomes. Making a clear sepa- day pressures of management compromise
ration between the role of the policymaker attention to outcomes on the ground. Take
and the provider organization is essential for the desire to find and fix problems (see the
aligning the incentives for the provider with spotlight on Johannesburg). When the poli-
the final outcomes that policymakers want cymaker takes a separate role from the
for citizens. Who is the policymaker, and who provider, it is easier to say “I don’t care what
is the provider organization? The policy- your problem is, just tell me the vaccination
maker is the person directly accountable to rates. Or the test scores. Or crime rates.”
the citizenry, preferably the poorer citizenry. When roles are mixed, bureaucracies become
And the provider organization is responsible insular and tend to hide mistakes.
13_WDR_Ch06.qxd 8/14/03 9:09 AM Page 99

Policymakers and providers 99

Is this separation really necessary? Is it Multiple principals


achieved in rich countries? Education, for The instructions of the policymaker to
example, is frequently administered through providers are not the only ones that count.
central ministries, which employ all teachers Public servants have to serve many masters.
directly with little monitoring from central Education providers are under pressure
staff agencies (such as finance). Perhaps sepa- from parents of poor children (with the
ration is not necessary for successful services. policymaker representing them), parents of
But rich countries benefit from a long children other than the poor, teachers’
evolution of the relationships between the unions, potential employers, various groups
state and frontline providers. Almost all ser- in society that want (or don’t want) particu-
vices provided directly to individuals in the lar items on the curriculum, and others.
now-rich countries were originally provided Power and water providers are under pres-
privately. They were eventually absorbed or sure from different segments of the market
consolidated by a state institution that had to cross-subsidize them, from producers to
been separate from the existing provider buy specific types of equipment, from peo-
organizations. The state began as an indepen- ple who want more extensive connections,
dent outside monitor and regulator of private and from others who want more reliable,
activities. It largely retained that indepen- continuous operation. The day-to-day pres-
dence as a monitor after the same activities sure of local demand for health care can
became public (box 6.4). compromise efforts in disease prevention
For the developing world the desire for and other public health activities that are
rapid expansion of public financing and pro- not demand-driven.292 Whom is a provider
vision short-circuits this historical develop- to listen to?
ment. Both the monitoring and the provision
are taking place simultaneously. This is not
necessarily a bad thing—the poor might oth-
erwise have to wait much longer for services
to reach them. But it does show that the cur-
rent institutional features of rich countries
BOX 6.4 Learning to regulate
may not transfer directly to poor countries Although the state pays for health care in incorporating private schools into the pub-
without the establishment of a complemen- most Organisation for Economic Co-opera- lic network after a system of managing indi-
tary regulatory structure, a structure that may tion and Development (OECD) countries, vidual schools had already developed.
private practitioners still provide it (excep- Even the core networked services of
need to be established beforehand. Without tions on the finance side include the United water, electricity, gas, and railways—services
this structure progress may be slow—possi- States; exceptions on the provision side, the now thought of as natural monopolies—
bly slower than if a not-for-profit or private United Kingdom).The state carries out the began as purely private activities. In the
sector were allowed to develop and later insurance function in these countries but United Kingdom early water systems were
not the services. It is the insurance market sometimes developed with duplicate pipes
brought under the supervisory wing of the that is hampered by severe market failure. laid by competing firms. Only after cover-
government. In Germany, the current system is a consoli- age was substantial were these
Separating the policymaker from the dation, begun under Bismarck in 1883, of a rationalized—and then for reasons of pub-
system of guild-based insurance schemes. lic health rather than duplication. German
provider organization also helps to increase
For most OECD countries, the current railways also began with duplicate lines. In
the accountability of providers. But if the poli- system of public ownership or control other cases, companies worked out agree-
cymaker knows what services to deliver, why dates from a time after World War II when ments that divided markets without the
can’t providers just be given instructions—in a they had incomes at least as high as the duplication experienced in the railway mar-
upper-middle-income countries today. kets in the United States and England—for
contract—to do them? That is, why can’t out- Before these programs were brought under example, bus systems in many large urban
puts just be specified and paid for accordingly? public management, the state already had areas and German natural gas transport.
regulatory powers over the medical profes- These were then brought under a regula-
sion. The timing was fortuitous since it was tory regime but only after reaching quite
Limits to accountability only in the 20th century that technical high service penetration.
All public services face three problems that changes in medicine made public In each of these cases the independent
oversight essential. regulatory capacity of the policymaker pre-
make this solution impossible: providers
Universal public education is also fairly ceded the incorporation of private
face multiple principals, undertake multiple recent. It came out of a conflict between providers into a public system.
tasks, and produce outcomes that are hard church and state. In the period of expansion
to observe and hard to attribute to their of public facilities, the main mechanism was Source: Klein and Roger (1994).

actions.291
13_WDR_Ch06.qxd 8/14/03 9:09 AM Page 100

100 WORLD DEVELOPMENT REPORT 2004

Multiple tasks individual frontline providers depend on out-


Personnel in health clinics are supposed to comes. All contracts will necessarily be
provide curative care to people who come to incomplete, requiring at least some payment
them. They are also to provide immuniza- of wages independent of outputs. When the
tions, health education, and other preventive actions of the provider are specified in great
measures to everyone, whether they come in detail, the results are often less than optimal
on their own or not. And they are to keep because of inflexible response to local varia-
statistics, attend training sessions and meet- tion. The impossibility of specifying such
ings, and do inspections of water and food. rules ahead of time is illustrated by “work-to-
Police officers have to deal with everyone rule” strikes, in which strikers bring an activity
from lost children to dangerous criminals. to a “grinding halt” by following rules entirely
They are, at various times, investigators of to the letter (box 6.5). The balance between
crimes, social workers intervening in neigh- control and flexibility is not easily struck.
borhood and family disputes, and dissemi- Further, since the provider does many
nators of information. This diffusion natu- things, some or all of them hard to observe by
rally blunts the precision of incentives. the policymaker, there is the ever-present risk
that payments for measured outcomes will
Measuring and attributing displace hard-to-measure tasks (box 6.6).
outcomes This risk has been discussed in the education
literature as “teaching to the test.” When
The most difficult problems, particularly for
teacher compensation (pay or promotion
the social sectors, are the dual problems of
prospect) is measured by students’ perfor-
measuring outcomes and attributing these
mance on a standard test, there will be a ten-
outcomes to the actions of providers. Test
dency to downplay those aspects of pedagogy
scores may adequately reflect certain educa-
not covered by the test and to concentrate on
tional goals, but abstract thinking and social
those that are. In Kenya teachers manipulated
adaptability are not so easily measured. The
test scores by offering tutoring sessions aimed
alleviation of pain is a subjective judgment
specifically at these tests. There was no
of the patient. Many outcomes, even when
improvement in other indicators of quality,
observable to the patient and the doctor, are
such as homework assignments, teacher
not “contractible” in the sense that, if a dis-
absences, or teaching methods.293
pute arises, compliance can be proved to a
Several industrial countries, in reforming
judge or other mediator. And attributing
the civil service or other providers of public
impacts to provider actions is difficult in
services, have tried to use performance con-
almost all social services.
tracts. The evidence of success is mixed:294
These problems make it impossible to have
many problems are tied to the dependence of
performance contracts that make payments to
the policymaker on information the agency
provides—a problem closely related to the
regulation of private firms. Some informa-
BOX 6.5 Be careful what you wish for—part 1 tion used for performance contracts can be
“Anyone who has worked in a formal orga- press a point on the municipal authorities easily falsified or, less pejoratively, presented
nization—even a small one strictly about regulations or fees, they sometimes in too favorable a light. For example, when
governed by detailed rules—knows that launch a work-to-rule strike. It consists education reforms were instituted in the
handbooks and written guidelines fail merely in following meticulously all the reg-
utterly in explaining how the institution ulations in the Code routier and thereby
United Kingdom, truancies were redefined as
goes about its work. Accounting for its bringing traffic throughout central Paris to a excused absences.295
smooth operation are nearly endless and grinding halt.The drivers thus take tactical
shifting sets of implicit understandings, advantage of the fact that the circulation of
tacit coordinations, and practical mutuali- traffic is possible only because drivers have
Overcoming the limits
ties that could never be successfully mastered a set of practices that have Separating policymakers from provider orga-
captured in a written code.This ubiquitous evolved outside, and often in contravention, nizations can help sharpen incentives to help
social fact is useful to employees and labor of the formal rules.”
unions.The premise behind what are
poor people. Assigning policymakers the role
tellingly called work-to-rule strikes is a case of devising a compact for the provider orga-
in point. When Parisian taxi drivers want to Source: Scott (1998). nization and assigning provider organiza-
tions the responsibility of management can
13_WDR_Ch06.qxd 8/14/03 9:10 AM Page 101

Policymakers and providers 101

enable the use of higher-powered incentives


to align the interests of the frontline provider BOX 6.6 Be careful what you wish for—part 2
with those of the policymaker representing
The Sears Corporation lost a $48,000,000 most repeat business.That the intention of
the poor, for the following three reasons. class action suit in which its automobile the instruction was to encourage courteous
First, policymakers, balancing political pres- repair department was accused of deliber- behavior did not impress the court.
sures, can help insulate providers from the ately sabotaging customers’ vehicles.The
corporation was held responsible, having
problem of satisfying masters with conflict- Source: Sears Automotive Center Consumer
instructed its employees that bonuses Litigation, Action No. C-92-2227, U.S. District
ing aims and offer unambiguous instruc- would be paid to those branches with the Court, San Francisco.
tions. Second, provider organizations can
face performance-based payments when
individuals cannot. Third, managers of the
provider organizations, if they have flexibility Cuba). What can be considered measurable
over operational decisions, can supervise staff varies by the size of the organization—larger
and choose the appropriate form of remu- ones being easier to hold to account.
neration that best reflects local conditions. The problem of multiple tasks is partly a
problem of economies of scale as well. Some
Insulating providers from politics tasks can be divided into groups of comple-
That providers have to satisfy many masters mentary activities—all immunizations as a
reflects the inability of government to insu- group, say, or all health education activities
late them from political pressures. While pol- based on home visits (chapter 8). Then a
icymakers for education need to address fairly homogeneous organization can be
concerns of potential employers, teachers’ charged with the responsibility to carry out a
unions, or interest groups who want to influ- simpler set of tasks, with clear standards of
ence curricula, there is no reason why this accountability.
should affect day-to-day activities in a Reform in Johannesburg, South Africa
school, or indeed any organization of front- (see spotlight), was in large part a reevalua-
line providers. If the policymaking function tion of the appropriate set of services to be
can be separated from the provider organiza- grouped together to deliver specified outputs.
tion, the policymaker can handle the politics Departments were reorganized so that their
of the overall objectives of education while outputs were clearly identifiable and verifi-
the provider can be given more precise able, with the department’s CEO able to
instructions and be held accountable to the retain any savings over contract expenditures.
policymaker. Poor people might legitimately At one extreme, commercial enterprises—
delegate to policymakers curriculum devel- such as the athletics stadium, the airport, and
opment as well as the responsibility to bal- metro gas—were simply sold to the private
ance their interests with those of unions. sector and directly faced the forces of the
market, where payment is very much depen-
Organizations and individuals dent on outcomes.296
Individual providers will not accept perfor-
mance contracts that leave them exposed to Management flexibility
excessive risk. But the variability of aggregate Each of these potential effects depends on
performance over all providers in an organi- managers in provider organizations having the
zation—say, those dealing with infant mor- flexibility and authority to design the incen-
tality for a district—is very much smaller, tives for the frontline providers in their organi-
which provides a way of sharing the risk. zations. This allows them to adapt to local (or
While a single doctor may not be able to sectoral) variation to see whether performance
absorb the risk to income of the bad luck of pay or salaries with supervision works better.
any particular patient, a district health board Flexibility for the manager is essential, a major
would. Teams—schools, school districts, part of “institutional capacity.” Managers must
health boards, city police departments—can have control over the pay scheme or the sanc-
be the recipients of performance-based tions for poor performance.
incentives where teachers, nurses, and police- Salaried systems work as long as there is
men cannot (see spotlight on Costa Rica and the ability either to fire or to grant raises on
13_WDR_Ch06.qxd 8/14/03 9:10 AM Page 102

102 WORLD DEVELOPMENT REPORT 2004

the basis of merit. The worst case is when ments—for how many people sign up with
salaried workers face neither sanctions for the doctor. But it is supplemented by specific
poor performance nor increased pay or pres- additional payments for the provision of
tige for good performance. Civil servants in immunizations to counter any incentive to
Singapore enjoy high salaries and a lot of skimp on this priority service.
prestige, but also work under a credible threat
of being fired. A problem with some of the New providers for expanding supply
recent reforms in developed countries insti- Where will the providers of services come
tuting contractual relations with providers is from? One possibility is that competition for
that they undermine the public service ethos. compacts will attract more provider organi-
(“If I am to be treated as a mercenary, I might zations. The benefits from competition are
as well act like one.”) Increased accountability reduced costs, greater effort, and better
through monetary incentives was partly off- information—even when public provision is
set by reduced accountability through inter- the dominant form, as long as public and
nal motivation.297 Developing countries that other provider organizations are treated
have instilled this sense of duty should be even-handedly. Three types of competition
wary of compromising it. But they should be are relevant for services: competition in the
brutally honest with themselves before market, competition for the market, and
declaring this a major consideration. benchmarking.
Sometimes performance pay is appropri-
ate and necessary but should be a matter for Competition. Competition in the market
local experimentation. Several health inter- simply means allowing private providers. For
ventions have benefited greatly by introduc- health and education, such providers are
ing performance-based incentives for workers everywhere, and in many places larger play-
(box 6.7). In other contexts, those incentives ers than the government (chapter 4). Recent
are precisely what is needed to obtain particu- technological advances have made it possible
lar desired results. In the British National to open services formerly believed to be nat-
Health Service most general practitioner pay ural monopolies to competition. Indepen-
is determined on the basis of capitation pay- dent power producers, for example, can be
used to sell electricity to a larger grid. The
cost of allowing free entry into natural
BOX 6.7 Incentive pay works for specific health monopolies is the risk of inefficient duplica-
interventions tion of investments. Efficient regulation is
necessary but complicated. If political and
The Bangladesh Rural Advancement Com- In Haiti, NGOs were given performance-
mittee (BRAC), one of the largest NGOs in based contracts, directly from the U.S. administrative limitations on the indepen-
Bangladesh, paid workers to teach mothers Agency for International Development, to dence and effectiveness of regulators are
how to use oral rehydration therapy for chil- provide preventive health care services severe, allowing the duplication may be the
dren with diarrhea. Independent of the such as immunizations, health education,
lesser of two evils.298
providers, bonuses were paid on the basis prenatal care, and family planning. Again, an
of surveys of random samples of 5–10 per- independent monitor, l’Institut Haitien de The impact of competition can go both
cent of the mothers.The greater the num- l’Enfance, a local survey research firm, was ways: the presence of the public sector can
ber of women who could explain how to used to verify performance. Immunization impose indirect discipline on the private sec-
make and use the rehydration solution, the rates increased dramatically along with sev-
higher the payment. More than half of total eral other outputs. Interestingly, some of the
tor, both on prices and on quality. In Malaysia
compensation was paid as a bonus. NGOs experimented with performance pay a credible public health system has kept price
The mothers’ knowledge increased dra- themselves but found lower morale and rises modest in the private sector.299 The ben-
matically—to 65 percent of those taught performance when workers (low paid them- efits of public provision extend beyond the
two years after the training. Most important, selves) faced such risky incomes.The NGOs,
the teaching techniques that the workers while satisfied with the high-powered
numbers of patients treated publicly. Simi-
used changed from standard lectures to incentives by which they were paid, found larly, the presence of qualified medical per-
more hands-on demonstrations. Rather better ways to pay frontline providers in sonnel can force quality improvements in
than have the right teaching technique accordance with local circumstances. private markets.300
specified for them from on high, workers
developed the best way to achieve the If natural monopolies exist, there can be
measured outcome—finding out for them- Sources: Chowdhury (2001) and Eichler, Auxilia, competition for the market. Potential com-
selves what worked in their context. and Pollock (2001). petitors bid for concessions—compacts—to
provide the service. Much government pro-
13_WDR_Ch06.qxd 8/14/03 9:11 AM Page 103

Policymakers and providers 103

curement in richer countries uses this model. is particularly important because there are
It requires the ability to let, monitor, and fewer “perks” for working in poor areas—pri-
enforce the explicit contracts for the winner. vate earnings after working hours (for med-
Recent innovations in the state of Madhya ical personnel and teachers) are lower, living
Pradesh in India allow NGOs to compete for conditions harsher.
concessions to primary schools. Payments are In the long run, a public sector with a strong
conditional on improved test scores based on ethos of public service will be needed. In many
independent measurement. One advantage places it already exists. It does no good to pre-
the developing world has over earlier experi- tend, however, that expanding the civil service
ence in Europe is that it has firms with good under current recruitment and incentive
reputations and experience in the supply of regimes will attract those best suited to serving
water, power, and transport—and interna- poor people. In Nepal an anthropological
tional courts for dispute resolution.301 But study showed that health staff’s view of their
the recent experience of Enron in India’s jobs often differed from the official view.302
Maharashtra State provides a reality check on Many staff saw the health program solely as a
over-enthusiasm for these benefits. source of employment. A broader set of poten-
Benchmark or yardstick competition can tial providers is needed to accept the compacts.
be used when different providers are given NGOs—so much a part of the African
parts of a larger system to run. Even when the scene and active in several other countries,
public sector is the main provider of services, such as Bangladesh—are possible candidates.
information from varying experiences can be They are a varied group. Many are not directly
valuable. Information on costs of production involved in service provision, and many com-
may be much cheaper to obtain by simple bine service with advocacy. Those that provide
observation of one’s own activities than from services often have a great deal of autonomy,
detailed technology assessments. Informa- choosing where and how to deliver services. To
tion on consumer preferences may be that extent, they might be treated the same as
cheaper to obtain by counting customers the rest of the private sector in planning public
than by conducting market research. services. The government should not be in the
For road construction in Johannesburg, an business of displacing them.
explicit contract was made between the city NGOs that have a tradition of altruistic
manager and an autonomous public agency, service can frequently be lower-cost produc-
the Johannesburg Road Agency, to build a ers. In a recent study, religious NGOs provid-
given number of kilometers of road for a ing health care in Uganda were found to offer
negotiated price. The basis of the negotiation higher-quality service than their public sector
was the set of historical costs in the public counterparts. They also paid lower wages than
agencies. The manager of the autonomous the private sector and very much lower than
agency then used both the public works the public sector. Unlike the private sector,
department and private sector firms as con- they were more likely to provide public health
tractors. Competition among the contractors services (as opposed to simply medical care)
determined subsequent allocations of funds. and to charge less. And they used an extra cash
Even though it was not possible to fire person- grant to lower fees and provide more services,
nel from the public agency, competition for such as laboratory tests, whereas the public
funds ensured that the public agency would sector used the grant to increase pay.303
match the efficiency of the private firms NGOs are often, though not always, better
(which it did for many contracts). There able to reach poor people. A substantially
could be a gradual shift to private provision, higher fraction of the clientele of NGOs pro-
but only on the basis of proven performance. viding health care in Zambia comes from
poorer segments of society than does the clien-
Limits to competition and the search for tele of government facilities or private
suppliers. For contracts that cannot be providers.304 But even they have a hard time
complete, aspects of delivery outside the con- reaching the very poorest. NGOs may also be
tract will remain a matter of trust. For the in a better position, with their greater flexibility
provision of services to poor people, this trust and their internal motivation, to bring services
13_WDR_Ch06.qxd 8/14/03 9:11 AM Page 104

104 WORLD DEVELOPMENT REPORT 2004

to otherwise excluded groups (box 6.8). And altruism.306 Indeed, many appear to be run by
smaller organizations can reach niche popu- former civil servants who have lost their jobs as
lations that a broad-based bureaucracy may a result of the downsizing of public sectors but
find hard to serve. who know how to approach donors and gov-
In combating AIDS, community outreach ernment contracting agencies. A rapid expan-
often needs to deal with prostitutes, drug users, sion of contracts for NGOs will tend to attract
and very sick, stigmatized people. The same the same people, and their motives may be
difficulties in assigning public personnel to exactly the same as those of a for-profit firm—
remote areas have been found in reaching these requiring the same monitoring and care in con-
subgroups. In Brazil, however, NGOs compet- tract enforcement. NGOs with a track record of
ing for government funds were able to reach good performance and dedication to poor peo-
high-risk segments of society that usually avoid ple are potentially very important elements of a
public programs (such as prostitutes), to dis- strategy to extend services to the neediest peo-
tribute 2.6 million contraceptives, and to take ple. But establishing a track record, by its very
11,000 hotline calls. The relative independence nature, does not happen as fast as donors would
of NGOs from the core of the public service like. The development of trust takes time.
may make it easier for them to fund their activ-
ities from public resources by granting policy- New challenges to supply. Although there
makers an extra layer of deniability. may be ways to extend the supply of providers
The altruistic motives of people working by promoting competition and efficient con-
in NGOs can overcome the incompleteness of tracting with NGOs and the private sector, two
contracts. NGO providers are generally less recent trends in developing countries are mak-
likely than for-profit providers to exploit the ing skilled professionals scarcer, or more
difficulties of monitoring contract terms for expensive. First, professionals—doctors, teach-
their own benefit. Their altruism may partly ers, and engineers—are increasingly part of
outweigh a reluctance to locate in difficult, integrated global markets and recruitment
remote, rural areas that are hard to staff with needs to compete at world wage rates. And it is
civil servants. This possibility has led one ana- not only to the rich countries that staff are emi-
lyst, thinking of Africa, to conclude that ser- grating. Botswana, for example, has been
vices to poor people may, for the time being, recruiting teachers from other, poorer English-
have to be left to such groups, particularly the speaking countries. The global market for ser-
church.305 vices is changing rapidly due to international
Once again, patience is called for. Donor agreements and could lead to new sources of
enthusiasm has led to a massive proliferation of supply. Whether this turns out to help or hin-
NGOs, many of them not at all motivated by der services in developing countries remains to
be seen (see box 6.9).
BOX 6.8 NGOs can be more flexible than government Second, HIV/AIDS, particularly in Sub-
Saharan Africa, has dealt a major blow to the
One advantage that NGOs may have over start in the kitchen?” While the two women
ranks of service providers. More teachers died
the public sector is the freedom from fixed were cleaning, they had a terrific conversa-
civil service rules or standard operating pro- tion about what was going on in that fam- of AIDS in Malawi in 2000 than entered the
cedures. In some ways this reduces account- ily. When I told the story at a meeting, I was profession (see box 1.2). Botswana’s search for
ability, but it can avoid unnecessary interrupted by the head of a university clini- teachers, originally to meet a burgeoning
constraints. cal psych department who said,“What that
demand for education, was given greater
therapist did was unprofessional.”
A social worker in a family protection pro-
Well, all I can say is if we want effective urgency by the country’s AIDS problem. And
gram calls on a family threatened with hav-
interventions that have transformative just as demands for health service workers are
ing a child removed for neglect. She’s
effects on people, then we had better rede- increasing, their supply is being cut.
greeted by the mother, who says “If there is
fine what is professional, or allowable in the
one thing I don’t need in my life right now,
expenditure of public funds.
When a factor of production becomes
it’s one more social worker telling me what scarcer, its use must be conserved—in one of
to do.You know what I really need? To get (from Common Purpose by Schorr, 1997)
two ways. First, techniques that are less skill-
my house cleaned up.” In many countries there is no way for
The social worker, who happened to be intensive can be chosen. Distance learning,
publicly employed social workers to violate
a highly trained clinical psychologist, the opinions of the university professor, but while not ideal for pedagogical purposes, may
responded by saying,“Would you like to more independent NGOs could do so. need to be explored to save scarce teaching
time. Similarly, it may be appropriate to use
13_WDR_Ch06.qxd 8/14/03 9:12 AM Page 105

Policymakers and providers 105

water systems that require less technical used. Recent trends may merely have made
inputs for maintenance. Second, some kinds this misallocation more costly.
of services that happen to be highly skill-
intensive may be reduced. Curative medical Monitoring and performance
services that require trained professionals may All contracts—both compacts and man-
be cut back relative to public works or public agement relationships within provider
health education, more intensive in capital organizations—need to be monitored with
and unskilled labor. It is possible that these independence and objectivity. With the separa-
interventions (low-maintenance water sys- tion of the policymaker and the provider orga-
tems, use of village health workers or tradi- nization, the policymaker will want to know
tional healers) may always have been under- whether compact provisions are satisfied.

BOX 6.9 Is the GATS a help or a hindrance?


For a new agreement that has so far not had mitments.These promises to eliminate or limit alizing commitments and new rules in areas
much impact on actual policy, the WTO’s Gen- barriers to foreign supply were mainly the out- such as domestic regulation. Informed debate
eral Agreement on Trade in Services (GATS) is come of negotiations—but some were volun- would undoubtedly help ensure that future
viewed with a surprising degree of both hope teered, particularly in telecommunications. Most GATS rules and commitments reflect broader
and trepidation. In the current Doha agenda existing commitments entailed little liberaliza- development concerns and not just the dictates
negotiations, some look to the GATS to deliver tion beyond existing market conditions. Many of domestic political economy or external nego-
much-needed reform of services from which the countries committed on tourism, financial, busi- tiating pressure.
poor will also benefit, while others see it as a ness, and telecommunication services, but rela- At this stage, however, the main issue is not
threat to regulatory sovereignty and pro-poor tively few in health, education, and environmen- so much what the GATS forces countries to do or
policies. tal services. Of the 145 WTO member countries, what it prevents them from doing, but that it
In principle, multilateral negotiations can only 43 (12 developing) have made does not—indeed cannot—ensure the comple-
foster reform in services, as in goods, by elimi- commitments in primary education, 52 (24 mentary action that is needed to deliver pro-poor
nating or reducing protective barriers through developing) in hospital services, and none on liberalization.This raises a legitimate concern: in a
mutual agreement and by lending credibility to water distribution (which was not an explicit complex area like services, trade negotiations alone
the results achieved through legally binding part of the original negotiating list of services could lead to partial or inappropriately sequenced
commitments.The expectation is that more sectors). reform. One possibility—already visible in some
open markets and greater predictability of pol- The most serious charge against the GATS cases—is that less emphasis will be placed on
icy will lead to the more efficient provision of is not its meager harvest of liberalization— introducing competition than on allowing a
services.That is the rationale for the GATS. We after all the process has only recently begun— transfer of ownership of monopolies from
address three questions: How much market- but that it deprives governments of the free- national to foreign hands or protecting the posi-
opening has happened so far under the GATS? dom to pursue pro-poor policies. It is argued tion of foreign incumbents. Another is that mar-
Does the agreement prevent recourse to the that the rules of the agreement threaten pub- ket opening will be induced in countries that
complementary policies needed to ensure that lic education, health, and environmental ser- have not developed regulatory frameworks and
the poor have access to essential services in lib- vices; outlaw universal service obligations and mechanisms to achieve basic social policy objec-
eralized markets? Could the GATS process lead subsidized supply; and undermine effective tives.These flaws could conceivably make the
to liberalization before other necessary reforms, domestic regulation. These charges do not poor worse off.The problem is accentuated by
and how can this be prevented? seem well founded for three reasons. First, ser- the difficulty in reversing inappropriate policy
The GATS is certainly wide in scope. It vices supplied in the exercise of governmental choices that have been translated into legally
applies to virtually all government measures authority are excluded from the scope of the binding external commitments.
affecting trade in almost all services, including GATS, although the definition—services that The danger of adverse outcomes would be
educational, health, and environmental services. are not supplied on a commercial basis or substantially reduced if two types of activities
Moreover, in recognition of the fact that many competitively—offers scope for clarification. receive greater international support.The first is
services require proximity between consumers Second, even in sectors that have been increased policy research and advice within
and suppliers, trade in services is defined to opened to full competition, the agreement developing countries and outside to identify the
include not only cross-border supply but also does not prevent the pursuit of domestic pol- elements of successful reform—and to sift the
foreign investment and the temporary migra- icy objectives, including through subsidies or areas where there is little reason to defer market
tion of service consumers and providers.The the imposition of universal service obligations opening from those where there is significant
broad reach of the GATS contrasts with the flexi- as long as these do not discriminate against uncertainty and a consequent need for tempered
bility of its rules.The generally applicable rules foreign suppliers. Finally, the agreement recog- negotiating demands. An even greater need is for
merely require of each country that its trade- nizes the right of members, particularly devel- enhanced technical and financial assistance to
affecting measures be transparent and not dis- oping countries, to regulate to meet national improve the regulatory environment and pro-
criminate among its trading partners.Thus, if a policy objectives, and its current rules on poor policies in developing countries.The devel-
country were to prohibit all foreign supply and domestic regulations are hardly intrusive. opment community is already providing such
make this fact public, then it would have met its However, the concerns noted above are not support, but a stronger link could be established
general obligations. so much about what the GATS is but what it may between any market opening negotiated inter-
The extent of market openness guaranteed become after the current (and any future) round nationally and assistance for the complementary
by a country depends on its sector-specific com- of negotiations—which will aim for more liber- reform needed to ensure successful liberalization.
13_WDR_Ch06.qxd 8/14/03 9:12 AM Page 106

106 WORLD DEVELOPMENT REPORT 2004

Competition among providers helps, since ery. They are also clear public goods and core
the policymaker will not feel locked into a responsibilities of government. Accurate infor-
particular provider, obliged to ignore bad mation can motivate the public, particularly
news. If the separation between the two is not the poor, to demand better services—from
achieved, an independent regulator or auditor providers and from policymakers—and arm
should be assigned the monitoring activities. them with facts. Knowledge of the real impact
Clear and observable provisions make of programs helps the policymaker set priori-
monitoring easier. When the provisions are not ties and design better compacts. Knowledge of
so easily observed, the policymaker may want the impact of different techniques of service
to enlist the help of other kinds of monitors. delivery helps the provider organization better
The health program in Ceará, Brazil (see spot- fulfill its compact. If the means to better ser-
light), used applicants to the program who had vice is the alignment of incentives with out-
not been selected as informal monitors. comes, knowing what those outcomes are and
When monitoring is difficult because of the how services contribute to them is central.
technical nature of the service, self-monitoring Good evaluation is the research necessary to
by professionals may be necessary. In assign causality between program inputs and
Bangladesh attendance by staff is much higher real outcomes. It should be directed at the full
in larger facilities due to informal self-moni- impact of programs—not just the direct out-
toring, among other factors.307 Professional puts of specific projects. But few evaluations
associations can also serve as self-monitors, have been done well, even though most major
establishing professional, ethical, and technical donors (including the World Bank) have always
standards for medical care providers, teachers, made provisions for them. Evaluation, though
and engineers. But the risk in self-regulation is primarily a responsibility of governments, is an
that professional groups become effective lob- area in which donors can help. It costs a small
byists for their members. fraction of the programs examined and a small
A third source of monitors is the public. fraction of the value of the information pro-
Even if clients are not the active monitors duced, but it does require some expensive tech-
described in chapter 4—that is, they are not nical inputs. And since other countries will use
purchasers of services or direct participants in the results, the international community should
service delivery—soliciting information (as defray some of the costs.
private business often does) can be useful in There are impediments to collecting such
public services. Publicizing the results of information. Provider organizations often do
scorecards led to a substantial improvement not want to acknowledge their lack of impact
of many services run by the Bangalore Munic- (even if it does not affect their pay directly),
ipal Corporation. This practice was replicated but knowing when things are not working is
in most states in India. essential for improvements. Further, it is nec-
When day-to-day monitoring to assess essary to know not just what works but also
performance is not possible, independent why—to replicate the program and increase
monitoring of the performance of services on the scale of coverage.
an occasional basis can still be valuable—by
bringing public information to bear on Provider incentives
provider behavior. The Public Expenditure in eight sizes
Tracking Survey in Uganda (see spotlight on Returning to the decision tree of figure 6.2
Uganda) is an example. More regular public- from the perspective of provider incentives,
ity of service characteristics on several dimen- the decision concerning the difficulty of
sions—such as absentee rates, regular delivery monitoring is, of course, key. When moni-
of pharmaceuticals, hours of operation for toring is easy—sizes 1, 3, 5, and 7—oppor-
electricity or water—could all mobilize com- tunities for more explicit incentives and the
munity concern and informal influence. use of contracts should be explored. How-
ever, contracting with a private sector is
Evaluation often a bad idea for sizes 5 and 7. Such con-
Generating and disseminating information tracts are a common source of corruption
are powerful ways of improving service deliv- that governments find harder to manage
13_WDR_Ch06.qxd 8/14/03 9:13 AM Page 107

Policymakers and providers 107

and citizens find harder to detect than if The boxes suggest eight sizes appropriate
services were provided by government. in different circumstances. They also indi-
When monitoring is difficult—the even- cate the relative difficulty of carrying them
numbered sizes—one goal is to improve the out—the degree of government failure
ability to monitor with the methods dis- associated with them. Generally speaking,
cussed in this chapter. More competition, the severity of the government failure
more careful measurement of outcomes, increases with the size number. The degree
the evaluation of the effect of inputs on of market failure needed to justify relatively
outcomes, and the provision of incentives easy policies to carry out is modest, or,
to groups of providers such as schools or equivalently, the highest-priority policies
districts can all help. are those with large market failures or

Figure 6.2 Eight sizes fit all

1 Central government financing with contracting. Performance contracts


let by government. Contract recipients can be public providers, NGOs or
the private sector as long as rewards can be made contingent on
outcomes. Network infrastructure can have national oversight. Contracts
Easy to require information for monitoring, low risk of government failure or of
monitor contracting.

2 Central government provision. Technical reforms to allow better


Hard to monitoring of outcomes that allow a movement toward size 1 may be
monitor considered. These are the “New Zealand reforms.” Otherwise, (a) if
Homogeneous
clients difficult for government to monitor but easier for clients, consider using
latter as monitors as in chapter 4; (b) evaluations of programs provide
essential information. Low risk of government failure depending on
monitoring abilities.

3 De-concentrated central or local government provision with contracting.


As in size 1 but: performance contracts possible by local or de-
Heterogeneous concentrated central government. Local or regional regulatory boards for
clients Easy to network infrastructure. Low risk of government failure if government can
Pro-poor monitor accommodate relevant variation in preferences.
politics
4 Local or de-concentrated central government provision.
Hard to As in size 2, some reforms to improve monitoring may be possible.
monitor Contracts need more flexibility to accommodate differing preferences.
Incentives to “teams” of providers. Regular evaluation of program
success essential for replication and scaling up. Risk of government
failure moderate since both monitoring and variation of preferences are
challenges.

5 Client power—experiment with contracts. Communities may rely on


contracting with private sector or NGOs. Contracts let by problematic
levels of government are prone to corruption. If only local government is
a problem, center can contract as in size 1 with local government as
Easy to potential provider subject to contract monitoring. Government failure is
monitor moderate if communities can be given more authority or only one level of
Clientelist government is problematic.
politics

Homogeneous Hard to 6 Client power—experiment with providers. Explicit contracts difficult.


clients monitor Communities (and donors) may want to rely on altruistic providers since
monitoring is difficult (subject to caveats in chapters 4 and 11). Public
dissemination of information is essential. Government failure moderate to
severe.

7 Client power—experiment with community control. Similar to size 5.


Heterogeneous Public disclosure essential. Evaluation of program performance
clients Easy to important. Risk of government failure moderate to severe due to the
monitor added problem of accommodating varying preferences.

Hard to 8 Client power—imitate market. Similar to size 6. Local input important


monitor from varying preferences. Evaluation of program performance and public
disclosure is essential. Risk of government failure is severe.
13_WDR_Ch06.qxd 8/14/03 9:13 AM Page 108

108 WORLD DEVELOPMENT REPORT 2004

strong redistributive effects. For the hard- Scaling up, scaling back,
est cases such as case 8, market failures and wising up
must be quite costly to justify intervention, There is no “right” way to make sure services
given the many legitimate claims on gov- reach poor people. The appropriate technical
ernment. interventions—and the institutional struc-
Including government’s ability to tures that generate them—vary enormously.
implement—that is, the degree of govern- Education was expanded dramatically in
ment failure to be expected—can lead to a Chile by markets and vouchers, in Cuba by a
substantial re-ranking of public policies central ministry, and in El Salvador by local
relative to conventional analyses. For school committees. Beyond trial and error,
social security systems, for example, there scaling up means watching what you’re
is no particular reason on conventional doing, evaluating whether it works, deter-
economic grounds for the public sector to mining why it works or doesn’t, replicating
send out checks to pensioners. But many success, and evaluating the replications as
governments with well-developed admin- well. Sometimes things work for idiosyn-
istrative procedures do it quite well, and cratic reasons—a charismatic (and literally
there is no compelling reason to change— irreplaceable) leader or a particular (and
market failures are not terrible but neither unrepeatable) crisis that solidifies support for
is it hard for government to do. Much of a politically difficult innovation. So one-time
the controversy about whether rich coun- successes may not be replicable. Experimen-
tries should emulate New Zealand’s tation, with real learning from the experi-
reforms surrounds this point. New inno- ments, is the only way to match appropriate
vations in contracting with a private sec- policies with each country’s circumstances.
tor or with a government agency might Scaling up also means scaling back—
improve the functioning of government abandoning failures unless a good, remedia-
somewhat. But if government is already ble reason for failure is found. Abandoning
doing tasks acceptably, the gains may be failures is harder than it sounds. Simply
small and possibly not worth the disrup- admitting failure is hard enough, particularly
tion caused by the change itself. for politicians. But with the severe resource
When applied to the health sector some constraints in developing countries—they
standard prescriptions are reinforced by are poor after all—badly performing pro-
these considerations while others are chal- grams are simply unaffordable. Where pro-
lenged. The provision of traditional public grams are intensive in management (and
health services, such as pest control to pre- auditors and managerial talent are scarce) or
vent infectious disease, is relatively easy to intensive in trained personnel (and teachers
carry out. But staffing and maintaining a and doctors are scarce), states need to let go
large network of primary health centers in of programs that are not working and find
remote areas is often hard to do, even alternative ways to achieve better outcomes.
though the redistribution effects are If the political will exists, the key to scaling
potentially beneficial. It might be wiser, up is information. Beyond evaluating pro-
until government capabilities improve, to grams and projects, a continuing focus on
try to get poor people to government facil- making services work for poor people—edu-
ities, even to much maligned hospitals, cated children, better health, reliable water,
than get facilities to poor people. Not only lighted homes, safer streets—depends on the
would this address a serious market fail- continuing measurement of progress toward
ure, the absence of insurance for expensive these goals. “What gets measured is what
care, but it will be easier to implement counts.” This focus on outcomes helps poli-
since working in less remote areas is more cymakers choose the best options for serving
consistent with providers’ interests and poor people. It helps the providers know
easier to monitor, with a smaller number when they are doing a good job. And it helps
of larger facilities.308 clients judge the performance of both.
14_pgs 109-110_Ch06Spot.qxd 8/14/03 3:26 PM Page 109

spotlight on Cambodia

Contracts to improve health services—quickly


Cambodia began experimenting with different forms of contracting to improve health services in 1998. The lesson—
thanks to good evaluation—is that contracting can help increase the coverage of some key services in a short time.

M ore than 25 years of conflict left


Cambodia with little health
infrastructure. In the late 1990s
its health indicators were among the worst
in Southeast Asia. Average life expectancy at
more than 20 percent of its planned health
facilities functioning. All had very poor
health service coverage. And all were com-
parable in their socioeconomic status.
Annual per capita recurrent spending by
in contracted-in and control districts. The
reduction was especially marked among the
poor ($35 a year, or 70 percent), indicating
better targeting and more efficient transfers
of subsidies.
birth was less than 55 years. Infant mortal- donors and government was higher in the Even though the health ministry encour-
ity was 95 per 1,000 live births. And mater- contracted-out districts: $2.80 in the con- aged all districts to implement official user
nal mortality was 437 per 100,000 live tracted-in districts, $4.50 in contracted-out fees, only one contracted-in district estab-
births.309 The public health care system districts, compared with $2.90 in control lished a formal user fee system and used the
remained rudimentary: average facility use districts.311 These differences are large and receipts from the system to reward health
was 0.35 contacts per person per year, and represent slightly less than 20 percent of the care workers with monthly performance
patients complained of very low quality. health expenditures (including private and and punctuality bonuses. That could
Then in 1998 the government con- excluding capital investments from the gov- account for slightly higher spending for this
tracted with nongovernmental entities to ernment) in all of the districts. type of district.313
provide health services in several districts. There are several possible reasons for
The contracting increased access to health Contracting for better results these pro-poor outcomes in the contracted
services—and not at the expense of equity. All districts improved service coverage in a districts.
short time. After only 2.5 years of the four- • The regular availability of drugs and qual-
Contracting primary health care year experiment, all districts had achieved ified staff strengthened service provision
services (in and out) their contractual obligations for most of at health centers in the villages, where
the evaluation indicators.312 The use of most poor people are concentrated.
Intervention and control areas consisted of
health services among the poorest half of
randomly selected rural districts, each with
the populace increased by nearly 30 per- • The contracted nongovernmental orga-
100,000 to 200,000 people.310 Contractors nizations used a market-based wage and
centage points in the contracted-out dis-
were chosen through a competitive process benefits package to attract and retain
trict (figure 1). One possible explanation is
based on the quality of their technical pro- health care providers.
that the contracted-out districts did not
posal and their price. Three approaches
were used.
charge official user fees; they also discour- • A reduction in the private out-of-pocket
aged health care workers from taking cost of services and a more predictable
and transparent fee structure increased
• Contracting out. Contractors had full “unofficial” user fees by paying signifi-
the demand for health care services by
responsibility for the delivery of speci- cantly higher salaries to providers than in
fied services in the district, directly the other types of districts. the poor.
employed their staff, and had full man- The pattern of increases is similar
agement control (two districts). across a variety of service and coverage Figure 1 Percentage of illnesses treated at a
• Contracting in. Contractors provided indicators (figure 2). The contracted-out health facility for people in the poorest half of
only management support to civil ser- districts often outperformed contracted-in the populace
vice health staff, and recurrent operat- districts, which outperformed control dis- Percent
ing costs were provided by the govern- tricts. But not all indicators were as respon- 35
ment through normal government sive. The share of deliveries assisted 30
channels (three districts). changed by only a small amount in all three 25
districts. And there was no difference
• Control areas. The usual government
between contracted-in and contracted-out
20
2001
provision was retained (four districts). 15
districts in the increase in vitamin A cover- 1997
A budget supplement was provided to con- age. The level of immunization in con- 10
tracted-in and control districts. tracted districts also remained quite mod- 5
Performance indicators were measured est, peaking at only 40 percent. 0
for all the districts by household, and health Out-of-pocket expenditures on health Control Contracted Contracted
facility surveys, which were conducted in care services fell dramatically in the con- in out
1997 before the experiment. No district had tracted-out districts but increased slightly Source: Bhushan, Keller, and Schwartz (2002).
14_pgs 109-110_Ch06Spot.qxd 8/14/03 3:26 PM Page 110

110 Spotlight on Cambodia

Figure 2 Coverage of selected health indicators between own funds and, in one district, allocated a
1997 and 2001 in control and contracted districts of Cambodia larger share of user-fee income. The con-
Percent trol districts, left to their own devices,
60 allowed workers to pursue private income-
Control
50 Contracted in maximizing behavior through unofficial
Contracted out fees and private practice, to the detriment
40
of the public health care services for the
30 poorest of the poor.
20 Transparent and predictable fee struc-
tures are important in improving access to
10
health services. Official user charges were
0 introduced in only one contracted-in dis-
–10 trict, in consultation with communities, to
Antenatal Tetanus Assisted Full Vitamin A provide incentives to health workers. To
care toxoid deliveries immunization coverage remove ambiguity about charges, a sched-
Source: Bhushan (2003). ule of user fees was prominently displayed
in all health facilities. This discouraged pri-
• The availability of health services in vil- hold surveys and spot checks by government vate practice and helped bring “under-the-
lages reduced travel expenditures to seek staff. Payments were linked to achieving tar- table” payments formally into the system.
health care, and NGOs enforced rules gets, with bonuses for better-than-agreed-on Out-of-pocket spending on health fell in
against informal payments by patients. performance. that district. No user fees were introduced
Improving health services for the poor in the other two contracted-in districts, or
Agreements on deliverables— requires that health workers be adequately in the control districts, where out-of-pocket
and enforceable contracts compensated and effectively supervised and spending did not come down.
Contracting health services to NGOs can supported. The NGOs working in con- Contracting health services to NGOs
expand the coverage for poor people. In tracted-out districts revised the salaries of can be difficult for policymakers to accept.
Cambodia it took agreements on deliver- health care providers, bringing them in line But the Cambodian experience shows that
ables and an enforceable contract, which in with average salaries in the private sector. In it can be effective and equitable. It helped
turn required an independent performance return, the NGOs required the providers to convince policymakers that the model
verification system. Once targets for 13 key work full time in health facilities and to could be adopted on a larger scale. They are
health indicators were agreed on—for poor have no private practice. extending contracting to 11 poor and
people—progress toward achieving them In the contracted-in districts, the NGOs remote districts, where the public provision
was measured through independent house- supplemented provider salaries with their of services is dismal.

You might also like