Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 16

ECONOMIC INCENTIVES FOR

ENVIRONMENTAL PROTECTION:
INTEGRATING THEORY AND PRACTICE

ROBERT W. HAHN

AND

ROBERT N. STAVINS

91-15 DECEMBER 1991

Prepared for Presentation


at the 1992 Meetings of the American Economic Association
New Orleans, Louisiana
January 5, 1992
CITATION AND REPRODUCTION

This document appears as Discussion Paper 91-15 of the Center for Science and International
Affairs and as contribution E-91-05 to the Center's Environment and Natural Resources Program.
CSIA Discussion papers are works in progress. Comments are welcome and may be directed to the
author in care of the Center.

This paper may be cited as: Robert W. Hahn and Robert N. Stavins, Kennedy School of
Government, Harvard University. "Economic Incentives for Environmental Protection:
Integrating Theory and Practice." CSIA Discussion Paper 91-15, Kennedy School of
Government, Harvard University, December 1991.

The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and publication does not imply their
endorsement by CSIA and Harvard University. This paper may be reproduced for personal and
classroom use. Any other reproduction is not permitted without written permission of the Center for
Science and International Affairs, Publications, 79 JFK Street, Cambridge, MA 02138, telephone
(617) 495-1351 or telefax (617) 495-1635.
ECONOMIC INCENTIVES FOR ENVIRONMENTAL PROTECTION:
INTEGRATING THEORY AND PRACTICE

Robert W. Hahn and Robert N. Stavins*

1. INTRODUCTION

For decades, economists have been extolling the virtues of market-based or economic-
incentive approaches to environmental protection. Some seventy years ago, Pigou (1920) suggested
corrective taxes to discourage activities that generate externalities. A half century later, Dales
(1968) showed how the introduction of transferable property rights could work to promote
environmental protection at lower aggregate cost than conventional standards. From these two
seminal ideas -- corrective taxes and transferable property rights -- a substantial body of research
has developed.

In the last two decades, the pace of related research has increased dramatically, with
economists seeking to determine how these ideas would work in theory and in practice. Until
very recently, most analyses have focused on theory or on related simulations, due to the paucity of
actual experiences with incentive-based environmental mechanisms. This began to change somewhat
in the 1980's, with increasing use by governments of fees and tradeable permits to control
pollution. This experience suggests that there is a large gap between the theory developed by
economists and the application of these tools in practice.

Both environmental taxes and marketable permits are coming of age in the policy arena.
Examples include the introduction of marketable permits in the U.S. to: reduce the leaded
content of gasoline; limit the production and use of chlorofluorocarbons; and limit sulfur dioxide
(SO2) emissions as a precursor of acid rain (Hahn and Stavins 1991). Charges have been used to
limit air and water pollution, principally in European nations, while deposit-refund systems
have been used for beverage containers in North America and for a more diverse set of products
in Europe (Opschoor and Vos 1989). Beyond these existing applications, there are now
numerous proposals, both in the U.S. and abroad, to apply incentive-based mechanisms to a host
of other environmental problems, ranging from local hazardous waste to global climate change
(Pearce, Markandya, and Barbier 1989; and Stavins, ed. 1991). While many of these proposals
may remain theoretical curiosities, it is

*Mr. Hahn is a Resident Scholar at the American Enterprise Institute and an Adjunct Research Fellow at the John
F. Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University. Mr. Stavins is an Assistant Professor of Public Policy and a
Senior Research Associate, Center for Science and International Affairs, at the John F. Kennedy School of
Government, Harvard University, and a University Fellow of Resources for the Future. This paper was prepared for
presentation at the 1992 meetings of the American Economic Association. The comments of Richard Zeckhauser are
gratefully acknowledged, but the authors alone are responsible for any remaining errors.
likely that there will be a significant increase in the use of market-based approaches during the
coming decade.

The introduction of these tools on a large scale provides a unique opportunity to


extend the frontiers of knowledge. This essay seeks to identify important issues that merit
investigation. Section 2 examines some possible objectives of environmental regulation, the
consequent criteria by which alternative policies can be judged, and the major categories of
regulatory instruments available to policy makers. Section 3 focuses on opportunities for
research in the area of policy design and evaluation, and Section 4 highlights what is known about
how instruments are actually chosen. The major themes of the paper are summarized in Section 5 in
terms of implications for environmental policy and the economics profession.

2. ALTERNATIVE POLICY INSTRUMENTS FOR ENVIRONMENTAL PROTECTION

2.1 Objectives, Constraints, and Criteria for Instrument Selection

Although some policy makers would claim that the singular objective of environmental
regulation is to protect environmental quality, the decision problem actually faced by policy
makers is more complex, involving tradeoffs among multiple objectives and real and frequently
binding constraints. In the economist's usual version of public-policy heaven, the objective might
be seen as one of aggregate welfare maximization, with the consequent criteria for good public
policy being (potential) Pareto efficiency -- maximizing the net benefits (benefits minus costs) of
environmental protection. Alternatively, one might apply a cost-effectiveness criterion, seeking to
achieve a given level of environmental protection while minimizing the related costs of pollution
control. Efficiency and cost-effectiveness, however, are by no means the only possible criteria by
which environmental policies can or should be judged. In searching for public policies that
provide real improvements over existing or alternative environmental regulations, consideration can
also be given to: overall effectiveness; equity; information requirements; monitoring and
enforcement capability and costs; political feasibility; and clarity to the general public (Lave 1981;
Bohm and Russell 1985). Based on these and other criteria, alternative policy instruments can
be considered and evaluated.1

1
Of course, it also makes a difference whether particular yardsticks are taken as objectives or constraints. For
example, suppose the political feasibility of different projects could be assessed in terms of the likelihood they
would be implemented. Then, a policy that maximized economic efficiency subject to having a certain likelihood of
implementation would, in general, be different from a policy that maximized some combination of economic
efficiency and political feasibility. Under special conditions, given well behaved functions, the two problems can
be shown to be equivalent, however.
2.2 Categories of Available Instruments

Economists frequently divide policy instruments for achieving environmental


objectives into two broad categories: those that provide firms. with relatively little flexibility in
achieving goals -- so-called "command-and-control" approaches -- and those that provide firms
with greater flexibility in making environmental progress along with incentives to look for more
effective ways of making sustained environmental progress -- so-called market-based or
incentive-based mechanisms.2

Comparisons between conventional command-and-control regulation (including


technology standards and performance standards) and market-based approaches (including
taxes and markets in pollution rights) have repeatedly noted that conventional regulations fail
to achieve environmental objectives in the least costly manner. For example, acid rain could
be reduced by a specified amount by requiring the largest twenty power plants emitting.
S02 to install scrubbing devices -- an example of command-and-control. Because firms would
thus be compelled to control to the same level of emissions, rather than to the same level of
marginal control costs, the solution would not be cost-effective.

In contrast, well-designed market-based approaches provide an incentive for firms to equate


abatement costs at the margin, thus achieving a given level of environmental quality at least
cost. One market-based approach to the acid-rain problem would limit pollution from sulfur
dioxide by defining a suitable number of emission rights, distributing these rights, and then
allowing firms to trade them freely. A firm would not be legally allowed to emit unless it
owned emission rights that equaled or exceeded its emissions. This approach can yield
static cost savings due to the trading of the emission rights among sources (and can also
yield dynamic incentives for firms to cut back their emissions even further by adopting
cleaner and less costly production technologies). Indeed, in the case of reducing acid rain in
the U.S., simulations indicate that approximately $1 billion may be saved annually by
substituting a market-based approach for a command-and-control approach. In theory, a
similar result could be achieved through the introduction of an emission charge or tax.

The above comparison of command-and-control with marketable permits is


intentionally simple, and thus obscures a number of subtleties, including the fact that both sets
of instruments are typically embedded in complex regulatory systems. Not all systems are
feasible in a technical, legal, economic, or political sense. Indeed, recent experience has shown that
political constraints can serve to limit dramatically the range of instruments that are actually
considered to protect or enhance environmental quality.

2
Several instruments of importance to policy makers do not fall conveniently within these two categories, including
monitoring and enforcement techniques, use of the courts, and the use of information.
2.3 The Search for Better Instruments for Environmental Protection

There has been greatly heightened interest over the past two years in market-based
approaches for environmental protection among all four sectors of the environmental policy
community -- government, private industry, environmental organizations, and academia.3 In
the midst of this flurry of interest, there has been an unmistakable tendency to allow
interest in popular policy instruments to take precedence over critical consideration of policy
objectives.4 While less attention is being paid to the economic desirability of particular
objectives, the policy community now seems mesmerized by the possibility of using markets and
other incentive-based approaches to achieve specific objectives. Thus, potential means (such
as market-based instruments) of achieving policy objectives are often being -intentionally or
unintentionally -- confused with objectives themselves (such as efficient or cost-effective
environmental regulation). The danger is that analysts may come to ignore the selection of
goals, and may focus exclusively on specific means for achieving these goals. Economic perspectives
have important roles to play in both the selection of goals and the selection of means.

Economists have shown a marked preference for incentive-based instruments over


command-and-control because these instruments typically provide a more cost-effective way of
achieving a given level of environmental quality -- at least, in theory. In practice, the picture
is less clear, particularly because these instruments are usually implemented in an intensely
political environment. It is important for economists to keep an open mind about which
instruments are likely to be most "economical;" that is, which instruments will actually achieve the
greatest level of efficiency relative to some appropriate benchmark. Indeed, given political
and technological constraints, there are some problems for which incentive-based approaches
are poorly suited. In such cases, economists will want to focus on the design of other
instruments, such as various kinds of standards, to meet particular objectives.

Another reason to broaden the range of instrument search is to accommodate


legitimate objectives other than efficiency or cost effectiveness. These other objectives could
reasonably include equity and administrative simplicity, for example. If market-based
instruments are considered, then the investigation should include not only charges and
tradeable permits, but also deposit-refund schemes, strategies to reduce government barriers to
market activity, and means of eliminating or at least reducing problematic government
subsidies.5 Moreover, a host of other ("non-market") approaches should also be considered,

3
For an investigation of the causes of this increased interest, see: Hahn and Stavins 1991.
4
For example, as part of the reauthorization process for the Clean Water Act, the U.S. Environmental Protection Agency
(EPA) held public hearings for the purpose of "seeking ways to apply economic-incentive mechanisms to water-
quality protection." See: Cooney 1991.
5
The rather sudden interest by "mainstream economists" in environmental issues brought about by concerns
regarding global climate change has manifested itself almost exclusively in investigations of carbon charges and
other tax schemes. "Environmental economists" have also focused on tradeable permit systems. Neither group of
analysts has moved beyond the usual charge/permit set of instruments.
such as different kinds of standards, strengthened monitoring and enforcement mechanisms, and the
provision of information.

Whether any specific instrument is desirable depends on how it is designed and


implemented. Thus, the economist's search for improved environmental policies -- even if relying
exclusively on criteria of efficiency or cost-effectiveness -- should cover a much broader terrain than
typically has been the case. This search should be driven by an understanding of what exists and
what is truly feasible. Neither standards, nor tradeable permits, nor enforcement mechanisms, nor
any other kind of policy instrument are homogeneous products; each exists in a multitude of forms
and variations.

It is important to recognize that the nature of individual environmental problems can


dramatically affect the choice of preferred policy instruments. Thus, for example, for highly localized
pollution problems with threshold (non-linear) damage functions, source-specific standards may
be appropriate, whereas for pollution problems characterized by more uniform mixing over
larger geographic areas, market-based approaches may be particularly desirable. Likewise, especially
high costs for monitoring emissions may mean that technology-specific standards are preferable on
economic grounds.

Variations in technology, skills, and administrative resources can have important implications
for policy design. In general, it is more appropriate to "fine-tune" policies when administrative
agencies have the capability to implement them. Thus, for example, Los Angeles may be in a
position to implement a market to reduce smog-causing emissions, which allows trading of emission
reductions between vehicles and stationary sources. In contrast, Indonesia or Mexico might consider
policies that are simpler to administer. One possibility would be to use an indirect instrument, such
as a gasoline tax, or a more general fuel tax. The basic approach should be to try to tailor the
tool to the problem and the institutional and cultural context. To date, there has been a great
deal of study of how to design tools for highly sophisticated systems. A comparable level of study
would be useful in defining the trade-offs in designing environmental policy tools where resources
for management and control are severely limited, such as in developing countries.

This brief review of alternative instruments for environmental protection suggests: first, that
economists' analyses would benefit significantly from expanding the set of instruments under
consideration; and, second, that the set of preferred instruments will vary not only with the criteria
adopted but also with the problems being addressed.
3. POLICY DESIGN AND EVALUATION

Increased interest in economic criteria for environmental policy and increased interest
in market-based approaches both imply potentially critical roles for economists in the design and
evaluation of environmental policies and programs. In this section, we identify some prominent
issues which merit investigation. While recognizing the validity of the broad set of criteria
mentioned in the previous section, we follow the general thrust of the existing literature by
focusing our attention on issues of efficiency.

3.1 Static Efficiency and Cost Effectiveness

Some measure of static efficiency is typically used in most economic analyses of alternative
policy instruments. In some cases, the measure may include explicit calculations of the benefits of
pollution control, but in most cases, a cost-effectiveness measure is utilized. Conventional
standards are frequently compared with some market-based system, and potential gains from trade
in permits or efficiency gains from charging a pollution fee are simulated. This approach
requires estimation of pollution control costs, along with specification and estimation of the cost
of status quo regulations.

As implemented, this approach tends to exhibit several significant problems. First, it is


important that the existing regulatory environment be considered when new (additional) policies are
being designed and evaluated. Failure to do so can be highly problematic. For example, the new
SO2 tradeable allowance program for acid rain control was codified in the 1990 amendments to the
Clean Air Act, but no statutory provision was made (nor apparently seriously considered) to
ensure that state public utility commissions would adopt or consider regulations that would give
appropriate incentives to electrical utilities to participate in the trading program.6

Although empirical analyses have begun to examine the outcomes of actual


applications of market-based policy mechanisms, there is a pressing need for rigorous tests of
hypotheses regarding these and other mechanisms. In carrying out such analyses, it is essential to
use the appropriate benchmark for counterfactual analysis. For example, Tietenberg (1985)
assimilated the results from ten analyses of the costs of air pollution control, and in a frequently
cited table, indicated the ratio of cost of the actual command-and-control program to a least-cost
benchmark for each case. Unfortunately, the resulting ratios (which ranged from 22.0 to 1.1)
have been taken by others to indicate the potential gains from adopting specific ("cost effective")
mechanisms such as tradeable emission permits. A more realistic comparison would be between
actual command-and-control policies and either actual trading programs (such as EPA's bubble
policy) or a reasonably constrained theoretical permit or charge program.

6
If regulated utilities cannot retain some fraction of the benefits from trading, they will have little or no incentive to
engage in trades.
A special case of this problem is that economists typically estimate the gains from trade in
moving to a market-based system in which there are no transactions costs, even though previous
work on actual applications suggests that transactions costs in tradeable-permit markets can be
substantial. Far too often, the response of economists to politicians' nearly exclusive focus on
allocation issues has been to assert that the equilibrium allocation of marketable permits (subsequent
to exchange) will be independent of the initial allocation. With transaction cost functions of the form
experienced in practice, however, the quantity of transactions, the equilibrium allocation of permits,
and hence the aggregate costs of control (degree of relative cost effectiveness) are indeed
sensitive to the initial permit allocation.

Given the observed importance of transactions costs in trading, statistical analysis is needed
of the effects of transaction costs on market activity in actual applications, such as the phasedown
in leaded gasoline through the trading of rights among refineries. Also, the consequences of
alternative trading rules on actual permit markets merits empirical analysis. In general, quantitative
investigations are needed of our experiences with existing market-based and conventional policies.
In the former case, attention should be given both to the use of tradeable permits in the U.S. and
various kinds of charge systems in European nations.

A particularly challenging area that has received little attention in the empirical
literature on incentive-based approaches is the impact of differential monitoring and
enforcement capabilities on efficiency. For example, if there is an international agreement limiting
greenhouse gas emissions, countries are likely to vary in terms of their desire and ability to
monitor and enforce such an agreement. This could have a dramatic impact on efficiency as well
as how such an agreement is structured.

A further problem affecting empirical analyses is that serious attempts are rarely made
to note the quantitative consequences of uncertainties. In part, this is due to the difficulty of
developing meaningful error distribution estimates for control cost functions. In most applications,
estimated cost functions are taken as true cost functions. This has important implications for
estimating gains from trade in moving to alternative systems. Estimates of the potential savings of
markets over command-and-control could be quite different if the stochastic nature of cost-
function estimates were taken into account. Furthermore, while some analyses have included
uncertainty in stylized ways, most have failed to deal adequately with the problem of designing
robust policies -- ones that have a high probability of leading in the direction of a particular
desired result, even if that result is not achieved (Hahn, McRae, and Milford 1988). Robust policies
can be particularly useful in situations where substantial uncertainty is associated with pollution-
transmission or damage mechanisms or with the implementation costs of selected policy
instruments.7

7
Robust policies move the system under study in the desired direction, regardless of the outcome of current
uncertainties. For example, there is great uncertainty associated with the impacts on regional precipitation patterns of
greenhouse-induced global warming. Some models indicate, for instance, that the flow of the Colorado River
will increase; others indicate a net decrease in annual flow. One robust greenhouse policy, then, would be a
mechanism -- such as provision for market-oriented voluntary water transfers or elimination of water
Over the next decade, there will be a unique opportunity to carry out empirical
analyses of a variety of new approaches to environmental improvement. Examples include the new
S0 2 allowance trading system in the U.S. for acid-rain control and the carbon dioxide (C0 2) taxes,
which are just now being initiated in a number of European nations. Such analyses could provide
important insights into the conditions under which alternative instruments perform relatively well,
and these analyses could also provide clues regarding the feasibility of implementing better
environmental policy mechanisms .8

3.2 Dynamic Incentives

In the long run, the effect of public policies on technological change may be among the
most important determinants of success in environmental protection. For example, much of the
policy discussion regarding the threat of global climate change has centered on alternative means of
increasing energy efficiency -- whether in production or consumption. Economists, of course, have a
simple answer of how to achieve the efficient level of diffusion of any energy-efficient technology --
set the prices correctly, such as through carbon taxes, and let the market do the rest. Engineers,
lawyers, and most politicians do not see it quite this way; they tend to be more interested in using
energy-efficiency standards, whether for motor vehicles, home appliances, or home construction.

The debate has until now rested largely on theory. Economists continue to claim that market-
based policies will not only be cost-effective (in a static sense), but will also provide dynamic incentives
for the development and adoption of improved pollution-control technologies. In the absence of
empirical research, this remains largely an untested hypothesis. This need not be the case. By
drawing upon our experiences with market-based and command-and-control policies and by
investigating some "natural experiments" with changing energy prices, it is possible to investigate
empirically the relative effectiveness of these two categories of policy mechanisms in terms of their
relative impacts on the diffusion of improved technology (Jaffe and Stavins 1991).

It should also be recognized that the standard theory of factors affecting dynamic
efficiency may need to be revised in the light of political constraints. For example, it is not clear
that governments are capable of making the type of long-term credible commitments under
markets that would be required to encourage affected firms to adopt new and improved
technologies. Even in the case of the market for sulfur oxides to reduce acid rain, there are
significant questions about whether Congress will change the rules governing the market in
midstream. The statute clearly states that a tradeable permit (called an

subsidies -- which would make the agricultural economy (the choice of crops) more sensitive (via the price
mechanism) to changes in water availability.
8
For example, the auctions developed in the add rain portion of the Clean Air Act are based, in part, on the idea of a zero-revenue
auction developed by Hahn and Noll (1982). If implemented, the performance of these auctions can be compared
with results from laboratory experiments (Franciosi, Isaac, Pingry, and Reynolds 1990).
"allowance") "does not constitute a property right,"9 thus giving some cause for concern. The real
challenge is to compare paths of technological change under political institutions that use
standards with other feasible regimes that use market-based instruments (Milliman and Prince 1989).

3.3 Other Criteria for Policy Evaluation

Given the broad range of criteria by which environmental policies can be evaluated, it is
important that economists begin to move beyond their traditional reliance upon efficiency
and cost effectiveness for judging the efficacy of alternative means of reaching policy goals. Whether
singly or in combination, other legitimate criteria of success should be considered, principal
among these being the relative distributional equity or fairness associated with specific policies. It
is becoming clear that alternative notions of "equity" may mean the difference between life and
death for new policy proposals in the political realm.10 For example, one of the major challenges
in developing a substantive agreement for controlling greenhouse gas emissions will be to define
de facto emission rights in such a way as to satisfy a sufficient number of the parties to such an
agreement (Grubb and Sebenius 1991).

4. WHY ENVIRONMENTAL POLICY INSTRUMENTS ARE CHOSEN

In contrast with the substantial amount of work that has been done by economists on
designing market-based approaches to environmental protection, relatively little effort has been
devoted to developing or testing a positive theory of instrument choice. Without understanding
the conditions under which various instruments are likely to be feasible, it is difficult to develop
meaningful comparisons among those instruments. Relatively little is known about why particular
instruments are selected, despite the fact that Buchanan and Tullock (1975) developed an
argument as to why standards might be preferred to taxes, and subsequent work by Maloney and
McCormick (1982) developed a more general positive theory of environmental regulation, based on
the notion of rent seeking.

One problem with current theoretical models of instrument choice is that they lack the
detail required to provide guidance in specific policy situations. Moreover, they do not

9
Public Law 101-549, November 15, 1990, Clean Air Act, S403f p.202, 104 STAT 2591, 42 USC 7651b.
10
Under certain circumstances, consideration should therefore be given to second-best policies, which provide for
specific forms of compensation of "losers" from the social gains due to use of cost-effective instruments (Burtraw and
Portney 1991). This is arguably what was done in the case of the add-rain tradeable allowance program in the
1990 amendments to the Clean Air Act. In separate legislation, a program was established to provide job-training and
other forms of compensation for workers displaced by the new law, at an estimated cost of $50 million per year over five
years. As indicated above, the tradeable permit program itself is expected to yield savings of $1 billion per year. See:
Schneider 1990.
help distinguish among the array of instruments that are actually applied. For example, there
are a large variety of standards and subsidies, but there is little understanding of why particular
ones are selected. To begin developing such a theory, it would be useful to focus initially on the
incentives faced by key decision makers and the institutions and environments in which they
function.

Some work has been done on the impact of procedures and rules implemented by
Congress (McCubbins, Noll, and Weingast 1989), but neither the House of Representatives nor the
Senate is a key player in defining the details of many environmental policies. Indeed, a
striking feature of many Federal environmental policies is the extent to which program staff
within EPA play a central role in developing and advancing options (Hahn and Stavins 1991). A
closer look, at the bureaucracy is needed to gain a deeper understanding of instrument choice
(Wilson, ed.1980). Moreover, the relationship between the bureaucracy, the White House, and the
Congress deserves further exploration. Finally, it is necessary to include the role of environmental
organizations in any comprehensive model of instrument choice, since these groups play an
increasingly important role in shaping national policy (Hahn 1990).

A more refined positive theory of instrument choice could lead to useful insights. For
example, the level of transactions costs may be affected by the degree to which there is
consensus over the underlying distribution of property rights. EPA's emissions trading program was
characterized by high transactions costs whereas the lead trading program had relatively low
transactions costs. This difference in costs can be explained in part by the underlying consensus over
the de facto ownership of the property rights. Thus, while there may be some flexibility in
designing market-based approaches with relatively low transactions costs, this flexibility is likely to
be limited by the political environment.

A more careful and comprehensive articulation of a positive theory of instrument


choice will lead to a richer statement of available alternatives. This point is illustrated by the
recent negotiation over legislation to reduce acid-rain emissions by implementing a market-
based approach. Environmentalists seized this opportunity to require that power plants install
continuous emission monitors, which yield measurements that are far more accurate than those
required under traditional standards-based approaches. Thus, the political choice of markets
versus standards also depends on other aspects of policy design - - in this case, the nature of
monitoring and enforcement.

As in most any area, theoretical modeling is necessary but not sufficient for full
understanding of economic phenomena. A variety of hypotheses merit empirical examination. It
has been hypothesized (Hahn and Stavins 1991) that the following factors favor a more positive
reception by the policy community of market-based environmental-protection strategies:

(1) increasing marginal costs of pollution control and consequent concern regarding cost
effectiveness;
(2) macroeconomic concerns about domestic productivity and international
competitiveness;

(3) government budgetary concerns and consequent reluctance to attack existing


environmental problems simply by spending more on monitoring and
enforcement of existing approaches;
(4) existence of "new" environmental problems that have not been addressed by
previous policies (and hence lack constituencies for the status quo approach);

(5) changing political realities generally more sympathetic to market-based approaches


to various social problems;
(6) separation of means from ends (cost-effectiveness), avoiding questions of efficiency
that raise controversial benefit-cost issues;

(7) absence of concentrated losers (who are politically vocal); and

(8) potential of market-based policies to improve environmental quality while sustaining


private industry profits, compared with available alternatives.
These and other hypotheses need to be examined by rigorous methods of analysis, including but not
limited to statistical approaches.

The positive theory of instrument choice can be complemented with an analysis of emerging
institutions designed to address environmental problems, particularly those of a regional or global
nature. The nature of these institutions and their participants will limit the range of feasible
instruments. In the case of acid rain regulation in the U.S., the market in tradable allowances was
an integral part of the package that included the 10 million ton reduction in sulfur oxides
emissions. In contrast, in the case of the Montreal Protocol aimed at protecting the ozone layer,
countries were given a great deal of discretion over the instruments they could select to
implement the Protocol. One critical challenge is to identify the range of politically feasible
institutions for addressing global and regional problems and describe how these institutions could
affect the available choice of instruments.

5. IMPLICATIONS FOR PUBLIC POLICY AND THE PROFESSION

The decade of the 1990's may be remembered as a full-employment period for


environmental economists; one of the key factors fueling the demand for services will likely be
continued experimentation with a variety of market-based approaches for environmental protection.
Although economists have developed some useful insights regarding marketable permits and
effluent fees for environmental management, it is time to move to a more
realistic statement of the problems that need to be solved. This can best be accomplished by
allowing theory to be guided by experience.

Theory and experimentation can be useful in the design and evaluation of market-based
instruments. It is clearly unlikely, for example, that the tradeable-permit program adopted in the
recent Clean Air Act amendments would have even been considered had economists and
others not developed and refined the idea over the previous decade. Thus, there remains a need
for economists to develop and refine new instruments that may prove useful for future policy
makers. This search for new instruments should recognize that appropriate mechanisms will vary
depending on the relevant government agency's resources and capabilities. Much of the work on
markets and emission taxes assumes that there is a reasonably sophisticated environmental
control agency that can administer incentive-based programs. This may be a reasonable
assumption for many industrialized nations, but is probably the exception, rather than the
rule, in developing countries. The design of incentive-based instruments that require less
administrative expertise and fewer resources to implement could facilitate more and better
applications.

The most worthwhile research agenda will link theory and empirical work. Even in the
case of normative theorizing, relevance can be increased by carefully articulating political
constraints on institutional design and facilitating the development of more realistic institutional
comparisons. Such comparisons should exploit what is known about institutions, while at the same
time, being careful to recognize the limitations of our knowledge.

The research agenda of environmental economics can do a better job of informing the
quest for better public policies. It should be recognized, however, that most of what is already
known about the design of market-based approaches for environmental improvement has yet to be
assimilated by policy makers. This assimilation is unlikely to occur unless economists become more
aware of the environmental policy process, since such awareness is a prerequisite for more relevant
research. At present, however, the incentive structure faced by most academic economists works
against such concerns. This is unfortunate, since environmental economics can make a real
difference in the world in which we live.
REFERENCES
Bohm, Peter and Clifford S. Russell. "Comparative Analysis of Alternative Policy Instruments." Handbook of Natural
Resource and Energy Economics, Volume I, eds. Allen V. Kneese and James L. Sweeney, pp. 395-460.
Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1985.

Buchanan, James and Gordon Tullock. "Polluters' Profits and Political Response: Direct Controls Versus Taxes." American
Economic Review 65 (1975):139-147.

Burtraw, Dallas and Paul R. Portney. "Implementing Market-Based Environmental Policies: The Role of
Compensation." Paper presented at the John F. Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University,
Cambridge, Massachusetts, April 24, 1991.

Cooney, Catherine. "EPA Drafts Permit Trading Scheme for Water Pollution." Environment Week, March 21, 1991, page
6.

Dales, J. Pollution, Property and Prices. Toronto: University Press, 1968.

Franciosi, Robert, Mark Issac, David Pingry, and Stanley Reynolds. "Marketable Add Rain Emissions Permits: An
Investigation of Revenue Neutral Auctions." Department of Economics, University of Arizona, Tucson, Arizona,
1990.

Grubb, Michael and James K. Sebenius. "Participation, Allocation and Adaptability in International Tradeable
Emission Permit Systems for Greenhouse Gas Control.” Paper Prepared for OECD Workshop on
Tradeable Greenhouse Gas Permits, Paris, France, June 1991; amended September 10, 1991.

Hahn, Robert W. "The Political Economy of Environmental Regulation: Towards a Unifying Framework." Public Choice
65(1990):21-45.

Hahn, Robert W., Gregory J. McRae, and Jana B. Milford. "Coping with Complexity in the Design of
Environmental Policy." Journal of Environmental Management 27 (1988):109-125.

Hahn, Robert W. and Roger Noll. "Designing a Market in Tradable Emissions Permits." Reform of
Environmental Regulation, ed. Wesley Magat, pp. 119-146. Cambridge: Ballinger, 1982.

Hahn, Robert W. and Robert N. Stavins. "Incentive-Based Environmental Regulation: A New Era from an Old Idea?"
Ecology Law Quarterly 18(1991):1-42.

Jaffe, Adam B. and Robert N. Stavins. "The Energy Paradox and the Diffusion of Conservation Technology: Modelling
the Effectiveness of Economic Incentives and Direct Regulation." Paper prepared for the National Bureau of
Economic Research Conference on Economics of the Environment, Cambridge, Massachusetts, December 13,
1991.

Lave, Lester. The Strategy of Social Regulation. Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institution, 1981.

Maloney, Michael T. and Robert E. McCormick. "A Positive Theory of Environmental Quality Regulation." Journal of
Law and Economics 25(1982):99-123.

Milliman, Scott R. and Raymond Prince. "Firm Incentives to Promote Technological Change in Pollution Control."
Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 17(1989):247-265.
McCubbins, Matthew, Roger Noll, and Barry Weingast. “Structure and Process, Politics and Policy: Administrative
Arrangements and the Political Control of Agencies." Virginia Law Review 75(1989):431-482.

Opschoor, J. B. and Hans B. Vos. Economic Instruments. for Environmental Protection. Paris: Organization for
Economic Cooperation and Development, 1989.

Pearce, David, Anil Markandya, and Edward B. Barbier. Blueprint for a Green Economy. London: Earthscan
Publications, 1989.

Pigou, A. C. The Economics of Welfare, first edition. London: Macmillan & Co., Ltd., 1920.

Schneider, Keith. "Lawmakers Reach an Accord on Reduction of Air Pollution." New York Times, October 23, 1990,
pp. Al, A18.

Stavins, Robert N., ed. Project 88 -- Round II: Incentives for Action: Designing Market-Based Environmental
Strategies. A Public Policy Study sponsored by Senator Timothy E. Wirth, Colorado, and Senator John Heinz,
Pennsylvania. Washington, D.C., May 1991.

Tietenberg, T. H. Emissions Trading: An Exercise in Reforming Pollution Policy. Washington, D.C.: Resources for
the Future, 1985.

Wilson, James Q., ed. The Politics of Regulation. New York: Basic Books, Inc., 1980.

You might also like