Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 20

Network Paper No.

132
Agricultural Research
& Extension Network July 2003

CHANGING INCENTIVES FOR AGRICULTURAL EXTENSION –


A REVIEW OF PRIVATISED EXTENSION IN PRACTICE

Robert Chapman and Robert Tripp


Abstract
This paper summarises a recent AgREN email discussion on privatised extension. The discussion highlighted the
fact that private extension delivery is subject to a range of interpretations. A number of experiences in both
industrialised and developing countries provide opportunities for examining the advantages and limitations of a
privatisation strategy for extension. The examples include instances of purely market-based extension service,
extension service linked to the private provision of inputs or purchase of outputs, cost-recovery schemes for public
services, and public programmes that provide a partial subsidy for private extension providers. No single model is
adequate to describe private extension, and the empirical evidence illustrates a range of experience regarding the
adequacy of private providers, the ability of farmers to take advantage of a privatised system, and the capacity of
governments to manage the transition.

Research findings
• Private extension is not a single entity, but includes a wide range of modalities, from the spontaneous emergence
of private markets for certain types of advice and service to carefully guided public support for the development
of private extension provision.
• A key to understanding private extension is the fact that it is possible to separate the provision of funding from
the provision of service.
• Although a ‘privatised’ extension service may require significant public support, the most significant change is
the development of a new incentive system, in which the quality and content of extension provision is more
responsive to farmers’ priorities.
• If privatised extension is to make a contribution, it will not embody the replacement of a monolithic public
extension system by a similarly undifferentiated private system; instead, it will allow the development of a range
of extension modalities and funding strategies.

Policy implications
• The transition to privatised extension modalities, with improved incentives, takes a significant amount of time
and investment, and policymakers should prepare appropriate long-term plans.
• Private extension provision will only be effective if there are well-trained personnel who are willing and able to
respond to farmers’ requirements; considerable public sector investment in education and training will be
required.
• Similarly, farmers need increased capacity to be able to contract, manage and evaluate private extension
provision. This capacity may be enhanced through appropriate farmer associations and through decentralised
political structures, but both of these areas present many pitfalls.
• An evolution towards private extension modalities should begin with those themes that are most likely to elicit
farmer demand and investment; public responsibility for financing extension on themes such as environmental
protection will likely remain, although private delivery modalities may prove useful.

Contact details
Robert Chapman is a Research Officer of the Overseas Development Institute,111 Westminster Bridge Road, London SE1 7JD, UK.
Tel: 44 (0)20 7922 0300 Fax: 44 (0)20 7922 0399 Email: r.chapman@odi.org.uk

Robert Tripp is a Research Fellow of the Overseas Development Institute, 111 Westminster Bridge Road, London SE1 7JD, UK.
Tel: 44 (0)20 7922 0300 Fax: 44 (0)20 7922 0399 Email: r.tripp@odi.org.uk

The Agricultural Research and Extension Network is sponsored by the UK Department for International Development (DFID)
The opinions expressed in this paper do not necessarily reflect those of DFID.
We are happy for this material to be reproduced on a not-for-profit basis. The Network Coordinator would appreciate receiving details
of any use of this material in training, research or programme design, implementation or evaluation.

Network Coordinator: Robert Tripp Administrative Editor: Alana Coyle Administrator: Fiona Drysdale

ISBN 0 85003 679 8


Changing incentives for agricultural extension…

CONTENTS
Page

Abstract i
Contact details i
Acronyms and abbreviations iv
1 INTRODUCTION 1
2 PRIVATE EXTENSION LINKED TO COMMODITIES OR INPUTS 2
3 THE INTRODUCTION OF PRIVATE INCENTIVES TO GENERAL
AGRICULTURAL EXTENSION 3
4 THE MANAGEMENT OF PRIVATISED EXTENSION 7
The service providers
The farmers
The nature of the service
Targets
Funding

5 POLICY IMPLICATIONS 10
6 CONCLUSIONS 11
REFERENCES 12
Boxes, figures and tables
Box 1 Livestock extension services supplied by dairy unions in India 3
Figure 1 Public and private characteristics of agricultural information 4
Figure 2 Privatised extension options for funding and delivery 5
Table 1 Case studies of agricultural extension programmes using privatised services 6
Table 2 Privatised extension approaches to promote environmental management priorities 9

iii
Agricultural Research and Extension Network Paper No. 132

Acronyms and abbreviations


ADAS Agricultural Development Advisory Service
GIS Geographic Information System
ICTs Information and Communication Technologies
IPM Integrated Pest Management
ITC Indian Tobacco Company
NAADS National Agricultural Advisory Services
NABARD Ministry of Agriculture and the National Bank
T&V Training and Visit

iv
CHANGING INCENTIVES FOR AGRICULTURAL EXTENSION –
A REVIEW OF PRIVATISED EXTENSION IN PRACTICE

Robert Chapman and Robert Tripp

1 INTRODUCTION
Agricultural extension finds itself in the midst of Privatised extension can take many forms and it has
significant changes and uncertainty. Processes of become clear that it does not represent a simple,
change have been underway for some time but in many undifferentiated alternative to the monolithic public
developing countries these have been accelerated by extension system it is often expected to replace. By
structural adjustment reforms aimed at reducing public examining a number of experiences around the world
sector spending. An environment of declining it is clear that extension services vary considerably by
government budgets combined with waning donor the degree to which they have adopted privatised
interest has led to significant cuts in public extension extension mechanisms. For this reason it is less useful
services (Farrington, 1994). Those public extension to talk of a ‘model’ of privatised extension that can be
activities that remain are under increasing pressure to adopted wholesale than to consider what aspects of
provide an accountable and responsive service to privatised extension offer genuine options under which
citizens. At the same time, the retreat of governments circumstances. In this way policy makers will be able
from managing agricultural input and output marketing, to choose from a range of privatised extension
a diversification in the sources of agricultural research, mechanisms to achieve the most equitable and efficient
and increased opportunities for trade, have opened extension service with the resources available.
many new opportunities for the private sector, including What exactly is meant by private extension? Is it a
extension provision. single entity or a broad set of principles? What has
In addition, there is growing uncertainty about what been the experience to date, and what policy lessons
role extension is supposed to play in the development might be learned? Our purpose in this paper is not to
process. There is now a much-reduced emphasis on define what proportion of extension services should
uniform messages (such as those provided by the T&V be privatised, but to review the various interpretations
system). The need to involve farmers more in the of privatised extension, assess lessons to date, and draw
extension process itself has been recognised for some implications for extension policy. The paper is based
time and a number of participatory and facilitation on an email discussion on the subject of privatised
approaches have been developed (Roling, 1995; extension hosted by AgREN March 10–21, 2003 (website
Coldevin, 2000). In addition, farmers need extension address: www.rimisp.cl/agren03 ). The paper attempts
on a diverse range of rural development options to summarise major points raised by participants in
including information on markets, rural industry and that discussion and includes case material provided
other income opportunities (Farrington et al., 2002). by participants and other literature that was reviewed
Privatised extension has been the subject of in preparation for the discussion.
widespread discussion by those considering the Section 2 considers the various forms of privatised
challenge of providing an efficient agricultural extension that emerge in the course of agricultural
extension system for farmers in developing countries development, often linked to markets for certain
(Farrington, 1994; Kidd et al., 2000; Rivera, 2001; Katz, commodities and inputs. It is useful to consider some
2002). Although new private extension initiatives offer of these examples of private extension that have
many opportunities for commercial farmers, there is developed to fill gaps or opportunities in the market
less certainty about the implications for resource-poor place before considering privatised extension as a more
farmers whose connections to, and command of, strategic concept for achieving public extension reform
markets is much more tenuous. It is generally in Section 3. This section will draw on the cases outlined
recognised that many of these farmers have been poorly in the electronic discussion to examine how the theory
served by conventional, public sector extension in the of privatised extension has been put into practice in
past, but does a call for ‘privatisation’ of extension different countries and contexts. Section 4 focuses on
imply any greater hope for them? Can private extension those issues relating to the management of privatised
initiatives serve the needs of commercial farmers (in extension. The diversity of circumstances alluded to in
order to strengthen the contribution of agricultural the preceding section creates the need for flexible and
markets to economic development) and at the same pluralistic extension methods. Privatised extension can
time redress the neglect suffered by many resource- only offer an improved service to farmers if it is able
poor farmers whose production is principally for to deliver according to their diverse requirements.
subsistence? Tailoring an extension service to farmers’ needs requires
Agricultural Research and Extension Network Paper No. 132

the development of sufficient management expertise Mahindra and Mahindra Limited, a tractor company,
to enable the farmers, funders and service providers has also begun to offer private extension services
to organise themselves effectively. Section 5 considers through its dealerships and franchisees. These services
the possible policy implications for privatised extension are provided on a fee-per-area basis and include sale
based on the issues raised in the earlier sections. of farm inputs, credit, field visits by trained supervisors
and produce procurement. The service was aimed
2 PRIVATE EXTENSION LINKED TO initially at rice farmers and has been expanded since it
COMMODITIES OR INPUTS began in 2000 to include sugar cane, maize and wheat
Any discussion of private extension must acknowledge (Sulaiman, 2003). EID Parry also initiated farmer
that there are several different types of activity that extension services through locally managed information
may qualify for this label. This section briefly reviews centres in order to strengthen the relationship between
some of the instances of private extension activity that its sugar mill in Tamil Nadu and the contract sugar
emerge more or less spontaneously with the cane farmers. The farmers are provided with more
development of agricultural markets. These include timely information on the status of their account in
extension related to contract farming, the activities of terms of credit, input supplies and produce sales and
agricultural input and commodity firms, the can access a range of extension advice. It is clear that
contributions of producer co-operatives, and the all these initiatives are in their early days and have
provision of veterinary services. arisen in a particular context of a competitive
There has been considerable growth in contract agribusiness sector and improving information
farming, and this is often associated with the provision technology facilities. These initial experiences show
of extension advice. For instance, farmers in Kenya signs of a developing range of privatised extension
who grow horticultural crops on contract to exporting services from private companies, where farmers are
firms can expect to receive some advice and support willing to invest with no public sector encouragement.
on crop management, not only to ensure the exporter A commodity-based link to extension may also be
of good quality produce but also to provide a service initiated from the farmers’ side. A good example is the
to the contracted farmers. Contract farming can offer activity of producer co-operatives or commodity
significant opportunities to farmers (Benziger, 1996), associations that organise the provision of extension
but there are also many problems, including farmers’ advice on behalf of their members. The Maharastra
potential loss of control over farm management Grape Growers Association is one of India’s oldest
decisions and dependence on a single buyer (Porter farmers’ organisations with approximately 17,000
and Phillips-Howard, 1997). The extension advice members with 20 elected members working as
offered under contract farming may be of good quality, ‘extension functionaries.’ The association has four
but it is usually confined to the crop in question, and offices in the state through which it organises discussion
farmers have little choice about the content or nature groups and seminars, and publishes printed materials
of information delivery. The degree to which extension such as a monthly information newsletter. The
provision in contract farming responds to farmers’ association carries out research and development on a
priorities is a function of the distribution of power designated research farm and provides facilities for soil,
between the firm and the producers. The cost of water and plant testing and brings outside experts to
providing the extension advice is usually included solve specific problems (Sulaiman and Sadamate, 2000).
(although not necessarily explicitly) in the contract with Commodity associations that fund their own research
the farmer; indeed the higher extension needs of usually provide some type of extension to disseminate
smaller farmers is one reason that firms often prefer to the results among their members. In Colombia, a Rice
avoid such producers in contract farming (Key and Producers’ Federation funds adaptive research and
Runsten, 1999). extension in which local farmers participate in
Other opportunities may link extension advice to identifying priorities and evaluating results (Estrada et
the delivery of a commodity or the purchase of inputs. al., 2002). Producer co-operatives may provide
Several recent examples from India show how important extension services to their members without
commodity firms or input suppliers may be motivated becoming involved in research activities. Box 1 outlines
to provide extension services (e.g., crop management the range of extension activities provided by milk
advice, weather reports) to their clients. The provision producer unions in India, and shows how the charges
of this service may be strictly linked (so that farmers are divided between farmers and the union.
who are not clients of the firm are excluded from the Another example of private extension can be found
service), or may be provided as an inducement (e.g., in the organisation of veterinary services in many parts
to encourage farmers to sell their harvest to a particular of the world. Although the state has often provided
buyer). Rallis, an input marketing company, has veterinary services, there are many instances of a
established rural service centres to provide a range of parallel private market, particularly for curative services
integrated services to farmers growing wheat, soybean, on a fee basis provided by veterinarians or dealers of
vegetables and fruits. In return for a fee, farmers are pharmaceutical products. The motivations for such
provided with regular visits by agronomists, assistance service are clear: livestock keepers are willing to pay
with credit arrangements, access to farm inputs, soil for good quality advice and products to maintain the
testing and a guaranteed market for their produce. health of their animals, which represent a valuable stock

2
Changing incentives for agricultural extension…

Box 1 Livestock extension services supplied by dairy unions in India


Livestock extension services can help to assist milk producers at every stage of production, from improved animal husbandry
through to better quality milk and increased production. In India over 11 million farmers receive these services through their
cooperative milk unions, and the National Dairy Development Board helps to improve the quality of the service through training
the dairy union staff, introducing new extension approaches and new technologies. The milk unions have technical officers and
extension supervisors that provide the services to the dairy farmers. The farmers are expected to pay for services both indirectly
through their milk union and directly, depending on the type of service received. Although the exact funding arrangement varies
from one union to another according to their relative financial strength, the split between indirect and direct payment for livestock
extension services is illustrated in the following table:

Extension Services Type 1 Type 2 Type 3


1. Animal health care services
Veterinary first aid and emergency care ✓ ✓
Vaccinations, Deworming, Mastitis control ✓ ✓
Brucellosis screening ✓
2. Artificial Insemination and Infertility camps ✓ ✓
3. Feed and Fodder activities
Promotion of ration and feed management ✓
Varietal demonstration on fodder crops and Silvipasture demonstration ✓
Promotion of fodder production on individual farmers’ lands and seed ✓
multiplication of fodder crops at farmers land
Fodder demonstration unit at union land ✓
Supply of quality seeds of fodder crops ✓ ✓
Promotion and demonstration of fodder management techniques ✓ ✓
4. Other training and institution building activities

Type 1: Total cost directly charged to farmers
Type 2: Total cost borne by milk union
Type 3: Part of cost borne by milk union (indirect payment) + part directly charged to farmers

The unions provide a core set of extension services on topics of broad interest such as clean milk production or a clearly defined
priority area such as capacity building for women. These services are supplied to all members irrespective of their social and
economic status. Many of the other services listed above represent specific assistance related to the farmer’s scale and method of
production. The farmers own the milk unions and therefore all the services provided must correspond to the underlying imperative
of profitable production while at the same time ensuring that the diverse needs of different producers are addressed.

Source: Sabyasachi Roy, 2003

of savings and a source of income. As long as there is adequate licensing and regulation (Carney, 1998).
adequate choice and competition, farmers have a Veterinary associations can also play an important role
chance of receiving an efficient service. in promoting a privatised service and enforcing
Elements of privatised veterinary service appear even regulations (Leonard, 1993)
among resource-poor herders. Actionaid/Vetaid set up The example of veterinary services has implications
a paravet service in the Sanaag Region of Somaliland for crop extension: farmers are willing to pay for
in the early 1990s. There were no other veterinary extension service, but particularly when it is related to
services and a network of 30 paravets was formed to issues of significant economic importance and involves
cover the large isolated area. Privatisation through the fairly straightforward, targeted measures. On the other
sale of veterinary drugs at commercial rates based on hand, preventive measures and public goods issues in
the establishment of veterinary pharmacies in each livestock management (just as in crop extension) are
district emerged as the most sustainable strategy, less likely to see the spontaneous development of a
following consultation with pastoralists. The proposal market for private provision. The next section will
also included linking paravets to the pharmacies and consider the way private incentives influence general
linking the pharmacies to traders to ensure the mutual extension activities.
exchange of technical, veterinary and business
knowledge (Catley, 1996). The emergence of a private 3 THE INTRODUCTION OF PRIVATE
veterinary sector depends on the policy environment. INCENTIVES TO GENERAL
For instance, it is often difficult for privatised veterinary AGRICULTURAL EXTENSION
services to compete with subsidised public services. In theory, private extension is simply the provision of
In addition, regulations and professional jealousies a service or advice by a private firm in exchange for a
sometimes stand in the way of the development of an fee; the terms and conditions of the transaction are
independent private veterinary sector. It is important negotiated in an open market. The degree to which
to develop the political will for reforms to take place this can be done in practice depends on the extent to
through the promotion of relevant training, clear which extension services can be converted into a
distinction between veterinarians and paravets, and private good. Agricultural information is commonly

3
Agricultural Research and Extension Network Paper No. 132

Figure 1 Public and private characteristics of agricultural information

Excludability

Low High

Public Goods Toll Goods


• Mass media information • Time-sensitive production,
Rivalry/Subtractability

• Time-insensitive production, marketing, or management


marketing and management information
Low

information of wide applicability

Common Pool Goods Private Goods


• Information embodied in locally • Information embodied in
available resources or inputs commercially available inputs
High

• Information on organisational • Client-specific information or


development advice

Source: Alex et al., 2002

seen as a public good because of its low excludability of individual fields and the generation of soil fertility
and low subtractability. The common distinction maps are available from various suppliers. Farmers tend
between public and private goods is illustrated in to contract this service directly from the local
Figure 1. Much agricultural information can spread cooperative, private input supply firm or a private
easily amongst farmers and retains its value despite agricultural consulting firm. Farmers are able to use
wide access, and is thus considered a public good. the analysis to define their use of fertiliser and agro-
Agricultural information with private good chemical input requirements with the potential of
characteristics could be tied to the use of a purchased saving costs on inputs and improving overall yields. A
input (such as instruction on the use of a particular reduction in the application of nitrogen in Illinois
chemical), specific to the fields of an individual farmer following the adoption of precision farming practices
(such as tailored soil or pest management advice), or has also resulted in ‘public’ environmental benefits by
provided through long-term interaction with a farmer alleviating some of the damaging effects of nitrogen
or group of farmers. The other two cells in Figure 1 being introduced into the local freshwater and
represent additional categories of information. An Mississippi River delta ecosystems (Swanson et al., 2002).
example of a toll good might be time-sensitive market The Indian government has launched an ambitious
information for which a farmer was willing to pay, initiative to encourage private extension with the
and an example of a common pool good might be Ministry of Agriculture and the National Bank
information on the management of common forest or (NABARD). Graduates are being trained to become
grazing resources. ‘agripreneurs’ and on completion of their courses they
Agricultural information provided as a private good receive a loan to establish an ‘agriclinic’ or ‘agribusiness
can occur in various circumstances and does not centre’. Farmers are expected to pay a fee for their
necessarily require the existence of a highly commercial services and the agripreneurs are expected to identify
agricultural system. For instance, in the 1930s, villagers the demand for a broad range of services from soil
in northern Thailand employed lowland rice growers testing to advice on organic production and food
to teach them how to terrace and farm irrigated fields processing. So far 112 businesses have been set up in
(Kunstadter, 1987). But in general, instances of 10 states and it is intended that the new services will
extension information provided through private market provide specialist advice that may be beyond the scope
mechanisms are more likely to occur with highly of the service presently offered to farmers through
commercial agriculture. In some instances in Europe public extension (Shekara and Charyulu, 2002).
and North America, private extension markets have The performance of private extension services is
developed to meet a broad set of needs. In the UK, for more complicated than the theory suggests because of
example, a private extension sector has been active the difficulties inherent in making information a
for many years, even before the public Agricultural commodity, subject to excludability, as well as because
Development Advisory Service (ADAS) was privatised of market imperfections that may reduce social welfare
(Garforth, 2002). In the US, many farmers pay private (Hanson and Just, 2001). An important part of
consulting firms to provide technical extension services. agricultural extension is the provision of knowledge
In the state of Illinois, for example, precision farming on the benefits of new technologies and techniques.
services such as grid soil testing using geographic However, much of this type of knowledge cannot be
information system (GIS) software for precise mapping restricted for use only to those who pay for it. Without

4
Changing incentives for agricultural extension…

‘excludability’ of this kind the service providers cannot government at the time of privatisation and formed an
prevent the information being shared by other potential executive agency within the Ministry of Agriculture.
buyers and are therefore unable to profit from providing The government also retained the option of subsidising
the service. One strategy is to link the advice to another certain services by contracting ADAS or another
product that is excludable, such as an input. There are consulting company to offer the service for them
cases when this can lead to a conflict of interest. Hanson (Garforth, 2002). There are various opportunities for
and Just (2001) describe examples from Maryland (US) cost recovery in public extension activities and these
where private firms offering advice on nutrient need to be explored.
management and integrated pest management (IPM) Cell C represents cases where public funds are used
link their services to the sales of fertiliser or pesticide to contract private suppliers of extension. In some cases
(respectively), which constitutes moral hazard. In the transition proceeds almost completely towards
addition, if farmers are unaware of the value of the private funding. In Germany the shift to private
information they receive and the benefits are not easy incentives was initiated in some areas following
to observe, then it can be very difficult to establish a reunification. The state of Thuringia is one example
market price for the service. that has attempted to introduce private extension in
Social benefits from extension will be reduced under order to reduce public expenditure; the budget was
a private extension system when market imperfections cut from DM 5.2m to DM 2.5m per year (Currle et al.,
arise. Imperfections may be associated with the costs 2002). In Chile the reform process has been going on
of reaching remote areas or the failure to provide for over 25 years with the first privatised extension
affordable services to smaller farmers. In the Maryland service in 1978. There has been significant investment
case described by Hanson and Just (2001), the private over this period by the government, and it still funds
companies that supply nutrient management plans tend 85%–90% of the programme’s total cost. The process
to concentrate on larger farms, and private IPM services has therefore been more about improving the quality
also focus on major crops and larger farms. In the UK, and efficiency of the service than simple cost recovery
although new clients were attracted to the privatised or privatisation (Berdegué and Marchant, 2002). A major
extension service, many smaller farmers were unable experiment in Africa is recently underway with the
or unwilling to pay for advisory services (Garforth, National Agricultural Advisory Services (NAADS) in
2002). There is thus a concern that this type of Uganda, where farmer forums at the local level are
privatisation will not come close to addressing the much being constituted to use funds provided through local
more diverse, and often more subsistence-based, needs government to identify and contract private extension
of the majority of resource-poor farmers in the South. providers. The reforms are operating in 10 districts
In these cases, general calls for ‘privatised extension’ initially with further expansion into the remaining 46
may be diversionary or irrelevant unless more thought within 5 years. The contracts are expected to be
is given to how private incentives might be directed managed locally through local government and farmers’
towards the reform of conventional extension. organisations with small groups of advisers and private
Although it is possible to question the relevance of companies.
private extension because of these limitations of private The following section will consider some of these
extension markets, it is necessary to recall the aspects of transformation that affect the management
overarching problem of public extension’s current high of privatised extension with respect to a number of
costs and low efficiency. There is a need to reduce case studies. The examples include a mixture of types
public expenditure and challenge the centralised and B, C, and D from Figure 2. It is important to understand
top-down structure of public sector extension. It is also that whilst in many cases such experiments in private
important to recall that current approaches to extension are meant to ‘replace’ the public service, it
government activity favour a ‘new policy agenda’ under
which greater participation and decentralisation are Figure 2 Privatised extension options for
expected (Kidd et al., 2000). funding and delivery
One of the first steps is to recognise that it is possible
to separate the funding of extension from its delivery. Delivery Public Private
Figure 2 summarises the major possibilities. Cell A
represents classic public extension and Cell D
represents the ‘pure’ form of private extension service,
Funding
such as the examples that have been discussed in this
section. However, there are two other possibilities. Public A. Free public C. Subsidies to
Cell B represents various cost-recovery strategies that extension service private extension,
extension contracts,
can provide income to public services and improve voucher schemes
efficiency. In the UK, ADAS was privatised in 1997 but
an earlier change in legislation (Agriculture Act 1986) Private B. Cost-recovery D. Private
paved the way for fee-charging and set a target of 50% by government enterprise
agents
cost recovery from charges to farmers over a period of
five years. These targets were readjusted in the run-up
to privatisation. Certain services such as environmental Source: Kidd et al., 2000
protection and conservation were retained by the

5
6

Agricultural Research and Extension Network Paper No. 132


Table 1 Case studies of agricultural extension programmes using privatised services
Country Description Service Provider Contractual Level of Service Beneficiaries Funding
Case arrangements
Chile (a) Covers the whole Since 1990 NGOs, Arranged between Both technical and 25,000 small 85–90% funded by the government. Co-financing by
country. First small farmers’ organisa- farmers and municipal professional services ranging farmers targeted farmers increased since 1997 with allowances for
privatisation in 1978 tions and qualified authorities or directly from farm management to up to 1990 then 20,000 small farmers
private sector firms with service providers legal advice increased to 52,000
China (b) Grassroots extension ATEC system operates Fee-based, cost- Full spectrum of advisory All farmers, but high- Three types of funding:
system operates at all at the grassroots level sharing and services with 371,000 value crop producers 1. Contract or fee-based
levels through the using 500,000 farmer commercialised professional, technical and and members of 2. Farmer Associations formed by World Bank-
Agro-Technical technicians, 6.6 million agricultural services administrative staff commodity associa- funded project (1993–2001) with cost-sharing for
Extension Centre demonstration tions most able to pay technical consultants’ fees for some specific advice
(ATEC) households 3. Commercialised services
Estonia (c) All forms of Certified advisers and Different contracts Services provided by Farmers and farmers’ Funding provided by the government. Farmers
agricultural advice approved specialists according to scale of advisers funded annually organisations or contribute 15% towards small individual services
provided from organisations activities (individual include training days, project-specific target and 50% for larger contracts. Services to groups
including universities farmers, groups, demonstrations, seminars groups managed by county-level administration recover
and institutes demonstrations) and publications 20% of the cost from farmers
Germany – Thuringia joined the Advisers from other State-specific advisors Private extension services 4300 farmers State-level funding reduced from DM 5.2m to
Thuringia Federal Republic of regions came to fill the approved to work on focus on individual technical, cultivating 802,000 ha DM2.5m per year including DM1.4m to cover
State (d) Germany in 1989; requirements for private contracts up to financial and administrative of arable land. advisor personnel costs, with the remainder covering
privatised extension extension services. DM 130,000 value farm management. Environ- Following privatisation residual public service and administration costs.
system began in 1998 Young local advisers over three years mental issues, promotion of number requesting Private fee rates variable under contracts with
also trained as existing women, plant protection advice fell from 80% average charges to farmers of DM 66
public sector staff retained as public service to 13%
resisted the transition
Netherlands Extension service The DLV and the Farmers agree Service changed to more All farmers 30m Dutch Guilders provided by the government to
(e) became independent National Farmers’ contracts for timing, client-oriented approach subsidise the plan determined by the Ministry of
of government funds in Association implement payment, personnel, from previous transfer of Agriculture
1990 and renamed agricultural projects for and plan of activities technology approach
DLV the government with advisers
Romania (f) Agricultural NGO provides the Contracts agreed Site visits and written 7000 farmers in NGO funded initially, with a shift to partial cost-
Development Project service. Public service between advisors and advice, group meetings, western part of recovery from farmers in the form of service fees
Vaida set up for cannot provide frequent farmers based on demonstrations of growing Romania
vegetables, corn, or planned services at a service, price and methods, testing and analysis
wheat, soybean comparable level frequency
Uganda (g) The National Small groups of advisers Majority of funding Range of advice focused Project currently Programme budget is $108m over 7 years with
Agricultural Advisory such as NGOs, private expected to be on improving agricultural being operated in only expectation that farmers will take an increasing
Services (NAADS) companies and managed by sub- productivity 10 of a planned total responsibility for paying service providers
programme set up individuals county governments of 56 districts
following recent with contracts
extension reforms arranged between
them and farmers
Source: a) Berdegué, J. and Marchant, C. (2002), b) Chuang, N., Swanson, B. and Yan, F. (2002) c) Loolaid, U. (2002) d) Currle, J., Hoffmann, V. and Kidd, A. (2002) e) Proost, J. and Duijsings, P. (2002)
f) Plaas, K. (2003) g) Nahdy, S. (2002)
Changing incentives for agricultural extension…

is not a case of a one-for-one exchange, where a public new services therefore had to draw on private sector
provision system is, for instance, substituted by a single, advisers from other states and it was necessary to train
subsidised, system for contracting private extension younger staff who were less entrenched in the old
providers. The hope is that this is simply one step system. One of the premises for privatised extension
towards a significant diversification in extension improving the quality and relevance of the service to
provision, where a wide range of providers, contracted farmers is based on there being a choice of service
or directed through various modalities, is available to provider and a degree of competition between them.
farmers. Those lamenting the loss of services provided In many of the cases it is the development of a large
in type A should also reflect on the extent to which an enough supply of trained advisers to fill not only one
equitable and efficient service has previously been extension service organisation but several competing
achieved in any given context. The options for reform ones that has taken considerable time and resources.
offered by privatised extension are not merely low- Attracting private sector advisers from one area to
cost versions of the status quo but should be marked another such as in the example of Thuringia is
improvements in the transfer of agricultural information obviously not an option in Uganda, for example, where
and advice for long term development objectives as capacity is absent throughout the whole country. For
well as promote a strengthening of farmer control and this reason the alternative strategy of building on the
evaluation of the extension service. Although public existing capacity of NGOs has been adopted out of
sector cost-recovery and subsidy programmes should necessity. In Chile many of the existing private sector
be regarded as transitional (Umali and Schwartz, 1993) organisations including NGOs and far mers’
a flexible mix of services is likely to be required for a organisations were excluded from contracting under
long time before fully privatised services can be the government funded extension programme for
achieved. political reasons up until 1990, when these constraints
were removed and the range of service providers began
4 THE MANAGEMENT OF PRIVATISED to diversify.
EXTENSION Training schemes and training institutions, including
This section provides a brief review of issues related those related to extension, have tended to suffer
to the management of privatised extension. The issues particularly severely from public sector budget cuts.
include the development personnel and services for In the transition to privatised extension delivery the
private extension, the organisation of farmer demand need for training is likely to increase and responsibility
for that service, the nature of the service provided, the for funding this activity may rest with the public sector
ability of such systems to reach poorer households, for a considerable time. Sasakawa Africa Association
and funding modalities. The following discussion will and Winrock International have been collaborating
make reference to the cases summarised in Table 1 as since 1993 to provide mid-career extension training to
well as examples provided during the recent email help public sector extension workers adjust to new
discussion. challenges. These innovative extension training
programmes have been established in Ghana, Tanzania,
The service providers Ethiopia and Uganda through the Sasakawa Africa Fund
A key to any type of private extension is the availability for Extension Education (SAFE). Although extension
of skilled service providers. In most countries the workers benefit from further technical training it is also
majority of this expertise has been concentrated in the important that they understand the structural changes
public extension service. In theory, such extension taking place and to ‘grasp the new roles that the private
agents can establish new careers in the private sector. sector is playing and the likely prospects for private-
This has happened to some extent in Europe, but the sector participation in extension delivery and financing’
transition is not always easy. In the new Uganda (Opio-Odongo, 2000:9). It is necessary to consider the
strategy, much reliance is being put on the staff of implicit training requirements in transition strategies
NGOs (some of whom are former public extension and ensure that not only the funding but also the
agents). In Guatemala, farmer organisations encouraged capacity is available for local training programmes to
to hire extension agents have tended to favour local be made available.
personnel, which has the advantage of increasing the
communication between farmers and the agent, but The farmers
may imply some sacrifice in technical skills. The In cases where farms are very large, or there is high
programme in India for establishing ‘agriclinics’ is demand for an individualised service (such as veterinary
training recent agricultural graduates, most of whom treatment), privatised extension may be managed on a
have never worked in the public sector, to help them farm-by-farm basis. But in the majority of the cases
establish their own consultancies. that were reviewed, the service is channelled through
There is a need to think about how such extension some type of farmer organisation. In these cases, a
agents will be trained, and the conditions of service challenge is to identify the type of farmer organisation
that will induce someone to follow this career when it that is most appropriate for this purpose. In some of
is no longer linked to a protected civil service position. the cases discussed in Section 2, commodity-based
In the German example of Thuringia State, the public organisations already exist and these are a natural
sector staff proved unable to adjust to serving their conduit for extension advice. But dealing with smaller
clients through a privatised system of extension. The farms and more diversified needs requires a different

7
Agricultural Research and Extension Network Paper No. 132

type of organisation. There is not yet enough depend on the ability of the majority of resource-poor
experience to assess the degree to which organisations farmers to make their voices heard and to develop the
purposively formed to provide an interface with an capacity to evaluate the services provided in their names
extension market will be effective. Private extension (Kidd et al., 2000). The range of services provided by
provision will have to deliver a certain minimum level the milk co-operatives shown in Box 1 illustrates how
and value of service to elicit broad-based and vigilant an organisation owned by its members provides
participation from farmers in the organisation that is pluralistic extension services in response to diverse
responsible for contracting and monitoring. Experience needs. It is also worth restating that it has taken 35 years
(outside of private extension) has shown that it is easier for the milk producer co-operatives to develop the
for external agencies to form groups of subsistence organisational capacity that they have today. It cannot
cultivators than it is to guarantee that these will be be assumed that such institutions will blossom
self-sustaining. In a comprehensive review of immediately under conditions of privatisation and
Associative Peasant Business Fir ms, farmers decentralisation.
organisations that are being promoted in Chile,
Berdegué (2001) shows that those peasant associations The nature of the service
that focus on specialised commodity markets with high The nature of privatised extension service offered to
transaction costs are most likely to be viable. Those farmers will depend on the strategies of extension
associations that are formed to gain advantage in delivery and the range of ICT that may be enlisted. An
traditional wholesale commodity markets do less well, additional issue is the responsibility for providing
and those that lack ‘effective links to specific markets extension that promotes long-term environmental
will either collapse from lack of purpose, or will management concerns or other public policy issues
become…a channel for government or intermediate that are unlikely to respond to a private extension
agency funds, taking advantage of the greater political market.
leverage enjoyed by almost any organised group of An important issue for the future of privatised
farmers’ (ibid.,265). extension is an understanding of exactly what type of
One approach has been introduced in Estonia that service is to be provided. No matter what the future of
differentiates the amount of cost-recovery required to privatised extension, it is widely acknowledged that
reflect the scale and indivisibility of the services being the traditional model of top-down, uniform instruction
offered. For individualised services farmers pay a on crop management recommendations (characteristic
minimum of 15% and a maximum of 50% depending of much public extension) is far from the requirements
on the overall size of the contract. Services provided of today’s farmers. In the first place, where extension
to farmers as a group tend to be managed by county is successful, it is more likely to involve strong farmer
level administration and are charged to farmers at a participation and to feature joint problem solving rather
rate of 20% of the total cost. The farmers and certified than standardised solutions. To what degree such
advisers are registered in order to operate under the requirements can be met by building farmers’ capacity
individual contracts for services that are agreed between (to solve their own problems), farmer organisation (to
the two parties but also require county level seek joint solutions), or an efficient market for extension
government approval. The individual agricultural advice (responding to clearly articulated farmer needs)
advisory services are therefore subsidised but the remains to be seen. Secondly, public agricultural
contracts allow the farmers greater flexibility to extension has traditionally been seen (although not
determine the nature of the services they receive always functioned) as a conduit between farmers and
(Loolaid, 2002). public agricultural research. Public research must face
In a number of cases the administration of private some important changes itself (Byerlee and Echeverria,
extension is linked to decentralised government 2002) and it is not clear how private extension might
structures that provide the funds and liaise with farmer fit in. Recent innovations in which competitive grant
groups. In Uganda, for example, the majority of funding programmes for agricultural research encourage the
is expected to be managed by contracts between sub- participation of public and private organisations, NGOs,
county level government entities and farmers. However and farmer organisations (Reifschneider et al., 2000;
farmers (both as individuals and as members of groups Bingen and Brinkerhoff, 2000). Such competitive grants
contracting for the provision of services) are likely to could be extended to encourage private extension and
need capacity building to benefit fully from such better links between research and dissemination.
mechanisms. As many governments are involved in In addition, the technology for providing extension
decentralisation, this can provide an impetus for private messages is changing and it is necessary to consider
extension, but if the decentralisation process itself is how things like FM radio (as well as more effective
badly managed, then the prospects are not good. use of traditional print media) can be marshalled in
Farmers’ organisations in particular are often seen as support of new extension modalities. The arrival of
the beneficiaries of privatised extension reforms but new information and communication technologies
they require long ter m investment to build (ICTs) has reduced the cost of information transfer and
organisational capacity before increased decision- is likely to continue to do so. Garforth et al. (2003)
making regarding extension service provision should suggest that farmers in developed countries are using
be transferred to them. Although a structure of farmer them increasingly for specific tasks such as business
groups and forums is being developed, much will planning. However, harnessing these technologies for

8
Changing incentives for agricultural extension…

resource poor farmers in developing countries is not There is also the problem that any private extension
straightforward and institutional arrangements are likely system will naturally tend to concentrate on those issues
to be as important as technical and investment concerns that have the highest immediate payoff to farmers. The
for improving extension services. It could be that a limited experience to date indicates that farmers
focus on improving the dissemination of under-utilised participating in private extension express much lower
information generated by public research through the demand for long-term environmental management
imaginative use of ICTs would be a useful strategy for issues. This has traditionally been an area of concern
the retained subsidised public extension service (although not necessarily of accomplishment) for public
(Chapman and Slaymaker, 2002). There are a number extension. It is important to understand how to structure
of agribusinesses using ICTs to strengthen their the incentives of private extension systems towards
competitive advantage whilst improving the information environmental concerns.
that farmers receive as producers (for processing and Table 2 summarises three European experiences in
export companies) or clients (for input suppliers). The which extension related to environmental management
Indian Tobacco Company (ITC) has established 1200 has been channelled through partially privatised
village information kiosks (e-chaupals) that place mechanisms. The use of the voucher system in the
computer terminals in villages. They cover a range of Netherlands (i) case has had only limited success, with
crop advice for over 750,000 farmers in four states. only 25% of farmers taking up the vouchers. Despite
Farmers receive information in the local language their face value of 227 Euros, farmers find the
through the company website on farming techniques procedures for cashing them in time consuming and
and other services such as district-level forecasts from many of the environmental policies have alienated the
the state Department of Meteorology. Farmers can send farmers sufficiently to prevent them from attempting
queries by email, access inputs and services from to achieve standards perceived to be unrealistic. On
partner organisations and verify the price at ITC’s the other hand, the small focussed study groups of the
procurement centres (Sulaiman, 2003). pilot study in the Netherlands (ii) case have proved
Public sector information and communication popular since their inception in 2001. This has proved
infrastructure already exists in the form of mass media more successful at encouraging farmers to tackle the
networks in many countries. The relevance of extension problems associated with nitrogen runoff management,
information can also be affected by the language and drinking water quality and ammonia emission through
culturally appropriate methods of dissemination. more holistic integrated farm management (Van
Vernacular radio dramas performed by local groups Weperen, 2003). The case of support to the viticulture
are one example of how information can be adapted producers in the Douro Valley of Portugal focussed on
to make it more context specific whilst at the same agro-environmental training and IPM practices. The IPM
time maximising its dissemination (Farrington, 1994; associations have strengthened their capacity through
Chapman et al., 2003). Both new and old ICTs can be the programme and more careful use of pesticides and
harnessed in this way and can be integrated to improve chemicals has been observed amongst the small-scale
the decentralised production of information materials. producers. The contractual arrangements are stringent,
Printed materials, for example, can offer more practical requiring farmers to attend courses, conform to IPM
and directly relevant information advice if farmers are rules, use IPM phytopharmaceutical products
encouraged to describe their own experiences in terms exclusively, and follow IPM association rules for a
that other farmers are likely to understand (Padre et minimum of five years. Farmers are requested to
al., 2003). document the biological cycle of the crop’s pests,

Table 2 Privatised extension approaches to promote environmental management priorities

Case Study Description Service Contractual Level of Service Beneficiaries Funding


Provider Arrangements
Netherlands Mineral Private Voucher system Training courses, 80,000 out of 18m Euros (farmers
(i) (a) management consultancy books, software, 110,000 arable and each get 227 Euro
support unit firm advice dairy farmers voucher)
established 2001
Netherlands Intensive dairy Dairy farmers Farmers’ Four study groups 40 farmers in Drenthe 260,000 Euros over
(ii) (b) farmers receive platform representatives and formed to follow Province 3 years from EU,
advice on sought private provincial officers programme provincial and
holistic sector support form guiding farmers’ org. funds
management committee
Portugal (c) Support to IPM Farmer receives Training, on-farm 38,000 producers EU (75%) and
small-scale associations subsidy and pays trials, individual with small (2-acre) government (25%)
viticulture 25% to IPM Assoc technical support farms important for
producers in of which must be a and info wine industry
Douro Valley. member

Source: a, b) Van Weperen, 2003 c) Cristóvão et al., 2002

9
Agricultural Research and Extension Network Paper No. 132

conduct periodical risk assessments and damage on public sector policy. Obligations for financing from
evaluations, and provide the information to a control the international community can be determined in
agent in a log book (Cristóvão et al., 2002). relation to the level of ‘global’ public goods in the
extension programme (Katz, 2002). Donor funding,
Targets however, has historically exhibited significant variability
The targeting of private extension is also an important over years and between regions, contributing to
issue. Although the demise of public extension may instability in planning and discontinuities in extension
be seen as an abandonment of the cause of resource- programmes. A review of World Bank lending for
poor farmers, that argument requires a specification of extension between 1981–2000 illustrates this variability
how well public extension has served the poor in the (Alex et al., 2002). Governments and donors
past. The term ‘private’ in agriculture is immediately undertaking extension reform need to consider not
associated with larger, commercial farmers, and indeed only the need for some degree of absolute public
the emergence of many types of private extension bears support for services but also the strategic impact of
this out. In this sense, poorer households may not be changes in funding over time. Phasing privatisation
able to take advantage of privatised extension. In the can assist in the process of institutional reform of the
case of Thuringia (Germany) in Table 1, the proportion national extension service provider, for example, during
of farmers seeking advice fell from 80% to 13% when the transition phase. In Holland, for example, the
the extension system was privatised, and the majority extension service (renamed DLV) was officially
of those requesting advice were farms of over 500 ha. privatised in 1990 but funding continued for five years
But the discussion has shown that there are also models albeit with a diminishing subsidy (10% per year). From
in which public funding and public policy can structure 1996–2000 competition for the government subsidy was
the incentives that characterise private markets in the limited to the DLV and the national farmers association
service of more equitable agricultural development. (LTO). The two organisations were allocated funds
This will not be an easy task, however, and it requires according to project proposals submitted in response
broad-based and knowledgeable participation from to the annual plan of the Ministry of Agriculture. This
farmers themselves and adequate monitoring and process ensured that these service providers were able
regulation. It is also acknowledged that this will require to rely on the public subsidy for part of their costs
a significant level of subsidy in those cases where there while adjusting to supply a private sector market for
are many resource-poor farming households who are their services over an extended period of time (Proost
not able to pay more than a fraction of the actual cost and Duijsings, 2002).
of the service provided. At a time when public
extension services are being severely cut (for budgetary 5 POLICY IMPLICATIONS
reasons), there is a need for devising the most cost- One of the most important conclusions from this review
effective system possible. of private extension experience is the amount of time
required to implement a transition from conventional
Funding public sector extension to a more agile and
Funding tends to be the focus of the debates on differentiated strategy that takes better advantage of
privatised extension. The impact of funding on the private incentives. Even in the European examples in
management of privatised extension has been discussed which public services were privatised in an
in terms of the different approaches that service environment of highly commercial agriculture, adequate
providers and farmers can be expected to use under time had to be allowed for the transition. In the case
different funding mechanisms. Many of the experiences of Chile, the developing country with the longest and
with privatised extension rely on a significant level of most extensive experience at implementing private
public sector funding. In the UK, where more complete extension modalities, the system is still evolving after
privatisation has taken place, the relative percentage 25 years. In Uganda, one of the most ambitious plans
would be expected to be small. In other countries such for the privatisation of extension in Africa envisions a
as Chile and Uganda, with partial privatisation, the similar time period for making the transition. Any policy
public sector contribution is likely to be much higher. aimed at introducing private extension needs to plan
The underlying factor of concern for many developing (and budget) for considerable experimentation and
countries with less dynamic agricultural sectors is that flexibility.
the level of public sector funding will most likely The experience of many experiments in privatised
continue to be a high proportion of the total. extension indicates that human resource development
Withdrawal of public funding, therefore, needs to be may be one of the most important bottlenecks. No
carefully managed to avoid the sudden decline in extension system, public or private, can function
farmers’ access to the service. Even with relatively without adequately trained and motivated personnel.
modest targets the process may take a long time; for As public extension systems decline because of lack
example farmer contribution in Chile is now only 10– of funding and poor management, their staff may leave
15% after 25 years. Contracting directly with service for other endeavours and not be available to participate
providers remains an option even for those in new strategies. Similarly, public support for education
governments that have privatised completely, such as and training is jeopardised when the public extension
the UK which may request ADAS or another competing service is in decline. Thus any plans for the
private organisation to provide certain advice based establishment of a privatised extension strategy cannot

10
Changing incentives for agricultural extension…

neglect attention to the public role in agricultural policies that focus on themes such as resource
education. In addition, extension agents working in conservation will require more time to find a place in
the private sector will require business and management privatised extension delivery. Finally, at least until the
skills that are not currently found in most agricultural emergence of a truly diverse and competitive market
curricula. of private extension providers, there will be the need
On the other side of the equation, a privatised for a public role in regulating the provision of private
extension system will only function if farmers are extension.
capable of articulating their needs, managing and
enforcing contracts with private extension providers, 6 CONCLUSIONS
and evaluating the results. Considerations of efficiency Agricultural extension has come to be so firmly
indicate that these functions will often need to be associated with the public sector that any talk of
managed by some type of farmer group or association privatisation risks sounding like the thoughtless
(unless farmers have very large holdings or are willing abandonment of goals for broad-based agricultural
to pay for individually tailored advice). The dilemma development and appearing as a mere pretence for
is that farmers’ groups require specific incentives (e.g., cutting public budgets. This review indicates that such
commodity marketing) in order to elicit broad-based fears are not warranted. In the first place, private
participation, and it is questionable whether contracting extension alternatives have been debated and
occasional extension services will be a sufficient developed precisely because of concerns with the poor
motivation for the emergence of sustainable groups. performance of much of public extension, including
Thus private extension may be delivered to farmer its inability to consistently deliver useful information
groups formed for purposes that have more economic to resource-poor farmers. Any critique of private
immediacy. One strategy to ease the burden on nascent extension should include an analysis of current and
farmer groups is to channel some of the contracting past performance of the public system. Secondly,
and evaluation of private extension through ‘privatisation’ in the case of agricultural extension
decentralised political structures. Ideally, this strategy implies a long-term transition to more responsive forms
not only eases the transition to the delivery of private of information delivery; that transition will require
extension that is more responsive to farmer needs, but significant public funding for the foreseeable future.
also represents the development of more responsive The goal is to make the public investment in extension
local government that can deliver public (agricultural more efficient, not to eliminate it. Although some types
and other) services as well. However, it is important to of private extension emerge spontaneously in the
recognise the serious challenges to establishing effective course of agricultural development, the more
decentralised political structures in developing countries challenging aspects require a combination of public
and to treat the linkage of privatised extension and policy and funding and the encouragement of an
decentralised politics with some caution. expanded range of professional capabilities in
In considering strategies to make better use of agricultural extension.
privatised extension modalities, policymakers will need An explanation of the nature of private extension
to draw links to other areas that have traditionally been requires an understanding of the possibility of
public responsibilities. Public agricultural research is separating the funding of extension activities from their
undergoing significant changes of its own, and these delivery. Under conventional agricultural extension, a
need to be examined in the context of the possibilities public agency was granted a yearly budget and was
for private extension delivery. In addition, the means responsible for all extension activities. Consideration
of communicating extension infor mation are of private extension recognises that public moneys can
diversifying rapidly, and ICTs offer possibilities for be used to fund private activities, and that public
improving the efficiency of public media as well as services may benefit from private (cost-recovery)
opening new horizons for private information delivery. revenues. The single most important feature of
Policies that support the development of a privatised extension systems is not a change in the
comprehensive ICT policy can make a big difference source of funds but rather a change in the nature of
to the performance of private extension options. incentives that drive information provision. There are
Finally, there are several responsibilities that remain certainly many instances of dedicated public extension
firmly in the public domain. A shift towards privatised personnel who labour to meet the needs of client
extension strategies can only be justified if it improves farmers. Nevertheless, much public extension is
the efficiency of service and meets the needs of the characterised by the mechanical delivery of messages
majority of the farming population. In developing and an almost total lack of feedback mechanisms. The
countries, privatised extension systems will have to be key to privatised extension is to devise modalities
structured so that the majority of resource-poor farmers through which farmers can express their requirements
receive better service than they do under the public and evaluate the results. The ideal would be a
extension system. Thus farming populations, areas and competitive, private market for agricultural information,
themes that are not amenable to some type of privatised affordable to all and responsive to farmers’ needs. The
extension approach will remain as public realities of agricultural development and the nature of
responsibilities. It is likely that it will take a longer agricultural information make that ideal difficult to
time for any privatised extension system to reach more realise. Therefore privatisation represents a much more
remote areas, for instance. As well, public agricultural difficult series of experiments to elicit the most

11
Agricultural Research and Extension Network Paper No. 132

responsive and equitable system possible, under a Chapman, R. and Tripp, R. (2003) ‘Case studies of
given set of circumstances. agricultural extension programmes using privatised
The signs so far indicate that some progress has service provision’. Prepared for AgREN electronic
already been made, but that we have much to learn discussion 10–21 March, 2003 and posted on
and many more experiments to carry out and evaluate. conference website: www.rimisp.cl/agren03
Concerns include the skills and incentives available Chuang, N. Swanson, B. and Yan, F. (2002) ‘Financing
for the providers; the capacities of the farmers to extension: Lessons from China in extension and rural
contract for the service; the fact that some types of development: A convergence of views on
service are much more amenable to private provision institutional approaches?’ Workshop papers;
than others; and the importance of assessing the equity November, 2002, IFPRI, Washington, D.C.
implications of any reform in extension policy. A Coldevin, G (2000) Participatory communication and
conclusion of the recent AgREN discussion on private adult learning for rural development. Rome: FAO
extension was that considerable time and Cristóvão, A., Alves, F. and Koehnen, T. (2002) ‘Portugal:
experimentation were required for the evolution of Contracting for IPM extension by the Association
any comprehensive strategy. There is a crucial need for Viticultural Development in the Douro Valley’
for more experience, evaluation and analysis from the in W.M. Rivera, and W. Zijp (2002) Contracting for
field to help guide that process. agricultural extension. International case studies
and emerging practices. Washington D.C.: CABI
REFERENCES Publishing.
Alex, G., Zijp, W. Byerlee, D. (2002) ‘Rural extension Currle, J., Hoffmann, V. and Kidd, A. (2002) ‘Federal
and advisory services: New directions’. Rural Republic of Germany: Contracting for agricultural
Strategy Background Paper, No. 9. Washington, extension Thuringia’ in W.M. Rivera, and W.Zijp
D.C.: AKIS Thematic Team, World Bank. (2002) Contracting for agricultural extension.
Benziger, V. (1996) ‘Small fields, big money: Two International case studies and emerging practices.
successful programs in helping small farmers make Washington D.C.: CABI Publishing.
the transition to high value-added crops’. World Estrada, R., Holmann, F. and Posada, R. (2002) ‘Farmer
Development, Vol. 24, No. 11, pp. 1681–1693. and industry funding of agricultural research in
Berdegué, J. (2001) Cooperating to compete. Colombia’ in Byerlee and Echeverria (eds).
Associative peasant business firms in Chile. PhD Farrington, J. (1994) ‘Public sector agricultural
Thesis, Wageningen Agricultural University. extension: Is there life after structural adjustment?’
Berdegué, J. and Marchant, C. (2002) ‘Chile: the Natural Resource Perspectives No. 2. London:
evolution of the Agricultural Advisory Service for Overseas Development Institute.
Small Farmers: 1978–2000’ in W.M. Rivera, and Farrington, J., Christopolos, I., Kidd, A. and Beckman,
W. Zijp (2002) Contracting for agricultural M. (2002) ‘Can extension contribute to rural poverty
extension. International case studies and emerging reduction? Synthesis of a six country study’.
practices. Washington D.C.: CABI Publishing. Agricultural Research and Extension Network Paper
Bingen, R.J. and Brinkerhoff, D.W. (2000) ‘Agricultural No. 123. London: Overseas Development Institute.
research in Africa and the Sustainable Financing Garforth, C. (2002) ‘ADAS and the privatisation of
Initiative’. Technical Paper No. 112. Washington, advisory services in England and Wales’ in IFPRI
D.C.: Office of Sustainable Development, Bureau (2002) ‘Extension and rural development: a
for Africa, USAID. convergence of views on institutional approaches?’
Byerlee, D. and Echeverria, R. (eds) (2002) Agricultural Workshop November 12–14, 2002, International
research in an era of privatization. Wallingford, UK: Food and Policy Research Institute, Washington, D.C.
CABI Publishing. Garforth, C., Angell, B., Archer, J., and Green, K. (2003)
Carney (1998) Changing public and private roles in ‘Improving farmers’ access to advice on land
agricultural service provision. London: Overseas management: Lessons from case studies in
Development Institute. developed countries’. Agricultural Research and
Catley, A. (1996) Pastoralists, paravets and privatisation: Extension Network Paper No. 125. London: Overseas
experiences in the Sanaag region of Somaliland. Development Institute.
Pastoral Development Network Paper 39d. London: Hanson, J. and Just, E. (2001) ‘The potential for
Overseas Development Institute. transition to paid extension: Some guiding
Chapman, R. and Slaymaker, T. (2002) ‘ICTs and rural principles’, American Journal of Agricultural
devlopment: Review of the literature, current Economics Vol. 83, p.777–784.
interventions and opportunities for action’ ODI Hoffmann, V., Lamers, J. and Kidd, A. (2000) ‘Reforming
Working Paper No. 192. London: Overseas the organisation of agricultural extension in
Development Institute. Germany: Lessons for other countries’, Agricultural
Chapman, R., Blench, R., Kranjac-Berisavljevic’, G., and Research and Extension Network Paper No. 98.
Zakariah, A. (2003) ‘Rural radio in agricultural London: Overseas Development Institute.
extension: the example of vernacular radio Hubbard, M. (1995) ‘The “new public management”
programmes on soil and water conservation in and the reform of public services to agriculture in
N.Ghana’. Agricultural Research and Extension adjusting economies: the role of contracting’. Food
Network Paper No. 127. London: ODI. Policy, Vol.20, No.6, pp. 529–536; Elsevier Science.

12
Changing incentives for agricultural extension…

Katz, E. (2002) Innovative approaches to financing Rivera, W. (2001) Agriculture and rural extension
extension for agriculture and natural resource worldwide. Options for institutional reform in the
management. Conceptual considerations and developing countries. Rome: FAO.
analysis of experience. Contributions from Armin Rivera, W., Zijp, W. and Alex, G. (2000) ‘Contracting
Barandun. Lindau, Switzerland: LBL Swiss Center for extension. Review of emerging practices’.
for agricultural Extension. Agricultural Knowledge and Information Systems
Key, N. and Runsten, D. (1999) ‘Contract farming, Good Practice Note. Washington D.C.: World Bank.
smallholders, and rural development in Latin Rivera, W.M. and Zijp, W. (2002) Contracting for
America: The organization of agroprocessing firms agricultural extension. International case studies
and the scale of outgrower production’. World and emerging practices. Washington D.C.: CABI
Development, Vol. 27, No. 2, pp. 381–401. Publishing.
Kidd, A., Lamers, J., Ficarelli, P., Hoffmann, V. (2000) Roling, N. (1995) ‘What to think of extension? A
‘Privatising agricultural extension: caveat emptor’, comparison of three models of extension practice’.
Journal of Rural Studies Vol. 16, pp. 95–102. AERDD Bulletin. Reading, UK: University of Reading.
Kunstadter, P. (1987) ‘Swiddeners in transition: Luá Roy, Sabyasachi (2003) ‘Livestock extension services
farmers in northern Thailand’ in B. L. Turner II and by milk producers cooperatives: Indian experience’.
S. B. Brush (eds) Comparative farming systems. New Paper prepared for AgREN electronic discussion on
York: The Guilford Press. privatised extension, March 2003.
Leonard, D. K. (1993) ‘Structural reform of the veterinary Shekara, C., and Charyulu, A. (2002) Agriculture to
profession in Africa and the New Institutional agripreneurship: Success stories of agripreneurs.
Economics’. Development and Change Vol. 24, Hyderabad: National Institute of Agriculture
pp. 227–267. Extension Management (MANAGE).
Loolaid, U. (2002) ‘Estonia: The role of contracting for Sulaiman, R. (2003) ‘Private extension in India: Recent
private agricultural advisory services’ in W. Rivera, Initiatives’. Agricultural Research and Extension
and W. Zijp, (2002) Contracting for agricultural Network Newsletter No. 47. London: Overseas
extension. International case studies and emerging Development Institute.
practices. Washington D.C.: CABI Publishing. Sulaiman, R. and V.V. Sadamate, (2000) Privatising
Nahdy, S. (2002) ‘The role of extension in rural agricultural extension in India. Policy Paper No.
development. The Ugandan National Agricultural 10, New Delhi: National Centre for Agricultural
National Agricultural Advisory Services (NAADS) in Economics and Policy Research (NCAP).
Extension and Rural Development: a convergence Sulaiman, R. and Van den Ban, A.W. (2003) ‘Funding
of views on institutional approaches?’ Workshop and delivering agricultural extension in India’.
papers; November, 2002, IFPRI, Washington, D.C. Journal of International Agricultural and Extension
Opio-Odongo,J. (2000) ‘Roles and challenges of Education, Vol. 10, No. 1.
agricultural extension in Africa’ in S. Breth, (ed.) Schwartz, L.A. (1994) The role of the private sector in
(2000) Innovative extension education in Africa. agricultural extension: Economic analysis and case
Second workshop on training mid-career agricultural studies. Agricultural Administration ( Research and
extension professionals. Sasakawa Africa Extension) Network Network Paper No. 48. London:
Association, Mexico City, 2000. Overseas Development Institute.
Padre, S., Sudarshana, and Tripp, R. (2003) ‘Reforming Swanson, B., Samy, M. and O’Rourke, P. (2002) ‘USA-
agricultural journalism. The experience of Adike Illinois: Contracting for precision agricultural
Pathrike in India’. Agricultural Research and services’ in W.M. Rivera, and W. Zijp (2002)
Extension Network Paper No. 128. London: Overseas Contracting for agricultural extension.
Development Institute. International case studies and emerging practices.
Plaas, K. (2003) ‘Agricultural Development Project Vaida Wallingford, UK: CABI Publishing.
in Romania’. Case study submitted to the AgREN Umali, D. and L. Schwartz (1993) ‘Public and private
electronic discussion on privatisation of agricultural agricultural extension: Beyond traditional frontiers’.
extension. World Bank Discussion Paper No. 236. Washington
Porter, G. and Phillips-Howard, K. (1997) ‘Comparing D.C.: World Bank.
contracts: An evaluation of contract farming schemes Van den Ban, A. (2000) ‘Different ways of financing
in Africa’. World Development, Vol. 25, No. 2, agricultural extension’. Agricultural Research and
pp. 227–238. Extension Network paper 106b. London: Overseas
Proost, J. and Duijsings, P. (2002) The Netherlands: Development Institute.
Going Dutch in extension, 10 years of experiences Van Weperen,W. (2003) ‘The voucher system for
with privatised extension in W. Rivera, and W. Zijp, information on fertiliser management in the
(2002) Contracting for agricultural extension. Netherlands and Dairy farmers’ platform: Intensive,
International case studies and emerging practices. high input dairy farming’. Case studies submitted
Washington D.C.: CABI Publishing. to AgREN electronic discussion on privatisation of
Reifschneider, F., Byerlee, D., de Souza, F. (eds) (2000) agricultural extension.
Competitive grants in the new millenium: A global Wolf, S. and Zilberman, D. (2001) Knowledge
workshop for designers and practitioners. Brasilia: generation and technical change: Institutional
EMPAPA/IDB/World Bank. innovation in agriculture. Norwell, M.A.: Kluwer.

13
Agricultural Research and Extension Network Paper No. 132

14
Changing incentives for agricultural extension…

15
Network Papers cost £3.00 sterling each (plus postage & packing).
This paper may be downloaded free of charge from the AgREN website at: www.odi.org.uk/agren
Please contact the Network Administrator at:
The Overseas Development Institute, 111 Westminster Bridge Road, London SE1 7JD, UK
Telephone: +44 (0)20 7922 0300 Fax: +44 (0)20 7922 0399 Email: agren@odi.org.uk

Information about ODI and its publications can be found on our website at:
http://www.odi.org.uk/

You might also like