Download as docx, pdf, or txt
Download as docx, pdf, or txt
You are on page 1of 6

Home 

     Discussion      Topics      Dictionary      Almanac
Signup       Login
Price elasticity of demand

Price elasticity of demand


 Topic Home
 Discussion
Discussion

Ask a question about 'Price elasticity of demand'

Start a new discussion about 'Price elasticity of demand'

Answer questions from other users

Full Discussion Forum


 

Encyclopedia
Price elasticity of demand (PED or Ed) is a measure used in economics to show the responsiveness, or elasticity, of
the quantity demanded of a good or service to a change in its price. More precisely, it gives the percentage change in
quantity demanded in response to a one percent change in price (holding constant all the other determinants of
demand, such as income). It was devised by Alfred Marshall.

Price elasticities are almost always negative, although analysts tend to ignore the sign even though this can lead to
ambiguity. Only goods which do not conform to the law of demand, such as Veblen and Giffen goods, have a positive
PED. In general, the demand for a good is said to be inelastic (or relatively inelastic) when the PED is less than one
(in absolute value): that is, changes in price have a relatively small effect on the quantity of the good demanded. The
demand for a good is said to be elastic (or relatively elastic) when its PED is greater than one (in absolute value): that
is, changes in price have a relatively large effect on the quantity of a good demanded.

Revenue is maximised when price is set so that the PED is exactly one. The PED of a good can also be used to
predict the incidence (or "burden") of a tax on that good. Various research methods are used to determine price
elasticity, including test markets, analysis of historical sales data and conjoint analysis.
Definition
PED is a measure of the sensitivity (or responsiveness) of the quantity of a good or service demanded to changes in
its price. The formula for the coefficient of price elasticity of demand for a good is:
The above formula usually yields a negative value, due to the inverse nature of the relationship between price and
quantity demanded, as described by the "law of demand". For example, if the price increases by 5% and quantity
demanded decreases by 5%, then the elasticity at the initial price and quantity = −5%/5% = −1. The only classes of
goods which have a PED of greater than 0 are Veblen and Giffen goods. Because the PED is negative for the vast
majority of goods and services, however, economists often refer to price elasticity of demand as a positive value (i.e.,
in absolute value terms).

This measure of elasticity is sometimes referred to as the own-price elasticity of demand for a good, i.e., the elasticity
of demand with respect to the good's own price, in order to distinguish it from the elasticity of demand for that good
with respect to the change in the price of some other good, i.e., a complementary or substitute good. The latter type
of elasticity measure is called a cross-price elasticity of demand.

As the difference between the two prices or quantities increases, the accuracy of the PED given by the formula
abovedecreases for a combination of two reasons. First, the PED for a good is not necessarily constant; as explained
below, PED can vary at different points along the demand curve, due to its percentage nature. Elasticity is not the
same thing as the slope of the demand curve, which is dependent on the units used for both price and quantity.
Second, percentage changes are not symmetric; instead, the percentage change between any two values depends
on which one is chosen as the starting value and which as the ending value. For example, if quantity demanded
increases from 10 units to 15 units, the percentage change is 50%, i.e., (15 − 10) ÷ 10 (converted to a percentage).
But if quantity demanded decreases from 15 units to 10 units, the percentage change is −33.3%, i.e., (15 − 10) ÷ 15.

Two alternative elasticity measures avoid or minimise these shortcomings of the basic elasticity formula: point-price
elasticityand arc elasticity.
Point-price elasticity

One way to avoid the accuracy problem described above is to minimise the difference between the starting and
ending prices and quantities. This is the approach taken in the definition of point-price elasticity, which
uses differential calculus to calculate the elasticity for an infinitesimal change in price and quantity at any given point

on the demand curve: 

In other words, it is equal to the absolute value of the first derivative of quantity with respect to price (dQd/dP)
multiplied by the point's price (P) divided by its quantity (Qd).

In terms of partial-differential calculus, point-price elasticity of demand can be defined as follows: let   be the
demand of goods   as a function of parameters price and wealth, and let   be the
demand for good  . The elasticity of demand for good   with respect to price   is

However, the point-price elasticity can be computed only if the formula for the demand function,  , is
known so its derivative with respect to price,  , can be determined.
Arc elasticity

A second solution to the asymmetry problem of having a PED dependent on which of the two given points on a
demand curve is chosen as the "original" point and which as the "new" one is to compute the percentage change in P
and Q relative to theaverage of the two prices and the average of the two quantities, rather than just the change
relative to one point or the other. Loosely speaking, this gives an "average" elasticity for the section of the actual
demand curve—i.e., the arc of the curve—between the two points. As a result, this measure is known as the arc
elasticity, in this case with respect to the price of the good. The arc elasticity is defined mathematically as:

This method for computing the price elasticity is also known as the "midpoints formula", because the average price
and average quantity are the coordinates of the midpoint of the straight line between the two given points. However,
because this formula implicitly assumes the section of the demand curve between those points is linear, the greater
the curvature of the actual demand curve is over that range, the worse this approximation of its elasticity will be.
History
Together with the concept of an economic "elasticity" coefficient, Alfred Marshall is credited with defining PED
("elasticity of demand") in his book Principles of Economics, published in 1890. He described it thus: "And we may
say generally:— the elasticity (or responsiveness) of demand in a market is great or small according as the amount
demanded increases much or little for a given fall in price, and diminishes much or little for a given rise in price". He
reasons this since "the only universal law as to a person's desire for a commodity is that it diminishes... but this
diminution may be slow or rapid. If it is slow... a small fall in price will cause a comparatively large increase in his
purchases. But if it is rapid, a small fall in price will cause only a very small increase in his purchases. In the former
case... the elasticity of his wants, we may say, is great. In the latter case... the elasticity of his demand is small."
Mathematically, the Marshallian PED was based on a point-price definition, using differential calculus to calculate
elasticities.
Determinants
The overriding factor in determining PED is the willingness and ability of consumers after a price change to postpone
immediate consumption decisions concerning the good and to search for substitutes ("wait and look"). A number of
factors can thus affect the elasticity of demand for a good:
 Availability of substitute goods: the more and closer the substitutes available, the higher the elasticity is
likely to be, as people can easily switch from one good to another if an even minor price change is made;
 Percentage of income: the higher the percentage of the consumer's income that the product's price
represents, the higher the elasticity tends to be, as people will pay more attention when purchasing the good
because of its cost;
 Necessity: the more necessary a good is, the lower the elasticity, as people will attempt to buy it no matter
the price, such as the case of insulin for those that need it.
 Duration: for most goods, the longer a price change holds, the higher the elasticity is likely to be, as more
and more consumers find they have the time and inclination to search for substitutes. When fuel prices
increase suddenly, for instance, consumers may still fill up their empty tanks in the short run, but when
prices remain high over several years, more consumers will reduce their demand for fuel by switching
to carpooling or public transportation, investing in vehicles with greater fuel economy or taking other
measures. This does not hold for consumer durables such as the cars themselves, however; eventually, it
may become necessary for consumers to replace their present cars, so one would expect demand to be less
elastic.
 Breadth of definition of a good: the broader the definition of a good (or service), the lower the elasticity.
For example, Company X's fish and chips would tend to have a relatively high elasticity of demand if a
significant number of substitutes are available, whereas food in general would have an extremely low
elasticity of demand because no substitutes exist.
 Brand loyalty: an attachment to a certain brand—either out of tradition or because of proprietary barriers—
can override sensitivity to price changes, resulting in more inelastic demand.
 Who pays: where the purchaser does not directly pay for the good they consume, such as with corporate
expense accounts, demand is likely to be more inelastic.

Interpreting values of price elasticity coefficients

Elasticities of demand are interpreted as follows:

Value Descriptive Terms

Ed = 0 Perfectly inelastic demand


- 1 < Ed < 0 Inelastic or relatively inelastic demand

Ed = - 1 Unit elastic, unit elasticity, unitary elasticity, or unitarily elastic demand

- ∞ < Ed < - 1 Elastic or relatively elastic demand

Ed = - ∞ Perfectly elastic demand

A decrease in the price of a good normally results in an increase in the quantity demanded by consumers because of
the law of demand, and conversely, quantity demanded decreases when price rises. As summarized in the table
above, the PED for a good or service is referred to by different descriptive terms depending on whether the elasticity
coefficient is greater than, equal to, or less than −1. That is, the demand for a good is called:
 relatively inelastic when the percentage change in quantity demanded is less than the percentage change in
price (so that Ed > - 1);
 unit elastic, unit elasticity, unitary elasticity, or unitarily elastic demand when the percentage change in
quantity demanded is equal to the percentage change in price (so that Ed = - 1); and
 relatively elastic when the percentage change in quantity demanded is greater than the percentage change
in price (so that Ed < - 1).

As the two accompanying diagrams show, perfectly elastic demand is represented graphically as a horizontal line,
andperfectly inelastic demand as a vertical line. These are the only cases in which the PED and the slope of the
demand curve (∆P/∆Q) are both constant, as well as the only cases in which the PED is determined solely by the
slope of the demand curve (or more precisely, by the inverse of that slope).
Effect on total revenue
A firm considering a price change must know what effect the change in price will have on total revenue. Generally
any change in price will have two effects:
 the price effect : an increase in unit price will tend to increase revenue, while a decrease in price will tend to
decrease revenue.
 the quantity effect : an increase in unit price will tend to lead to fewer units sold, while a decrease in unit
price will tend to lead to more units sold.

Because of the inverse nature of the relationship between price and quantity demanded (i.e., the law of demand), the
two effects affect total revenue in opposite directions. But in determining whether to increase or decrease prices, a
firm needs to know what the net effect will be. Elasticity provides the answer: The percentage change in total revenue
is equal to the percentage change in quantity demanded plus the percentage change in price. (One change will be
positive, the other negative.)

As a result, the relationship between PED and total revenue can be described for any good:
 When the price elasticity of demand for a good is perfectly inelastic (Ed = 0), changes in the price do not
affect the quantity demanded for the good; raising prices will cause total revenue to increase.
 When the price elasticity of demand for a good is relatively inelastic (- 1 < Ed < 0), the percentage change in
quantity demanded is smaller than that in price. Hence, when the price is raised, the total revenue rises, and
vice versa.
 When the price elasticity of demand for a good is unit (or unitary) elastic (Ed = -1), the percentage change in
quantity is equal to that in price, so a change in price will not affect total revenue.
 When the price elasticity of demand for a good is relatively elastic (- ∞ < Ed < - 1), the percentage change in
quantity demanded is greater than that in price. Hence, when the price is raised, the total revenue falls, and
vice versa.
 When the price elasticity of demand for a good is perfectly elastic (Ed is − ∞), any increase in the price, no
matter how small, will cause demand for the good to drop to zero. Hence, when the price is raised, the total
revenue falls to zero.

Hence, as the accompanying diagram shows, total revenue is maximised at the combination of price and quantity
demanded where the elasticity of demand is unitary.

It is important to realise that price-elasticity of demand is not necessarily constant over all price ranges. The linear
demand curve in the accompanying diagram illustrates that changes in price also change the elasticity: the price
elasticity is different at every point on the curve.
Effect on tax incidence
PEDs, in combination with price elasticity of supply (PES), can be used to assess where the incidence (or "burden")
of a per-unit tax is falling or to predict where it will fall if the tax is imposed. For example, when demand is perfectly
inelastic, by definition consumers have no alternative to purchasing the good or service if the price increases, so the
quantity demanded would remain constant. Hence, suppliers can increase the price by the full amount of the tax, and
the consumer would end up paying the entirety. In the opposite case, when demand is perfectly elastic, by definition
consumers have an infinite ability to switch to alternatives if the price increases, so they would stop buying the good
or service in question completely—quantity demanded would fall to zero. As a result, firms cannot pass on any part of
the tax by raising prices, so they would be forced to pay all of it themselves.

In practice, demand is likely to be only relatively elastic or relatively inelastic, that is, somewhere between the
extreme cases of perfect elasticity or inelasticity. More generally, then, the higher the elasticity of demand compared
to PES, the heavier the burden on producers; conversely, the more inelastic the demand compared to PES, the
heavier the burden on consumers. The general principle is that the party (i.e., consumers or producers) that
has fewer opportunities to avoid the tax by switching to alternatives will bear the greater proportion of the tax burden.
Selected price elasticities
Various research methods are used to calculate price elasticities in real life, including analysis of historic sales data,
both public and private, and use of present-day surveys of customers' preferences to build up test markets capable of
modelling such changes. Alternatively, conjoint analysis (a ranking of users' preferences which can then be
statistically analysed) may be used.

Though PEDs for most demand schedules vary depending on price, they can be modeled assuming constant
elasticity. Using this method, the PEDs for various goods – intended to act as examples of the theory described
above - are as follows. For suggestions on why these goods and services may have the PED shown, see the above
section on determinants of price elasticity.
 Cigarettes (US)
o -0.3 to -0.6 (General)
o -0.6 to -0.7 (Youth)
 Alcoholic beverages (US)
o -0.3 or -0.7 to -0.9 as of 1972 (Beer)
o -1.0 (Wine)
o -1.5 (Spirits)
 Airline travel (US)
o -0.3 (First Class)
o -0.9 (Discount)
o -1.5 (for Pleasure Travelers)
 Livestock
o -0.5 to -0.6 (Broiler Chickens)
 Oil (World)
o -0.4
 Car fuel
o -0.25 (Short run)
o -0.64 (Long run)
 Medicine (US)
o -0.31 (Medical insurance)
o -.03 to -.06 (Pediatric Visits)

 Rice
o -0.47 (Austria)
o -0.8 (Bangladesh)
o -0.8 (China)
o -0.25 (Japan)
o -0.55 (US)
 Cinema visits (US)
o -0.87 (General)
 Live Performing Arts (Theater, etc.)
o -0.4 to -0.9
 Transport
o -0.20 (Bus travel US)
o -2.8 (Ford compact automobile)
 Soft drinks
o -0.8 to -1.0 (general)
o -3.8 (Coca-Cola)
o -4.4 (Mountain Dew)
 Steel
o -0.2 to -0.3

See also
 Arc elasticity
 Cross elasticity of demand
 Income elasticity of demand
 Price elasticity of supply
 Supply and demand
 Yield elasticity of bond value

External links
 Approx. PED of Various Products (U.S.)
 Approx. PED of Various Home-Consumed Foods (U.K.)
The source of this article is wikipedia, the free encyclopedia.  The text of this article is licensed under the GFDL.
AbsoluteAstronomy.com © 2010.  All Rights Reserved.   About  |  Privacy Policy  |  Terms of Use  |  Contact  

You might also like