Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 6

American Economic Association

Why, Indeed, in America? Theory, History, and the Origins of Modern Economic Growth
Author(s): Paul M. Romer
Source: The American Economic Review, Vol. 86, No. 2, Papers and Proceedings of the
Hundredth and Eighth Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association San
Francisco, CA, January 5-7, 1996 (May, 1996), pp. 202-206
Published by: American Economic Association
Stable URL: https://www.jstor.org/stable/2118123
Accessed: 18-09-2018 08:22 UTC

REFERENCES
Linked references are available on JSTOR for this article:
https://www.jstor.org/stable/2118123?seq=1&cid=pdf-reference#references_tab_contents
You may need to log in to JSTOR to access the linked references.

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
https://about.jstor.org/terms

American Economic Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend
access to The American Economic Review

This content downloaded from 91.230.41.203 on Tue, 18 Sep 2018 08:22:39 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Why, Indeed, in America? Theory, History, and the Origins
of Modern Economic Growth

By PAUL M. ROMER *

Whether new growth theory and economic In addition, differences in rates of invest-
history are a good match depends on the kind ment in the two countries were not the result
of question one addresses and the kind of an- of exogenous differences in savings rates. The
swer one expects. I find that they complement remarkable fact about the British economy
each other when I try to answer questions during this period is how much of domestic
about the world. Economists who believe that savings was devoted to investment abroad. In
these lines of inquiry can go their separate the decade prior to 1913, net domestic invest-
ways are addressing entirely different kinds of ment was roughly equal to net foreign invest-
questions or have a different notion of what it ment (A. K. Cairncross, 1953 p. 121). By
means to give a good answer. 1914, net foreign assets were equal to 1.5
times GDP. To understand what happened in
I. Growth without History Britain, one must explain why investment
abroad, especially in the United States, was so
Many recent attempts at testing models of attractive to British savers.
growth proceed without making any reference It is difficult to look at the data for these two
to evidence from economic history. They rely countries without wondering whether the well-
on data series for many countries, typically for documented technological developments in
the last 30 or so years. They focus on questions the United States are not part of the story. Nev-
about models instead of questions about the ertheless, the standard model-testing exercise
world. A representative conclusion is that the does not even consider this possibility. Nor
right model of economic growth is neoclas- does it seek out any direct evidence that would
sical in an extreme sense: it assumes that help one decide how important any differences
technology is the same in all countries and in the technology might have been. This would
concludes that exogenous differences in sav- be a glaring flaw if the goal truly were to un-
ing and education cause all of the observed derstand events in the world, but it is as natural
differences in levels of income and rates of as a null hypothesis if all one wants to do is
growth (N. Gregory Mankiw, 1995). test models.
However, to take a specific case, differences
in saving and education do not explain why II. History without Theory
growth was so much faster in the United States
than it was in Britain around the turn of this A second approach recognizes the value of
century. In 1870, per capita income in the United economic history but denies the need for for-
States was 75 percent of per capita income in mal theory. It shows up each time someone
Britain. By 1929, it had increased to 130 percent. proposes a new piece of mathematical formal-
In the intervening decades, years of education ism. Only 30 years ago many economists still
per worker increased by a factor of 2.2 in Britain objected to a mathematical statement of the
and by a nearly identical factor of 2.3 in the relationship between output and capital in
United States. In 1929, this variable remained terms of an aggregate production function and
slightly lower in the United States. (Data are an aggregate stock of capital, Y = F(K, L).
taken from Angus Maddison [1995].)' Twenty years ago, a different group of econ-
omists objected when labor economists used
mathematical equations and a new human-
* Department of Economics, University of California,
Berkeley, CA 94720. Comments by Gavin Wright are
gratefully acknowledged. This work was supported by the
Canadian Institute for Advanced Research. in the United States are flawed. Final judgment about the
' Note added in proof: Recent work by Claudia Goldin importance of education should be withheld until better
(pers. comm.) suggests that Maddison's data on education evidence becomes available.

202

This content downloaded from 91.230.41.203 on Tue, 18 Sep 2018 08:22:39 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
VOL 86 NO. 2 NEW GROWTH THEORY AND ECONOMIC HISTORY 203

capital variable H to capture the observation the behavior of the whole engine, I now
that a person's skills could be enhanced by in- turn my curiosity on the steam governor
vesting in education or experience. Ten years itself.
ago, many economists readily acknowledged
that output of knowledge must somehow be The central element in this account of what
related to the inputs devoted to the production Dawkins calls hierarchical reductionism is a
of knowledge, but they objected nevertheless recognition that explanation operates on many
when growth theorists suggested that econo- levels that must be consistent with each other.
mists make another try at capturing these re- What theories do is take all the available
lationships using mathematical expressions of complicated information about the world and
the form dAldt = G(H, A). organize it into this kind of hierarchical
Every time a familiar argument is trans- structure.
lated for the first time from natural language In building this structure, good theory in-
into mathematics, the same objections arise. dicates how to carve a system at the joints. At
"These equations are so simplistic, and the each level, theory breaks a system down into
world is so complicated." This reflects a mis- a simple collection of subsystems that interact
apprehension of the role of formal theory. Set in a meaningful way. Dawkins could have
aside models. The key is to understand what it used a simple theory that makes a bad split of
means to answer a question about the world. the engine into its front and back halves. In-
In the lead-up to his exposition of evolutionary stead, he uses a simple theory that makes a
theory, Richard Dawkins (1986 p. 11) gives good split into the fire-box, the boiler, and so
a refreshingly straightforward description of on. What growth theory must do is provide a
what constitutes a good answer to a such a good, simple split of the opportunities avail-
question: able in the physical world.

If I ask an engineer how a steam engine Ill. Neoclassical versus New Growth Theory
works, I have a pretty fair idea of the
general kind of answer that would satisfy
Neoclassical growth theory explains growth
me. Like Julian Huxley, I should defi-
in terms of interactions between two basic
nitely not be impressed if the engineer
said that it was propelled by "force lo- types of factors: technology and conventional
comotif:" And if he started boring on inputs. At the next level, conventional inputs
about the whole being greater than the are subdivided into physical capital, labor, and
sum of its parts, I would interrupt him: human capital. The initial split into technology
"Never mind about that, tell me how it and conventional inputs is promising, because
works." What I would want to hear is technology does differ from all other inputs.
something about how the parts of an en- However, for technical reasons, neoclassical
gine interact with each other to produce
theory mapped this split onto the theoretical
the behavior of the whole engine. I
dichotomy between public and private goods.
would initially be prepared to accept
This means that the theory leads to a dead end
an explanation in terms of quite large
subcomponents, whose own internal when one tries to understand the details about
structure and behavior might be quite technology in a second-stage analysis analo-
complicated and, as yet, unexplained. gous to Dawkins's investigation of the steam
The units of an initially satisfying expla- governor. Technology in the model does not
nation could have names like fire-box, correspond to anything in the world. It is pos-
boiler, cylinder, piston, steam governor. sible to understand capital in terms of things
... Given that the units each do their par- like machine tools that can be observed, but
ticular thing, I can then understand how
for a description of technology, neoclassical
they interact to make the whole engine
theory only relates to things that live in mod-
move.
Of course I am then at liberty to ask els-shifting production possibility frontiers
how each part works. Having previously and the like.
accepted thefact that the steam governor The obvious real-world candidates for tech-
regulates the flow of steam, and having nology simply are not public goods. For ex-
used this fact in my understanding of ample, a promising line of work in the 1960's

This content downloaded from 91.230.41.203 on Tue, 18 Sep 2018 08:22:39 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
204 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY 1996

studied embodied technological change. Im- be worth far less than if it could be used all
plicitly, it modeled technology as designs for over the world. If there were only a few olive
machines. This line of work lost its momen- trees, no one would have bothered to figure out
tum, perhaps because of the difficulty people how to use the olives. If people can sometimes
had in reconciling what is known about ma- establish property rights over a nonrival good
chine design with an initial cut that makes like an operating system or a recipe (a possi-
technology a public good. In their evolution- bility precluded by the public-good approach)
ary alternative to neoclassical growth theory, differences in scale will change the rewards
Richard Nelson and Sidney Winter (1982) for producing new ideas.
rejected the public-good assumption and
represented technology as routines followed IV. Why in America?
within firms. Recent generations of neoclassical
growth theorists have not followed up on either A great deal of historical analysis has ad-
approach and have contented themselves with dressed the performance of the British and
a force locomotif explanation: "Technological American economies around the turn of the
change causes economic growth." century. For general discussions, see Nathan
New growth theory started on the technology- Rosenberg (1981), Nelson and Gavin Wright
as-public-good path and worried about where (1992), and Moses Abramovitz and Paul
technology came from, but it soon backed up David (1996). From the beginning, observers
and reconsidered the initial split that econo- have pointed to the abundance of natural re-
mists make in the physical world. New growth sources in the United States as an early advan-
theorists now start by dividing the world into tage, especially in agriculture. The surprising
two fundamentally different types of produc- conclusion that emerges from recent historical
tive inputs that can be called "ideas" and scholarship is that resource abundance also in-
"things." Ideas are nonrival goods that could teracted with scale to create a technological
be stored in a bit string. Things are rival lead in manufacturing that persisted well into
goods with mass (or energy). With ideas and the 20th century.
things, one can explain how economic growth The United States started as little more
works. Nonrival ideas can be used to rearrange than an importer of European technology,
things, for example, when one follows a recipe but by the first decades of the 19th century,
and transforms noxious olives into tasty and distinctively American technologies began
healthful olive oil. Economic growth arises to emerge. Entrepreneurs and inventors de-
from the discovery of new recipes and the veloped specialized machines that econo-
transformation of things from low to high mized on human effort and made prolific use
value configurations. of the natural resources and energy that were
This slightly different initial cut leads to in- available (Rosenberg, 1981). Other nations
sights that do not follow from the neoclassical in the new world also faced low prices for
model. It emphasizes that ideas are goods that natural resources relative to labor. For ex-
are produced and distributed just as other ample, Maddison's (1995) data suggest that
goods are. It removes the dead end in neo- Australia had the highest level of GDP per
classical theory and links microeconomic ob- capita from 1870 to 1900 because its stock
servations on routines, machine designs, and of resources was so large relative to its pop-
the like with macroeconomic discussions of ulation. What made the United States unique
technology. was the combination of resource abundance
In an analysis of American and British and large markets (Abramovitz and David,
growth, the insight that is most relevant con- 1996). In 1820, the population was 534,000
cerns scale. By definition, a nonrival idea can in Argentina, 33,000 in Australia, and 9.6
be copied and communicated, so its value in- million in the United States. Moreover, even
creases in proportion to the size of the market at this early date, the United States had a
in which it can be used. For example, if bar- transportation system and a commercial in-
riers to trade meant that a computer operating frastructure that effectively linked most of
system written in the state of Washington its citizens into a truly national market. By
could only be used within that state, it would 1870, the population had grown to 1.8 mil-

This content downloaded from 91.230.41.203 on Tue, 18 Sep 2018 08:22:39 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
VOL. 86 NO. 2 NEW GROWTH THEORY AND ECONOMIC HISTORY 205

lion in Argentina, 1.6 million in Australia, effect distinct from the one associated with
and 40 million in the United States, a third population size. Firms engaged in the produc-
more than lived in the United Kingdom at tion of many different kinds of goods (includ-
that time. ing machine tools themselves) all used the
As Rosenberg (1963, 1981) has observed, same kinds of machinery to shape first wood,
large markets-which were also populated then metal. Thus, the former machine shop of
here by relatively homogeneous consumers the textile mill sold not just to other textile
mattered, because they encouraged firms to in- firms, but to all manner of manufacturing en-
cur the design and setup costs necessary for terprises. As a result, the proliferation of spe-
long production runs of standardized goods as- cialized machine tools was limited only by the
sembled from interchangeable parts. As he extent of what came to be a very large market.
emphasizes, they also mattered because they Thus, scale acted through larger markets for
induced large markets for specialized ma- both final goods and capital goods. Scale in this
chines. The differences in incentives created sense was determined by a large population, an
by market size were presumably of great con- integrated market, and technological conver-
sequence when populations differed by a fac- gence. A large quantity of natural resources was
tor of 10 or 20 and flows of goods between important initially because it changed the price
nations were still relatively limited. More di- of materials relative to labor, thus encouraging
rect evidence that market size and incentives the use of machinery. Over time, abundant quan-
did matter for invention can be inferred from tities of potential natural resources created an
Kenneth Sokoloff 's (1988) evidence on the additional scale effect relating to the supply of
geographic distribution of patent awards in the things that could be transformed by any partic-
United States. His data show that inventive ac- ular new idea. This effect was most obvious
tivity was concentrated around locations that in the development of uses for by-products
had access to cheap transportation, and that it (Rosenberg, 1985). For example, the quantity
expanded into new areas when the transpor- of animal waste grew with the expansion of the
tation system improved. meat-packing industry. Its geographic concen-
Resource abundance and scale effects were tration also increased as refrigeration and the
therefore key elements in the development of railroad made it possible for meat-packing to be
production using specialized machinery, stan- separated from the site of final consumption.
dardized goods, and interchangeable parts. By This increase in the volume of animal by-
the middle of the 19th century, when the Brit- products and its concentration created incentives
ish first started to take notice, this system was for firms to come up with new nonrival goods-
used in only a few industries, gun-making literally, in this case, new recipes-for making
most famously. Other important industries in use of raw materials that had previously been
the United States, such as iron-making, still discarded as waste. This process ultimately led
lagged behind their British counterparts. It to the development of a by-products industry
took another half century or more for per cap- that was one of the early users of industrial
ita output in the United States to move ahead chemistry.
of Britain's. Scale effects continued to be cru- The same motivation led to the investments
cial in this later period as well. that were needed to take advantage of other
In the beginning, machinery was made in natural resources. Because of the quantities of
machine shops that were part of large manu- resources that were available and the large
facturing enterprises like textile mills. When markets for goods, large investments ip basic
markets grew, these shops eventually sepa- technologies for extracting and processing
rated from their parent firms and began to op-these resources could be sustained. This en-
erate as suppliers to many firms. However, the abled the United States to become the world's
growth in potential markets came not just leading supplier of virtually every industrial
through growth in the industry of the parent raw material, a fact that is reflected in high and
firm. Most of it came from growth in other increasing intensity of resources in U.S. ex-
industries because of what Rosenberg (1963) ports from 1880 to 1930 (Wright, 1990). With
has identified as a process of technological the exceptions of wood and land, the United
convergence which created an additional scale States achieved leadership in most raw mate-

This content downloaded from 91.230.41.203 on Tue, 18 Sep 2018 08:22:39 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
206 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY 1996

rials because of its intensive use of its endow- Exceptionalism," in Ralph Landau, Timothy
ment, not because of the endowment itself Taylor, and Gavin Wright, eds., The mosaic
(Wright, 1990). Because of the "congruence" of economic growth. Stanford, CA: Stanford
(in the terminology adopted by Abramovitz and University Press, 1996, pp. 21-62.
David [1996]) between the U.S. strength in in- Cairncross, A. K. Home andforeign investment
tensive resource use and its early strength in 1970-1913. Cambridge: Cambridge Uni-
manufacturing technologies, it developed a versity Press, 1953.
technological lead over the rest of the world Dawkins, Richard. The blind watchmaker. New
that expanded throughout the first half of this York: Norton, 1986.
century (Nelson and Wright, 1992). Maddison, Angus. Monitoring the world econ-
omy, 1820-1992. Paris: Organization for
V. Conclusion Economic Cooperation and Development,
1995.
Scale effects are clearly not the only inter- Mankiw, N. Gregory. "The Growth of Nations."
esting factor in this story. For example, new Brookings Papers on Economic Activity,
institutions like the United States Geological 1995, (1), pp. 275-326.
Survey, the private university, the large mul- Nelson, Richard R. and Winter, Sidney. An evo-
tidivisional firm, and the specialized research lutionary theory of economic change. Cam-
laboratory were important as well. Concerning bridge, MA: BeLknap, 1982.
the scale effects themselves, the arguments Nelson, Richard R. and Wright, Gavin. "The
presented here will not tell historians anything Rise and Fall of American Technological
they did not already know. The relatively Leadership: The Postwar Era in Historical
modest contribution that new growth theory Perspective." Journal of Economic Litera-
can make is to move the issue of scale up in ture, December 1992, 30(4), pp. 1931-64.
the conceptual hierarchy. Scale effects should Rosenberg, Nathan. "Technological Change in
no longer be treated in the manner of a growth the Machine Tool Industry, 1840-1910."
accountant like Edward Dennison, (i.e., as a Journal of Economic History, December
kind of afterthought that had something to do 1963, 23(4), pp. 414-43; reprinted in Per-
with plant size). They should be treated in the spectives on technology. Armonk, NY:
manner of Adam Smith: as a fundamental as- Sharpe, 1976, pp. 9-31.
pect of our economic world that follows from . "Why in America?" in Otto Mayr
the nonrival character of ideas. and Robert C. Post, eds., Yankee enterprise,
If new growth theorists have their way, the the rise of the American system of manufac-
first distinction economists will draw when tures. Washington, DC: Smithsonian Insti-
looking at the physical world will be the one tution Press, 1981; reprinted in Exploring
that separates rival things from nonrival ideas. the black box. Cambridge: Cambridge Uni-
Right from the start, this should be the way the versity Press, 1995.
physical world is carved up into a small number . "The Commercial Exploitation of
of interacting elements analogous to pistons Science by American Industry," in Kim B.
and boilers. When the resulting theoretical Clark, Robert H. Hayes, and Christopher
framework is combined with the evidence and Lorenz, eds., The uneasy alliance. Boston:
inferences from economic history, economists Harvard Business School Press, 1985, pp.
will be able to give a more convincing answer 18-51.
to the question of how industrial growth works Sokoloff, Kenneth L. "Inventive Activity in
and why it emerged first in America. Early Industrial America: Evidence from
Patent Records." Journal of Economic His-
REFERENCES tory, December 1988, 48(4), pp. 813-50.
Wright, Gavin. "The Origins of American In-
Abramovitz, Moses and David, Paul A. "Conver- dustrial Success, 1879-1940." American
gence and Deferred Catch-up: Productivity Economic Review, September 1990, 80(4),
Leadership and the Waning of American pp. 651-68.

This content downloaded from 91.230.41.203 on Tue, 18 Sep 2018 08:22:39 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms

You might also like