Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 6

American Economic Association

Children as Public Goods


Author(s): Nancy Folbre
Source: The American Economic Review, Vol. 84, No. 2, Papers and Proceedings of the
Hundred and Sixth Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association (May, 1994), pp.
86-90
Published by: American Economic Association
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2117807
Accessed: 12-12-2017 18:42 UTC

REFERENCES
Linked references are available on JSTOR for this article:
http://www.jstor.org/stable/2117807?seq=1&cid=pdf-reference#references_tab_contents
You may need to log in to JSTOR to access the linked references.

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
http://about.jstor.org/terms

American Economic Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend
access to The American Economic Review

This content downloaded from 144.82.238.225 on Tue, 12 Dec 2017 18:42:16 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Children as Public Goods

By NANCY FOLBRE *

Children tumble out of every category work based on individual optimization. This
economists try to put them in. They have framework treats familial altruism, like other
been described as consumer durables pro- tastes and preferences, as exogenously given
viding a flow of utility to their parents, and focuses on household responses to
investment goods providing income, and changes in prices and incomes. Altruism is
public goods with both positive and negative considered rare outside the family, where
externalities. Children are also people, with self-interest undermines the potential for
certain rights to life, liberty, and the pursuit collective action (Gary Becker, 1991).
of happiness. An alternative approach, influenced by
However we categorize children, we know feminist theory, places more emphasis on
that the consequences of raising them are self-interest within the home, and group
changing. Economic development tends to solidarity outside it. Individuals often en-
increase their costs to parents in general, gage in forms of collective action that shape
and mothers in particular. Yet the growth the social institutions that govern the distri-
of transfer payments and taxation of future bution of the costs of children (Folbre,
generations "socialize" many of the benefits 1994). The effects are visible not only in the
of children. All citizens of the United States history of family property rights and law,
enjoy significant claims upon the earnings of but also in public policies with disparate
future working-age adults through Social impacts on old and young, men and women
Security and public debt. But not all citizens (as well as upon groups defined by nation,
contribute equally to the care of these fu- race, and class).
ture adults. Individuals who devote rela- Considerable evidence suggests that par-
tively little time or energy to child-rearing ents in the now-developed countries once
are free-riding on parental labor. enjoyed important economic benefits from
Parents who derive sufficiently high non- child-rearing, not only because children be-
pecuniary benefits from their children may gan to work at an early age, but also be-
not care. Increases in the private costs of cause parental control over assets such as
raising children, however, are exerting family farms gave them leverage over adult
tremendous economic pressure on parents, children. Restrictions on women's ability to
particularly mothers. Economists need to support themselves outside of marriage low-
analyze the contributions of nonmarket la- ered the opportunity costs of children and
bor to the development of human capital: as limited women's ability to exercise repro-
children become increasingly public goods, ductive choice. Similar factors contribute to
parenting becomes an increasingly public high fertility in many developing countries
service. today (John Caldwell, 1982).
The growth of markets for labor, as well
I. Economic Development and the Costs as increased geographic mobility, has weak-
of Children ened patriarchal property rights, raised the
cost of children, and increased women's
Much of the economic literature on fami- economic independence. The imposition of
lies is couched within a neoclassical frame- mandatory education and laws restricting
child labor has improved children's future
productivity but has imposed new costs on
parents. Education has become an increas-
* Department of Economics, University of Mas-
sachnuetts. Amherst MA f10fl0
ingly important determinant of children's
86

This content downloaded from 144.82.238.225 on Tue, 12 Dec 2017 18:42:16 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
VOL. 84 NO. 2 THE ECONOMIC SUPPORT OF CHILD-RAISING 87

future earnings. In the long run, all these public transfers have contributed to an in-
factors have encouraged fertility decline. creased incidence of poverty. Income in-
However, people do not respond instantly equality is extreme: among African-Ameri-
or effortlessly to increases in the cost of can and Latino children in the United
children, which are often difficult to antici- States, the poverty rate is over 40 percent.
pate. Furthermore, the motives for raising Even in northwestern Europe, with more
children are mediated by values, norms, and generous family-support programs, single
preferences that are resistant to change. As mothers and their children remain more
a result, many families with young children vulnerable to poverty than any other group
experience prolonged forms of economic (Timothy Smeeding et al., 1988).
stress that result in increased susceptibility In short, public policies have reinforced
to poverty and weakened ability to care for and perhaps even augmented income flows
their dependent members. from the young to the old, giving the elderly
The growth of labor markets and geo- formal claims upon the earnings of the
graphic mobility lowers the cost of default- younger generation. At the same time, the
ing on the implicit contracts of family life. share of fathers' income transferred to
Towards the end of the 19th century, policy- mothers and children has declined, partly as
makers in both northwestern Europe and a result of the growth of families main-
the United States expressed fears that adult tained by women alone.
children were taking less responsibility for
the care of their elderly parents. Such fears II. Public Finance and Unpaid Labor
provided part of the rationale for the collec-
tive provision of public old-age insurance. The public economy of the state is often
Increases in the cost of children have also conceptualized in terms analogous to the
been associated with trends that shift a private economy of the family. Therefore, it
greater share of the cost to mothers, such as is hardly surprising that most theories of
new child-custody laws, growth in the pro- public finance assume either perfect self-
portion of families maintained by women ishness or perfect altruism and understate
alone, and poor enforcement of fathers' the potential for collective conflict along
child-support responsibilities (Folbre, 1994). lines of age, gender, race, and class. This
Recognition of the growing economic vul- problem is exacerbated by a tendency to
nerability of single mothers played an im- underestimate the value of unpaid labor
portant role in the development of public and a reluctance to consider the incentive
assistance programs in the early 20th effects of unequal opportunity.
century. The assumptions of intergenerational al-
However, public policies have provided truism, formalized by Paul Samuelson (1956)
far greater benefits to the elderly than to and Robert Barro (1974), have recently been
mothers and children on their own, particu- challenged by evidence of rent-seeking by
larly in the United States. Social Security the elderly as a group (Samuel Preston,
expenditures dramatically reduced poverty 1984). Also at stake is the relationship be-
among elderly men and married couples. tween present and future generations. If
Through the end of the 1980's, retirees in current fiscal policies persist, the lifetime
this country received between two and four net tax burdens of future generations
times as much from Social Security as they will likely be about 21-percent larger than
could have if they had placed their tax con- those of young Americans today (Laurence
tributions in a high-yielding private pension Kotlikoff, 1992 p. 29).
(Sylvia Ann Hewlett, 1991 p. 140). Those who benefit from children's future
Since 1960, public expenditures on adults income do so partly at the expense of pre-
have risen far more rapidly than expendi- sent-day parents. Reduction in children's
tures on children (Victor Fuchs and Diane future disposable income may lower future
Reklis, 1992 p. 3). Both poor child-support transfers from children to parents, elicit
enforcement and the declining adequacy of compensating transfers from parents to chil-

This content downloaded from 144.82.238.225 on Tue, 12 Dec 2017 18:42:16 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
88 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY 1994

dren, or lower parents' welfare by lowering night, why does a mother drag herself out of
children's welfare. Moreover, there is no bed to feed it? If she doesn't act from
reason to assume that parents are equally altruism alone, then the utility gains from
affected: mothers often invest more time, children don't fully "compensate" her for
energy, and affection in their children than the costs she pays (Julie Nelson, 1992).
do fathers. Both moral commitments and social
The direction and extent of intergenera- norms are subject to erosion as the price of
tional transfers are shaped by many factors satisfying them increases, and even altruistic
other than public transfers and debt, such preferences may be endogenous. In the long
as the composition of investment, the struc- run, failure to remunerate commitments to
ture of taxation, and the extent of environ- parental labor may weaken the values,
mental degradation. Also relevant are pri- norms, and preferences that supply it. Most
vate parental inputs into children (including economists ridicule the utopian socialist vi-
time, expenditures, and bequests) and the sion of a society based entirely on altruism.
value of "social capital" (the benefits of Is a utopian vision of a family sustained by
living in a safe, healthy community). Class love alone any more realistic?
and race inequalities greatly complicate in- However significant the disincentives now
tergenerational transfers: children from af- facing prospective parents, they may exert
fluent families are far more likely to enjoy less influence than disincentives imposed on
net transfers over their lifetime than are children who lack anything resembling equal
children from poor families. access to education and income. Large per
Inputs of parental labor are crucial. Yet capita differences in public educational in-
estimates of the value of nonmarket work vestments, social capital, and parental
lump child care in with other tasks and transfers result in very different rates of
value it at close to minimum wage (Robert return to individual children's efforts to de-
Eisner, 1989). Recent studies of the accu- velop their own capacities. Those who per-
mulation of human capital define it entire- ceive a very poor chance of success have
ly in terms of formal schooling (Dale less incentive to try hard and greater incen-
Jorgenson and Barbara Fraumeni, 1989). tive to subvert the rules.
Official definitions of the poverty line ignore Enormous criticism has been directed to-
nonmarket labor, with perverse results such ward social programs aimed at indigent
as failing to consider the cost of a paid families. Yet the Social Security system
substitute for a single mother's time when transfers almost as much money to children
she works outside the home (Trudi Renwick of dead or disabled workers as the AFDC
and Barbara Bergmann, 1993). program to children of divorced or deserted
Many economists seem to believe that mothers (Social Security Administration,
time and energy devoted to children reflect 1992 p. 57). Average survivors' and disabil-
an exogenously given preference that pro- ity benefits are more than 2.3 times higher
vides a compensating differential for costs than average AFDC benefits; no work re-
incurred. For instance, Becker (1991 p. 375) quirements or time limits are imposed. Of
suggests that divorced fathers pay little child course, the assumption is that social insur-
support because they have less contact with ance against death or disability is unlikely to
their children and therefore derive less prompt individuals to murder or maim a
pleasure from them. Similarly, Fuchs (1988) spouse, while social insurance against deser-
argues that women are more susceptible tion or divorce may create perverse incen-
than men to poverty because they derive tives.
more utility from children and are therefore While this may be true to some extent,
more likely to assume responsibility for the incidence of desertion and divorce has
them. increased rapidly among all families, partly
However, parents act out of a moral com- because men's values and preferences seem
mitment and sense of responsibility as well to have shifted more rapidly than women's
as altruistic feelings toward their offspring. away from family commitments. Many
When an infant cries in the middle of the mothers are just as powerless to avoid de-

This content downloaded from 144.82.238.225 on Tue, 12 Dec 2017 18:42:16 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
VOL. 84 NO. 2 THE ECONOMIC SUPPORT OF CHILD-RAISING 89

sertion or divorce as to avoid the death or instrumental terms. In the United States, as
disability of their childrens' father. Children well as in other countries, parental control
are certainly not to blame. over adult children's income has been asso-
Public transfers to children are extremely ciated with child abuse, forced marriages,
unequal, as well as small. And public policy and a preference for male children (who
literally transfers resources from parents to tend to earn more). Such personal forms of
nonparents by providing social insurance control are inconsistent with liberal princi-
based on participation in paid employment ples of individual autonomy and modern
without explicitly valuing time, effort, or family values. Furthermore, re-privatization
money devoted to children. In an economy ignores the issue of equal opportunity for
increasingly based on individual careers, children.
parenthood seems to promise moral and The same objections apply to a proposal
cultural rewards but no economic rewards. by James Coleman (1993) for an even more
incentive-based system, designed less to re-
III. New Directions for Family Policy munerate parents than to encourage greater
private investments in children: the state
Family policy has important macroeco- would pay a "bounty" to anyone who in-
nomic implications. In fiscal terms, children creased children's contributions to society
represent a positive externality. There are beyond their expected level. It is not clear
good reasons to believe that we are cur- what incentives children would have to take
rently underinvesting in human capital as responsibility for themselves, particularly if
well as flouting our collective moral obliga- their parents or communities lack the re-
tion for children's welfare. sources necessary to invest in them.
Those who believe that commitments to The best alternative is to promote more
children can be efficiently sustained by pure equal distribution of the costs of children
parental (or maternal) altruism may simply as well as more equal opportunity for chil-
call for the reinforcement of traditional dren themselves. Improved child-support
family values (particularly for women). enforcement would help, as would in-
Those with less confidence in altruism may creased public subsidies for child care. But
put their faith in immigration: the United however necessary, these are not sufficient.
States can probably rely on imports of skilled Parents should be compensated for their
labor from other countries, thus exporting efforts through a greater tax exemption or
the problem of nonsupport for family labor. credit for raising children. And families with
The simplest though most extreme way to children should be guaranteed the means to
remove the externality would be to elimi- obtain a minimum income above the poverty
nate all taxation of future generations, out line.
lawing all debt-financing as well as pay-as- While there are good reasons to encour-
you-go social-security funding. While non- age all capable adults to engage in job train-
parents would no longer be able to bene- ing or paid employment, it is important to
fit from unpaid parental labor, this would remember that nonmarket work is still work.
impose stringent and inefficient limits on In fact, it is probably the most important
macroeconomic and social policy. work we do.
Another alternative would be "re-privati-
zation" of the economic benefits of chil-
dren. Shirley Burggraf (1993) proposes REFERENCES
converting Social Security to a parents'
dividend. Deductions from workers' pay- Barro, Robert. "Are Government Bonds Net
checks could be sent to parents, rather than Wealth?" Journal of Political Economy,
to the older generation as a whole. This November-December 1974, 82(6), pp.
would provide less income security, but 1095-1117.
would certainly reward parental labor. Becker, Gary. A treatise on the family. Cam-
The form of the reward, however, might bridge, MA: Harvard University Press,
encourage parents to treat their children in 1991.

This content downloaded from 144.82.238.225 on Tue, 12 Dec 2017 18:42:16 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
90 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY1994

Burggraf, Shirley. "How Should the Cost of University of Chicago Press, 1989, pp.
Child Rearing Be Distributed?" Chal- 227-85.
lenge, September/October 1993, 37(5), Nelson, Julie. "Towards a Feminist Theory of
pp. 48-55. the Family." Unpublished manuscript
Caldwell, John. The theory of fertility decline. presented at the meetings of the Ameri-
New York: Academic Press, 1982. can Economics Association, New Or-
Coleman, James. "The Rational Reconstruc- leans, LA, 1992.
tion of Society." American Sociological Preston, Samuel. "Children and the Elderly:
Review, February 1993, 58(1), pp. 1-15. Divergent Paths for America's Depen-
Eisner, Robert. The total incomes system of dents." Demography, November 1984,
accounts. Chicago: University of Chicago 24(4), pp. 435-57.
Press, 1989. Renwick, Trudi and Bergmann, Barbara. "A
Folbre, Nancy. Who pays for the kids? Gender Budget-Based Definition of Poverty, with
and the structures of constraint. New York: an Application to Single-Parent Fami-
Routledge, 1994. lies." Journal of Human Resources, Win-
Fuchs, Victor. Women's quest for economic ter 1993, 28(1), pp. 1-24.
equality. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Uni- Samuelson, Paul. "Social Indifference
versity Press, 1988. Curves." Quarterly Journal of Economics,
Fuchs, Victor and Reklis, Diane. "America's February 1956, 70(1), pp. 1-22.
Children: Economic Perspectives and Pol- Social Security Administration. "Security for
icy Options." Science, 3 January 1992, America's Children: A Report from the
255(5040), pp. 41-46. Annual Conference of the National
Hewlett, Sylvia. When the bough breaks. The Academy of Social Insurance." Social Se-
cost of neglecting our children. New York: curity Bulletin, Spring 1992, 55(1), pp.
Basic Books, 1991. 57-75.
Kotlikoff, Laurence. Generational Accounting. Smeeding, Timothy; Torrey, Barbara and Rein,
Knowing who pays and when, for what we Martin. "Patterns of Income and Poverty:
spend. New York: Free Press, 1992. The Economic Status of Children and the
Jorgenson, Dale and Fraumeni, Barbara. "The Elderly in Eight Countries," in John
Accumulation of Human and Nonhuman Palmer, Timothy Smeeding, and Barbara
Capital, 1948-84," in Robert Lipsey and Boyle Torrey, eds., The vulnerable. Wash-
Helen Stone, eds., The measurement of ington, DC: Urban Institute, 1988, pp.
saving, investment, and wealth. Chicago: 89-119.

This content downloaded from 144.82.238.225 on Tue, 12 Dec 2017 18:42:16 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

You might also like