Cultural Economy: A Critical Review: Chris Gibson and Lily Kong

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 22

Progress in Human Geography 29, 5 (2005) pp.

541–561

Cultural economy: a critical review


Chris Gibson1* and Lily Kong2
1GeoQuest Research Centre, School of Earth and Environmental Sciences,
University of Wollongong, NSW 2522, Australia
2 Department of Geography, National University of Singapore, Singapore 117570

Abstract: This article reviews work on ‘cultural economy’, particularly from within geography,
and from other disciplines, where there are links to overtly geographical debates. We seek to clarify
different interpretations of the term and to steer a course through this multivalency to suggest
productive new research agendas. We review and critique work on cultural economy that
represents a relatively straightforward economic geography, based on empirical observation while
theoretically informed and driven by debates about Fordism and post-Fordism, agglomeration and
cluster theory. Some of these ideas about cultural economy have proven attractive to policy-
makers and we map a normative script of cultural economy, with its prescriptive recommendations
for economic development, which we then critique. Turning from this normative cultural economy,
we move to a more theoretical discussion which reinterprets the cultural economy in light of
debates on the culturization of ‘the economic’ in research praxis. We conclude that better
acknowledgement is needed of the contradictory uses of ‘cultural economy’, but point
nevertheless to the value of this multivalency as long as we reflect on the multiple contradictions
and interpretations. With many current absences in work on cultural economy, we suggest various
agendas waiting to be addressed.

Key words: cluster theory, creative industries, cultural economy, cultural policy, urban
regeneration.

I Introduction sociology (Zukin, 1995; du Gay, 1997; du Gay


The ‘cultural economy’ has become an and Pryke, 2002; Stevenson, 2003), media
increasingly common term, both theoretically and communications studies (Cunningham,
and empirically, in human geography. 2001; Hesmondhalgh, 2002), urban planning
Together with similar concepts such as ‘cre- (Landry, 2000) and economics (Howkins,
ative economy’ and ‘cultural industries’, it 2001; Caves, 2000; Throsby, 2001). This
has underpinned a flourish of activity from article reviews work on ‘cultural economy’,
researchers in economic and cultural geogra- particularly from within geography, but also
phy (Crewe and Forster, 1993; Pratt, 1997a; from these other disciplines where there are
2000a; Coe, 2000; Kong, 2000; Brown et al., links to overtly geographical debates.
2000; Scott, 2000a; Leyshon, 2001; Bassett A major impetus for this review is a recog-
et al., 2002; Gibson et al., 2002), but also nition that the economy is polyvalent, and the

*Author for correspondence. E-mail: cgibson@uow.edu.au

© 2005 Edward Arnold (Publishers) Ltd 10.1191/0309132505ph567oa


542 Cultural economy: a critical review

cultural economy is part of a wider set of and its malleability as a heuristic device may
complex relationships which is the economy. in itself be something of intrinsic value. We
The review is also prompted by the growing conclude, though, that better acknowledge-
interest in ‘cultural turns and the (re)constitu- ment is needed of contradictory uses of
tion of economic geography’, which recog- ‘cultural economy’, and of some of the poten-
nizes that ‘the economic is embedded in the tially more conservative interpretations and
cultural’, that ‘the economic is represented applications of the term. We also draw atten-
through cultural media of symbols, signs tion to the uneven geographies of academic
and discourses’, and the ‘cultural is seen as work in this broad area, and suggest the
materialized in the economic’ (Crang, 1997). need for future work to move beyond an
Another motivation is the desire to con- American/European focus.
tribute to this journal a critical review of We begin by reviewing work on cultural
the intersection between economy and economy that adopts a relatively straight-
culture that focuses precisely on the onto- forward economic geography perspective,
logical, to balance Castree’s (2004) review based on empirical observation. A particular
that treats ‘economy’ and ‘culture’ as ‘perfor- version of this cultural economy has become
mative key words’ that are discursively con- popular among policy-makers, so much so
structed (Castree, 2004). Of course, we that, we claim, it is possible to trace a norma-
hope this review will also be helpful to those tive script of cultural economy linked to
who are simply looking for some clarification prescriptive recommendations for economic
of the multivalent meanings of cultural econ- development. Subsequent sections critique
omy (and associated similar terms such as this policy direction, and contrast ‘orthodox’
‘creative economy’, ‘cultural industries’ and readings of cultural economy against work in
‘creative class’, all of which describe a space ‘new’ economic geography, where cultural
where the ‘cultural’ and ‘economic’ collide). economy is taken to refer to a culturization of
Some terms, such as ‘cultural industries’, ‘the economic’ in research praxis – an oppor-
have links back to earlier intellectual heritages tunity to radically ‘open out’ both empirical
such as Adorno’s (1991) ‘culture industry’. and theoretical terrain. Our final section
Meanwhile, ‘cultural economy’ has come to reflects on contradictions, interpretations
have a different meaning again in the context and current absences in work on cultural
of debates about the influence of the ‘cultural economy.
turn’ in economic geography. In this latter
context, ‘cultural economy’ has been used II Defining cultural economy
as a term to describe a particular approach ‘Cultural economy’ has been used in multiple
to non-neoclassical economics – a ‘new’ ways. We examine four approaches, the
economic geography influenced by post- difficulties associated with their use, and their
structuralist epistemologies. implications for research agendas. These four
We seek here to clarify different interpre- are the sectoral delineation of cultural econ-
tations of the term. We argue that ‘cultural omy, the labour market and organization of
economy’ has become a multivalent term production approach, the creative index
deployed within divergent geographical imag- definition, and the convergence of formats as
inations. We seek to steer a course through a defining feature of the cultural economy.
this multivalency in ways that suggest pro-
ductive new research agendas. Our aim is not 1 The sectoral approach
necessarily to empty the term of its ambigui- Opinions have varied about the specific
ties, nor to suggest a wholesale discarding of types of production that should be included
it (though there is much to critique) – ‘cultural in definitions of ‘cultural economy’. For Scott
economy’ remains a thoroughly useful phrase, (2001: 12), they include those ‘goods and
Chris Gibson and Lily Kong 543

services that serve as instruments of enter- Greenwood, 2002) to any household goods
tainment, communication, self-cultivation, where design beyond the merely utilitarian
ornamentation, social positionality, and so on, has played a role (for example, in furniture,
and they exist in both “pure” distillations, as kitchen appliances, souvenirs, rugs and car-
exemplified by film or music, or in combina- pets, wall-hangings). Following this logic,
tion with more utilitarian functions, as exem- apparently arbitrary decisions must be made
plified by furniture or clothing’. Pratt (1997a) about which of these household and personal
identified a number of sectors constituting commodities are more or less reliant on
the ‘Cultural Industries Production System’ semiotic content, as between, for example,
(CIPS): ‘fashion’ clothing items and ‘basic’ workwear.
Expensive lingerie may count, but mass-
performance, fine art, and literature; their
produced underwear (for which designs have
reproduction: books, journal magazines,
newspapers, film, radio, television, recordings remained more or less constant over time)
on disc or tape; and activities that link together may not. Do such distinctions themselves
art forms, such as advertising. Also considered become irrelevant when, using the same
are the production, distribution and display examples, workwear becomes a hot fashion
processes of printing and broadcasting, as well
item, in the case of Carhartt in the United
as museums, libraries, theatres, nightclubs, and
galleries. (Pratt, 1997a: 1958) States, or Blundstone or Hard Yakka in
Australia? Decisions such as these might
Adopting the sectoral approach poses some potentially have to be made across an almost
difficulties, as many sectors (including indus- infinite array of commodities, weakening the
tries such as furniture and industrial design, possibility of capturing a solid definition of
certain forms of niche food production and cultural economy based on characterizing
tourism) may now be viewed as part of the forms of production alone.
cultural economy because of their symbolic
content, when they were at best only periph- 2 The labour market and organization
erally considered part of ‘the arts’ previously. of production approach
The issue becomes complex in specific coun- If sectoral definitions pose difficulties, Scott
tries where variations in included sectors (1996: 307) points to flexible specialization by
occur. In Australia, for instance, sectors such ‘communities of workers’ with ‘special com-
as zoological parks and botanical gardens are petencies or instinct-like capacities’ (Scott,
included in official government statistical 2001: 12–13) as a distinguishing characteristic
definitions of ‘cultural’ industries (see Gibson of cultural economies. The production of
et al., 2002), but sport is not, despite it being symbolic forms is more often than not
for some people the defining feature of dependent on large inputs of human manual
Australian cultural life. and intellectual labour, even where digital and
Extending the various lists of sectors that information technologies play a major role in
make up the cultural economy to its logical the process. However, because of market
extremes also produces conceptual and volatility, driven by, among other things, the
methodological difficulties. It potentially cre- fickleness of consumer demand for symbolic
ates an unwieldy list with seemingly endless products like music and fashion, firms often
possibilities. If symbolic content is taken as a tend to be small and incorporated as modular-
starting point, then a much wider range of ized elements into wider production net-
activities could be included, from funeral works (see, however, later discussion in this
services (one industry linked to particular section about corporate integration).
socio-religious practices, and that wholly Individuals engaged in the cultural economy
relies on the construction of imagery, in also tend to operate on an informal, part-time
advertising and in ‘event management’; see subcontracted basis, earning the majority of
544 Cultural economy: a critical review

income from other sources (Gibson et al., Gomery, 1998; Puttnam and Watson, 1998;
2002: 184). This feature of subcontracted Prince, 2000).
work, consonant with vertical disintegration One of the difficulties of characterizing
of post-Fordist regimes, reflects in part the cultural economy by reference to labour
an attempt to exploit maximum variety of markets and post-Fordist modes of produc-
creative resources (Christopherson and tion is that the Fordist regime of accumulation
Storper, 1986; Morley and Robins, 1995). has also been evident in the production of
Writing in the context of film production, ‘cultural’ goods. This has entailed ‘mass
Christopherson and Storper (1986) argued workers’ in large factories; economies of scale
that large numbers of small flexibly specialized reaped through large-scale mass production; a
firms spring up in a wide range of subsectors, hierarchical bureaucratic form of work organ-
providing both direct and indirect inputs to ization, characterized by a centralized man-
the majors. One implication of this pattern of agement; and vertical integration, driven by a
work is the emergence of territorial localiza- desire to achieve cost efficiency in production
tion, the formation of cultural districts with and exchange (Robins, 1993; Allen, 1996).
agglomeration of firms because the instability Film production in early postwar Hong Kong,
of casualized employment relations and the for example, exemplified such economic
critical need to remain in contact networks behaviour (see Kong, 2003).
generate agglomeration tendencies. We will The focus on labour markets and modes of
discuss this in more detail in the next section, production has provided a possible way of
given the centrality of the issue to geography. identifying the cultural economy and changes
Another implication of this pattern of work is therein, but the ‘messiness’ of evolution and
that creative pursuits are ultimately not the defiance of linear development as postu-
determined by patterns of supply and demand lated theoretically make identification via
alone; they are also driven by individuals’ own Fordist/post-Fordist checklists only partially
social interests (Gibson, 2003; Brennan- helpful (see Hesmondhalgh, 1996; 1998).
Horley, 2004). For many, participation in
cultural activities is initially driven not by 3 The ‘creative index’ approach
career development motivations, but by a Cultural economy need not imply just a
personal desire to engage with the affective, discrete set of sectoral activities (however
emotive, cathartic dimensions of creative small or large the list of inclusions) or a
pursuits such as music, writing and painting. distinctive labour market and organization of
The above evidence of post-Fordist production. For some, cultural economy is a
modes of production as indicators of a cultural different way of categorizing all economic
economy are further supported by growing activities, and measuring their impact on
corporate integration or horizontal alignment urban and regional economies. Creativity
with large conglomerates and cross-media becomes central across all industries, indeed
ownership ‘at both national and international distinguishes whole new social groups, such
levels, with new alliances between broadcast- that Florida (2002) has argued for the emer-
ers, film and television producers, publishers, gence of a ‘creative class’ as a discrete seg-
record producers and so on’ (Morley and ment of society, employed in the creative
Robins, 1995: 32). These growing conglo- industries, but also found in R and D and
merates may be ascribed to attempts to other ‘creative’ occupations across all indus-
‘internalize the synergies that are frequently tries. Innovation and learning become central
found at intersections between different tenets of economic growth, no matter what
segments of the media and entertainment the industry.
(and hardware) industries’ (Scott, 2002: 961; The difficulty with this approach is a ten-
see also Acheson and Maule, 1994; Balio, 1998; dency to be reductionistic in the interpretation
Chris Gibson and Lily Kong 545

of culture, as policy-makers rush to turn (and reregulation of competitive markets),


cultural activity to creative index (see, for and the appearance of new forms of dissemi-
example, National Economics, 2002), includ- nation (cable, internet, mobile telephony; see
ing the computation of indices such as a Lury, 1993; Pratt, 1999). Following this inter-
bohemian index, gay index and so forth, in pretation, the cultural economy is essentially
order that the contributions of culture to a sector dominated by trade in, and protec-
economy may be measured and further policy tion of, intellectual property rights. Record
transformations introduced. This approach companies, for instance, no longer perceive
misses the complexity of cultural activity, themselves as firms who release music, but
and reduces contradictions and interpreta- instead describe themselves as traders in
tions to a numerical scale (see more detailed copyright material (see Connell and Gibson,
discussion below). 2003). Similar observations may may be
made of companies in film, design, publishing,
4 The convergence of formats advertising and fashion industries.
Finally, some authors use the convergence of The significance of using digitization as a
formats as a defining feature of the cultural starting point for analysis is that it takes the
economy: the media through which creative discussion regarding the organization of the
products are consumed are increasingly cultural economy a step further. It requires
reliant upon a common digital platform (see researchers to focus on the strategies of
Aksoy, 1992; Sadler, 1997; Pratt, 2000a), one companies and the technological means by
that is seen to define the ‘new’ economy. which they pursue economic objectives, since
Convergence upon the digital medium has ‘new technologies create the possibilities of
been mirrored by a political economy of new strategies, and also of the new economic
creative production, as corporate interests in objects that can be exploited and governed in
the arts, popular culture, telecommunications their different ways’ (Pratt, 2000b: 7). Such
and broadcasting have merged, amalgamated, thinking aligns some research in cultural econ-
or entered into joint ventures. Companies omy more strongly with an otherwise sepa-
which traditionally undertook activities previ- rate, and much older trajectory of research in
ously considered quite distinct became allies media and communications studies, which
and enemies, as mergers and joint ventures has been concerned with the political econ-
became more common (the most famous omy of media ownership (Garnham, 1990;
being the merger in 1999 of America On Line Aksoy and Robins, 1992; Carter, 1997), the
(AOL) with TimeWarner, parent company of role of ‘the culture industry’ in reproducing
CNN cable television network, WEA music the social hegemony of ruling classes via
and Warner Bros film studios). Such manoeu- entertainment ‘as mass deception’ (see
vres create links between cultural producers Adorno and Horkheimer, 1977; Adorno,
of ‘content’ (the music or film), and manu- 1991), impacts of convergence on creative
facturers and suppliers of information tech- production and intellectual property rights
nologies, the ‘hardware’.1 While information (Lury, 1993), and on cultural policy (for
has always been a key element of the func- overviews, see Jeffcutt, 2001; Cunningham,
tioning of production, a series of events has 2001; O’Regan, 2001). Such research has
suggested its renewed primacy, not just with been given a particularly geographical bent
developments in computer technology, but when considering the spatial contradictions
with the growth of a more globally integrated and tensions underpinning governance of
financial system, convergence between digital media and intellectual property rights
corporate interests in the telecommunica- (Aksoy, 1992; Leyshon, 2001; Connell and
tions and information industries, state dereg- Gibson, 2003), and effects of convergence
ulation of media and communications sectors and cultural production on both the role of,
546 Cultural economy: a critical review

and internal dynamics within, very large concentrated, and where cultural producers
cities (Castells, 1989; Graham, 1999; Sassen, can keep a close eye on competitors while
2000). Indeed, this latter urban/regional scale simultaneously benefiting from the work of
of analysis would emerge as a major unifying cultural intermediaries who construct mar-
theme of work in cultural economy. We kets through the various techniques of per-
return to this issue in a later section of the suasion and marketing (Negus, 2002: 504).
paper. Such agglomeration:
The multiple ways in which cultural econ- is magnified where divisions of labour in
omy may be considered are not mutually cultural or economic production are strongly
exclusive, and may indeed be used in rein- in evidence … where many specialized but
forcing ways. What this discussion illustrates complementary individuals and organizations
come together in constant interchange, thus
is that the polyvalent nature of cultural forming functional as well as spatial clusters of
economies means that there are myriad interrelated activities. (Scott, 2001: 12)
conceptions in the literature, and the produc-
tive task ahead is not to sink into endless Urban complexes represent collectivities of
efforts at defining cultural economies, but human activity and interests that continually
acknowledge the polyvalency and address create streams of public goods – these sustain
specific research agendas from there. We the workings of what Scott calls the ‘creative
turn now to those agendas that we believe milieu’, found most prominently in major
deserve attention. world cities. Socialization dynamics ensure
the preservation of local knowledge; infra-
III Locational proclivities: structures such as schools, colleges and train-
agglomeration, clustering or ing centres support skilled and specialized
metropolitan primacy? employment; and public-private partnerships
Numerous studies have sought to theorize promote certain technological or innovation
the spatial organization and geography of schemes. In Paris, for instance, despite its
specific forms of cultural production in partic- faltering in recent times from previous heights
ular localities (e.g., Hirsch, 1972; Driver and as the world capital of creative production,
Gillespie, 1993; Crewe and Forster, 1993; the city nonetheless ‘remains endowed with
Crewe, 1996; Power and Hallencreutz, 2002; rich infrastructures of specialized production
Power and Scott, 2004). Echoing earlier networks, skilled workers, an active frame-
spatial models, the overriding and repeatedly work of professional and trade associations
confirmed observation has been one of of all kinds, and other important assets, not
agglomeration and spatial concentration. To least of which are traditions and reputations
return to Scott (1999: 814), ‘creativity and bequeathed to it from the past’ (Scott, 2000b:
innovation in the modern cultural economy 567). This could also be said at the global
can be understood as social phenomena scale of Los Angeles, New York, Barcelona,
rooted in the production system and its Milan and Hong Kong, and, within nations,
geographic milieu’. Factors that contribute cities such as Toronto, Sydney and Seoul.
to the tendency to agglomerate are linked Based on Scott’s (1999) theory that
to the rapid, ever-changing circulation of spatial clustering also facilitates face-to-face
information, which ensures that there is a contact in the cultural economy, Pratt
constant tendency to destabilization of pre- (2000a) proposes that:
vailing norms and practices, and a certain in the field of new media a clustering of
propensity for new insights and new ways of producers will occur where new communi-
cations technologies are insufficient to capture
seeking accumulation. To stay in touch with the full range of human expression …
trends, producers must be ‘close to action’, clustering of producers will … occur in
in precincts where cultural consumption is particular places, namely those that afford a
Chris Gibson and Lily Kong 547

large degree of chance and random encounter (Amin and Thrift, 1995) – webs of supporting
with both similar and different producers, and organizations such as financial institutions,
users. (Pratt, 2000a: 429)
chambers of commerce, local authorities,
Pratt’s argument provides a counterpoint to marketing and business support agencies that
the ‘weightless economy’ thesis that was in ‘create synergy, and a collective sense of
favour among some economists and pro- identity and purpose within a cluster’ (Bassett
ponents of the ‘digital revolution’ in the et al., 2002: 173). These features, and the fact
mid-1990s (this essentially argued that new that cultural production requires the overlap-
communications technologies would signal ping skills of a highly differentiated workforce
the ‘end of geography’; Quah, 2002). Instead, (Pratt, 1999) mean that full-blown cultural
the form and practice of transactions are economies are often only present in large
most important, typified by the need for cities.
formal and informal in-person communi- Such discussions around clusters and their
cation. New communications technologies internal dynamics seek to put ‘culture’ on the
and media cannot replicate aspects of map of local economic policy. Power and
human interaction, particularly ‘in the prac- Scott (2004) imply this when drawing from
tices of learning, innovating, contracting, research on cultural economy to make three
employment, as well as socializing, eating, recommendations for places seeking to
relaxing … ‘ (Pratt, 2000a: 434), though they develop their cultural economy:
have enabled new kinds of public-private Policy-makers thus need to pay attention to
networks to be intermittently assembled three main ways of promoting collective
and disassembled (Sheller, 2004). Despite competitive advantage, which, on the basis of
technological advances, physical proximity the modern theory of industrial districts can be
identified as (a) the building of collaborative
still facilitates untraded interdependencies inter-firm relations in order to mobilize latent
(Storper, 1997), and enables a more frenetic synergies, (b) the organization of efficient,
traffic of interactions among key actors. high-skill local labor markets, and (c) the
Observations of the agglomerative potentiation of local industrial creativity and
tendencies in activities within the cultural innovation. (Power and Scott, 2004: 9–10)
economy concur with work in what has The import of such recommendations is
been labelled ‘new geographical economics’ that the cultural economy is a component of
(Krugman, 1998; Fujita et al., 1999; Porter, the contemporary economy that the state
2002). This examines clusters and networks can target as a priority growth area through
as defining spatial modes of economic activi- schemes such as centres of innovation and
ties. That clusters and networks appear to creativity, planning for cultural clusters or
have a heightened role in the spatial organiza- districts through mixed land use and/or
tion of the cultural economy generated a taxation incentives, and grants for network-
flourishing of work adopting this framework ing between firms. Indeed, urban economies
(Maskell et al., 1998; Keeble and Wilkinson, have become increasingly dependent on the
1999; Keeble et al., 1999). Links have been production and consumption of culture, so
drawn between clustering as a spatial trend, much so that cultural planning and urban
and increased capacity for learning and inno- planning are closely braided, indeed insepa-
vation; essentially expanding on the idea rable, as some argue (see, for example,
that there are certain ‘spillovers’ between Worpole and Greenhalgh, 1999; Landry,
individuals and companies located proxi- 2000). Certain precincts are remodelled and
mately – one learns from being close to com- reinvented as ‘cultural quarters’, and cultural
petitors, and is encouraged to collaborate industry activities are used as promotional
when in mutual best interests. Related is material for strategies in marketing cities
the concept of ‘institutional thicknesses’ and attracting mobile investment capital.
548 Cultural economy: a critical review

They underpin place making and city producing heightened forms of metropolitan
reimaging strategies, while cultural texts primacy (Gibson et al., 2002). Cunningham
portray specific places in ways that can either (2001) has argued that:
enhance or contest popular meanings of the industries which such policy rhetorics and
those locations (Gibson et al., 2002: 174). aspirations spawned have undoubtedly obeyed
However, cultures, cities and plans are not the iron laws of infrastructural agglomeration –
uncontested resources, and are embroiled in Paris or the provinces. Investing in large
national flagship institutions and national
an urban and cultural politics of planning.
flagship funding agencies – what we might call
Thus, Freestone and Gibson (2004) have Big Culture – generally speaking means further
foregrounded several issues, for example, that consolidation of cultural industries in one or
cultural projects are not consensual strategies two spatial hotspots in the country … national
but contested terrain (see also Bianchini, cultural policies have, by and large, contributed
to further centralization of cultural resource
1993; Evans and Foord, 2003); that there is
and cultural cachet, rather than contributing
no single model for culture-based urban plan- to their redistribution spatially … and the
ning; that urban cultural policies may produce institutions which deliver some of the
‘ersatz’ and ‘pastiche’ outcomes in the remak- core popular cultural product and service …
ing of a city’s cultural identity which may have been the worst centralizers: film and
television. (Cunningham, 2001: 30)
disenfranchise local communities, particularly
suburban and deprived populations (see also Indeed, Zukin (1995: 273) has argued that
Zukin, 1995); and that a city planned for cultural strategies, including those that
cultural consumption is not a culture capital promote clusters and innovation spaces,
if it simply functions as an ‘entrepot of the ‘are often a worst-case scenario of eco-
arts’ (Zukin, 1995: 150), buying and selling nomic development’, representing ‘a weapon
without producing the arts itself. Further, against the decentralization of jobs from
Zukin (1995) indicates that urban cultural established industrial concentrations’ at
projects legitimize the separation of rich precisely the moment that governments
areas from other parts of the city, which we seek to shrug off responsibilities for spatial
extend to a reminder that cultural clusters or redistribution as a countermeasure to
cultural quarters serve to create markers of uneven development. The cultural economy
social and cultural separation and distinction ‘confirm[s] the city’s claim on cultural hege-
within the city. Similarly, she questions if mony … a claim to these cities’ status in the
cultural strategies of economic redevel- global hierarchy’ (Zukin, 1995: 26), at the
opment destroy the conditions for original expense of nonmetropolitan areas. Such
cultural production by displacing artists and criticisms demand a quite different policy
performers through upgrading and increasing response than a wholesale adoption of the
property values in planned clusters (see also logic of promoting clusters, instead reminding
Kong, 2000). Thus, it remains to be said that economic development agencies of the spatial
cultural clusters in urban planning strategies political economy of (cultural) production
are often tied to civic boosterist agendas beyond the localized urban cluster.
of urban elites (Boyle, 1997) which deserve More fundamental than the critique of
critical understanding. strategies that privilege planned clustering
Instead of seeing clustering as an important are those critiques which trouble the very
new guiding principle of the cultural economy, primacy of clusters (e.g., Coe, 2000; Coe and
others have argued that the agglomeration Johns, 2004), the extent of embeddedness
of cultural production in major cities merely (Turok, 1993) and the role of learning and
reinforces the uneven distribution of economic knowledge in regions (MacKinnon et al.,
development that have always been charac- 2002). On cluster theory, Martin and Sunley
teristic of capitalist modes of production, (2003: 11–12) have stressed in their critique
Chris Gibson and Lily Kong 549

of Michael Porter that he has not adequately other countries transformations have been
addressed the geographical scale of ‘clusters’, brought about by counterurban ‘lifestyle’
which appear ‘highly and ridiculously elastic’. migration, commodifications of rural land-
They argue that there is ‘nothing in the scapes, telecommuting and the rise of arts
concept itself to indicate its spatial range or and cultural industry sectors – all examples of
limits, or whether and in what ways different or outcomes related to symbolic production.
clustering processes operate at different Here, proximity and clustering may be less of
geographical scales’. Coe’s (2000) work an influence on the particular form of cultural
simultaneously decentres the importance of economic practice than the pattern and sheer
geographical clusters by emphasizing the weight of urban-regional flows of capital,
significance of interpersonal relationships and commodities and people. In Broken Hill in
social networks in obtaining finance and remote Australia, a visual arts scene grew
securing distribution in Vancouver’s film because of a combination of spectacular land-
industry, where these relationships cut across scapes and cheap housing that artists could
geographical scales. In Asia, film-making has afford to rent even with intermittent
become increasingly international, quite the incomes. In rural Ireland, tourism would have
opposite of the clustering phenomenon. In a similar transformative effect, but on music
efforts to both appeal to pan-Asian audiences rather than art.
and take advantage of differences in labour While most research has tended to
costs, film-makers are increasingly using emphasize the agglomerative tendencies of
locations for shooting and postproduction cultural industries and the ways in which the
across national borders, and employ actors value of clustering can be harnessed, we
from different language or national back- suggest that there are other complexities
grounds. Even at this broad-brush level, that deserve at least equal attention. There is
regional differences matter. no doubt that agglomeration theory remains
The agglomerative tendencies of cultural a valid frame for analysis, but the relative
industries and the importance of the local neglect of other phenomena such as cross-
scale may therefore have been overstated national flows, spatial political economy
at the expense of understanding the role and rural cultural production prompt us
of global flows, national interventions in the to foreground their significance, and urge
regulation of production, and interscalar research where they have been comparatively
dimensions of cultural economic activities. neglected.
Moreover, creativity and innovation are not
unique to large cities. Though their critical IV ‘Normative’ cultural economy
mass clearly influences the number of firms Many recent discussions of cultural economy,
and size of output from creative sectors in and their capacity to transform urban loca-
cities, creativity is everywhere possible (Gibson tions, have tended to extend from empirical
and Connell, 2004), and transformations trig- data certain observations about the existence
gered by the rise of the cultural economy of a singular ‘cultural’ or ‘creative’ economy
have been as, if not more, profound, in rural or city. A common imperative has often been
and regional areas where the cultural indus- to make generalizations about the cultural
tries previously had little presence at all economy, as a transformative component of
(Kneafsey, 2001; Curry et al., 2001; Gibson, total economic activities in places, such that it
2002; Tonts and Grieve, 2002). Cultural can be considered as a whole-of-economy
production and the symbolic economy has phenomenon. We would argue that such
always to a certain extent been present in generalizations become normative, where
major cities, yet in rural areas in the UK, the meanings for cultural economy coalesce
USA, Australia, New Zealand and many around singular, definitive interpretations.
550 Cultural economy: a critical review

If a ‘normative cultural economy’ could be ‘cluster approaches to analysing Australia’s


distilled into a single script, it would probably content and application industries (and
look as follows: possibly to strategies supporting their -
• Contemporary capitalism is characterized development) address these capabilities’
by more recently dominant forms of (Australian DCITA and NOIE, 2002: 17).
accumulation, based on flexible produc- Yet, despite the growing importance given
tion, the commodification of culture and to the cultural economy by governments and
the injection of symbolic ‘content’ into all policy-makers in the Asia-Pacific, geographies
commodity production. of knowledge on cultural economy are highly
• Some places do better than others skewed towards Europe and North America.
from this: those that have highly skilled, Much of the research has been on major met-
creative, innovative, adaptive workforces, ropolitan areas in those two areas (e.g., Los
sophisticated telecommunications infra- Angeles, Manchester and Paris). This flies in
structures, interesting and diverse pop- the face not only of the significant urban and
ulations, and relatively low levels of cultural policy foci in Asia-Pacific cities, but of
government interference in regulating the rise in production and consumption of
access to markets, as well as lifestyle Asia-Pacific cultural products, evidenced in
attractions, restaurants and arts institu- the emergence and significance of creative
tions to attract the new ‘creative class’. industries such as Bollywood, the Hong Kong
• In order to compete in the new cultural and Korean film industries, Cantopop and
economy, places should seek to implement mandarin pop, Japanese manga and anime
particular policy initiatives: encourage productions, and so on. In particular, ‘pan-
cultural industry clusters, incubate learning Asian’ or ‘East Asian’ regional identities and
and knowledge economies, maximize economic networks that are anchored in the
networks with other successful places and popularity of Japanese, Korean, Taiwanese
companies, value and reward innovation, and Hong Kong pop idols draw attention to a
and aggressively campaign to attract the new ‘regionalism’ (Aoyagi, 2000: 318–319),
‘creative class’ as residents. aided by internet sites and webzines that sup-
In the 1990s and early 2000s, this normative port fans and idol clubs (Aoyagi, 2000: 321).
approach has proved attractive in several Where Neil Smith has argued that the focus
cities in the Asia-Pacific, particularly those on globalization and localization has impover-
such as Auckland, Sydney, Hong Kong and ished theoretical thinking about scales,
Singapore – important regional cities with oversimplifying the complexity of scalar rela-
already established national broadcasting, tionships in empirical reality, analysis of Asian
arts and cultural industries, but with aspira- cultural economies and related cultural identi-
tions for ‘world city’ status (see, for example, ties could offer opportunities for rethinking
Auckland City Council, 2002; Australian scales beyond the global and local, and under-
DCITA and NOIE, 2002; Hong Kong Trade standing economic and cultural interactions
Development Council, 2002; and Singapore as regional relations.
ERC Report 2002). For example, from the While acknowledging the geographical
language of developing a ‘Renaissance City’ bias and calling for redress, our analysis of
and a ‘regional hub for the arts’ to the creation the existing literatures, written mainly in
of a ‘creative cluster’ to generate the city- western contexts, is concerned with how
state’s ‘cultural capital’, Singapore’s economic the normative interpretation of cultural
strategies have fully embraced the normative economy performs certain purposes in the
approach to cultural economies. In Australia, context of the academic reception of new
it is also proclaimed that to enhance the geographical knowledges. On the one hand, it
innovative capacities of cultural industries, contains discourses of cultural economy
Chris Gibson and Lily Kong 551

within epistemological frameworks familiar beyond the confines of academia – a noble


in economic geography – a consecration of enough sentiment. Yet, as argued in greater
pragmatically empirical research focused on detail elsewhere (Gibson and Klocker, 2003;
what is ‘successful’ in the contemporary 2004), those who seek opportunities to
economy. It is an interpretation relatively publish ‘popular’ academic books on cultural
empty of self-reflexivity or other poststruc- economy have also been particularly adept
turalist influences on contemporary eco- at constructing an industry out of their own
nomic geography (compare, for example, work – a parallel perhaps to what Langbauer
Lee, 1997). Yet, precisely as these somewhat (1993) earlier dubbed the ‘celebrity-
orthodox interpretations are made, norma- economy’, made up of high-profile book
tive cultural economy ‘talks up’ that which it deals, conference tours and a well-paid
proposes as new. There is a ironic circularity corporate speaking network. Several of the
at work here: normative cultural economy key authors in cultural economy now earn
constitutes that which it seeks to docu- tidy incomes providing advice to urban and
ment and becomes part of the cultural regional governments on economic develop-
economy itself, even if not acknowledged as ment and have been successful in winning
such. In its most popularized form, cultural private consultancies in addition to publicly
economy has become a ‘brand’ representing funded research grants. (Charles Landry was,
a particular perspective of the ‘innovative’ for instance, the Australian city of Adelaide’s
in the contemporary economy, and is itself most recent ‘thinker in residence’, a position
an ‘innovative’ product. that allowed close access to power brokers,
This is a potentially illuminating critique, as well as further opportunities to promote
especially so in light of debates about how culture-led regeneration, an area in which
academic work is closely tied to the publishing his consultancy firm, COMEDIA, now
industry – the primary means through which specializes.) In the 1990s, Barnett (1998)
our work is valorized and attains circulation wrote about what he saw as a disturbing
(Mohan, 1994; Barnett, 1998; Sidaway, 2000). trend towards celebrity fetishism in cultural
In this case, several high-profile ‘popular’ studies and cultural geography. Hence:
academic books in this field (most notably With an increasingly mobile international
Florida’s and Landry’s) have hit bestsellers conference circuit allied to assertive forms of
lists and become widely read ‘manuals’ academic publishing, what has become central
of contemporary economic development think- to modes of authority in the ever more diffuse
ing. They have moved geography/urban studies field of cultural studies is not just the rhetorical
personification of ideas, but their ‘actual’
publishing well beyond scholarly journals and personification in ‘real’ people, with not just
the normal researcher/undergraduate market names but faces and especially personal
and into the popular nonfiction sections of biographies. It is in this (quite serious) sense
bookstores in shopping malls and airports. that one can begin to talk of the rise of
The normalization of ‘branded’ books in new forms of academic celebrity. (Barnett,
1998: 386)
cultural economy – ‘The creative city’
(Landry, 2000), ‘The creative economy’ Leaving aside the validity or otherwise of
(Howkins, 2001), ‘The rise of the creative class’ such claims in the context of cultural studies,
(Florida, 2002) – in a sense stakes claims for six or so years on from his observations it
the originality of the perspectives contained could certainly be argued that academic work
within, and this no doubt helps to sell books. on cultural economy exhibits the same trend.
To be fair, there is nothing particularly new As we see it, the danger in the celebritization
about this phenomenon: it is of course linked of select writers in cultural economy stems
to the desires of academics to become figure- not so much from the success or widespread
heads for certain concepts and to be heard appeal they might achieve (that is theirs
552 Cultural economy: a critical review

to enjoy), but in terms of the material impacts In the context of cultural industries, Healy
of normative cultural economy on policy (2002) has similarly warned that:
praxis in divergent circumstances. Here we Analyses of the creative industries might not
remind readers of Massey’s (2002) observa- generalize to other sectors of the economy, or
tion about the ‘policy relevance’ of geography: might apply in unexpected ways … There is
Rarely is policy change a question of simply something new for culture in the new
providing technically correct answers … Our economy – but not only one thing. The focus
wider role is not confined to answering on creativity and the creative sector provides a
already-specified questions … but is inevitably useful way to begin analysing the postindustrial
engaged in a contest between different economy. Those interested in promoting arts
understandings of the world … [The] complex and culture in this new environment, however,
articulation of intellectual responsibility with should bear in mind the difference between
political engagement is a far more difficult, using new economy jargon … and finding out
multifaceted and delicate matter. (Massey, what is actually going on. (Healy, 2002: 101)
2002: 646) Moreover, normative cultural economy
We would concur with regard to cultural chooses to ignore much of what critical
economy discourse. An obvious danger in cultural geographers have emphasized in
the emerging model of academic knowledge- recent years about culture itself. Cultural
to-policy traffic is one of assuming singular activities are somewhat collapsed into an
‘recipes’ for success in transforming places, overarching single urban culture of play-
based on advice from experts and advisors fulness and ceaseless invention, understating
not well enough grounded in places to the extent to which ‘culture’ is a mishmash of
account for the more complex and contested contradictory forces and shifting battle lines
geographies they contain. between dominant and marginalized voices
Perhaps in part a response to the popular- (Jackson, 1989; Mitchell, 1995). Similarly,
ity and universal appeal of normative cultural only selective interpretations of ‘innovation’
economy, a critique has begun to emerge and ‘creativity’ are deployed. Creativity is
which troubles the singularity of such dis- only generally discussed where it is possible
courses, and the politico-economic context of for it to be harnessed in productive ways for
academic knowledge production from which economic growth. Other forms of ‘creativity’
they emerge (see Heartfield, 2000; Healy, that do not automatically contribute to
2002; Osborne, 2003). Normative cultural economic development (or in fact resist it),
economy relies on generalizations that attract gain scant mention. One risk may be that
media interest, and more neatly translate into discourses of ‘creativity’ in the cultural
policy outcomes, but it is revealed as often economy themselves become normative, if
overstretching the mark in its generalizations. they have not already become so – such that
Prophetic depictions of the ‘new’ or ‘cultural’ only certain types of ‘creativity’ are promoted
economy are plagued by overstatements, and tolerated in society while others such as
generality, and problems of downplaying what skills in graffiti-art are rendered unproductive
are clearly important external influences, and abject (unless of course, they too can be
local variations, and more substantial inher- commodified).
ited social relations. For instance, Kneafsey Even within the epistemological confines
(2001) has unsettled the sense of the ‘new’ in of normative cultural economy, its implied
cultural economy by arguing that, in rural singularity (the cultural economy) is worth
contexts, cultural economy is situated within some unsettling. It is largely true that conver-
continually unfurling inheritance of prior gence of media, IT and cultural industries
social, gender and class relations, (re)produc- has been apparent, and indeed it is so that
ing ‘geometries of power’ rather than merely there are certain ‘spillovers’ across activities
generating new kinds of economic activities. in culture – for example, the links, shared
Chris Gibson and Lily Kong 553

infrastructures and patterns of ownership and prone to rapid and apparently illogical
apparent between advertising, film and transformation’ (Banks et al., 2000: 455).
television, music and media companies. Similarly, Pratt (2000a: 435) argued that
These observations are in part where recom- new media do not support the traditional
mendations about clusters and enhancing model of ‘stable entities’ and ‘one-way causal
interfirm synergies arise, particularly when relationships’ of firms and products.
these activities are proximate. Yet, in light of Work on music has demonstrated this. In
feminist critiques of political economy, which many respects it is normal to talk of the
have highlighted the various ways in which existence of ‘the music industry’ as a singular
academic work can mask the tendency to sector or organized system of production,
reify ‘The Economy’ as a singular economic distribution and retailing. There are processes
body that has an apparent life of its own, dis- that simultaneously affect the position of all
courses of a singular ‘thing’ called the ‘cultural players in music, across locations and spatial
economy’ must be interrogated. Our use scales, from restructuring of ‘accumulation’ to
of encompassing phrases might blind us to challenges of new technology – these would
the extent that the economic formations are make the framing of music as a single ‘indus-
merely imagined into solidity, only made try’ seem common sense. However, capitalist
hegemonic entities through our representa- forms of musical exchange (such as in the
tion of them, rather than through an a priori recording industry), like wider forms of
‘natural’ existence (Gibson-Graham, 1996; capitalism, may be as much characterized by
Yang, 2000; K. Gibson, 2001). While it may disorganization, fragmentation, unevenness
remain an important project to state and and variability as they are by stable regimes
critique claims for the importance of all of accumulation (Brennan-Horley, 2004; cf.
forms of creative endeavour, couched in Gibson-Graham, 1996; O’Neill and Gibson-
both cultural and economic terms, it is Graham, 1999). As Sanjek (1998: 176–77) has
problematic to assume that ‘the cultural put it, ‘we must more fully acknowledge the
economy’ has some existence outside the structural volatility of corporate systems. Too
social, political and cultural contexts within often, analysts presume record companies in
which individuals and groups of people particular operate in a homogeneous fashion,
work. As Scott (1999: 809) argued, ‘place- whereas empirical examination … illustrates
based communities such as these are not the amount of tension that lies behind the
just foci of cultural labour in the narrow sense, recording process’. Analysing the music
but are also vortexes of social reproduction industry also involves the context of produc-
in which critical cultural competencies are tion, systems of legal administration (from
generated and circulated’. Associated ques- intellectual property laws to local venue
tions of the uneven enterprise of cultural licensing), and the network of actors who
capital in the creative field (Bourdieu, 1984) engage with music commodities, influences
and of class and gender relations are thus and expressions (McLeay, 1998; Leyshon,
logical ways of extending cultural economy 2001; Homan, 2003). Some forms of cultural
beyond a singular script of economic develop- production are now sites of economic contes-
ment and a resultant, overly simple and tation, adding extra layers of uncertainty and
prescriptive policy focus. complexity to the already heady mix of risk
and volatility discussed above. The most
V Risk publicly performed contestation in this regard
In contrast to the ‘neatness’ of normative concerns debates over ‘piracy’ in music,
cultural economy, cultural production has particularly through file-sharing cultures of
been revealed through ethnography and distribution of music (in formats such as
careful local analysis to be ‘volatile, subjective MP3). Music is produced, distributed and
554 Cultural economy: a critical review

consumed in and through social and economic sectors. This task is even more important
formations that are multiple, shifting and given the highly uneven geography of the
contested. cultural economy outlined earlier. Such
This has particular implications for work- recommendations are not intended to chal-
ers. In the cultural industries, a lack of trust lenge, for instance, the characterization of
and high levels of personal risk are ‘more contemporary capitalism by Lash and Urry,
marked than in other industries because of and Scott, as reflexive, highly flexible and
the lack of any formalized career trajectory volatile – indeed in some respects they
commensurate with the linear, learning stage merely support such observations. What
models of business development embedded such research might more successfully
within banks, enterprise agencies, training achieve, however, is a tempering of the
programmes and other support institutions’ certainty with which normative cultural
(Banks et al., 2000: 460; see also McRobbie, economy can be translated into coherent
2002a; 2002b). Cultural industries are inher- policy prescriptions, and invite more reflective
ently risky, governed by fickle consumer research that seeks to frame such volatility
demand, rapid fashion cycles (Peterson and as part of a broader process of contestation
Berger, 1975), and significant redundancies of ‘the economic’.
represented by stockpiles of unsuccessful
products. The existence of a highly specialized VI Cultural economy – an
workforce linked to ‘hyperflexible’ organiza- enculturation of the economic?
tions, when looked at in another way, can be A major development that has enriched
depicted as a reserve army of labour (Menger, debate about cultural economy relates to
2001: 250), the presence of which allows the so-called ‘cultural turn’ in economic
larger interests in cultural production (such as geography. We have already mentioned the
entertainment corporations) to offset uncer- multivalency of the term ‘cultural economy’
tainties in demand for cultural products by in the context of its application to studies of
drawing on the expressions of a large number creative industry sectors. This multivalency
of artists to strategically overproduce. For has been given another twist because, in
example, entertainment companies hedge different contexts, ‘cultural economy’ has
their bets that at least some of their albums, also been used as an overarching descrip-
books or television shows will result in a tor for new theoretical branches of eco-
‘winner’, thus cross-subsidizing other less nomic geography – those emerging since
successful releases. the ‘cultural turn’ in the subdiscipline (see, for
More often than not, the more vulnerable example, Thrift, 2000; du Gay and Pryke,
workers in the cultural economy bear an 2002). This other use of the term requires
increasingly large burden of the risk associ- further discussion here, in order to clarify
ated with cultural industries through a prolif- the different approaches it entails, and how
eration of self-employment, project-based they differ to much of the ‘cultural economy’
employment, microbusinesses and startups, research already discussed. Moreover, as we
high levels of subcontracting, and the pitting will argue, many productive possibilities for
of creative workers against one another by research in cultural economy stem from this
‘client’ companies higher up the food chain theoretical shift.
(Grabher, 2002a; 2002b; 2002c; Blair, 2003). There is already substantial literature on
Much more research is required to under- the cultural turn in economic geography, and
stand just how workers in various occupa- we seek here merely to summarize its import,
tions across the cultural economy respond to rather than provide comprehensive overview
such circumstances, mitigate risk and estab- (for such overviews, see Lee, 1997; 2002;
lish relationships with other players in their Ray and Sayer, 1999; Barnes, 2001; 2003;
Chris Gibson and Lily Kong 555

2005; du Gay and Pryke, 2002). Principally, A concern that we have for possible future
the cultural turn in economic geography directions for research on cultural economy
has involved application of poststructuralist relates to this. It appears that there has
and feminist critiques to orthodox eco- been plenty of traffic which (re)interprets
nomic geography and political economy. It the cultural within a normatively ‘economic’
has included calls to acknowledge the framework – hence attempts to quantify
positionality of researchers (McDowell, the importance of cultural production sectors,
1992), and to foreground the subjectivities to examine creative industries or cultural
involved in the production of ‘economic’ districts, and so on. Taken collectively,
knowledges (Gibson-Graham, 1996). The though, this body of work may in fact
cultural turn also encourages thinking through continue to position ‘the economic’ as the
the ways in which economic landscapes and normative centre of our concerns. Culture
spaces can be interpreted through textual becomes an important consideration, but
analysis, deconstruction and ethnographic only in so far as it pertains to particular kinds
methods (Yeung, 2003), and through non- of productive activities or specified space-
representational theory, which emphazises economies. What seems to be strangely
affective relations between humans and non- absent from most writing on cultural econ-
humans, between corporeal and machinic omy is an importation of ‘cultural’ per-
entities (Latham and McCormack, 2004). spectives, those poststructuralist/feminist
Subsequent debates have concerned the insights that have unsettled understandings
political efficacy of destabilizing meanings of ‘the economic’ in economic geography
of ‘the economic’ (see Gibson-Graham, 1996; more generally.
Amin and Thrift, 2000; various articles in And what of traffic in the other direction –
Antipode 33(2), 2001). Rather than dedicating bringing ‘the economic’ to bear on ‘the
too much discussion to the complexities of cultural’? There are exciting, yet under-
these debates here, we seek to draw links theorized, possibilities for research on cultural
between theoretical insights from culturally economy to ‘speak back’ to debates in cultural
inflected economic geography, and specific geography, and/or about more obviously
research on ‘cultural economy’ summarized ‘cultural’ themes and debates. For example,
and critiqued in previous sections. policy debates on culture and creativity as
One perplexing feature of recent work ‘economic’ phenomena have had interesting
in economic geography is that little of the (and probably unintended) side-effects on
cultural turn in economic geography has debates about ‘high’ and ‘low’ culture in the
been brought to bear on ‘the cultural econ- arts and cultural policy arenas. In considering
omy’ as an empirical project. As discussed the appropriateness of government subsidy
above, much of the research on cultural to the arts, the distinction between ‘high’
economy has adopted a fairly conventional and ‘low’ culture is foregrounded, the former
economic geography framework imported deemed appropriate for subsidy, the latter to
from mainstream political economy. The be commercially provided. This tendency
relative absence of poststructuralist episte- reflects what Pratt (1997b: 4–5) calls a
mologies from ‘cultural economic geography’ ‘deification of the artist as the source of
in actual studies of cultural production is art’, as arts funding tends to be focused on
ironic, given the conjunction of culture and the artist and particular artistic forms, while
economy implicit in the term ‘cultural neglecting art forms associated with industrial
economy’ (for exceptions, see du Gay and production. In other circumstances, ‘high’
Pryke, 2002; Leslie and Reimer, 2003; culture institutions such as art galleries
various chapters in Amin and Thrift, 2003; and opera companies have been encouraged
Bain, 2004). to act more like ‘low’/’popular’ cultural
556 Cultural economy: a critical review

industries with increased emphasis on level about producing and selling meaning,
marketing, branding, and private sources of but these meanings are not simply ‘content’
income. for the particular sectors concerned. They
In spite of our critique of normative cul- indelibly shape the very industries them-
tural economy above, it is worth acknowledg- selves, as well as reproduce social relations
ing that research on cultural industries has had and norms.
the effect of breaking down regressive bina- This brief set of reflections on the traffic
ries that have hampered cultural policy devel- between the ‘cultural’ and the ‘economic’
opment. They have partially decoupled arts/ demonstrates the extent to which many of
cultural policy from the shackles of class the contradictory and divergent interpreta-
politics, which previously governed interpre- tions of cultural economy remain to be
tations of legitimate ‘high’ art, against illegiti- analysed. By opening up cultural economy to
mate or subversive ‘popular culture’. But theorization from poststructuralist and non-
lurking behind the economization of culture representational perspectives, we have not
are potentially dangerous politics: of cultural sought to encourage an abandonment of the
diversity, homosexuality, tolerance for differ- important tasks of documenting and theoriz-
ence as acceptable only when framed in ing creative production in place, in favour of
terms of economic benefits, as evident in the purely discursive (as opposed to quantitative)
use of creative indices. accounts of ‘culture’. Nor have we sought to
Many more everyday examples of sectors, suggest that ‘the economic’ in cultural econ-
events or ‘creative’ activities that have not yet omy can be completely accounted for within a
gained attention in empirical studies might poststructuralist or nonrepresentational frame-
offer concrete examples of where a more work (see Hudson, 2004). However, cultural
genuinely crossdisciplinary perspective – that economy, like ‘the economy’ as a whole:
does not privilege the economic over culture
is about far more than mere mechanics; its
(or vice versa) – become vital. One example is purposes necessarily embrace the world … the
the phenomenon in much of the western question is not whether to rediscover
world (and in parts of Asia) of weddings as economics or to go with the cultural, it is how
cultural-economic events. Of course, the to do both at the same time in ways that
recognize the political significance of these
practice of marriage is ancient, but more
intersections and provide a critical purchase on
recently various elements of weddings have prevailing economic processes. (Lee, 2002:
taken on industry-like scale and sophis- 335, emphases in original)
tication. Theorization is required in relation
to different actors in the wedding industry We think that this coupling – political
(photographers, writers, designers, clothing significance and critical purchase – is what is
manufacturers, event managers). But this most needed now in cultural economy
theorization cannot be unproblematically dis- research.
connected from cultural concerns. Weddings
have also become the means through which VII Conclusion
various social norms are established and One of our imperatives for writing this article
reproduced. Wedding magazines in Australia, was to sort through much of the messiness
for instance, regularly run stories on how to and incoherency of work that has emerged
be ‘an appropriate mother-to-be’ at weddings, under the banner of ‘cultural economy’. A
provide advice on the ‘right’ kinds of dresses temptation in this conclusion would be to
and suits to wear, at the same time that they come to some definitive interpretations, or
are principally advertorials for companies assert our perspective on what ‘cultural
delivering wedding-related services and economy’ should mean, or how research in
products. All cultural industries are at some this area should be conducted.
Chris Gibson and Lily Kong 557

We have sought to resist this urge. Instead, cultural geographers might talk through
we have attempted to reaffirm the multiva- implications of cultural economy. In attempt-
lency of cultural economy. This multivalency ing this though, critical reflection is required,
exists in both empirical and theoretical ways: and tendencies towards singular normative
a sense of fluidity within the normative cultural economy should be guarded against.
framework, about what is included in defini- In this way, productive research agendas and
tions of the cultural economy. Even within sensitive policy formulations may eventuate.
economic geography, there is still much room
for critical work that uses orthodox research Acknowledgements
techniques to illuminate differences between We are grateful to James Sidaway, Natascha
industries and places, and to unsettle assump- Klocker and three anonymous referees
tions about how to develop cultural for their comments. The funding support
economies. If normative cultural economy from the National University of Singapore
retains a usefulness as an empirical/descrip- (RP109-000-052-112), which made possible
tive phrase, it is perhaps more modestly and the assistance of Lynette Boey, is also
realistically a pluralistic depiction of an amal- acknowledged.
gam of activities that in some regards can be
taken pragmatically as a group with common Note
characteristics (for instance, in calculating the 1. Such mergers and joint ventures are strictly
amount of employment generated by creative not new, though the specific form may be.
activities) while at other times are cut across Note that when Walter Benjamin (1936)
wrote about the cultural economy some 70
by different sets of mitigating factors (such as
years ago, he too noted mergers of hitherto
the key role of intellectual property rights).
separate fractions of capital that underpinned
‘Cultural economies’ may be taken to repre- revolutions in cultural economy.
sent multiple sets of activities and diverse
forms of production. At one level, this is use- References
ful (for instance in arguing the importance of Acheson, K. and Maule, C.J. 1994: Understanding
the arts in contemporary economies as part Hollywood’s organisation and continuing success.
of securing public funding for arts institu- Journal of Cultural Economics 18, 271–300.
Adorno, T. 1991: The culture industry: selected essays on
tions), but at another level limiting. For cul-
mass culture. London: Routledge.
tural economy to remain relevant in this Adorno, T. and Horkheimer, M. 1977: The culture
regard, our research requires a balance industry: enlightenment as mass deception. In
between agendas focused on generalization Curran, J., Gurevitch, M. and Woollacott, J., editors,
of macroscale trends (without boosterish or Mass communication and society, London: Edward
Arnold and Open University Press, 349–83.
self-fulfilling jargon), and attention to the
Aksoy, A. 1992: Mapping the information economy:
complexities of interscalar processes and integration for flexibility. In Robins, K., editor,
relations. Understanding information: business, technology and
Additionally, and more importantly, we geography, London: Belhaven Press, 43–60.
have sought to foreground a sense of paradig- Aksoy, A. and Robins, K. 1992: Hollywood for the 21st
century: global competition for critical mass in image
matic multivalency about the different geog-
markets. Cambridge Journal of Economics 16, 1–22.
raphies of culture and economy that are Allen, J. 1996: Post-industrialism/post-fordism. In Hall,
interpreted. The normative policy script of S., Held, D., Hubert, D. and Thompson, K., editors,
cultural economy referred to earlier has the Modernity: an introduction to modern societies,
effect of closing off potential connections and Oxford: Blackwell, 546–55.
Amin, A. and Thrift, N. 1995: Globalisation, institu-
dialogues that could occur, because it erases
tional thickness and the local economy. In Healey, P.,
a lot of the messiness of culture. We urge Camerson, S., Davoudi, S., Graham, S. and Madani-
the opening up of a discursive space where, Pour, A., editors, Managing cities: the new urban
for instance, economic policy-makers and context, Chichester: Wiley, 92–108.
558 Cultural economy: a critical review

— 2000: What kind of economic theory for what kind Bourdieu, P. 1984: Distinction: a social critique of the
of economic geography. Antipode 32, 4–9. judgement of taste. London: Routledge and Kegan
— editors 2003: The Blackwell cultural economy reader. Paul.
Oxford: Blackwell. Boyle, M. 1997: Civic boosterism in the politics of local
Aoyagi, H. 2000: Pop idols and the Asian identity. In economic development – ‘institutional positions’ and
Craig, T., editor, Japan pop! Inside the world of Japanese ‘strategic orientation’ in the consumption of hallmark
popular culture, Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe, 309–26. events. Environment and Planning A 29, 1975–97.
Auckland City Council 2002: Rethinking Auckland as a Brennan-Horley, C. 2004: Work and play: post-
creative city: concepts, opportunities and practical steps. industry cultural production in sydney’s dance music
Working Report. Auckland: Auckland City Council. culture. Unpublished BSc thesis, University of New
Australian Department of Communications, South Wales, Sydney.
Information Technology and the Arts and Brown, A., O’Connor, J. and Cohen, S. 2000: Local
Australian National Office for the Information music policies within a global music industry: cultural
Economy (DCITA and NOIE) 2002: Creative indus- quarters in Manchester and Sheffield. Geoforum 31,
tries cluster study: stage one report. Retrieved 15 June 437–51.
2004 from http://www.noie.gov.au/publications/ Carter, D. 1997: ‘Digital democracy’ or ‘information
NOIE/DCITA/cluster_study_report_28may.pdf aristocracy’?: Economic regeneration and the infor-
Bain, A. 2004: Female artistic identity in place: the mation economy. In Loader, B.D., editor, The gover-
studio. Social and Cultural Geography 5, 171–93. nance of cyberspace: politics, technology and global
Balio, T. 1998: A major presence in all the world’s major restructuring, London and New York: Routledge,
markets: the globalisation of Hollywood in the 1990s. 136–52.
In Neale, S. and Smith, M., editors, Contemporary Castells, M. 1989: The informational city: information
Hollywood cinema, London: Routledge, 58–73. technology, economic restructuring and the urban-
Banks, M., Lovatt, A., O’Connor, J. and Raffo, C. regional process. Oxford: Blackwell.
2000: Risk and trust in the cultural industries. Castree, N. 2004: Economy and culture are dead! Long
Geoforum 31, 453–64. live economy and culture! Progress in Human
Barnes, T. 2001: Retheorizing economic geography: Geography 28, 2, 204–26.
from the quantitative revolution to the ‘cultural turn’. Caves, R. 2000: Creative industries: contracts between
Annals of the Association of American Geographers 91, art and commerce. Cambridge, MA: Harvard
546–65. University Press.
— 2003: Never mind the economy. Here’s culture. In Christopherson, S. and Storper, M. 1986: The city as
Anderson, K., Domosh, M., Pile, S. and Thrift, N.J., studio; the world as back lot: the impact of vertical
editors, The handbook of cultural geography, London: disintegration on the location of the motion picture
Sage, 89–97. industry. Environment and Planning D: Society and
— 2005: Culture: economy. In Cloke, P. and Johnston, Space 4, 3, 305–20.
R., editors, Spaces of geographical thought: deconstruct- Coe, N.M. 2000: The view from out West: embedded-
ing human geography’s binaries, London: Sage, 61–80. ness, inter-personal relations and the development of
Barnett, C. 1998: The cultural turn: fashion or progress an indigenous film industry in Vancouver. Geoforum
in human geography? Antipode 30, 379–94. 31, 437–51.
Bassett, K., Griffiths, R. and Smith, I. 2002: Cultural Coe, N.M. and Johns, J. 2004: Beyond production
industries, cultural clusters and the city: the example clusters: towards a critical political economy of
of natural history film-making in Bristol. Geoforum 33, networks in the film and television industries. In
165–77. Power, D. and Scott, A., editors, The cultural
Baudrillard, J. 1968: Le systeme des objets: la consum- industries and the production of culture, London and
mation des signes. Paris: Editions Gallimard. New York: Routledge, 188–204.
Benjamin, W. 1936 (1973 version): The work of art in Connell, J. and Gibson, C. 2003: Sound tracks: popular
the age of mechanical reproduction. In Benjamin, W., music, identity and place. London and New York:
Illuminations (translated by H. Zohn), London: Fontana. Routledge.
Bianchini, F. 1993: Culture, conflict and cities: issues Crang, P. 1997: Introduction: cultural turns and the
and prospects for the 1990s. In Bianchini, F. and (re)constitution of economic geography. In Lee, R.
Parkinson, M., editors, cultural policy and urban regen- and Wills, J., editors, Geographies of economies,
eration: the west european experience, Manchester: London and New York: Arnold, 3–15.
Manchester University Press, 199–213. Crewe, L. 1996: Material culture: embedded firms, orga-
Blair, H. 2003: Winning and losing in flexible labour nizational networks and the local economic develop-
markets: the formation and operation of networks of ment of a fashion quarter. Regional Studies 30, 257–72.
interdependence in the UK film industry. Sociology Crewe, L. and Forster, Z. 1993: Markets, design, and
37, 677–94. local agglomeration: the role of the small independent
Chris Gibson and Lily Kong 559

retailer in the workings of the fashion system. Gibson, C., Murphy, P. and Freestone, R. 2002:
Environment and Planning D: Society and Space 11, Employment and socio-spatial relations in
213–29. Australia’s cultural economy. Australian Geographer
Cunningham, S. 2001: From cultural to creative 33, 173–89.
industries: theory, industry, and policy implications. In Gibson, K. 2001: Regional subjection and becoming.
Mercer, C., editor, Convergence, creative industries Environment and Planning D: Society and Space 19,
and civil society: the new cultural policy, Zagreb: 639–67.
Culturelink/Institute for International Relations, Gibson-Graham, J.K. 1996: The end of capitalism (as
19–32. we know it): a feminist critique of political economy.
Curry, G., Koczberski, G. and Selwood, J. 2001: Oxford: Blackwell.
Cashing out, cashing in: rural change on the south Gomery, D. 1998: Hollywood corporate business
coast of Western Australia. Australian Geographer practice and periodizing contemporary film history. In
32, 109–24. Neale, S. and Smith, M., editors, Contemporary
Driver, S. and Gillespie, A. 1993: Structural change Hollywood cinema, London: Routledge, 47–57.
in the cultural industries: British magazine publishing Grabher, G., editor 2002a: Production in projects:
in the 1980s. Media, Culture and Society 15, 183–201. economic geographies of temporary collaboration.
du Gay, P. 1997: Production of culture/cultures of Regional Studies Special Issue 36(3).
production, London: Sage. — 2002b: Cool projects, boring institutions: temporary
du Gay, P. and Pryke, M., editors 2002: Cultural collaboration in social context. Regional Studies 36,
economy. London: Sage. 205–14.
Evans, G. and Foord, J. 2003: Shaping the cultural — 2002c: The project ecology of advertising:
landscape: local regeneration effects. In Miles, M. and tasks, talents and terms. Regional Studies 36, 245–62.
Hall, T., editors, Urban futures: critical commentaries Graham, S. 1999: Global grids of glass: on global cities,
on shaping the city, London: Routledge, 167–81. telecommunications and planetary urban networks.
Florida, R. 2002: The rise of the creative class: and how Urban Studies 36, 929–49.
it is transforming work, leisure, community and every- Greenwood, V. 2002: Weathering storms on the
day life. New York: Basic Books. Stygian ferry: the economic, social and cultural
Freestone, R. and Gibson, C. 2004: City planning and impacts of globalisation on the Australian funeral
the cultural economy. Paper delivered to the City industry. Unpublished thesis, Macquarie University.
Futures Conference, Chicago, 8–10 July. Healy, K. 2002: What’s new for culture in the new
Fujita, M., Krugman, P. and Venables, R. 1999: The economy? Journal of Arts Management, Law and
spatial economy: cities, regions and international trade. Society 32, 86–103.
Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Heartfield, J. 2000: Great expectations: the creative
Garnham, N. 1990: Capitalism and communication. industries in the new economy. London: Design
London: Sage. Agenda.
Gibson, C. 2002: Rural transformation and cultural Hesmondhalgh, D. 1996: Flexibility, post-Fordism and
industries: popular music on the New South Wales the music industries. Media, Culture and Society 18,
Far North Coast. Australian Geographical Studies 40, 469–88.
336–56. — 1998: The British dance music industry: a case study
— 2003: Cultures at work: why ‘culture’ matters in of independent cultural production. British Journal of
research on the ‘cultural’ industries. Social and Sociology 49, 234–51.
Cultural Geography 4, 201–15. — 2002: The cultural industries. London: Sage.
Gibson, C. and Connell, J. 2004: Cultural industry Hirsch, P.M. 1972: Processing fads and fashions: an
production in remote places: indigenous popular organization-set analysis of cultural industry systems.
music in Australia. In Power, D. and Scott, A., American Journal of Sociology 77, 639–59.
editors, The cultural industries and the production Homan, S. 2003: The mayor’s a square: live music and
of culture, London and New York: Routledge, law and order in Sydney. Sydney: Local Consumption
243–58. Publications.
Gibson, C. and Klocker, N. 2003: Cultural industries Hong Kong Trade Development Council 2002:
and cultural policy: a critique of recent discourses in Creative industries in Hong Kong. Retrieved 15 June
regional economic development. In Gao, J., Le 2004 from http://www.tdctrade.com/econforum/
Heron, R. and Logie, J., editors, Windows on a chang- tdc/tdc020902.htm
ing world, Auckland: NZ Geographical Society Howkins, J. 2001: The creative economy. London:
Conference Series No. 22, 131–35. Penguin.
— 2004: Academic publishing as ‘creative’ industry, Hudson, R. 2004: Conceptualizing economies and their
and recent discourses of ‘creative economies’: some geographies: spaces, flows and circuits. Progress in
critical reflections. Area 36, 423–34. Human Geography 28, 44–71.
560 Cultural economy: a critical review

Jackson, P. 1989: Maps of meaning: an introduction to Martin, R. and Sunley, P. 2003: Deconstructing
cultural geography. London and Boston: Unwin clusters: chaotic concept of policy panacea. Journal of
Hyman. Economic Geography 3, 5–35.
Jeffcutt, P. 2001: Creativity and convergence in the Maskell, P., Eskelinen, H., Hannibalsson, I.,
knowledge economy: reviewing key themes and Malmberg, A. and Vatre, E., editors 1998:
issues. In Mercer, C., editor, Convergence, creative Competitiveness, localised learning and regional
industries and civil society: the new cultural policy, development, London: Routledge.
Zagreb: Culturelink/Institute for International Massey, D. 2002: Geography, policy and politics: a
Relations, 9–18. response to Dorling and Shaw. Progress in Human
Keeble, D. and Wilkinson, F. 1999: Collective learning Geography 26, 645–46.
and knowledge development in the evolution of McDowell, L. 1992: Multiple voices: speaking from
regional clusters of high technology SMEs in Europe. inside and outside ‘the project’. Antipode 24, 57–80.
Regional Studies 33, 295–303. McLeay, C.R. 1998: The circuit of popular music:
Keeble, D., Lawson, C., Moore, B. and Wilkinson, production, consumption, globalisation. Unpublished
F. 1999: Collective learning processes, networking PhD thesis, Macquarie University, Sydney.
and ‘institutional thickness’ in the Cambridge region. McRobbie, A. 2002a: From Holloway to Hollywood:
Regional Studies 33, 319–32. happiness at work in the new cultural economy? In du
Kneafsey, M. 2001: Rural cultural economy: tourism and Gay, P. and Pryke, M., editors, Cultural economy,
social relations. Annals of Tourism Research 28, 762–83. London: Sage, 97–114.
Kong, L. 2000: Cultural policy in Singapore: negotiating — 2002b: Clubs to companies: notes on the decline of
economic and socio-cultural agendas. Geoforum 31, political culture in speeded up creative worlds.
409–24. Cultural Studies 16, 516–31.
— 2003: Cultural industries: producing economies, Menger, P. 2001: Artists as workers: theoretical and
creating meanings, defying dichotomies. Paper pre- methodological challenges. Poetics 28, 241–54.
sented at Constructing Pan-Chinese Cultures: Mitchell, D. 1995: There’s no such thing as culture:
Globalism and the Shaw Brothers Cinema. University towards a reconceptualisation of the idea of culture in
Of Illinois Urbana-Champaign, 2–4 October. geography. Transactions of the Institute of British
Krugman, P. 1998: What’s new about the new Geographers NS 20, 102–16.
economic geography? Oxford Review of Economic Mohan, G. 1994: Deconstruction of the con: geography
Policy 14, (2) 7–17. and the commodification of knowledge. Area 26,
Landry, C. 2000: The creative city. London: Earthscan. 387–90.
Langbauer, L. 1993: The celebrity economy of cultural Morley, D. and Robins, K. 1995: Spaces of identity:
studies. Victorian Studies 36, 465–72. global media, electronic landscapes and cultural bound-
Lash, S. and Urry, J. 1994: Economies of signs and aries. London and New York: Routledge.
space. London: Sage. National Economics 2002: The state of the regions.
Latham, A. and McCormack, D.P. 2004: Moving Melbourne: National Economics and the Australian
cities: rethinking the materialities of urban geogra- Local Government Association.
phies. Progress in Human Geography 28, 701–24. Negus, K. 2002: The work of cultural intermediaries
Lee, R. 1997: Economic geographies: representations and the enduring distance between production and
and interpretations. In Lee, R. and Wills, J., editors, consumption. Cultural Studies 16, 501–15.
Geographies of economies, London: Arnold, xi-xiv. O’Neill, P. and Gibson-Graham, J.K. 1999:
— 2002: ‘Nice maps, shame about the theory’? Thinking Enterprise discourse and executive talk: stories that
geographically about the economic. Progress in destabilise the company. Transactions of the Institute of
Human Geography 26, 333–55. British Geographers NS 24, 11–22.
Leslie, D. and Reimer, S. 2003: Gender, modern design O’Regan, T. 2001: Cultural policy, cultural planning and
and home consumption. Environment and Planning D: creative industries policy making. In Mercer, C.,
Society and Space 21, 293–316. editor, Convergence, creative industries and civil
Leyshon, A. 2001: Time-space (and digital) compres- society: the new cultural policy, Zagreb: Culturelink/
sion: software formats, music networks, and the Institute for International Relations, 33–50.
reorganisation of the music industry. Environment and Osborne, T. 2003: Against ‘creativity’: a philistine rant.
Planning A 33, 49–77. Economy and Society 32, 507–25.
Lury, C. 1993: Cultural rights: technology, legality and Peterson, R.A. and Berger, D.G. 1975: Cycles in
personality. London: Routledge. symbol production: the case of popular music.
MacKinnon, D., Cumbers, A. and Chapman, K. American Sociological Review 40, 158–73.
2002: Learning, innovation and regional develop- Porter, M. 2002: Clusters and the new economics of
ment: a critical appraisal of recent debates. Progress competition. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Business
in Human Geography 26, 293–11. School Press.
Chris Gibson and Lily Kong 561

Power, D. and Hallencreutz, D. 2002: Profiting from — 1999: The cultural economy: geography and the cre-
creativity? The music industry in Sweden and ative field. Media, Culture and Society 21, 807–17.
Kingston, Jamaica. Environment and Planning A 34, — 2000a: The cultural economy of cities. London: Sage.
1833–54. — 2000b: The cultural economy of Paris. International
Power, D. and Scott, A. 2004: A prelude to cultural Journal of Urban and Regional Research 24, 567–82.
industries and the production of culture. In Power, D. — 2001: Capitalism, cities, and the production of
and Scott, A., editors, The cultural industries and the symbolic forms. Transactions of the Institute of British
production of culture, London and New York: Geographers NS 26, 11–23.
Routledge, 3–15. — 2002: A new map of Hollywood: the production and
Pratt, A.C. 1997a: The cultural industries production distribution of American motion pictures. Regional
system: a case study of employment change in Britain, Studies 36, 957–75.
1984–91. Environment and Planning A 29, 1953–74. Sheller, M. 2004: Mobile publics: beyond the network
— 1997b: The cultural industries sector: its definition perspective. Environment and Planning D: Society and
and character from secondary sources on employment Space 22, 39–52.
and trade, Britain 1984–91. Research Papers in Sidaway, J.D. 2000: Recontextualising positionality:
Environmental and Spatial Analysis, no. 41, London: geographical research and academic fields of power.
London School of Economics, 3–31. Antipode 32, 260–70.
— 1999: Digital places. London: London School of Singapore Ministry of Trade and Industry
Economics. Economic Review Committee 2002: Creative
— 2000a: New media, the new economy and new industries development strategy. ERC Report Sub-
spaces. Geoforum 31, 425–36. Committee on Service Industries. Retrieved 15 June
— 2000b: The cultural industries: the case of new media in 2004 from http://www.mti.gov.sg/public/ERC/
world cities. In Kawasaki, K., editor, Cultural globaliza- frm_ERC_Default.asp?sid ⫽ 131
tion and cultural industries: experiences in UK and Japan. Stevenson, D. 2003: Cities and urban cultures.
Japan: Ministry of Education, Science and Culture. Maidenhead: Open University Press.
Prince, S. 2000: A new pot of gold: hollywood under the Storper, M. 1997: Regional economies as relational
electronic rainbow, 1980–1989. New York: Charles assets. In Lee, R. and Willis, J., editors, Geographies of
Scribner’s Sons. economies, London: Arnold, 248–58.
Puttnam, D. and Watson, N. 1998: Movies and money. Thrift, N. 2000: Pandora’s box? Cultural geographies
New York: Knopf. of economies. In Clark, G.L., Feldman, M.P. and
Quah, D. 2002: Spatial agglomeration dynamics. Gertler, M.S., editors, The Oxford handbook of
American Economic Review 92, 247–52. economic geography, Oxford: Oxford University
Ray, L. and Sayer, A., editors 1999: Culture and Press, 689–704.
economy after the cultural turn. London: Sage. Throsby, D. 2001: Defining the artistic workforce: the
Robins, J.A. 1993: Organisation as strategy: restructur- Australian experience. Poetics 28, 255–71.
ing production in the film industry. Strategic Tonts, M. and Greive, S. 2002: Commodification and
Management Journal 14(Special Issue), 103–18. creative destruction in the Australian rural landscape:
Sadler, D. 1997: The global music business as an the case of Bridgetown, Western Australia.
information industry: reinterpreting economies of Australian Geographical Studies 40, 58–70.
culture. Environment and Planning A 29, 1919–36. Turok, I. 1993: Inward investment and local linkages:
Sanjek, D. 1998: Popular music and the synergy of how deeply embedded is ‘Silicon Glen’? Regional
corporate culture. In Swiss, T., Sloop, J. and Herman, Studies 27, 401–17.
A., editors, Mapping the beat: popular music and Worpole, K. and Greenhalgh, P. 1999: The richness of
contemporary theory, Oxford: Blackwell, 171–86. cities: urban policy in a new landscape. London:
Sassen, S. 2000: Analytic borderlands: economy and Comedia/Demos.
culture in the global city. In Bridge, G. and Watson, Yang, M. 2000: Putting global capitalism in its place:
S., editors, A companion to the city, Oxford: economic hybridity, Bataille, and ritual expenditure.
Blackwell, 168–80. Current Anthropology 41, 477–509.
Scott, A.J. 1996: The craft, fashion, and cultural- Yeung, H.W.C. 2003: Practicing new economic
products industries of Los Angeles: competitive geographies: a methodological examination. Annals
dynamics and policy dilemmas in a multisectoral of the Association of American Geographers 93,
image-producing complex. Annals of the Association 442–62.
of American Geographers 86, 306–23. Zukin, S. 1995: The cultures of cities. Oxford: Blackwell.

You might also like