Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 6

Nonlinear Persistence and Partial Insurance:

Income and Consumption Dynamics in the PSID


By M ANUEL A RELLANO , R ICHARD B LUNDELL AND S TEPHANE B ONHOMME∗

In this paper we highlight the important role used to provide new empirical measures of par-
the PSID has played in developing our under- tial insurance in which the transmission of in-
standing of income dynamics and partial insur- come shocks to consumption varies systemati-
ance, see for example, Krueger and Perri (2005), cally with assets, the level of the shock and the
Blundell, Pistaferri and Preston (BPP, 2008) and history of past shocks.
Attanasio and Pistaferri (2016).1 In the partial
insurance approach, transmission parameters are I. Earnings and consumption dynamics
specified that link ‘shocks’ to income with con-
sumption growth. These transmission param- A prototypical “canonical” panel data model
eters can change across time and may differ of (log) family (earned) income yit is:
across individuals reflecting the degree of ‘insur-
ance’ available. They encompass self-insurance yit = ηit + εit , i = 1, ..., N , t = 1, ..., T.
through simple credit markets as well as other
mechanisms used to smooth consumption. where yit is net of a systematic component, ηit
is a random walk with innovation v it ,
We explore the nonlinear nature of income
shocks and describe a new quantile-based panel ηit = ηit−1 +v it , i = 1, ..., N , t = 1, ..., T.
data framework for income dynamics, devel-
oped in Arellano, Blundell and Bonhomme and εit is a transitory shock.
(ABB, 2017). In this approach the persistence There is good economic reasoning behind this
of past income shocks is allowed to vary accord- decomposition: persistent shocks to income are
ing to the size and sign of the current shock. We more difficult to insure, especially for young
find that the model provides a good match with families with low assets. How families cope
data on family earnings and on individual wages with persistent shocks is the main focus of this
from the PSID. We confirm the results on in- research. Short-run fluctuations will matter too,
come dynamics using the extensive population of course, especially for households with low as-
register data from Norway. sets (or low access to liquid assets).
Exploiting the enhanced consumption and as- In the partial insurance framework, consump-
set data in recent waves of the PSID, we show tion growth is related to income shocks:
that nonlinear persistence has key implications
for consumption insurance. The approach is 4cit = φt v it + ψt εit + νit , i = 1, .N , t = 1, .T.

∗ Arellano: Cemfi, Madrid, arellano@cemfi.es Blun- where cit is log consumption net of a systematic
dell: University College London, Gower Street Lon- component, φt is the transmission of persistent
don, r.blundell@ucl.ac.uk Bonhomme: Chicago, sbon- shocks v it , and ψt the transmission of transitory
homme@uchicago.edu Acknowledgements: We are particularly
grateful to Luigi Pistaferri and Itay Saporta-Eksten for help
shocks; the νit are taste shocks, assumed to be
with the PSID data, Magne Mogstad and Michael Graber for independent across periods, see BPP.
providing the estimations using the Norwegian population This baseline panel data model specification
register data as part of the project on ‘Labour Income Dynamics can be summarised as:
and the Insurance from Taxes, Transfers and the Family’.
Arellano acknowledges research funding from the Ministerio de
Economı́a y Competitividad, Grant ECO2016-79848-P. Blundell 4cit = φv it + ψεit + νit ,
would like to thank the ESRC Centre CPP at IFS and the ERC
MicroConLab project for financial assistance. Bonhomme 4yit = v it + 4εit ,
acknowledges support from the European Research Council/
ERC grant agreement n0 263107. which implies covariance restrictions:
1 Blundell and Preston (1998) develop a similar framework
for repeated cross-section data. var (4cit ) = φ 2 σv2 + ψ 2 σε2 + σv2
1
2 PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MONTH YEAR

var (4yit ) = ση2 + 2σε2 lows ‘unusual’ shocks to wipe out the memory
of past shocks. Additionally the future persis-
cov(4yit 4yit−1 ) = −σε2 tence of a current shock will depend on future
cov(4cit 4yit ) = φσv2 + ψ σε2 shocks. We will see that the presence of ‘un-
usual’ shocks matches the data well and has a
cov(4cit−1 4yit ) = −ψ σε2 key impact on consumption and saving decisions
BPP show identification and efficient estimation over the life cycle.
using GMM. They include time(age) variation In this framework we maintain the permanent-
in the σ∗2 terms and in the insurance parameters. transitory factor structure
They also allow for measurement error and ex-
tend to MA(1) transitory shocks.2 yit = ηit + εit , i = 1, ..., N , t = 1, ..., T.
The parameters φt and ψt link the evolution
of consumption inequality to income inequality. but allow ηit to follow a general first-order
They indicate the degree of partial insurance, Markov process.3 Denoting the τ th conditional
and will differ by age, assets and human capital. quantile of ηit given ηi,t−1 as Q t (ηi,t−1 , τ ), we
For example, using a linearised approximation specify
to a simple benchmark intertemporal consump- ηit = Q t (ηi,t−1 , u it ),
tion model, Blundell, Low and Preston (2013) where (uit |ηi,t−1 , ηi,t−2 , ..) ∼ Uniform (0, 1),
show and εit has zero mean, independent over time.
φt = (1 − πit ) and ψt = (1 − πit )γ Lt The conditional quantile functions
Q t (ηi,t−1 , u it ) and the marginal distributions
where Fεt can all be age specific.
This framework allows for quite general non-
Assetsit linear dynamics of income, allowing a general
πit ≈
Assetsit + Human Wealthit form of conditional heteroscedasticity, skewness
and kurtosis. To see this, consider the following
and γ Lt is the annuity value of a temporary
measure of persistence
shock to income for an individual aged t retir-
ing at age L. ∂ Q t (ηi,t−1 , τ )
In the PSID estimates of (1 − πit ) typically ρt (ηi,t−1 , τ ) = .
∂η
average at around .82. BPP estimate a partial
insurance coefficient of .642 (.09). They docu- which measures the persistence of ηi,t−1 when,
ment higher values for samples without college at age t, it is hit by a shock u it that has rank τ .
education, for older cohorts, and for low wealth This measures the persistence of histories. Be-
samples. low we show strong evidence for such nonlin-
This linearised partial insurance framework earities in persistence.
provides key insights on the distributional dy-
namics of income and consumption. How- III. An Empirical Model for Consumption
ever, it rules out the nonlinear transmission of
shocks and restricts interactions in consumption
responses. To motivate the specification of consumption
we use a standard life-cycle incomplete mar-
II. Nonlinear Persistence kets model (some arguments are latent). Let
cit and ait denote log-consumption and assets
The aim in the new work on nonlinear persis- (beginning of period) net of age dummies. We
tence is to step back from the standard panel data model consumption in levels and leave the non-
model of income dynamics and take a different linear rule flexible. Our empirical specification
track: develop an alternative approach in which is based on
the impact of past shocks can be altered by the
size and sign of new shocks. The framework al- cit = gt (ait , ηit , εit , νit ) t = 1, ..., T,

2 Blundell and Preston (1998) develop these covariance re- 3 The first-order Markov assumption can be generalised to
strictions for repeated cross-sections. Markov (p), with any fixed p (although this requires larger T).
VOL. VOL NO. ISSUE NONLINEAR PERSISTENCE AND PARTIAL INSURANCE 3

F IGURE 1. Q UANTILE AUTOREGRESSIONS OF LOG - EARNINGS

(a) PSID data (b) Norwegian administrative data

1.2

1 1.2
persistence

1
0.8

persistence
0.8
0.6
0.6
0.4
0.4
0.2
0.2
0
1 0
1
0.8 1 0.8 1
0.6 0.8 0.6 0.8
0.4 0.6 0.6
0.4 0.4
0.2 0.4
0.2 0.2 0.2
0 0
percentile τ percentile τ percentile τ
0 0
percentile τ
init shock init shock

Note: Residuals yit of log pre-tax household labor earnings, Age 25-60 1999-2009 (US), Age 25-60 2005-2006 (Norway). Estimates
of the average derivative of the conditional quantile function of yit given yi,t−1 with respect to yi,t−1 . Quantile functions are specified
as third-order Hermite polynomials.
Source: Arellano, Blundell Bonhomme (2017).

where νit are independent across periods, and gt also cases where the consumption rule depends
is a nonlinear, age-dependent function, mono- on lagged η, or when η follows a second-order
tone in νit , νit may be interpreted a taste shifter Markov process, see Section 3 in ABB. The
that increases marginal utility. This consump- framework allow for additional, unobserved het-
tion rule is consistent, in particular, with the erogeneity in earnings and consumption. House-
standard life-cycle model, e.g. Kaplan and Vi- holds will also differ in their initial productivity
olante (2010). ABB derive conditions under η1 and initial assets.
which g is nonparametrically identified.
IV. Data and Estimation
With consumption specification given by

cit = gt (ait , ηit , εit , νit ) , t = 1, ..., T, The PSID went through a redesign in the late
1990s, introducing new consumption and asset
consumption responses to η and ε are modules. Since 1999 it collects some 70% of
consumption expenditures, and more than 90%
 
∂gt (a, η, ε, ν) since 2005. We use the sum of food at home,
φt (a, η, ε) = E , food away from home, gasoline, health, trans-
∂η
portation, utilities, etc. We also make use of
 
∂gt (a, η, ε, ν) the more detailed asset data, see Blundell, Pista-
ψt (a, η, ε) = E . ferri and Saporta-Eksten (2016), BPS. For com-
∂ε
parison we make use of family earnings data
where φt (a, η, ε) and ψt (a, η, ε) reflect the
from administrative records from the Norwegian
transmission of the persistent and transitory
population registers see Blundell, Graber and
earnings components, respectively. They gen-
Mogstad (2015).4
eralise the partial insurance coefficients of BPP.
The results we present on the PSID use data
Similar techniques can be used in the presence from the 1999 - 2009 surveys. Assets holdings
of advance information, e.g. are the sum of financial assets, real estate value,
 pension funds, and car value, net of mortgages
cit = gt ait , ηit , ηi,t+1 , εit , νit , and other debt. Income yit are residuals of log

or consumption habits, e.g. 4 The Norwegian results are part of the project on ‘Labour

 Income Dynamics and the Insurance from Taxes, Transfers and


cit = gt ci,t−1 , ait , ηit , εit , νit . the Family’. See ABB Appendix C.
4 PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MONTH YEAR

total pre-tax household labor earnings on a set of to ηi,t−1 , evaluated at percentile τshock and at
demographics - cohort and calendar time dum- a value of ηi,t−1 that corresponds to the τinit
mies, family size and composition, education, percentile of the distribution of ηi,t−1 . The es-
race, and state dummies. Log consumption cit timates are evaluated at mean age in the sam-
is also a residual, using the same set of demo- ple. Panel (b) in Figure 2 is based on data simu-
graphics as for earnings. Following BPS, we se- lated according to our nonlinear earnings model
lect married male heads aged between 25 and 59. with parameters set to their estimated values. It
In this paper we focus on a balanced sub-sample shows a close accordance with the persistence in
of N = 792 households. the PSID income data, see panel (a) of Figure 1.
The conditional quantile function for the per- Moving to the estimated consumption model,
manent income factor ηit , given ηi,t−1 , is speci- Figure 3 displays the average derivative of the
fied as conditional mean of cit given yit , ait and ageit
with respect to yit , evaluated at values of ait
Q t (ηt−1 , τ ) = Q(ηt−1 , aget , τ ) and ageit corresponding to their τassets and τage
K
X percentiles, and averaged over the values of yit .
= akQ (τ )ϕk (ηt−1 , aget ), It shows consumption responses vary system-
k=0 atically with age and assets and in a way that
accords with stand life-cycle theory. It also
where ϕk , k = 0, 1, ..., K , are polynomials shows a clear accordance between the consump-
(Hermite). Similarly for εit etc. The consump- tion model and data.
tion (log) function, g(at , ηt , εt , aget ), is speci- Finally, we provide preliminary evidence that
fied as a flexible polynomial in assets, perma- the nonlinear persistence we have uncovered in
nent income factor, the transitory shock and age. family earnings data is also evident in hourly
Estimation takes place in two steps, see ABB wage data. Figure 4, panel (a), presents es-
for details. The first step recovers estimates of timates of nonlinear persistence in the perma-
the income parameters. The second step re- nent component for PSID male hourly earnings.
covers estimates of the consumption parameters, Panel (b) provides the implication from the sim-
given an estimate of the income parameters. The ulated nonlinear model. These results show an
estimation algorithm alternates between draws important role for unusual shocks and nonlinear
of latent variables from candidate posteriors and persistence in hourly wage data, suggesting non-
quantile regressions using those draws, see also linear persistence maybe a key feature for life-
Arellano and Bonhomme (2016). cycle models of family labor supply.
V. Empirical Results
VI. Summary and Conclusions
Figure 1 provides our initial evidence for non-
linear income dynamics. It presents estimates of In this paper we have outlined a new frame-
the average derivative of the conditional quan- work to shed new light on income dynamics
tile function of yit given yi,t−1 with respect to and nonlinear transmission of income shocks
yi,t−1 for both the PSID in panel (a), and the to consumption. We have exploited important
Norwegian register data in panel (b). These are new measurements for consumption and assets
evaluated at percentiles of the shock τshock and in the PSID. We have also shown the comple-
at a value of yi,t−1 that corresponds to the τinit mentarities between ‘big’ administrative data,
percentile of the distribution of yi,t−1 . like the Norwegian registers, and purpose de-
The estimates in Figure 1 display distinct and signed panel surveys, like the PSID.
systematic nonlinearity. The persistence of in- A Markovian permanent-transitory model of
come shocks is much lower for large negative household income, which reveals asymmetric
(positive) shocks for high (low) initial incomes. persistence of unusual shocks, is shown to ac-
The results for the PSID are confirmed in panel cord well with the persistence of income in the
(b) for the Norwegian data. PISD and in Norwegian register data. An age-
Turning to the income model, Figure 2, panel dependent nonlinear consumption rule as a func-
(a) provides estimates of the average derivative tion of assets, permanent income and transitory
of the conditional quantile function of the per- income, is also applied to the PSID and shown
sistent income factor ηit on ηi,t−1 with respect to generate new empirical measures of the de-
VOL. VOL NO. ISSUE NONLINEAR PERSISTENCE AND PARTIAL INSURANCE 5

F IGURE 2. N ONLINEAR PERSISTENCE

(a) Persistent component ηit (b) Earnings, nonlinear model

1.2 1.2

1 1
persistence

persistence
0.8 0.8

0.6 0.6

0.4 0.4

0.2 0.2

0 0
1 1
0.8 1 0.8 1
0.6 0.8 0.6 0.8
0.4 0.6 0.4 0.6
0.4 0.4
0.2 0.2 0.2 0.2
0 0 0 0
percentile τ percentile τ percentile τ percentile τ
init shock init shock

Note: PSID data. Graph (a) shows estimates of the average derivative of the conditional quantile function of ηit on ηi,t−1 with respect
to ηi,t−1 , based on estimates from the nonlinear earnings model. Graph (b) is based on data simulated according to our nonlinear
earnings model with parameters set to their estimated values. Source: Arellano, Blundell and Bonhomme (2017).

F IGURE 3. C ONSUMPTION RESPONSES TO yit , BY ASSETS AND AGE

(a) PSID data (b) Nonlinear model

0.5
0.5
consumption response

0.4
consumption response

0.4
0.3
0.3
0.2
0.2

0.1 0.1

0 0
0 0 1
0.2 1 0.2 0.8
0.4 0.8 0.4 0.6
0.6 0.6 0.6 0.4
0.4
0.8 0.2 0.8 0.2
1 0 1 0 percentile τ
percentile τassets
percentile τage percentile τ assets
age

Note: Estimates of the average derivative of the conditional mean of cit given yit , ait & ageit with respect to yit , evaluated at values
of ait & ageit corresponding to their τassets & τage percentiles, and averaged over the values of yit . Source: Arellano, Blundell and
Bonhomme (2017).
6 PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MONTH YEAR

F IGURE 4. N ONLINEAR PERSISTENCE IN M ALE H OURLY WAGES

(a) Persistent component ηit (b) Earnings, nonlinear model

1.2 1.2

1 1
persistence

persistence
0.8 0.8

0.6 0.6

0.4 0.4

0.2 0.2

0 0
1 1
0.8 1 0.8 1
0.6 0.8 0.6 0.8
0.4 0.6 0.4 0.6
0.4 0.4
0.2 0.2 0.2 0.2
0 0 0 0
percentile τinit percentile τ percentile τinit percentile τ
shock shock

Note: Log male wages, Age 30-60 PSID 1999-2013 (US). Estimates of the average derivative of the conditional quantile function.
Source: Authors calculations.

gree of partial insurance. Risk Using Consumption Data”, Quantitative


The results also point to nonlinearities in the Economics, vol. 4(1), pages 1-37, 03.
dynamics of individual male wages. In future re- Blundell, Richard, and Ian Preston (1998)
search we will explore the impact of such non- “Consumption Inequality and Income Uncer-
linear persistence on family labour supply and tainty.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113(2):
consumption smoothing, building on Blundell, 603-640.
Saporta-Eksten and Pistaferri (2010) and Heath- Blundell, R., L. Pistaferri, and I. Preston
cote, Storesletten, and Violante (2014). (2008): Inequality and Partial Insurance,” Amer-
Future research could also usefully examine ican Economic Review, 98(5): 18871921.
firm to firm transitions and lay-offs, it could Blundell, R., L. Pistaferri, and I. Saporta-
focus on the role of housing equity and local Eksten (2016): Smoothing and Family Labor
labour markets. It could also look at health and Supply, American Economic Review, 106(2),
other types of (partially insured) shocks. 387-435.
A final word to the PSID. Congratulations at Guvenen, F., F. Karahan, S. Ozcan, and J.
50! Thanks for everything, for all those many Song (2015): What Do Data on Millions of
micro-data innovations and looking forward to U.S. Workers Reveal about Life-Cycle Earnings
the next 50 years! Risk?” NBER WP 20913.
REFERENCES Guvenen, F., and A. Smith (2014): Labor In-
Arellano, M., and S. Bonhomme (2016): come Risk from Economic Choices: An Indirect
Panel Data Estimation via Quantile Regres- Inference Approach,” Econometrica, November,
sions,” Econometrics Journal, 19, C61-C94. 82(6), 20852129.
Arellano, M., Blundell, R. and S. Bonhomme Heathcote, J., K. Storesletten, and G. Vi-
(2017): Earnings and Consumption Dynamics: olante (2014): and Labor Supply with Partial In-
A Nonlinear Panel Data Framework”, Econo- surance: An Analytical Framework,” American
metrica, 85, 693- 734 Economic Review, July, 104(7), 20752126.
Attanasio, Orazio. P., Luigi Pistaferri (2016) Kaplan, Greg and Giovanni Violante (2010),
‘Consumption Inequality’, Journal of Economic “How Much Consumption Insurance Beyond
Perspectives, vol. 30, no. 2, Spring (pp. 3-28) Self-Insurance.”American Economic Journal,
Blundell, R., M. Graber and M. Mogstad 2(4), 53-87.
(2015): Income Dynamics and the Insurance Krueger, Dirk, and Fabrizio Perri. 2006.
from Taxes, Transfers, and the Family,” Journal “Does Income Inequality Lead to Consumption
of Public Economics, 127, 5873. Inequality? Evidence and Theory.” Review of
Blundell, Richard, Hamish Low and Ian Pre- Economic Studies, 73(1): 163-193.
ston (2013) “Decomposing Changes in Income

You might also like