Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 8

Journal of Retailing and Consumer Services ∎ (∎∎∎∎) ∎∎∎–∎∎∎

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Journal of Retailing and Consumer Services


journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jretconser

Effects of pricing strategies and product quality on private label


and national brand performance
Rainer Olbrich, Hans Christian Jansen n, Michael Hundt
University of Hagen, Universitätsstr. 11, 58097 Hagen, Germany

art ic l e i nf o a b s t r a c t

Using product test ratings and panel data from more than 35,000 participating households in Germany,
Keywords: this study addresses the impacts of price, quality, and promotion shares on the market shares of different
Pricing products, including national brands and private labels, as well as food and non-food products. The results
Quality of a path analysis reveal important differences across the four segments, as well as insights regarding the
National brand use of everyday low price and high–low retail pricing strategies. The findings also lead to key implica-
Private label tions for manufacturers and retailers.
EDLP & 2016 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
HiLo

1. Introduction literature. Even as retail market conditions continue to change


rapidly, current marketing literature lacks an up-to-date analysis
In the German consumer goods market, concentration and that relies on actual purchasing data or product quality informa-
crowding at the retail level has proceeded steadily over time, tion (Anders, 2008; Groeppel, 1993; Machek, 2012). We seek to
leading to greater sales consolidation among a few, large retailers close this gap by analyzing the determinants of market share ac-
(Anders, 2008; Olbrich and Grewe, 2013; Weiss and Wittkopp, cording to German panel data that reflect reports by more than
2005). The underlying concentration process parallels several de- 35,000 households. In addition, we account for product quality
velopments related to price, product, and product range policies information as one possible determinant of market share. Instead
(Lamm, 1981; Olbrich and Grewe, 2009, 2013; Olbrich et al., 2009). of surveys or experiments, which are common in prior research,
For example, regarding the ranges of products, some retailers have we investigate actual purchasing behavior using a broad, re-
chosen to adopt dual roles, offering their own products and ser- presentative database. In so doing, we address potential differ-
vices (i.e., private labels), often at a lower price than comparable ences across expressed attitudes, intentions, and behavior (Belk,
national brands (Méndez et al., 2008; Olbrich and Grewe, 2009), 1985). Furthermore, we differentiate between national brands and
rather than solely distributing goods produced by the branded private labels at the product level (brand type) and between food
goods industry. The resulting proliferation of private labels invokes and non-food products at the commodity group level (product
strong price competition (Connor and Peterson, 1992; Olbrich and type). Thus, we are able to highlight differences among the four
Grewe, 2013; Olbrich et al., 2009, 2014). segments.
This study investigates the impact of price, pricing strategy, and To reach these insights, we start with a foundation in research
product quality on the overall market share of a particular product, that shows that consumers tend to link the perceived quality of
in an effort to answer two key research questions: private labels with their view of the retailer. Private-label product
RQ1:What impacts do product price, pricing strategy, and quality thus is particularly important for defining the retail brand
product quality have on the market shares of different product and and establishing store attractiveness, and retailers seek sufficiently
brand types? high quality to avoid negative carryover from their private label to
RQ2:What differences arise between national brands and pri- their retail brand (Olbrich and Jansen, 2014; Vahie and Paswan,
vate labels? Between food and non-food products? 2006). Unlike prices, product quality is difficult to change and
We address these questions in the dynamic German retailing cannot be adjusted quickly. For national brands, product quality
sector and thereby make several substantive contributions to also has the critical task of justifying any price premium and en-
suring a competitive advantage (Steenkamp et al., 2010).
n
Yet the prevalence of private labels continues to increase, in
Corresponding author.
E-mail addresses: Rainer.Olbrich@fernuni-hagen.de (R. Olbrich),
turn creating greater price competition between private labels and
Hans.Jansen@FernUni-Hagen.de (H.C. Jansen), corresponding national brands, as well as among the various pri-
Michael.Hundt@fernuni-hagen.de (M. Hundt). vate labels offered by different retailers (Blattberg and Wisniewski,

http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jretconser.2016.01.012
0969-6989/& 2016 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

Please cite this article as: Olbrich, R., et al., Effects of pricing strategies and product quality on private label and national brand
performance. Journal of Retailing and Consumer Services (2016), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jretconser.2016.01.012i
2 R. Olbrich et al. / Journal of Retailing and Consumer Services ∎ (∎∎∎∎) ∎∎∎–∎∎∎

1989; Olbrich and Grewe, 2013). Therefore, retailers actively seek target outcome for many companies. Yet empirical literature often
different pricing strategies to establish unique profiles (Ellickson fails to measure market share or its underlying consumer beha-
and Misra, 2008). For example, a retailer that adopts a high–low viors and focuses instead on preferences, purchase intentions, or
(HiLo) promotion strategy tries to stimulate customer demand queries to proxy for recent and current purchasing behavior,
through time-limited price promotions. Price-based special offers generally due to a lack of available data (e.g., Anselmsson and Jo-
aim to attract consumers to the store while also signaling price hansson, 2009; Sinha and Batra, 1999; Walsh and Mitchell, 2010).
competency for the assortment. In contrast, a retailer with an Yet actual retail market conditions, including intensified compe-
everyday low price (EDLP) strategy largely eliminates price pro- tition among retailers competing for market share by offering
motions and offers products for a consistently low, non-varying national brands and private labels in food and non-food sectors,
price (Pechtl, 2004). indicates the powerful need to identify the primary determinants
All these competitive factors—prices, price strategies, and pro- of market share.
duct quality decisions—also depend on the product type, such as From our empirical findings, we also derive managerial im-
whether the offering is a food or a non-food product (Böhm et al., plications for manufacturers and retailers. In particular, the results of
2007; Olbrich and Jansen, 2014). Food invokes habituated pur- our multigroup path analysis reveal the impacts of price, pricing
chasing behavior; consumers generally use non-food products for strategy, and product quality on market shares. By calculating critical
longer periods. Non-food products also are associated with greater ratios for differences, we compare both brand and product types and
expenses, perceived purchase risk, and involvement in the deci- find that in the food sector, a higher price results in a lower market
sion process. Accordingly, retailers can and should strategically share for both national brands and private labels, whereas in the
adjust several factors to succeed in competitive retail environ- non-food sector, the reverse is true. For all four segments, higher
ments: their pricing policies (price levels and pricing strategy), the product quality leads to more market share. However, for the pricing
quality of the products in their assortment, and considerations of strategy, the results are more controversial. That is, for national
the differences between national brands and private labels, as well brands, a HiLo pricing strategy seems appropriate, because it in-
as between food and non-food products. To highlight the necessity creases market share for both food and non-food products. For
of such considerations, Fig. 1 details the notable revenue shares of private labels though, an EDLP pricing strategy is preferable; the
private labels of food products in several countries (METRO AG, increased use of price campaigns for private labels goes hand-in-
2015). For example, in Germany, private labels enjoy an average hand with reductions in their market share.
market share of 34.5 percent. In the next section, we present the theoretical background on
In general, market share represents an important economic pricing strategies and product quality, from which we derive
figure for decision makers (Buzzell et al., 1975), because it reflects several propositions regarding food/non-food national brands/
the firm's own position in relation to competitors’. In this sense, private labels. After outlining the data and method for our em-
market share provides an indicator of the likely long-term success pirical study, we discuss the results and present managerial im-
of a company. The cutthroat competition in the consumer goods plications for manufacturers and retailers, while also noting some
sector also has moved market share into a central position as a limitations of our study.

Switzerland 44.5%
Spain 42.0%
Great Britain 41.4%
Germany 34.5%
Portugal 32.9%
Belgium 31.3%
Austria 28.5%
France 27.4%
Netherlands 27.2%
Denmark 25.4%
Sweden 25.2%
Hungary 25.2%
Poland 24.3%
Finnland 23.6%
Slovakia 22.7%
Norway 22.7%
Czech Republic 22.4%
Italy 17.6%
0% 10% 20% 30% 40% 50%
Fig. 1. Revenue Share of Private Labels in 2014.

Please cite this article as: Olbrich, R., et al., Effects of pricing strategies and product quality on private label and national brand
performance. Journal of Retailing and Consumer Services (2016), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jretconser.2016.01.012i
R. Olbrich et al. / Journal of Retailing and Consumer Services ∎ (∎∎∎∎) ∎∎∎–∎∎∎ 3

2. Literature overview Few studies combine pricing strategy with brand type though.
In an EDLP setting, the price differences between national and
2.1. Pricing strategies private-label brands is more visible for consumers, but the per-
formance of private labels remains unclear. Dhar and Hoch (1997)
In retailing, an ideal pricing strategy reflects a well-informed offer ambivalent results, in which EDLP benefits private labels only
choice between offering relatively stable prices across a wide range in categories with lower quality, though retailers’ promotional
of products or emphasizing deep and frequent discounts on a smaller activities can enhance private-label shares. Furthermore, Pechtl
set of goods (Ellickson and Misra, 2008). The first strategy implies (2004): 230 points out that EDLP-prone consumers exhibit greater
everyday low pricing (EDLP), whereas the second refers to promo- brand preferences than HiLo-prone shoppers, possibly due to their
tional pricing (HiLo), such that the two strategies represent a con- higher risk awareness, which “implies that EDLP programs should
tinuum (Ailawadi and Keller, 2004; Hoch et al., 1994). When they use use national brands and not private or virtually unknown labels.”
EDLP, retailers quote a fixed, low price for every time period and For this investigation, we examine the impact of pricing stra-
avoid price promotions, and they target consumers who are not tegies on market share by differentiating both between private
willing to expend substantial time or effort to find the best prices labels and national brands and between food and non-food pro-
(e.g., visiting different stores, looking for coupons). With a HiLo ap- ducts. This distinction leads to differentiated insights about the
proach, retailers instead use frequent promotional prices to attract impacts of pricing strategies on performance in individual product
consumers who actively search for attractive prices for individual segments.
products. However, their normal product prices tend to be higher
than those in EDLP stores (Ghose et al., 2005). 2.2. Product quality
By adopting a position according to these strategic pricing
poles, retailers try to influence consumers’ store choices and During the 1930s, comparative product tests were established
purchasing behavior (Ailawadi and Keller, 2004). Bell and Lattin in the United States. Nelson (1970), in distinguishing between
(1998) show that large basket shoppers prefer EDLP stores, experience and search goods and between durable and non-dur-
whereas small basket shoppers tend toward HiLo stores (see also able goods, suggests that test ratings are more applicable to pur-
Pechtl, 2004). The former shoppers are more sensitive to prices chase decisions involving experience rather than search goods and
across many categories, because they purchase in many product for durable rather than non-durable goods. Marquardt and
categories and lack the flexibility to take advantage of occasional McGann (1975) also underline the importance of test ratings for
price deals. Therefore, large basket shoppers seek lower prices for consumer well-being but caution that heavily advertised products
their complete basket by purchasing in EDLP stores. Small basket tend to earn unusually high proportions of top quality ratings.
shoppers instead can take advantage of price variations for single They also establish that it is less likely that consumers will pur-
products over time. By purchasing products when they are on sale, chase products with poor test ratings.
they lower their overall basket price, even if the average prices in Especially when they consider new products, consumers may
the HiLo stores they prefer are comparatively high. Ho et al. (1998) sense a purchase risk, due to their lack of experience. Many of
also show that the average prices in HiLo stores are comparatively them are risk averse, such that negative information and poor
higher, but the average purchase quantities are lower. Therefore, a product quality have strong impacts on consumers’ decision-
HiLo pricing strategy increases purchasing frequency, whereas an making processes (Kahneman and Tversky, 1979). As Mizerski
EDLP approach decreases it. Furthermore, EDLP generates higher (1982) points out, unfavorable ratings have significantly stronger
revenue per unit of time than HiLo. Such findings help explain why effects on product performance and purchasing behavior than do
both pricing strategies can coexist in practice. favorable product ratings. In this context, negative product per-
Hoch et al. (1994) also examine the impact of category-level formance exerts a greater impact on consumers’ decision not to
price changes on sales responses, using field experiments in 26 buy a product (Shen and Wyer, 2008).
product categories sold by an 86-store grocery chain. Its inelastic However, product tests can change the scope and structure of
response to changes in everyday prices makes an EDLP format consumers’ information processing (Kaas and Tölle, 1981), in that
generally inappropriate for increasing purchase quantity. In this they enable consumers to use test ratings before purchasing a
sense, the HiLo format outperforms the EDLP format in terms of product, which also prompts them to rely more on other in-
profitability. However, Ghose et al. (2005) note that manufacturers formation sources, such as the advice of store clerks. Therefore,
that face constant demand can better match their production level test ratings influence not just purchasing behavior but also social
to market demand when they supply independent EDLP stores. In impact levels. For example, poor product quality may lead to in-
contrast, the supply to HiLo stores fluctuates with demand, which creased customer churn rates or direct dissent, in the form of
in turn varies in response to changing prices. To cover such fluc- negative word of mouth or complaints.
tuating demands, retailers must carry deep and expensive in- Previous research also investigates the effect of product quality
ventories. Finally, Gauri et al. (2008) argue that improved service on key outcomes, such as revenue or sales volume. The most
features, higher income neighborhoods, populous neighborhoods, discussed studies in this context are based on the PIMS database
and distance to competition are elements more associated with (Buzzell and Gale, 1987). In general, studies find that product
HiLo than with EDLP pricing strategies. Accordingly, Ellickson and quality has a strong impact on business success, as represented by
Misra (2008) suggest that EDLP is usually aimed at lower income market share, among other key variables. In an interview study,
consumers with larger families. Fritz et al. (1984) find that 82 percent of interviewed retailers
As these examples show, prior literature mainly discusses pri- reported diminished sales volumes subsequent to the publication
cing strategies in relation to the stores themselves and consumers’ of a poor test rating, leading to revenue decreases of 15–27 per-
store choices (e.g., Bell and Lattin, 1998; Gauri et al., 2008; Ho cent. Nineteen percent of interviewed manufacturers indicated a
et al., 1998). However, Bolton and Shankar (2003) show that pri- significant drop in revenue due to poor product quality, and 92
cing strategies often reflect the brand rather than the store level, percent of all interviewed stores and mail-order companies
such that several strategies might coexist within a single store. eliminated products that scored poorly on the tests from their
Shankar and Bolton (2004) also argue that retailers’ pricing stra- assortments, though this level was only 33 percent among spe-
tegies and tactics depend on upstream (e.g., manufacturer/brand, cialized retail stores. In another survey, Hilger et al. (1984) find
category) and downstream (customer) factors. that 40 percent of the interviewed department stores lowered the

Please cite this article as: Olbrich, R., et al., Effects of pricing strategies and product quality on private label and national brand
performance. Journal of Retailing and Consumer Services (2016), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jretconser.2016.01.012i
4 R. Olbrich et al. / Journal of Retailing and Consumer Services ∎ (∎∎∎∎) ∎∎∎–∎∎∎

prices of products that earned poor quality ratings. Jin and Leslie promotional prices), as an indicator of price promotions. A high
(2003) also uncover altered consumer behavior and shifts in de- promotion share signals a frequent use of price promotions (i.e.,
mand away from poor providers toward good providers. In a res- HiLo pricing strategy) and a low promotion share signals an EDLP
taurant setting, they observe that demand increases at restaurants pricing strategy (Ellickson and Misra, 2008). We predict that a high
with good hygiene reviews but decreases for providers that receive promotion share attracts customers and ultimately results in
poor hygiene reviews. higher market share for the corresponding, promoted national
Objective quality has a greater impact on perceived quality brands.
than subjective expertise or familiarity (Cordell, 1997), though However, for private labels, a high promotion share may lead to
quality perceptions also depend on consumers’ knowledge. Simi- low market shares (Dhar and Hoch, 1997), for both food and non-
larly, Moussa and Touzani (2008) highlight that quality informa- food products. Price promotions of private labels likely represent a
tion can reduce asymmetric information, such that consumers can strategic effort to dispose of poorly selling products. In addition,
better judge product quality, leading them to develop stronger customers that choose to buy private labels generally seek non-
intentions to buy. Publicity relates to product quality perceptions varying prices, to reduce the effort involved in comparing prices
too (Dean, 2004). Ahluwalia et al. (2000) argue that commitment (Olbrich and Grewe, 2009; Ortmeyer et al., 1991). Retailers ac-
influences consumer behaviors in response to negative publicity; cordingly use private labels to signal their pricing competency and
Reinstein and Snyder (2005) find that negative reviews have sig- increase the attractiveness of their stores (Olbrich and Jansen,
nificant negative effects on revenue. Simonsohn (2011) further 2014). Therefore, private labels should be offered at a low, non-
asserts that expert advice sways consumer demand, though the varying price, which results in a low promotion share for these
link is difficult to uncover, because expert recommendations may products.
correlate with other information consumers hold. We assume that price has a negative impact on market share: A
higher price decreases the market share of the corresponding
product (Dhar and Hoch, 1997). However, this relationship may
exhibit varying strengths for segments of food/non-food national
3. Propositions
brands/private labels. For food products, previous studies show
that consumers’ price consciousness drives purchases of private
Fig. 2 presents our research framework, with which we analyze
labels (e.g., Anselmsson and Johansson, 2009; Baltas, 1997; Burger
the impact of product price, promotion share, and product quality
and Schott, 1972; Hsu and Lai, 2008; Lin et al., 2009; Olbrich et al.,
on the market share of corresponding products. We adopt a
2014; Sinha and Batra, 1999). Their low prices provide an incentive
multigroup methodology to account for the moderating effects of
for consumers to buy private labels instead of national brands. For
both product type and brand type. To estimate the impacts of
national brands, price still is important, but its impact on con-
these independent variables on market share, we derive our pro-
sumers’ buying decision is weaker than that for private labels.
positions on the basis of prior literature.
Therefore, the impact of the price of private-label food products on
Our in-depth literature review reveals that product quality
their market share should be greater than the impact for national
positively influences the market shares of both food and non-food
brand foods.
products, as well as private labels and national brands (Garvin,
For national brands, we also predict a different relationship
1984; Hoch and Banerji, 1993). If the quality of a product is poor, it
between price and market share. Non-food products generally are
loses attractiveness and its market share decreases, independent
used for longer than food products (e.g., a bottle of detergent is
of product or brand type. In addition to lowered consumer de-
used for more time than a carton of milk). The usage patterns
mand, retailers react to poorly performing products in ways that
suggest non-food products may be adopted in conjunction with
likely decrease their market share further, such as by delisting
more expensive, previous purchases, such as detergent used to
poor quality private labels and national brands (Olbrich et al.,
watch an expensive shirt. Therefore, consumers’ involvement in
2016). Therefore, in all cases, higher quality should result in
this purchase process should be higher (Laurent and Kapferer,
greater market share.
1985; Rothschild, 1979). Perceived purchase risks also tend to be
Price promotions also are independent of the food versus non-
lower when prices are higher, because consumers assume a linear
food product type, suitable for any products that are well known relationship between price and quality (Olbrich and Jansen, 2014).
to the customer and widely available. For retailers, well-known, Accordingly, we anticipate that for non-food products, price has a
ubiquitous national brands are appealing targets for price pro- smaller impact on market share than it does for food products.
motions, because they can attract customers to stores (Ailawadi Noting the conventional wisdom about the price–quality re-
et al., 2001). In this context, price promotions represent the re- lationship, we even predict that a higher price may result in a
tailer's effort to define its brand in the competitive environment higher market share for some non-food national brands.
(Olbrich et al., 2014). We use promotion share, defined as all sales
at promotional prices divided by total sales (at normal and
4. Data and method

Product Price We gained access to a German consumer panel with purchase


data about products bought by approximately 35,000 households
between 2006 and 2011. The data set consists of 1,473,070 records,
each representing one product bought by one household on one
Promotion Share Market Share day. For this study, we selected as focal products roasted coffee
(1,187,996 records) and detergent powders (285,074 records). We
chose these product categories according to the availability of test
ratings and to account for differences between food and non-food
products as explanatory factors for distinct purchasing behaviors
Product Quality (Böhm et al., 2007; Olbrich and Jansen, 2014). The panel's re-
presentative character enables us to calculate market shares,
Fig. 2. Conceptual Framework. promotion shares, and prices for each product.

Please cite this article as: Olbrich, R., et al., Effects of pricing strategies and product quality on private label and national brand
performance. Journal of Retailing and Consumer Services (2016), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jretconser.2016.01.012i
R. Olbrich et al. / Journal of Retailing and Consumer Services ∎ (∎∎∎∎) ∎∎∎–∎∎∎ 5

Table 1 products  72 months). However, the market introduction of a few


Distribution of national brand and private label sales. products was later than the start of our observation, so we ob-
tained 1,139 observations for our database (see Table 2). This ap-
Product type National brand Private label
proach enabled us to avoid imbalances across different products or
Food 78.95% 21.05% commodity groups. In calculating the quality and price measures,
Non-Food 43.44% 56.56% we considered them relative to the average quality or price in the
commodity group for the selected products for each month. In
addition, we distinguished between national brands and private
Both roasted coffee as a food and detergent powder as a non-
labels.
food product are designated for daily use. However, the con-
Our path analysis, based on a multigroup methodology, used an
sumption of coffee should induce less risk than the use of de-
asymptotically distribution-free estimator to estimate the impact
tergent powders. If coffee tastes poor, it is the only damage the
of the price, promotion share, and product quality simultaneously
consumer will suffer. In contrast, laundry needs to be cleaned both
on the market share of the corresponding product, even as we
well and gently, to preserve long-term use of clothing. Thus, the
differentiated between food and non-food products and between
purchase process of detergent powders likely differs from the
national brands and private labels. Finally, we calculated critical
purchase process for coffee, characterized by not only higher in- ratios for differences to compare the four segments. These z-values
volvement but also a greater need for quality. represent differences across estimates, divided by an estimate of
Our database covers 35,303 households. With regard to the the standard error of the difference.
demographics of the panel sample, most households have no
children (81.16%) or one child (10.41%) under the age of 14. They
are relatively evenly split among households that consist of one 5. Results and discussion
person (35.33%), two persons (35.99%), or more (28.68%). Many
households earn net income between 1,250 € and 1,499 € (10.21%) To determine the impacts of prices, pricing strategies, and
or between 2,000 € and 2,249 € (10.58%). Table 1 presents the product quality, we measured the market share of each product
distribution of private labels and national brands. For food pro- according to the sales volume represented in the German house-
ducts, national brands dominate. For non-food products, private hold panel data, while differentiating between national brands
labels outnumber national brands. Thus, we find differences in the and private labels and between food and non-food products. Ta-
distribution of food versus non-food products, as well as between ble 2 contains the descriptive statistics for our aggregated data set,
private labels and national brands. including the number of cases (N), minimum and maximum va-
To measure product quality, we supplemented the consumer lues, means, and standard deviations for product price, product
panel data with test ratings published by Stiftung Warentest (Sti- quality, promotion share, and market share, separated by brand
Wa), in three issues of its magazine between 2009 and 2010. StiWa and product type.
performs impartial and objective product tests. To ensure non- Using national brand food products as an example, our analysis
alignment, it conducts independent test planning, does not accept featured 1,139 cases. Each case described the four focal variables
advertisements in its publications, and relies on anonymous pur- for one product in one month. Thus product price was relative to
chases of test samples. We could match 56 tested products with the commodity group, and with an average price of 100 percent
data from the consumer panel. The products earned average for all food products (private labels and national brands), the
market shares of 28.96 percent for non-food and 47.40 percent for minimum price of a national brand was 46 percent and the
food products, in terms of their sales volume within their com- maximum was 173 percent. On average, national brands were
modity groups. slightly more expensive (102.3%), and the standard deviation in
To address our research questions, we aggregated the data set product prices was .23846. (The statistics for the other variables in
monthly for each product. The observation period covers the years Table 2 reflect similar approaches.) For product quality, a higher
2006 to 2011, so the resulting data set consists of a maximum of 72 value represented better quality, such that values greater than
records for each product; each record includes the price, promo- 1 represented better-than-average quality.
tion share, product quality, and market share of one product in one In Table 3 we present the results of the path analysis, which
month. For example, for food national brands, we analyzed 19 highlights the impact of the independent variables on market
products that could have provided a maximum of 1,368 cases ( ¼19 share. All paths were highly significant. The explained variance

Table 2
Descriptive statistics.

Brand type Product type Variable N Minimum Maximum Mean Standard deviation

National brand Food Product price 1139 .46 1.73 1.0230 .23846
Product quality .81 1.71 .9958 .21209
Promotion share .00 1.00 .4771 .30947
Market share .00 .18 .0235 .03249
Non-Food Product price 570 .70 2.03 1.4418 .23508
Product quality .92 1.14 1.0110 .07894
Promotion share .00 1.00 .3741 .20119
Market share .01 .07 .0158 .00949
Private label Food Product price 785 .62 1.46 .8783 .18585
Product quality .77 1.80 1.0061 .29007
Promotion share .00 1.00 .1153 .22683
Market share .00 .06 .0093 .01321
Non-Food Product price 1096 .72 1.36 .8839 .06355
Product quality .93 1.20 .9943 .04859
Promotion share .00 1.00 .0392 .10767
Market share .01 .10 .0108 .01706

Please cite this article as: Olbrich, R., et al., Effects of pricing strategies and product quality on private label and national brand
performance. Journal of Retailing and Consumer Services (2016), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jretconser.2016.01.012i
6 R. Olbrich et al. / Journal of Retailing and Consumer Services ∎ (∎∎∎∎) ∎∎∎–∎∎∎

Table 3 labels generally adopt an entry price level, such that their prices
Impacts of product price, promotion share, and product quality on market share. tend to be similar, gaining a competitive advantage solely by ad-
justing prices is difficult. In turn, product quality had a stronger
Brand type Product Impact on market share
type impact on the market share of private labels than that of national
Product Promotion Product brands (food: z¼ 8.035, po .001; non-food: z¼8.835, p o.001).
price share quality Finally, the test ratings by the independent organization StiWa
raised consumers’ acceptance of private labels, by communicating
National Food  .098nnn .464nnn .228nnn
brand Non-Food .270nnn .323nnn .197nn
their product quality.
Overall  .097nnn .469nnn .226nnn In conclusion, both brand type and product type moderate the
Private label Food  .395nnn  .250nnn .336nnn relationships of the independent variables product price, promo-
Non-Food  .067nn  .091nnn .397nnn tion share, and product quality with the dependent variable
Overall  .225nnn  .175nnn .246nnn
market share.
Overall Food  .177nnn .410nnn .213nnn
Non-Food .098nnn .079nnn .353nnn

nn
p o.01. 6. Implications
nnn
p o.001.

The results of this study have several important implications


(R2) of market share was .34 for food national brands, .32 for food for manufacturers and retailers. The market share performance of
private labels, .40 for non-food national brands, and .18 for non- national brands does not depend as heavily on the price as it does
food private labels. Therefore, for all four segments, the explained on promotion share and product quality. For manufacturers of
variance in market share is quite substantial. non-food products, a higher price even may lead to higher market
A higher price led to a lower market share for food (standar- shares. Such findings are appealing for manufacturers, which often
dized estimate b ¼ .177, po .001), across both national brands have limited influence over the prices that customers see, because
(b¼  .098, p o.001) and private labels (b ¼ .395, po .001). retailers in Germany possess substantial pricing autonomy (Ol-
However, the market share of private-label food was affected to a brich and Buhr, 2004; Olbrich and Grewe, 2013; Olbrich et al.,
significantly greater degree (critical ratio z ¼ 3.832, p o.001). For 2014). Therefore, instead of focusing on prices, manufacturers
the non-food product though, a higher price could lead to in- should consider increased uses of price promotions, which often
creased market shares (b¼.098, p o.001). Among private labels, are passed directly on to customers, such that they give the retailer
the predicted negative relationship between price and market an incentive to promote their product. This strategic move in-
share emerged but was weak (b ¼ .067, p o.01); for national directly increases price promotions and may have a positive in-
brands, market share actually increased with a higher price fluence on the market share of the corresponding product. As
(b¼ .270, p o.001). This finding contrasts with traditional market Shankar and Bolton (2004): 45 point out, manufacturers that try to
theory, according to which sales decline after price increases. It establish “higher relative brand prices at the retail level could
also confirms that consumers take price–quality relationships into distribute primarily through stores that are less price consistent,
consideration, likely to reduce their quality uncertainty and pur- more promotion intensive, and more price-promotion co-
chase risk, so higher prices help increase market shares. Thus, ordinated.” However, because frequent price promotions can da-
higher prices were significantly more detrimental to the market mage the image of the national brand, they demand some caution
shares of food (b¼  .177, po .001) than non-food (b ¼.098, (Grewal et al., 1998; Olbrich and Grewe, 2013). In addition, man-
p o.001; z¼ 14.771, p o.001); a low price also was more important ufacturers must make product quality a priority. It is critical to
for private labels (b¼  .225, p o.001) than for national brands distinguish a manufacturer’s national brands from competitive
(b¼  .097, po .001) as a means to increase market shares private labels, to appeal to quality-oriented customers (Nenycz-
(z ¼ 8.210, p o.001). We posit that for private labels, competition Thiel and Romaniuk, 2014). We recommend that manufacturers
is not based primarily on product innovation or product diversi- focus on price promotions and product quality, instead of a low
fication. Rather, for the generally homogeneous products in our price, to compete with private-label options.
data set, price represents a key competitive factor. For retailers, we highlight the need to differentiate between
The promotion share indicates retailers’ pricing strategies, in national brands and private labels. The primary goal of any retailer
that EDLP is characterized by relatively steady prices and the ab- is to increase not the market share of a singular product but the
sence of price promotions (i.e., promotion share close to zero), overall purchases in the store that ultimately increase store-level
whereas a HiLo pricing strategy features the frequent use of price revenues and profit. In this effort, the implications of this study are
promotions and a higher promotion share. Our results showed fourfold.
that a higher promotion share increased the market share for First, retailers frequently use private labels to attract customers
national brands (b¼.469, po .001), whether the products were and bind them to the store. Especially for products that consumers
food (b¼ .464, p o.001) or non-food (b¼.323, p o.001). We found buy frequently, private-label versions have powerful impacts on the
a different relationship for private labels though (b ¼  .175, retailer's pricing competence image. To gain competitive ad-
p o.001; z ¼  30.312, po .001): A higher promotion share re- vantages with these offerings, retailers should apply low prices to
sulted in a lower market share for both food (b ¼ .250, p o.001) their private labels (i.e., entry-level price). Because low prices are
and non-food (b¼  .091, p o.001) products. Thus, successful easy for competitors to copy, often in less than one business day,
products (in terms of market share) were priced using a EDLP retailers also must keep product quality in mind; this competitive
pricing strategy if they were private labels but a HiLo pricing advantage cannot be imitated readily. That is, retailers need to find
strategy if they were national brands. a way to establish a low, market-oriented price and high quality for
Across all four conditions, higher quality resulted in a higher their private labels, offering products that are capable of satisfying
market share. The effect was slightly stronger for private labels the basic needs of customers. Therefore, implementing an EDLP
(food: b ¼.336, p o.001; non-food: b¼ .397, p o.001) than for na- pricing strategy aimed at this target market should increase market
tional brands (food: b ¼.228, p o.001; non-food: b¼.197, p o.01). shares and help sustain performance in a competitive environment.
That is, in the competition among private labels, both price and Second, for the national brands they carry, retailers should rely
quality (“good and cheap”) drove market shares. Because private on price promotions and adopt a HiLo strategy. National brands

Please cite this article as: Olbrich, R., et al., Effects of pricing strategies and product quality on private label and national brand
performance. Journal of Retailing and Consumer Services (2016), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jretconser.2016.01.012i
R. Olbrich et al. / Journal of Retailing and Consumer Services ∎ (∎∎∎∎) ∎∎∎–∎∎∎ 7

tend to be better known than private labels, so price promotions Dean, D.H., 2004. Consumer reaction to negative publicity: Effects of corporate
on these familiar products may increase store attractiveness. To reputation, response, and responsibility for a crisis event. J. Bus. Commun. 41
(2), 192–211.
avoid negative carryover effects to the retail brand, retailers should Dhar, S.K., Hoch, S.J., 1997. Why store brand penetration varies by retailer. Mark.
avoid including poor quality products, with low test ratings, in Sci. 16 (3), 208–227.
their price promotions (Jansen et al., 2014). However, other than Ellickson, P.B., Misra, S., 2008. Supermarket pricing strategies. Mark. Sci. 27 (5),
811–828.
these price promotions, national brands do not need to be priced Fritz, W., Hilger, H., Raffée, H., Silberer, G., Förster, F., 1984. Testnutzung und Test-
low. The harmful impact of higher prices on market shares is ra- wirkungen im Bereich der Konsumgüterindustrie. In: Raffée, H., Silberer, G.
ther weak, and in some cases, a higher price even can increase (Eds.), Warentest und Unternehmen – Nutzung, Wirkungen und Beurteilung
des vergleichenden Warentests in Industrie und Handel. Campus Verlag,
market shares. Furthermore, retailers might use high-priced na-
Frankfurt, New York, pp. 27–114.
tional brands to signal the attractiveness of their low-priced, pri- Garvin, D.A., 1984. What does “product quality” really mean? Sloan Manag. Rev. 26
vate-label alternatives (i.e., umbrella pricing). (1), 25–43.
Gauri, D.K., Trivedi, M., Grewal, D., 2008. Understanding the determinants of retail
strategy: An empirical analysis. J. Retail. 84 (3), 256–267.
Ghose, S., Liu, J.J., Bhatnagar, A., Kurata, H., 2005. Modeling the role of retail price
7. Limitations and further research formats, and retailer competition types on production schedule strategy. Eur. J.
Oper. Res. 164, 173–184.
Grewal, D., Krishnan, R., Baker, J., Borin, N., 1998. The effect of store name, brand
Several limitations of our study offer opportunities for additional name and price discounts on consumers’ evaluations and purchase intentions.
research. For example, information about the households that J. Retail. 74 (3), 331–352.
contribute these data could offer an interesting extension. By taking Groeppel, A., 1993. Competitive retailing strategies in Germany: an empirical study.
Proc. 1993 Acad. Mark. Sci. (AMS) Annu. Conf., 643–654.
household information into account, further research could draw Hilger, H., Fritz, W., Silberer, G., Raffée, H., Förster, F., 1984. Testnutzung und Test-
insights about different buyer types (e.g., smart shoppers), accord- wirkungen im Bereich des Konsumgüterhandels. In: Raffée, H., Silberer, G.
ing to their sociodemographic and psychographic attributes, and (Eds.), Warentest und Unternehmen – Nutzung, Wirkungen und Beurteilung
des vergleichenden Warentests in Industrie und Handel. Campus Verlag,
thereby lead to a deeper understanding of ways to address different
Frankfurt, New York, pp. 115–200.
buyer types. In certain circumstances, household net income could Ho, T.-H., Tang, C.S., Bell, D.R., 1998. Rational shopping behavior and the option
be a promising topic for further analysis (Olbrich et al., 2014). value of variable pricing. Manag. Sci. 44 (12), 145–160.
Hoch, S.J., Banerji, S., 1993. When Do Private Labels Succeed? Sloan Manag. Rev. 34
Our data were limited to sales; we hope additional research
(4), 57–67.
takes profits into consideration too. Profits are a key determinant, Hoch, S.J., Drèze, X., Purk, M.E., 1994. EDLP, Hi-Lo, and margin arithmetic. J. Mark.
and increased market shares do not necessarily produce higher 58 (4), 16–27.
profits. A loss of market share may be acceptable if overall profits Hsu, H.-C., Lai, C.-S., 2008. Examination of factors moderating the success of private
label brands: A study of the packaged food market in China. J. Food Prod. Mark.
still rise. However, information about profits tends to be protected 14 (4), 1–20.
carefully by retailers and is difficult to access. Jansen, H.C., Olbrich, R., Teller, B.C., 2014. Quantifying anti-consumption of private
Finally, this research did not address a wide range of com- labels and national brands: Impact of poor test ratings on consumer behavior.
In: Lee, M.S.W., Hoffmann, S. (Eds.), ICAR Educators Proceedings: Anti-Con-
modity groups or different products. Additional research should sumption and Consumer Wellbeing. University of Kiel, Kiel, pp. 65–70.
investigate other food and non-food products, including higher Jin, G.Z., Leslie, P., 2003. The effect of information on product quality: Evidence from
priced products that tend to induce consumer involvement (e.g., restaurant hygiene grade cards. Q. J. Econ. 118 (2), 409–451.
Kaas, K.P., Tölle, K., 1981. Der Einfluß von Warentestinformationen auf das In-
alcoholic beverages, personal care products).
formationsverhalten von Konsumenten. J. Consum. Policy 5 (4), 293–309.
Kahneman, D., Tversky, A., 1979. Prospect theory–an analysis of decision under risk.
Econometrica 47 (2), 263–291.
Lamm, R.M., 1981. Prices and concentration in the food retailing industry. J. Ind.
References
Econ. 30 (1), 67–78.
Laurent, G., Kapferer, J.-N., 1985. Measuring Consumer Involvement Profiles. J.
Ahluwalia, R., Burnkrant, R.E., Unnava, H.R., 2000. Consumer response to negative Mark. Res. 22 (1), 41–53.
publicity: the moderating role of commitment. J. Mark. Res. 37 (2), 203–214. Lin, C.-Y., Marshall, D., Dawson, J., 2009. Consumer attitudes towards a European
Ailawadi, K.L., Keller, K.L., 2004. Understanding retail branding: conceptual insights retailer’s private brand food products: An integrated model of Taiwanese
and research priorities. J. Retail. 80 (4), 331–342. consumers. J. Mark. Manag.(9/10), 875–891.
Ailawadi, K.L., Neslin, S.A., Gedenk, K., 2001. Pursuing the value-conscious con- Machek, M., 2012. Retail market structure development in central Europe. Cent. Eur.
sumer: store brands versus national brand promotions. J. Mark. 65 (1), 71–89. Bus. Rev. 1 (3), 22–27.
Anders, S.M., 2008. Imperfect competition in German food retailing: Evidence from Marquardt, R.A., McGann, A.F., 1975. Does advertising communicate product quality
state level data. Atl. Econ. J. 36 (4), 441–454. to consumers? Some evidence from Consumer Reports. J. Advert. 4 (4), 27–31.
Anselmsson, J., Johansson, U., 2009. Third generation of retailer brands–retailer Méndez, J.L., Oubiña, J., Rubio, N., 2008. Expert quality evaluation and price of store
expectations and consumer response. Br. Food J. 111 (7), 717–734. vs. manufacturer brands: An analysis of the Spanish mass market. J. Retail.
Baltas, G., 1997. Determinants of store brand choice: a behavioral analysis. J. Prod. Consum. Serv. 15 (3), 144–155.
Brand. Manag. 6 (5), 315–324. METRO AG. Metro-Handelslexikon 2015/2016 Düsseldorf 2015.
Belk, R.W., 1985. Issues in the intention-behavior discrepancy. In: Sheth, J.N. (Ed.), Mizerski, R.W., 1982. An attribution explanation of the disproportionate influence
Research in Consumer Behavior Vol. 1. JAI Press, Greenwich, CT, pp. 1–34. of unfavorable information. J. Consum. Res. 9 (3), 301–310.
Bell, D., Lattin, J.M., 1998. Shopping behavior and consumer preference for store Moussa, S., Touzani, M., 2008. The perceived credibility of quality labels: A scale
price format: why “large basket” shoppers prefer EDLP. Mark. Sci. 17 (1), 66–88. validation with refinement. Int. J. Consum. Stud. 32 (5), 526–533.
Blattberg, R.C., Wisniewski, K.J., 1989. Price-induced patterns of competition. Mark. Nelson, P., 1970. Information and consumer behavior. J. Polit. Econ. 78 (2), 311–329.
Sci. 8 (4), 291–309. Nenycz-Thiel, M., Romaniuk, J., 2014. The real difference between consumers’
Böhm, J., Witte, Td, Schulze, H., Spiller, A., 2007. Preis‐Qualitäts‐Relationenqualitäts- perceptions of private labels and national brands. J. Consum. Behav. 13 (4),
relationen im Lebensmittelmarkt: Eine Analyse auf Basis der Testergebnisse der 262–269.
Stiftung Warentest, Department für Agrarökonomie und Rurale Entwicklung, Olbrich, R., Buhr, C.-C., 2004. Impact of private labels on competition: Why Eur-
Georg‐August‐Universität Göttingen. Göttingen. opean competition law should permit resale price maintenance. Eur. Retail. Dig.
Bolton, R.N., Shankar, V., 2003. An empirically derived taxonomy of retailer pricing 41, 50–55.
and promotion strategies. J. Retail. 79 (4), 213–224. Olbrich, R., Grewe, G., 2009. Consequences of competition between national brands
Burger, P.C., Schott, B., 1972. Can private brand buyers be identified? J. Mark. Res. 9 and private labels: Empirical results from different German outlet formats. Int.
(2), 219–222. J. Retail. Distrib. Manag. 37 (11), 933–951.
Buzzell, R., Gale, B., 1987. The PIMS Principles: Linking Strategy to Performance. Olbrich, R., Grewe, G., 2013. Proliferation of private labels in the groceries sector:
Free Press, New York. The impact on category performance. J. Retail. Consum. Serv. 20 (2), 147–153.
Buzzell, R.D., Gale, B.T., Sultan, R.G.M., 1975. Market share – a key to profitability. Olbrich, R., Grewe, G., Orenstrat, R., 2009. Private labels, product variety, and price
Harv. Bus. Rev. 53 (1), 97–106. competition–lessons from the German grocery sector. In: Ezrachi, A., Bernitz, U.
Connor, J.M., Peterson, E.B., 1992. Market-structure determinants of national brand- (Eds.), Private Labels, Brands, and Competition Policy–The Changing Landscape
private label price differences of manufactured food products. J. Ind. Econ. 40 of Retail Competition. Oxford University Press, Oxford, UK, pp. 235–257.
(2), 157–171. Olbrich, R., Hundt, M., Grewe, G., 2014. Willingness to pay in food retailing – An
Cordell, V.V., 1997. Consumer knowledge measures as predictors in product eva- empirical study of consumer behaviour in the context of the proliferation of
luation. Psychol. Mark. 14 (3), 241–260. organic products. Eur. Retail. Res. 28 (1), 67–101.

Please cite this article as: Olbrich, R., et al., Effects of pricing strategies and product quality on private label and national brand
performance. Journal of Retailing and Consumer Services (2016), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jretconser.2016.01.012i
8 R. Olbrich et al. / Journal of Retailing and Consumer Services ∎ (∎∎∎∎) ∎∎∎–∎∎∎

Olbrich, R., Jansen, H.C., 2014. Price–quality relationship in pricing strategies for Shen, H., Wyer Jr., R.S., 2008. Procedural priming and consumer judgments: Effects
private labels. J. Prod. Brand. Manag. 23 (6). on the impact of positively and negatively valenced information. J. Consum.
Olbrich, R., Jansen, H.C., Teller, B., 2016. Quantifying anti-consumption of private Res. 34 (5), 727–737.
labels and national brands: Impacts of poor test ratings on consumer pur- Simonsohn, U., 2011. Lessons from an “oops” at Consumer Reports: Consumers
chases. J. Consum. Aff., in press follow experts and ignore invalid information. J. Mark. Res. 48 (1), 1–12.
Ortmeyer, G., Quelch, J.A., Salmon, W., 1991. Restoring credibility to retail pricing. Sinha, I., Batra, R., 1999. The effect of consumer price consciousness on private label
Sloan Manag. Rev. 33 (1), 55–66. purchase. Int. J. Res. Mark. 16 (3), 237–251.
Pechtl, H., 2004. Profiling intrinsic deal proneness for HILO and EDLP price pro- Steenkamp, J.-B.E.M., Van Heerde, H.J., Geyskens, I., 2010. What makes consumers
motion strategies. J. Retail. Consum. Serv. 11 (2004), 223–233. willing to pay a price premium for national brands over private labels? J. Mark.
Reinstein, D.A., Snyder, C.M., 2005. The influence of expert reviews on consumer Res. 47 (6), 1011–1024.
demand for experience goods: A case study of movie critics. J. Ind. Econ. 53 (1), Vahie, A., Paswan, A., 2006. Private label brand image: Its relationship with store
27–51.
image and national brand. Int. J. Retail. Distrib. Manag. 34 (1), 67–84.
Rothschild, M.L., 1979. Advertising Strategies for High and Low Involvement Si-
Walsh, G., Mitchell, V.-W., 2010. Consumers’ intention to buy private label brands
tuations. In: Maloney, J.C., Silverman, B. (Eds.), Attitude Research Plays for High
revisited. J. Gen. Manag. 35 (3), 3–24.
Stakes, Chicago, pp. 74–93.
Weiss, C.R., Wittkopp, A., 2005. Retailer concentration and product innovation in
Shankar, V., Bolton, R.N., 2004. An empirical analysis of determinants of retailer
food manufacturing. Eur. Rev. Agric. Econ. 32 (2), 219–244.
pricing strategy. Mark. Sci. 23 (1), 28–49.

Please cite this article as: Olbrich, R., et al., Effects of pricing strategies and product quality on private label and national brand
performance. Journal of Retailing and Consumer Services (2016), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jretconser.2016.01.012i

You might also like