Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 13

American Economic Association

Does Consumer Sentiment Forecast Household Spending? If So, Why?


Author(s): Christopher D. Carroll, Jeffrey C. Fuhrer, David W. Wilcox
Source: The American Economic Review, Vol. 84, No. 5 (Dec., 1994), pp. 1397-1408
Published by: American Economic Association
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2117779
Accessed: 06/10/2010 18:08

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless
you have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you
may use content in the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use.

Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at
http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=aea.

Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed
page of such transmission.

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of
content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms
of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

American Economic Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The
American Economic Review.

http://www.jstor.org
Does Consumer Sentiment Forecast Household Spending?
IfSo, Why?

By CHRISTOPHER D. CARROLL, JEFFREY C. FUHRER,


AND DAVID W. WILCOX*

In the three months following the Iraqi refute traditional life-cycle or permanent-
invasionof Kuwait,the Universityof Michi- income models of consumption.Nor does it
gan's Index of Consumer Sentiment (ICS) necessarily make the job of forecasting
fell an unprecedented24.3 index points, to changes in consumption any easier. From
its lowest level since the 1981-1982 reces- the point of view of an economicforecaster,
sion.' This collapse in householdconfidence the questions of interest are first, whether
became the focus of a great deal of eco- an index of consumer sentiment has any
nomic commentaryand, indeed, frequently predictive power on its own for future
was cited as an important-if not the lead- changes in consumptionspending,and sec-
ing-cause of the economic slowdownthat ond, whether it contains informationabout
ensued. future changes in consumerspending aside
Concern was fueled by the well-known from the information contained in other
contemporaneouscorrelation between the availableindicators.
ICS and the growthof household spending. In Section I, we present evidencethat the
Figure 1 shows quarterly averages of the answerto the firstquestionis a clearyes: we
index, 1978-1993, together with the quar- find that laggedvalues of the ICS, taken on
terly growth in real personal consumption their own, explain about 14 percent of the
expenditures as measured in the national variationin the growthof total real personal
income accounts (Bureau of Economic consumption expenditures over the post-
Analysis).The correlationis impressive. 1954period.Furtherinvestigationshowsthat
Of course, it is not surprisingthat senti- the answerto the second questionis proba-
ment and the growthof spending are posi- bly yes as well, though here the margin is
tively correlated.This correlationmay sim- narrowerand the evidencemore murky.The
ply reflect that, when economic prospects ICS contributesabout3 percentto the R2 of
are poor, householdscurtail their spending a simple reduced-formequation for total
and also give gloomyresponsesto interview- personal consumptionexpendituresin the
ers. Thus, the contemporaneouscorrelation longer of the two sample periodswe exam-
between sentiment and spending does not ine, but nothingin the shortersampleperiod
(thoughthe latterresultis heavilyinfluenced
by the observationfor 1980:2).For the major
*
Carroll:Division of Research and Statistics,Stop subcategoriesof spending,the contribution
80, Federal Reserve Board, Washington,DC 20551: generally ranges between 1 percent and 8
Fuhrer:ResearchDepartment,Federal Reserve Bank percent. Overall, we read the evidence as
of Boston, Boston, MA 02106: Wilcox: Division of pointingtowardat least some significantin-
MonetaryAffairs, Stop 71, Federal Reserve Board, crementalexplanatorypower.
Washington,DC 20551. We have benefited from the
researchassistanceof StephenHelwigand Christopher Therefore, we take as given for the re-
Geczy and the comments of an anonymousreferee. mainder of the paper that sentiment fore-
The views expressed in this paper are those of the casts spending,and we turn to the issue of
authors and not of the Federal Reserve Board, the how that statistical relationshipshould be
Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, or the other mem-
bers of the staffof either institution. interpreted.One possible interpretationis
IThe ConferenceBoard'sConsumerConfidenceIn- that sentiment is an independent driving
dex also plungedat the same time. factor in the economy, and that changes in
1397
1398 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW DECEMBER 1994

Index points Percent change, compound annual rate


115 10

Consumer sentiment (left scale)

95 5

0 8; & 8>^{l 2
75 0;W

Personal consumption expenditures (right scale)

35 I I I I| I I I I I I I I I
1979 1981 1983 1985 1987 1989 1991 1993

FIGURE 1. CONSUMER SENTIMENT AND THE GROWTH IN CONSUMER SPENDING

sentiment not only forecast changes in dependent driving factor: when prospects
spending,but also cause them. An alterna- for the real economy are bright, forward-
tive interpretationis that sentiment fore- lookinglife-cyclerswill give optimisticread-
casts spendingbecause it reflectsthe overall ings on consumer sentiment. On average,
outlook for the economy:when consumers their optimism will be borne out, and in-
are optimistic about the outlook for the come will rise. When it does, spending of
economy, they give upbeat responses to in- rule-of-thumberswill increase.Thus, in this
terviewers.On average,those optimisticex- account, the survey responses of forward-
pectations are substantiated,and spending looking householdspredict the spendingof
eventually increases as foreshadowed by rule-of-thumbhouseholds.
sentiment. The Campbell-Mankiw model is useful in
This alternative account of the role of this context because it delivers a testable
sentiment must involve some violation of implication-that sentiment should appear
the simplest certainty-equivalenceversions in the predictionequation for consumption
of the life-cycleand permanent-incomethe- only indirectly,in its role as a predictorof
ories; otherwise, current spending would income. Our objective in Section III is to
fully reflect the optimism or pessimism of develop evidence on the validityof this ex-
households about future prospects for the planationof the predictivecontent of senti-
economy,and sentimentwould have no pre- ment.
dictive power for future changes in spend- In answer to the first question posed in
ing. In Section II, we introducesuch a viola- the title, we conclude that consumersenti-
tion using the mechanismproposedby John ment does indeed forecastfuturechangesin
Y. Campbelland N. GregoryMankiw(1989, household spending. Whether sentiment
1990, 1991). Specifically, Campbell and shouldbe characterizedas helping"a little"
Mankiw posit that some households are or "a lot" is a more difficultquestion.Given
strictlife-cyclerswhile others follow a "rule the amountof attentionthat has been paid
of thumb" and set consumption equal to to these indexes recently, their predictive
income. In an economy containing those abilityseems underwhelming.Fromthe per-
two types of consumers, sentiment might spective of the recent academic literature
well forecast spendingwithout being an in- on consumption, however, their perfor-
VOL. 84 NO. 5 CARROLLETAL.: CONSUMER SENTIMENTAND SPENDING 1399

mance is impressive because it stacks up period, lagged values of the ICS taken on
relativelywell against the track record of their own explain about 14 percent of the
other variables that previously have been one-quarter-aheadvariation in the growth
noted to have some predictive power for of total real personalconsumptionexpendi-
personalconsumptionexpenditures(e.g., in- tures (PCE) (row 1). The probabilitythat
terest rates, stock prices, the unemployment this explanatory power was generated
rate). merely by chance is estimated to be essen-
In answer to the second question, we tiallynil (row 1, numberin parentheses).As
conclude that the Campbell-Mankiwmodel shown in rows 2-4, sentiment taken alone
does not provide an adequate explanation has the most explanatorypower for one-
for the predictive power of sentiment for quarter-aheadgrowthin PCE for goods ex-
changesin householdspending.Part of that cluding motor vehicles (17 percent of the
predictivepowerappearsto operatethrough variationexplained)and the least explana-
a direct channel (or channels), rather than tory power for PCE for motor vehicles
the indirectincome channel allowedfor un- (4 percent of the variationexplained).
der the rule-of-thumbaccount we outlined The second columnreportsresultsfor the
above. In the concludingsection, we specu- period since 1978, during which time the
late about other possible explanationsfor Survey Research Center has conducted its
that predictivepower. surveyof consumerson a monthlybasis (see
footnote 2). Unfortunately,the results are
I. SomeReduced-FormRegressions rather sensitive to this change in sample
period. Using the post-1978 data, we find
A simple way to judge the near-termpre- that lagged values of the sentiment index
dictive abilityof the ICS is to examine the explain only 5 percent of the variation in
R2,Sfrom regressionsof the growthof vari- the growth of real PCE, 2 percent of the
ous measures of household spending on variationin PCE for services, and none of
laggedvalues of the ICS: the variationin PCE for motor vehicles. In
the case of goods excludingmotor vehicles,
N however,the R2 is even a bit higherthan it
A log(C,) = ao + E iS-i + et.
i=1

Note that this procedureamountsto a test that quarter,and the readingfromthe precedingquar-
ter if one was not.) We ended both sampleperiodsin
of Robert E. Hall's (1978) random-walkhy- 1992:3to exclude a very dramaticfluctuationin wage
pothesis;if the 8's are significantlydifferent and salaryincome in 1992:4and 1993:1reflectingtax-
from zero, that hypothesisis rejected.Table motivated shifts of income (especially bonuses and
1 reports the results of implementingthis commissions)from 1993into 1992.
procedure at the quarterlyfrequencyusing We partitionPCE into three categories(motorvehi-
cles, other goods, and services)ratherthan the more
four lags of the ICS.2 Over this sample traditionaltwo categories(durablesand nondurables
plus services)to better reflect the proceduresused by
the Bureau of Economic Analysis to estimate con-
sumer spending. Briefly, PCE for motor vehicles is
2The left-hand-sidevariable in each regressionis estimatedmainlyfrom data on the unit sales of new
the log difference of the indicated category of real cars and trucks;PCE for other goods is derivedfrom
household spending.The startingdate of the longer the monthlyretail sales data; and PCE for servicesis
sample period was chosen to exclude data from the estimatedfrom a varied collection of source data in-
Korean War era. The starting date of the shorter cluding, among others, employmentin service indus-
sampleperiodwas chosento coincidewith the moveby tries, the stock of occupiedhousingunits as estimated
the Universityof Michiganto administertheir Survey in the CurrentPopulationSurvey,and paymentsfor
of Consumerson a monthlybasis. (Priorto 1978, the electricityand naturalgas as reflectedin the monthly
surveyusuallywas taken only once each quarter,and billingsof utilities. See Wilcox(1992) for furtherdis-
occasionallynot even that frequently.For the period cussion.The data from the nationalincome accounts
since 1978, the quarterlyobservationis defined to be reflect the annualrevisionreleased by the Commerce
the averageof the monthlyobservations.For the pe- Departmentin September 1993. RATS code and a
riod prior to 1978,the quarterlyobservationis defined completedata set are availablefrom the authorsupon
to be the monthlyreadingif a surveywas taken during request.
1400 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW DECEMBER 1994

TABLE 1-REDUCED-FORM EVIDENCE: R2 'S AND INCREMENTAL R2 s


FROM SIMPLE PREDICTION EQUATIONS

4
A log(C,) = a0 + E fiS,ti + 'YZt-I + Et
i=l

Category of Incremental R2
Row real PCE 1955:1-1992:3 1978:1-1992:3 1955:1-1992:3 1978:1-1992:3

1 Total 0.14 0.05 0.03 - 0.03


(0.000) (0.013) (0.000) (0.056)
2 Motor vehicles 0.04 -0.01 0.08 0.03
(0.000) (0.130) (0.000) (0.013)
3 Goods excluding 0.17 0.20 0.05 0.03
motor vehicles (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.001)
4 Services 0.10 0.02 0.01 - 0.07
(0.002) (0.030) (0.188) (0.969)

Notes: S,t- i i= 1.4) are lagged values of the Index of Consumer Sentiment. Zt,
is a vector of control variables. The regressions underlying the results reported in the
first two columns used only the lagged values of sentiment as explanatory variables;
the regressions underlying the results reported in the third and fourth columns
included the control variables. These controls included four lags of the growth in real
labor income (defined as wages and salaries plus transfers minus personal contribu-
tions for social insurance). The numbers in parentheses are p values of the joint
significance of the lags of sentiment. Hypothesis tests were conducted using a
heteroscedasticity- and serial-correlation-robust covariance matrix (allowing serial
correlation at lags up to 4).

was in the longer sample period. In each estimatingequationsof the followingform:


categoryother than motor vehicles, the co-
efficientson the lags of sentimentare jointly N
significantat the 3-percent level or better. A log(C,) = ao + E jS,j + yZIt-1 + Et
Sensitivityto sample period notwithstand- i=l1
ing, we interpretthese results as constitut-
ing reasonablystrongsupportfor the propo- where Zt is a vector of other variables.Of
sition that sentiment taken alone has some course, the choice of which other variables
predictive power for future changes in to include in the equation is inherently
householdspending.3 somewhat arbitrary.The third and fourth
We next investigate whether the senti- columns of Table 1 present results for a
ment index has any predictive ability once minimal specification of such other vari-
one controls for informationcontained in ables that includes four lags of the depen-
other variables availableto economic fore- dent variableand four lags of the growthof
casters. We implementthis investigationby real labor income, defined as wages and
salaries plus transfersminus personal con-
tributionsfor social insurance,all deflated
by the implicitdeflatorfor total PCE. (The
use of labor income, rather than total dis-
3We also estimatedsimple predictionequationsus- posable income, is motivatedby our investi-
ing lags 2-5 of sentiment,rather than lags 1-4. The gation in Sections II and III of the rule-of-
resultswere similarexcept for goods excludingmotor thumb hypothesisas an explanationfor the
vehicles, in which case the R2 fell to 8.5 percent (p predictive power of sentiment and will be
value= 0.4 percent) in the longer sample period, and
4.5 percent (p value= 7.3 percent)in the shorterpe- discussed in greater detail there). In these
riod. two columns, the upper entry in each cell
VOL. 84 NO. 5 CARROLL ETAL.: CONSUMER SENTIMENTAND SPENDING 1401

records the incrementto the adjusted R2 cles are quite strong. For the latter two
providedby the lagged values of consumer categories of spending, the coefficients on
sentiment,while the lower entry (in paren- the lags of sentiment remainjointly signifi-
theses) displaysthe p value from the test of cant even controllingfor our minimalspeci-
the joint hypothesisthat the coefficientson ficationof other known information.(If the
the four lagged values of the sentiment in- observationfor 1980:2is omitted, the k2,S
dex equal zero. for motorvehicles and goods excludingmo-
Evidently,some-but not all-of the in- tor vehicles rise to 6 percent and 7 percent,
formation in the ICS is held in common respectively.)4
with the control variables.As the first row In sum, we read these results as showing
of the third column shows, the ICS adds that sentimenttaken on its own has consid-
only 3 percent to the explanatorypower of erable predictive ability for various mea-
the equation for the growth of total real sures of householdspending.Further,senti-
PCE over the longer sample period (5 per- ment likelyhas some (thoughprobablynot a
cent if the observationsfor 1975:2 [Social great deal) of incremental predictive power
Securitybonus and income-taxrebate] and relativeto at least some other indicatorsfor
1980:2 [credit controls] are omitted). the growthof spending.We turn now to the
Nonetheless, the coefficients on the four interpretationof this finding.
lags of sentimentare estimatedto be statis-
tically significantat better than the 0.1-per- II. Interpretingthe Influenceof Sentiment:
cent level. A similarresult holds for goods Framework
The Campbell-Mankiw
excludingmotorvehicles,with sentimentac-
counting for a smaller, but still statistically In a series of recent papers, Campbell
significant, proportion of the variation in and Mankiw(1989, 1990, 1991)investigatea
the growth of spending in the presence of simple modificationof the pure life-cycle/
the controlvariables.In the case of services, permanent-incomehypothesis.They assume
sentimentadds only 1 percent to the R2 of that there are two types of consumers.
the reduced-form equation, and the four One type sets spending strictly according
lags are not jointly significantat any of the to a standardlife-cycle/permanent-income
usual levels. In the motor-vehiclescategory, model; the other sets spending equal to
a counterintuitiveresult holds:the contribu- current income. In the simplest version of
tion to the R2 from the sentimentvariables their model, the consumptiongood is com-
is substantiallylargerwhen the controlvari- pletely nondurable,and the decision period
ables are included in the regression than of consumerscoincidesexactlywith the fre-
when they are not. quencyof the data. In this case, the change
The fourthcolumnin Table 1 repeats the in the consumption of life-cyclers is a
experimentusing the post-1978 data only, white-noise process (equivalently,the level
no doubt at substantial econometric risk
given that 13 coefficients are being esti-
mated in a sample of only 59 observations.
If all observationsare retained in the sam-
ple, the inclusion of sentiment actually 4Whenwe reestimatethe equationsunderlyingthe
slightly reduces the A2 of the prediction results displayedin the third and fourth columns of
equation for total PCE. However, if the Table 1 laggingall right-hand-sidevariablesan addi-
observationfor 1980:2is omitted (result not tional period,the resultsare considerablyweaker.For
example,over the longersampleperiod,the sentiment
shown in the table), sentiment adds 4 per- variables subtract 0.4 percent from the R2 of the
cent to the R2, and the four lags are jointly equationfor total PCE ratherthan adding3 percent.
significantat the 0.1-percentlevel. The re- Over the shorter period, inclusionof sentiment sub-
sults for services are dismal (a finding that tracts from the R2 of the predictionequationfor all
four categoriesof spending.We interpretthese results
appearsto be robustto omission of various as illustratingthe importanceof retaininguse of ex-
observations),but the results for motor ve- planatoryvariablesat the firstlag, as we do in Section
hicles and for goods excludingmotor vehi- III.
1402 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW DECEMBER 1994

follows a randomwalk): equation(1) would be modifiedas follows:

ACL
t
_
Et
(2) ACt= A}Yt+ ut ut 1 MA(1).
Because ut is seriallycorrelated,it need
where, as usual, et representsthe news re-
not be orthogonalto variablesdated t -1.
ceived in period t about lifetime resources.
Campbell and Mankiw (1989, 1990, 1991)
Rule-of-thumbconsumersset the change in addressthis problemby laggingtheir instru-
their consumptionequal to the change in ments an extra period (so that all instru-
their currentincome: ments are dated t -2 or before) and by
correctingtheir test statisticsfor serial cor-
relation in the residuals. They find that,
AC = AYyR even with the instrumentsdated t -2 or
before, they have enough power to reject
A crucial assumption in the Campbell- the hypothesisthat A equalszero;theirpoint
Mankiwframeworkis that rule-of-thumbers estimatesof A center on 0.5.
receive a constant proportion A of total A disadvantageof this estimationstrategy
income. Given that assumption,aggregate is that it throws away the most up-to-date
consumptionis given by predictors of the change in income; from
the point of view of a real-timeforecaster,it
would be extremelydesirableto recoverthe
(1) ACt=AAYt +Et. use of variables dated t - 1. This objective
can be achievedby estimatingequation(3):
Of course, AYt will be correlatedwith Et,
but a consistent estimate of A can be ob- (3) ACt =AAYt+ vt-Ovt
tained using the standardinstrumental-vari- which differs from (2) only in its treatment
ables technique.5 of the error term. In equation (3), the
Campbelland Mankiw(1989, 1990, 1991) moving-averageparameter 0 is estimated
implementa slightlymore complicatedver- explicitly;as a result, one can enforce the
sion of equation (1). Many authors (e.g., restrictionthat anyvariabledated time t -1
Lawrence J. Christiano et al., 1991) have or before should be orthogonal to vt even if
noted that if consumption decisions are it is not orthogonalto vt 7.
made continuouslybut the data are mea- We begin the next section by presenting
sured as time-aggregates,the observed se- resultsof estimatingequation(3) using data
ries on spending will follow an IMA(1,1)
even if consumerbehaviorconformsexactly
to the life-cyclemodel and the consumption 7Thisestimationprocedurewill also be valid under
good is completelynondurable.6In this case, certain (possiblyunrealisticallystringent)assumptions
if the MA(1) structureof the error term is generated
by measurementerror in the level of consumption.If
that measurementerroris of the classicalvariety-that
is, orthogonalto income and the instruments-then
5WefollowCampbellandMankiw(1989,1990,1991) the resultingestimateswill be consistent.There are at
in applyingthe model to log changes in consumption least two mechanismsthroughwhich this assumption
and incomeratherthan arithmeticchanges. could be violated. First, the measurementerror in
6Other authorshave suggesteddifferentreasonswhy consumptioncould reflect the BEA's use of either
the error term might follow an MA(1) specification. income or one of our instrumentsas an indicatorof
For example,Mankiw(1982) shows that the changein spending.(In fact, the BEA uses informationfrom the
spendingwill follow an MA(1)processif the consump- Bureauof Labor Statistics'labor-marketsurveysboth
tion good is durable.Strictlyspeaking,equation(2) is to interpolatesome of the detailedcomponentsof PCE
not consistent with the durabilitymotivationfor the for servicesand to constructthe estimatesof dispos-
MA(1)errortermif the rule of thumbis understoodas able personal income.) Second, there could be feed-
applyingto consumptionof the services of durable back from the measurementerror to our instruments
goods.Nonetheless,we believethat durabilityhas much if, for example,pricesin financialmarketsrise or fall in
to do with the interpretationof our results.We address responseto news of unexpectedlyweak or strongesti-
this issue in greaterdepth at the end of SectionIII. mates of economicgrowth.
VOL. 84 NO. 5 CARROLL ETAL.: CONSUMER SENTIMENTAND SPENDING 1403

for the four categories of spending we ex- particular,a householdthat consumedall of


amined in Table 1. Such results are of inter- its incomewould not accumulateassets, and
est because (i) the Campbell-Mankiw model so would not receivecapitalincome.Consis-
has not (to our knowledge) been tested on tent with this interpretation,we identified
data for goods and for services separately Y, with a crude measure of labor income,
(Campbell and Mankiw [1989, 1990, 1991] constructed as wages and salaries plus
used the model to explain the growth in the transfers minus personal contributionsfor
sum of PCE for nondurables and PCE for social insurance.8
services); (ii) the test uses instruments dated
t -1 and thus should have more power than III. The Campbell-Mankiw
Modeland
the conventional implementation of the test ConsumerSentiment:EmpiricalResults
based only on instruments dated t -2 or
before; and (iii) our proposed explanation Table 2 presents 16 sets of results, re-
for the predictive power of sentiment is flecting the combination of four categories
based on the Campbell-Mankiw model and of household spending, two specifications of
so depends on its overall adequacy. the estimating equation [equation (3), in
Lagged sentiment does not appear in which sentimentappearsneither directlyas
equation (3) directly. Nonetheless, the a regressornor indirectlyas an instrument,
Campbell-Mankiw model does not prohibit and equation (4), in which sentiment ap-
lagged sentiment from predicting current pears both directlyand indirectly],and two
growth in consumption; it does require, specifications of the instrument list. The
however, that any predictive power of lagged first list of instrumentscomprises the re-
sentiment for current growth in consump- gressorsused in columns3 and 4 of Table 1.
tion should only reflect predictive power of The second list of instruments comprises
lagged sentiment for current growth of in- three lags each of the dependent variable,
come. In short, according to the model, the growthof real labor income, the change
lagged sentiment should enter equation (3) in the unemploymentrate, the change in
at most as an instrument for current growth the 3-monthTreasurybill rate, and the per-
of income. The alternative hypothesis is that centage change in the S&P 500 stock price
lagged sentiment enters the prediction index. The sample period for all results
equation for spending directly and thus ex- shown in Table 2 is 1955:1-1992:3.9
plains current growth of spending for some
reason other than that it helps predict cur-
rent growth of income. This alternative hy- 8Thus, our measurediffersfrom disposableincome
pothesis is represented in equation (4): in omittingother labor income (mainlyemployercon-
tributionsfor pension and welfare benefit plans and
directors'fees), as well as interest, dividend,rental,
N and proprietors'income,and in not deductingpersonal
(4) ACt=AAYt+ EF38iSt_i+vt-OVt-1. tax and nontaxpayments.The latter omissionreflects
i=1 the fact that the tax series sometimesis heavilyinflu-
enced by fluctuationsin tax payments induced by
strategiesprobablyonly availableto (and almost cer-
tainlyonly exploitedby) the relativelywell-off.If rule-
We test the restrictions implicit in equation of-thumb-typehouseholdsmainlypay ordinaryincome
(3) by estimating the more general equation tax, then the growth of their pretax income will be
(4) using the method of nonlinear instru- highly correlatedwith the growth of their after-tax
mental variables and testing the joint signif- income.
9If the rule-of-thumbexplanationof the predictive
icance of the f8i's. abilityof sentimentis to have any chance of holding
One note on the measurement of income: water, then sentiment must be shown to predict the
previous investigators have identified Yt with growthof real labor income. We tested this require-
total disposable income. In our view, how- ment by regressingthe growthof real laborincomeon
ever, a literal interpretation of the rule-of- instrumentlists 1 and 2, augmentedwith four and
three lags of sentiment, respectively.Because both
thumb parable suggests that Yt should be instrumentlists includelaggedspending,we estimated
identified with some measure of income that a total of eight regressions(four spendingcategories
rule-of-thumbers would actually receive. In and two specificationsof the remaininginstruments):
1404 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW DECEMBER 1994

TABLE 2-ESTIMATING THE CAMPBELL-MANKIW MODEL WITH AND WITHOUT LAGS


OF THE INDEX OF CONSUMER SENTIMENT

N
ACt =AAYt+ giSt-i+'t- Ot-1
i=l

Without sentiment With sentiment


p value on:
Joint
Instru- p value on Over- significance of
Category of real ment overidentifying identifying the coefficients
Row PCE list A 0 restrictions A 0 restrictions on sentiment

1 Total 1 0.700 0.131 0.605 0.543 0.199 0.772 0.013


(0.115) (0.081) (0.148) (0.072)
2 0.734 0.148 0.332 0.612 0.198 0.335 0.002
(0.108) (0.067) (0.139) (0.064)
2 Motor 1 1.786 0.298 0.736 1.217 0.532 0.673 0.000
vehicles (1.040) (0.085) (0.858) (0.071)
2 1.999 0.319 0.724 1.558 0.390 0.857 0.000
(1.022) (0.086) (1.986) (0.086)
3 Goods 1 0.801 0.008 0.330 0.584 0.018 0.314 0.049
excluding (0.156) (0.077) (0.195) (0.069)
motor 2 0.651 0.020 0.195 0.452 0.015 0.280 0.001
vehicles (0.136) (0.064) (0.160) (0.057)
4 Services 1 0.474 -0.001 0.390 0.276 -0.012 0.674 0.014
(0.123) (0.071) (0.126) (0.070)
2 0.530 0.000 0.228 0.566 - 0.050 0.212 0.719
(0.092) (0.066) (0.104) (0.070)

Notes: Instrument list 1 contains a constant, ACt_j, and AYt_ (i= 1.4); instrument list 2 contains a constant,
ACt-i, AYt_j, AUt-i, ARt_ji and AQt-i (i = 1,.*-,3), where ACt is the dependent variable, Yt is real labor income,
Ut is the unemployment rate, Rt is the 3-month Treasury bill rate, and Qt is the S&P 500 price index. The test
statistic for the test of overidentifying restrictions (not shown in the table) is distributed as chi-square with degrees
of freedom equal to the number of instruments less three. Figures in parentheses underneath A and 0 are standard
errors. The sample period for estimation is 1955:1-1992:3.

We focus first on results obtained from we use the second list. The test of overiden-
estimation of equation (3), in which senti- tifying restrictions provides no evidence
ment plays no role; these results are shown against the specification with either instru-
in the first three columns of the table. For ment list.
total PCE, we estimate A to be about 0.7, When we apply this specification to the
with a standard error of about 0.1, for ei- data for the three components of PCE, the
ther list of instruments. We estimate 0 to be point estimates of A differ markedly by cat-
about 0.15; this estimate is significant at the egory. For motor vehicles, we estimate A to
11-percent level when we use the first list of be about 1.8 or 2.0 (depending on the in-
instruments, and at the 3-percent level when strument list); for goods excluding motor
vehicles, about 0.65 or 0.8; and for services,
about 0.5. Such differences do not fit neatly
into the original interpretation of A as the
the p values on the joint exclusion tests were all below fraction of income accruing to rule-of-thumb
0.10, with the exception of the second instrument list families, but they seem to correspond to the
when we included lagged growth of spending on ser-
vices, in which case the p value was 0.217. Thus, we
relative durability of the goods or services in
concluded that sentiment does have significant incre- the different categories, with motor vehicles
mental predictive power for income. (the most durable) having the highest A and
VOL. 84 NO. 5 CARROLL ETAL.: CONSUMER SENTIMENTAND SPENDING 1405

with services (the least durable)havingthe ment is excluded, but the estimates of A
lowest A. Below, we provide an alternative remain statisticallysignificantexcept in the
interpretationof this parameter in which case of motor vehicles. The estimates of 0
the originalinterpretationis appropriatefor are somewhatlargerfor motorvehicles and
the special case in which the consumption total PCE, but still about zero for goods
good is completelynondurable. excludingmotorvehicles and for services.In
The estimates of 0 for goods excluding no case do we reject the overidentifying
motorvehicles and for servicesare of trivial restrictions.
magnitudeand statisticallyinsignificant.For To investigatethe robustnessof our re-
motor vehicles, we estimate 0 to be about sults, we estimated several variants of the
0.3, with a standard error of slightly less basic model. First,we tried estimatingequa-
than 0.1. These results are inconsistentwith tion (4) includingonly one lag of sentiment
the hypothesis that time aggregationof a as an instrument and only one lag as a
continuous-timeprocess is the mechanism regressor;we found that the p values on
that gives rise to the moving-averagestruc- the significanceof the single sentiment re-
ture of the error term, since if that were gressorwere higherin everycase, and above
the right mechanism, then all three cate- the usual criticalvalues except in the cases
gories of spending would be expected to of total PCE with the second instrumentlist
have moving-averageparameters of about (5.1 percent) and goods excluding motor
0.25 (see Luigi Ermini, 1989). Finally,in no vehicles with the second instrument list
case do we rejectthe overidentifyingrestric- (0.2 percent).Whenwe includedtwo lags of
tions. In fact, among these six equations, sentiment as regressors and instruments,
the lowest p value is 19.5 percent (goods the results resembled those we report in
excludingmotor vehicles, using the second Table 2 much more closely:the two lags of
instrument list). In this sense, the Camp- sentiment were jointly significant at the
bell-Mankiwmodel seems to providean ac- 6-percent level or better in every category
ceptable description of the behavior of exceptservices.We also estimatedthe model
spendingin all four categorieswe examine. using a single lag of the changein sentiment
We turn now to the tests that bear di- (despite evidencederivedfrom conventional
rectlyon the role of sentimentin the deter- Dickey-Fullertests indicatingthat the ICS
minationof spending.To executethese tests, is stationaryover our sample period) and
we include lags of sentiment in the specifi- obtained results similar to those that arise
cationboth as regressorsand as instruments when we use two or more lags of the level
(four lags when we use the first instrument of sentiment. The lagged change in senti-
list, three lags when we use the second list), ment was significantin every case except
and we test whether the coefficientson the total PCE with the first instrumentlist and
sentimentregressorsare jointly significantly serviceswith either instrumentlist.10
differentfrom zero. Second, we estimated equations (3) and
These results are presented in the re- (4) using the more traditionalapproachof
mainingcolumnsof Table 2. The results on laggingall the instruments(includingsenti-
the role of sentiment are clear: in every ment) twice; againwe found that the lags of
category except services (when we use the sentiment (2-5 in the case of the first in-
second instrument list), we reject the hy- strumentlist, 2-4 in the case of the second
pothesis that sentimentpredictsthe growth
of spendingonly throughthe income chan-
nel. In most cases, these rejections are at
the 2-percent level or better. As for the
other aspects of the results, pairwise com- 100ne importantdifferencebetween the resultsob-
parison of the first and fourth columns of tainedusingone laggedchangein sentimentversustwo
lagged levels is that the single lagged change has no
the table showsthat the estimatesof A are a incrementalpredictivepower for the growthof labor
bit smallerin most cases when sentimentis income, whereas the two lagged levels generallydo
included directlythan they are when senti- have incrementalpredictivepower.
1406 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW DECEMBER 1994

list) generallywere jointly significantlydif- be given (approximately)by


ferent from zero, though the p values were
more often than not a bit higherthan those (6) A log(X,)
we report in Table 2. Finally, we reesti-
mated the models omittingthe observations 1(1 -3) L
=A A log(Y,) + U
for 1975:2 and 1980:2; on the whole, the
results were little changed from those we
report in Table 2, and the p values on the ut MA(1)
joint significanceof the lags of sentiment,if
anything,tended to be a bit lower. Equation (6) predicts that the overall coef-
We close this section by addressingthe ficient on contemporaneouschanges in in-
interpretationof our estimatesof A. Clearly, come is an increasingfunction of the dura-
the original interpretationof A as repre- bilityof the consumptiongood (a decreasing
senting the fraction of aggregate income function of 8), consistent with the results
accruingto rule-of-thumbconsumerscannot shown in Table 2.12
be maintainedin the face of estimates that
exceed 1. A naturalreinterpretationcan be IV. Conclusion
derived, however, by supposing that rule-
of-thumbersmove their consumption,as dis- The evidence we have presented suggests
tinct from their outlays,in line with contem- that lagged consumer sentiment has some
poraneouschanges in income.1'In particu- explanatorypower for current changes in
lar, suppose that the stock of durablegoods householdspending.What sorts of explana-
that rule-of-thumberswish to hold is a lin- tions for that power are admissible?We
ear functionof their income, ruled out the pure life-cycle/permanent-
income model immediately,on the grounds
that that model would admitof a contempo-
K, = axYt raneous correlationbetween sentiment and
spending, but not one in which sentiment
and that durablegoods accumulateaccord- precedes spending.
ing to We then proposed and tested a second
possible explanation, based on Campbell
and Mankiw'smodel in which some house-
Kt = ( 1- 8) K, 1 + Xt holds spend accordingto a simple rule of
thumbwhile the others are strictlife-cyclers.
where a is the rate of depreciationand X, In this model, lagged sentiment predicts
is the rate of spendingon the durablegood. currentconsumptiongrowthonly because it
Then we can express the spending of rule- predicts current income growth. However,
of-thumberson durablegoods as the follow- we found that in most cases we could reject
ing function of their income (after taking a the hypothesisthat lagged sentimentaffects
first-orderTaylorexpansion): consumptiongrowth only through such an

j 12Strictlyspeaking, equation (6) is not consistent


(5) A log(XtR) =[( Alog(YtR) with the specificationwe estimated because it intro-
ducesone lag of the growthof incomeas an additional
regressor.Limited experimentationon our part sug-
gested that the data have no interestin such a lagged
Aggregate spending on durable goods will term.We interpretthis findingas consistentwith those
of previous authors, notably Mankiw (1982), that
the predictionsof this genre of models for the serial-
correlationpropertiesof spending on durable goods
are very far off. Nonetheless,these modelsdo seem to
"1Weare gratefulto N. GregoryMankiwfor sug- make realisticpredictionsconcerningthe income elas-
gestingthis alternativeinterpretation. ticitiesof spendingon durables.
VOL. 84 NO. 5 CARROLL ETAL.: CONSUMER SENTIMENTAND SPENDING 1407

income channel. We have not formally Thus, neither a simple model of precau-
tested other leading models of consump- tionary saving nor a simple model of habit
tion, but we believe that at least the sim- formation appears to be capable of ex-
plest versions of other models may also have plaining our results. However, there is
some difficulty explaining our results. some reason for thinking that a model that
If consumer sentiment is, in part, a mea- incorporates both habit formation and pre-
sure of uncertainty, one might hope that a cautionary saving motives might be consis-
model of precautionary saving would be tent with the pattern of facts we encounter.
consistent with our results. Carroll (1992) An increase in uncertainty in such a model
shows that a model in which precautionary would cause the desired level of consump-
saving plays an important role does lead to tion to be lower, but habit formation would
correlations between uncertainty and the prevent consumption from adjusting down-
growth rate of consumption: an increase in ward instantly and fully. In contrast with the
uncertainty causes the level of consumption simple precautionary-saving model, con-
to fall, as consumers attempt to build up sumption might fall for an extended period
their stock of assets. But in subsequent peri- before beginning to rise again. Further-
ods, while the level of consumption will more, in contrast with the habit-formation
remain lower than it would have in the model, it is no longer clear that all relevant
absence of the shock, the growth rate of information about the expected current
consumption will be higher because the ur- growth rate of consumption should be con-
gency of additional saving will wane as the tained in the lagged growth rate of con-
stock of assets grows. Consumption growth sumption. In particular, lagged sentiment
will therefore be negatively correlated with might provide incremental information
contemporaneous uncertainty, but positively about current consumption growth.'3
correlated with lagged uncertainty. If the To our knowledge, no formal work has
consumer-sentiment index is high when un- been done on the short-term dynamic prop-
certainty is low, this model would imply that erties of a model that incorporates both
lagged sentiment should be negatively asso- habit formation and precautionary saving
ciated with consumption growth. Instead, motives, so our suggestion that such a model
lagged sentiment seems to be positively cor- might explain our results remains highly
related with consumption growth. speculative. Nonetheless, such a model
Another departure from the standard strikes us as a worthy candidate for future
life-cycle/permanent-income model that research in this area.
has received considerable attention recently
is habit formation. Karen E. Dynan (1993) REFERENCES
shows that a simple model of habit forma-
tion implies that lagged consumption growth Bureau of EconomicAnalysis. Survey of cur-
should have predictive power for current rent business. Washington, DC: U.S. De-
consumption growth. Because lagged senti- partment of Commerce, various issues.
ment is correlated with lagged consumption Campbell, John Y. and Mankiw, N. Gregory.
growth, it might be possible to explain a "Consumption, Income, and Interest
correlation of lagged sentiment with current
consumption growth as arising from the cor-
relation of lagged sentiment with lagged
consumption growth. Unfortunately, such a
13Carrolland David N. Weil (1993) also suggest that
hypothesis cannot explain our results, be- a model incorporating both habit formation and pre-
cause lagged consumption growth was al- cautionary saving might explain their empirical results
ways included in our instrument sets; given on the low-frequency correlations between saving and
that lagged consumption growth should be a growth in both household and aggregate data, and
George M. Constantinides (1990) argues that such
sufficient statistic for expected current con- a model may provide an explanation for the equity-
sumption growth, sentiment should have had premium puzzle of Rajnish Mehra and Edward C.
no incremental explanatory power. Prescott (1985).
1408 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW DECEMBER 1994

Rates: Reinterpreting the Time Series June 1990, 98(3), pp. 519-43.
Evidence," in Olivier J. Blanchard and Dynan, Karen E. "Habit Formation in Con-
Stanley Fischer, eds., NBER macroeco- sumer Preferences: Evidence from Panel
nomics annual 1989. Cambridge, MA: Data." Board of Governors of the Fed-
MIT Press, 1989, pp. 185-216. eral Reserve System Economic Activity
_ "Permanent Income, Current In- Working Paper No. 143, October 1993.
come, and Consumption." Journal of Ermini, Luigi. "Some New Evidence on the
Business and Economic Statistics, July Timing of Consumption Decisions and on
1990, 8(3), pp. 265-79. Their Generating Process." Review of
. "The Response of Consumption to Economics and Statistics, November 1989,
Income: A Cross-Country Investigation." 71(4), pp. 643-50.
European Economic Review, May 1991, Hall, Robert E. "Stochastic Implications of
35(4), pp. 723-67. the Life Cycle-Permanent Income Hy-
Carroll, Christopher D. "The Buffer Stock pothesis: Theory and Evidence." Journal
Theory of Saving: Some Macroeconomic of Political Economy. December 1978,
Evidence." Brookings Papers on Eco- 86(6), pp. 971-87.
nomic Activity, 1992, (2), pp. 61-155. Mankiw, N. Gregory. "Hall's Consumption
Carroll, Christopher D. and Weil, David N. Hypothesis and Durable Goods." Journal
"Saving and Growth: A Reinterpre- of Monetary Economics, November 1982,
tation." Carnegie-Rochester Conference 10(3), pp. 417-26.
Series on Public Policy, March 1993, 40, Mehra, Rajnish and Prescott,EdwardC. "The
pp. 133-92. Equity Premium: A Puzzle." Journal of
Christiano, LawrenceJ.; Eichenbaum, Martin Monetary Economics, March 1985, 15(2),
and Marshall, David. "The Permanent In- pp. 145-61.
come Hypothesis Revisited." Economet- Universityof Michigan.Surveys of consumers.
rica, March 1991, 59(2), pp. 397-423. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Sur-
ConferenceBoard. Consumer confidence sur- vey Research Center, various issues.
vey. New York: Conference Board, vari- Wilcox,David W. "The Construction of U.S.
ous issues. Consumption Data: Some Facts and Their
Constantinides,GeorgeM. "Habit Formation: Implications for Empirical Work." Amer-
A Resolution of the Equity Premium ican Economic Review, September 1992,
Puzzle." Journal of Political Economy, 82(4), pp. 922-41.

You might also like