1438347636kenneth Kletzer Discussants

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 11

“Understanding Inflation in India”

by
Laurence Ball, Anusha Chari and Prachi
Mishra

Comments by
Kenneth Kletzer
IPF 2015
About the paper

• This is a valuable contribution to the analysis and


discussion of inflation in India.
• It is clear and concise.
• In particular, the paper applies a well accepted
approach for the US and other advanced economies
to the measurement of core inflation and the sources
of short-run inflation volatility for India.
Core inflation
• Short-run inflation is significantly more volatile than
trend inflation.
• Defining core inflation is an attempt to remove high
frequency fluctuations in nominal prices from
persistent inflation.
• The distinction between core and headline inflation is
motivated by the classical dichotomy between the
monetary and real sides of the economy.
• Trend inflation ought to be due to monetary
phenomenon only. With nominal rigidities, short-run
changes in the price level can arise from non-monetary
sources. Of course, short-run inflation volatility can
also be caused by monetary policy.
Measuring core inflation
• Limited influence estimators (eg. trimmed means or
median) remove transitory effects of the tails of
skewed distributions of price changes (Bryan and
Cecchetti (1995)).
• Assuming menu costs, unexpected price changes are
made by firms that experience large shocks (Ball and
Mankiw (1995)).
• Differences between mean and median inflation tend
to be transitory.
• Limited influence estimators and econometric
approaches (eg. Quah and Vahey (1995)) are preferable
to ad hoc measures, such as “all items less food and
energy.”
Core inflation in India

• Ball, Chari and Mishra illustrate the difference between


weighted median and weighted mean inflation in
Figure 2 and show that food and fuel contribute
significantly to upper tail price changes.
• Limited influence estimators have been advocated for
India before (eg. Mohanty, Rath and Ramaiah (2000)).
• The second part of the paper uses the weighted
median to estimate the contribution of real activity to
inflation using the Friedman-Phelps Phillips curve.
• Inflation expectations are backward looking in this
model.
Phillips curve regressions
• The authors estimate Phillips curves with core inflation
and headline inflation against the quarterly output gap.
• The implicit price-setting model suggests using a PPI,
rather than CPI. The WPI is an imperfect substitute, but
it’s the best they have.
• The authors point out weaknesses in the data,
although their suspicions about the smoothness of the
quarterly GDP data could be investigated and
discussed.
• The results show that a Phillips curve for India fits the
data using median inflation.
• Aggregate supply shocks are taken out of the equation
by replacing actual inflation by core inflation.
• The reported regressions show that expectations can
be represented by either lagged median or headline
inflation.
• That is, cost shocks come in through headline inflation
in regression 3 of Table 3.
• Regression 2 is noted as mis-specified. It is missing cost
shocks, the third variable in the standard
accelerationist Phillips curve.
• The analysis is based on a menu costs model of price
setting.
• It may be helpful to repeat the PC estimation in Ball
and Mankiw (1995) of inflation on expected inflation,
output gap, and skewness interacted with the variance
of inflation.
• An alternative approach is the estimation of a new
Keynesian Phillips curve (Anand, Ding and Tulin (2014)
estimate a NK model for India in a recent IMF paper).
Critique

• This paper ends by offering its evidence in favor


of using the weighted median measure of core
inflation for India.
• But is that enough? The title “Understanding in
India” promises more.
• The persistence of inflation in India has fostered
substantial debate over monetary policy and non-
monetary sources of inflation.
• Having a measure of trend inflation in hand, it
makes sense to apply it.
Persistence of inflation in India
• Much discussion has focused on the influence of food
and energy price increases and non-monetary
interventions on inflation (eg. MSP).
• How do deviations between food and fuel inflation
from core inflation play out over time?
• Headline inflation and core inflation converge following
shocks to food and fuel prices (Anand, Ding and Tulin
(2014) find that 75% of a gap closes in a year).
• Food and fuel inflation often persists and shocks to
commodity prices tend to lead to increases in core
inflation.
• The results in the paper tells that (i) upper tail
prices changes are important, and (ii) inflation
depends on real economic activity.
• One wonders whether supply shocks lead to
inflation persistence because of monetary
accommodation.
• The stickiness in inflation comes through
backward-looking expectations that discount the
past slowly.
• As a next stage, it would be good to look at how
supply shocks future core inflation.
Policy implications for now

• The conclusion that inflation in India compares to


inflation in the 1970s in advanced economies is
informative.
• As elsewhere, reforms (such as those explored in
the Patel report) leading to anchored
expectations may also lead to taming Indian
inflation.
• I look forward to reading the authors’
interpretation of what it means for policy making
for some characteristics of inflation look like the
1970s in the US.

You might also like