Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 8

F4 National Institute Economic Review No.

227 February 2014

commentary: intergenerational and


intragenerational equity
Jonathan Portes*

The concept of ‘intergenerational fairness’ was introduced a) The evolution of the relative incomes of different
to the UK policy debate by David Willetts MP (now, cohorts. Have older generations (and in particular
somewhat ironically, the Minister for Universities and pensioners) done particularly well by comparison to
Science, and hence responsible for the new system of younger generations over the past twenty years or
student finance) in his book, The Pinch: How the Baby so?
Boomers stole their childrens’ future and how they can
give it back (Willetts, 2010). But it has only taken off b) The burden of austerity: have the specific policy
in political discussion over the past couple of years; the measures taken over the past few years to reduce the
idea that somehow the old are getting a better deal than deficit hit the young particularly hard, while favouring
the young, both before the financial crisis and during the the old?
ensuing period of austerity, has gained popularity across
the political spectrum. As Angus Hanton, Director of the c) Are the young ‘subsidising’ the old via taxation and
Intergenerational Foundation, put it (Intergenerational the provision of public services?
Foundation, 2013):
d) Will this generation ‘be the first to be worse off than
“Rising intergenerational unfairness should matter to their parents’?
everyone. The usual focus on inequality between rich
and poor misses the important inequalities between What has happened to incomes?
generations. Poorer young people are increasingly and Have pensioners done better than non-pensioners?
systematically financing richer older people. Urgent Fortunately, the ONS produces a very long series
action must be taken as the Baby Boom cohort starts for household incomes. From 1977 to 2011, median
to retire.” equivalised disposable income (that is, adjusted for
family size) for pensioner households rose from £7,090
But what does ‘intergenerational fairness’ (or its opposite) to £19,250 (in 2011–12 prices). The rise for non-
mean? And how would we know if it is ‘rising’? In pensioner households was from £12,080 to £25,700
practice, this discussion is bedevilled by confusion, both (ONS, 2013).
conceptual and empirical. The purpose of this article is
to set out some of the possible meanings of the term So the incomes of pensioner households rose significantly
‘intergenerational fairness’ and, at a very stylised level, faster on average than for non-pensioners. But there
what the evidence suggests. I identify four different, and is no indication that this process accelerated in recent
conceptually distinct, issues: years; the pace of convergence was roughly the same

*National Institute of Economic and Social Research and Centre for Macroeconomics. I am grateful to Raquel Fernandez for very helpful
comments and to various authors at the Institute for Fiscal Studies for permission to reproduce two of the charts. E-mail: j.portes@
niesr.ac.uk.
Portes Commentary: Intergenerational and intragenerational equity  F5

Figure 1a. Growth in non-retired household income Figure 1b. Growth in retired household income

£60,000
60
90
80 50
£50,000
70
40
£40,000
60

£ thousands
£ thousands

50 £30,000
30
40
30 £20,000
20

20
£10,000
10
10
0 £00
Income deciles Income deciles

1996-97 2011-12
1996-97 2011-12

Source: ONS, author’s calculations.

in the first half of this period as in the second. And, of


course, pensioner incomes remain considerably lower Figure 2. Basic pension plus winter fuel payments as a
than non-pensioner incomes throughout this period, percentage of average earnings
even on an equivalised basis. The discrepancy would
be considerably larger in cash terms, since pensioner 30%
households are smaller on average. The median non-
retired household, with an income of more than 25%
£25,000, would still be at about the 80th percentile of
the pensioner income distribution; in other words only 20%
20 per cent of retired households are better off than
the median non-retired household. Most pensioners are 15%
not ‘rich’ compared to non-pensioners.
10%
What about the distribution of these gains? Figure 1 shows
5%
real income growth by decile for retired and non-retired
households, between 1996–7 and 2011–12. It shows that
0%
gains were actually reasonably well spread, with poor
1961

1967

1973

1979

1985

1991

1997

2003

2009

non-retired households, and middle-income retired ones,


doing relatively well (although these statistics, based on
survey data, do not show the particularly strong growth Basic pension plus WFP as percentage of average earnings
for incomes of the very highest earners – the top 1 per Source: DWP, author’s calculations.
cent and 0.1 per cent – during this period). Even leaving
this aside, it remains the case that inequality within both
the retired and non-retired groups is much greater than
disparities between the two.
F6 National Institute Economic Review No. 227 February 2014

What are the drivers of this relative improvement in the fairness’ has been driven by a set of policy decisions taken
position of pensioners? It appears to be a combination by the Coalition government. It is argued that these have
of two factors: the maturing of relatively generous ensured that older people have been ‘protected’ from the
defined benefit pension schemes has helped middle and spending cuts and tax rises imposed to reduce the budget
upper income pensioners, while the introduction of deficit. These policies include:
Pension Credit and the Minimum Income Guarantee has
benefited poorer ones, with a notable fall in pensioner • The ‘triple lock’, guaranteeing that pensions should be
poverty (as measured by relative income) over the past increased by 2.5 per cent, earnings or RPI, whichever
decade (DWP, 2013). is the greater;

It does not, however, represent any increased generosity in • Ancillary to this, the Prime Minister’s personal
the level of the basic, non-means-tested state pension: even commitment to preserving other universal pensioner
including ancillary universal benefits such as Winter Fuel benefits (winter fuel payments, free bus passes);
Payments (see below) the value of the basic state pension
relative to earnings fell very substantially in the 1980s • At the same time, a series of spending cuts which
and 1990s, and has not recovered significantly since. As appear to fall most heavily on the relatively young: the
with the income distribution as a whole (Portes, 2011), abolition of the Education Maintenance Allowance,
the 2000s saw an increase in the inequality of original the very large increase in university tuition fees, large
income (before tax and benefits) that was in large part cuts to working age benefits and tax credits, while
mitigated by increases in the redistributive impact of the health spending (which is heavily weighted towards
tax and benefit system, but most of that redistribution the old) is protected in real terms.
was intragenerational rather than intergenerational.
On the face of it, it does seem obvious that these policy
The burden of austerity changes will, taken together, tend to hurt those of
While the above analysis suggests that pensioners have working age rather more than pensioners. And indeed
been doing rather better than non-pensioners – in the this is the case. Figure 3, from the IFS Green Budget
sense that their incomes have been catching up – the 2013, shows the distributional impact of tax and benefit
current focus of the political debate on ‘intergenerational reforms.

Pensioner households do indeed lose considerably less on


average than working age households without children.
But in fact working age households without children do
Figure 3. Distributional impact of tax and benefit changes
no worse than pensioners. And arguably more important
are the intra- (rather than inter-) generational issues.
Poorer pensioners have indeed been protected; less so
richer ones. By contrast, relatively well off working-age
Percentage change in net income

0%
-2% households without children have lost very little, except
at the very top, while poorer childless households have
-4% suffered. Meanwhile, households with children have lost
-6% out across the board. This is likely to reflect the net impact
-8% of cuts to working age benefits, especially disability-
related benefits, hitting poorer working-age households
-10%
(with and without children); cuts to child benefit and tax
-12% credits, hitting families across the board; the increase in
-14% the personal allowance, benefiting particularly middle-
Poorest 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Richest All income working households; and the protection to
Income decile group poorer pensioners afforded by the triple lock.

Households with children In the light of this, it is interesting to consider the


implications of one policy that has become something
Pensioner households
of a lightning rod for this debate: the Prime Minister’s
Working-age without children personal commitment not to withdraw the Winter
Source: IFS Green Budget 2013. Fuel Payment (WFP) for pensioners. Arguably, this is
Portes Commentary: Intergenerational and intragenerational equity  F7

something of a distraction; while the WFP may be an It is also important to note that the calculations described
anomaly, it is very difficult to argue that over the longer above only represent a snapshot. Clearly protecting
term the level of universal state provision for pensioners pensions at the expense of working age benefits
has become more generous, as figure 2 shows, or that redistributes from relatively poor people currently of
means-testing it would make the system either ‘fairer’ working age to pensioners in general. But those currently
or more rational (Portes, 2012). But, leaving logic aside, of working age will eventually become pensioners; the
what would be the distributional impact of means-testing net impact on them will depend on the extent to which
WFP? By definition, the impact would primarily be on the policy is in fact sustainable and sustained (or, put
middle-income pensioners (poor pensioners would be another way, how it is financed). As Chris Dillow has
protected, while for richer ones WFP is not a significant pointed out (Dillow, 2013):
income source).
“Rising pensions are better for youngsters than
But, as figure 3 shows, middle-income pensioners have oldsters. This is simply because they can look forward
actually already lost more from recent policy changes to many years of rises, whilst an old person will
than either poorer or richer ones. The chart suggests probably die after only a few years of getting them.
that if the objective of policy was to smooth the burden If you’re 40 years shy of pension age, a 0.5 per cent
of deficit reduction amongst these groups (“we’re all annual real rise in the state pension increases the value
in this together”) by targeting a group that had got off of your retirement wealth by over 25 per cent. This
relatively lightly so far, the appropriate target group is much more than an 80-year-old will get, who can
would be relatively high income working households anticipate only eight years of rising pensions before
(albeit not the very richest) without children. Ironically, he dies.”
this group benefits significantly from the government’s
signature tax policy of raising the personal allowance It follows that a government decision to implement a
(Browne, 2012), suggesting that those who are critical more generous pension uprating policy redistributes to
of the distributional impact of current policy might be the elderly only if some other assumption is made: for
better off focusing on this policy decision rather than example, that the policy is unsustainable and will have to
that on WFP. be offset in future through tax increases or spending cuts
that will fall on those now younger. In order to assess
This analysis only looks at taxes and benefits, not at this argument, we need to look at tax and spending over
other spending, so excludes the impact of tuition fees, time.
the ring-fencing of NHS spending, etc. Distributional
analyses of the impact of these measures suggest that Are the young subsidising the old?
overall they are regressive by income (Horton and Reed, The concept of ‘intergenerational accounts’ as a means
2011); but no age-related analysis exists at present, to analyse long-term distributional consequences of
although it seems likely that the relative protection tax, transfers and public spending was developed by
afforded to health spending compared to other areas Auerbach, Gokhale and Kotlikoff (1994). Generational
will indeed favour older age groups, while lower income accounts are designed to show the net discounted
working-age families with children will be the biggest lifetime contribution, positive or negative, that people,
losers. One policy where the intergenerational impacts as a function of their age, are expected to make to
have been much distorted in public debate, however, is the Exchequer. This involves a number of steps: first,
that of university tuition fees. In fact, taxpayer subsidies calculating taxes and public spending by age groups
to students have tended to rise over recent decades. What over time (for the past), and then projecting these
has changed is that the subsidy is distributed over far forward on some assumption about future policies.
more students, as HE participation has tripled since the Since the government must satisfy its intertemporal
late 1970s. The introduction of income-contingent fees – budget constraint – the future discounted value of taxes
better described as a capped graduate tax – probably does must equal the value of future spending plus any existing
not reduce expenditure much (the situation is obscured debt – any gap that emerges from this must be filled
by the way the government accounts for student loans) somehow, by adjusting future taxes or spending.
while making the distribution of the subsidy rather more
progressive. Certainly the idea that the pre-tuition fee Of course, the outputs of these calculations – the degree
regime, with far fewer students receiving higher subsidies, to which the government is redistributing income
and going on to receive excellent labour market returns, between different generations, past, present, and future
was in any sense ‘fairer’ seems hard to sustain. – depend crucially on various assumptions, of two kinds:
F8 National Institute Economic Review No. 227 February 2014

Table 1. Base generational accounts for the United Kingdom, 2008 prices

£ Present 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Total Income Production Social Other Other Health Education Pensions Social Other
taxes taxes security current receipts welfare
taxes
0 68375 185937 162813 105814 28065 605 –97286 –84054 –99138 –88379 –46002
5 79151 208916 177933 118217 32206 629 –109472 –80723 –120423 –95786 –52346
10 106868 214902 177112 121688 32941 599 –108462 –64469 –120990 –94232 –52222
15 143165 222432 176536 126413 33806 568 –106613 –47106 –118940 –92011 –51921
20 157700 210679 163527 119437 32333 510 –100363 –20180 –113558 –85404 –49280
25 124486 188883 146281 105726 29869 454 –98709 –6100 –117130 –77117 –47672
30 67684 165298 132273 89908 27998 417 –101299 –3400 –125197 –70539 –47774
35 29832 140823 117553 74758 25441 376 –97370 –1990 –122741 –61130 –45889
40 –11925 116689 105451 61122 23139 343 –95838 –1312 –125064 –52625 –43829
45 –58601 92564 93644 47705 20919 313 –95601 –895 –128811 –46391 –42049
50 –105011 68902 81086 34205 18622 280 –94238 –398 –132239 –41241 –39990
55 –155058 45561 68463 20933 16455 250 –92747 –169 –139669 –36364 –37771
60 –198930 26152 55373 9814 14004 217 –88205 –96 –150746 –30645 –34799
65 –223183 14720 43770 4309 11687 187 –84436 –57 –152334 –27965 –33063
70 –206912 9827 33943 2848 9539 157 –78861 –33 –129289 –26270 –28776
75 –177732 7165 25016 2032 7438 124 –69391 –18 –103037 –23590 –23472
80 –143375 5364 17428 1530 5514 93 –58735 –9 –76743 –20782 –17038
85 –114636 3968 12206 1155 3936 69 –48766 –3 –53878 –18082 –15240
90 –86040 2997 8653 886 2851 52 –40058 –1 –37718 –14248 –9454
95 –57721 2085 5491 616 1853 35 –28216 –1 –24879 –10151 –4555
Future
Generations 159668

Source: McCarthy, Sefton and Weale (2011).

first, those that determine how large the gap that needs But this in itself shows the (necessarily) somewhat
to be filled is (these include demographic projections, arbitrary nature of the assumptions here. Clearly there
the definition of the ‘unchanged policy’ baseline, and is no set of feasible policy changes that will impose an
macroeconomic variables such as the growth rate and extra £90,000 lifetime burden on someone born next
the real interest rate) and second, how the gap is filled year (‘future generations’) compared to those born last
(on whom does the burden of future tax or spending year. Adjustment will in practice be shared between
changes fall). those currently alive and future generations.

The most recent generational accounts for the UK were It is also worth noting that the substantial burden on
produced by McCarthy, Sefton and Weale (2011) and are those currently young, and future generations, arises
reproduced here (table 1). They show net contributions/ from the calculation that current tax and spending
receipts for all those now alive, assuming ‘unchanged policies are very far from sustainable, with a projected
policy’ applies to all those currently alive; and assume future gap between revenues and expenditures of about
that the full burden of any necessary adjustment falls 6–6.5 per cent of GDP (in NPV terms). This is much
equally on ‘future generations’. more pessimistic than the picture shown by the OBR’s
most recent Fiscal Sustainability Report, although the
These do indeed show a considerable degree of key trends and drivers – pension and health spending
intergenerational redistribution. Taken at face value, the in particular – are the same (OBR, 2013). This partly
table suggests that those currently aged 65 will receive reflects recent policy changes (such as the commitment
£220,000 more in spending than they pay in tax, over to raise the state pension age in future, and reductions
their lifetimes. Those just born will pay in £68,000; while in future public sector pensions) which will impact those
future generations will each contribute almost £160,000. alive now as well as future generations.
Portes Commentary: Intergenerational and intragenerational equity  F9

A further point bearing on the ‘fairness’ issue emerges


from looking more closely at table 1. The substantial net Figure 4. Equivalised median household income by age and
payment to those currently aged 65, and net contribution birth cohort
from those in their twenties and thirties, emerges not
because the older generations are getting more from the
800
state (in pensions, health care, education and so on) – if
anything the reverse (given the rise in life expectancy,

(£ per week, 2011-12 prices)


700
and substantial real terms increases in health spending

Real household income


over the past few decades, those who are young now 600
are expected to get considerably more from the state on
average than those now old). The spending reductions 500
now being implemented are unlikely to change that.
Instead, it is because they are expected to pay much more 400
in tax. And this in turn is not primarily because tax rates
have increased over the past half century or so, but rather 300
because the later generations have earned more (and spent
more) and will do so (assuming continued economic 200
growth) in the future, hence paying much more in taxes. 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70
This also of course implies that their lifetime consumption Age
(taking into account both their after-tax income and their
consumption of public services) is likely to be considerably 1940s 1950s 1960s 1970s
higher than that of previous generations.
Source: Hood and Joyce (2013), figure 2.3a.
To see this in a very rough and ready way, note that the
net present value of future taxes, on unchanged policies,
for those currently aged 20 is estimated at well over £0.5
million, implying lifetime consumption (private and the labour market will be “the first to be worse off than
public) of well over £1 million in NPV terms, even after their parents”. On the surface, this seems implausible:
their net ‘contribution’ of £157,000; while those now UK GDP growth over the past half century, up to the
age 50 will pay something over £0.2 million in taxes; 2008 crisis, has averaged a little over 2 per cent per
even after net ‘receipts’ of about £105,000, their lifetime year; this has, by and large, translated into real income
consumption will be closer to £0.7 million. growth. As Dillow (2014) points out,

So what is essentially happening here is not that the “Barring an improbable disaster, today’s young people
government is deliberately favouring the currently old in will on average be better off than my generation on
terms of public spending, but rather that the government average.”
is redistributing some of the ‘fruits of growth’ from those
now earning and producing to those who did so in the However, a recent IFS analysis (Hood and Joyce, 2013)
past. Since the growth that makes this possible relies – suggests that there was at least some truth in this
both in an economic sense (investment, research, etc.) thesis. Figure 4 shows the path of cohort incomes, and
and, more broadly, in political, institutional and moral does indeed suggest that those born in the 1970s are
terms, on the contribution of previous generations – this doing worse at this point in their careers than earlier
casts such redistribution in a somewhat different light. cohorts.
Whether the level of redistribution implied by current
policies is ‘fair’ or not is obviously a subjective issue, but it This represents a combination of cyclical and structural
is certainly not axiomatic that government should seek to factors. Developments in the UK economy and labour
balance generational accounts of the form shown here. market over the past decade have clearly disadvantaged
younger generations, both in absolute and relative terms:
Will this generation “be the first to be working-age income growth has slowed (and gone into
reverse since 2008) just at the time when, on the basis
worse off than their parents”? of past experience, those in their thirties would have
Perhaps the phrase that has most resonance in this debate expected to see rapid progression. Will this damage
has been the claim that the generation currently entering prove permanent? This obviously depends on broader
F10 National Institute Economic Review No. 227 February 2014

issues, and in particular the pace of future productivity It is also worth noting that, just as intragenerational
and real wage growth. However, assuming that UK inequality remains considerably more important than
productivity and hence output growth does return to intergenerational inequality, so does intragenerational
something approaching the historical average, it is redistribution. The top decile of non-retired households
difficult to see that real wage growth will not eventually pay £30,000 more annually in taxes than they receive in
follow suit. benefits and services, while the bottom decile benefit by
£10,000; while the figures are not directly comparable
How the fruits of this growth are distributed is a very to those in the generational accounts described above, it
different matter, as the example of the US shows. The US seems clear that over a lifetime this type of redistribution
has averaged output and productivity growth of about 2 – from richer to poorer, not from younger to older
per cent per year over the past three decades. However, cohorts – is likely to dominate for most households.
incomes for the top 1 per cent of households nearly The same is true for changes to policy: the main impact
quadrupled, while those for the bottom quintile grew by of the government’s changes to benefits will not be to
only 18 per cent over the entire period (CBO, 2011). The redistribute from young to old, but from poorer to
result was that nearly a third of all the income growth middle-income and richer households.
over the period went to the top 1 per cent.
Similar considerations apply to the structural changes
Although inequality increased in the UK in the first half set out in the analysis, in particular lower levels of home
of this period (1979–95), this pattern was not replicated ownership and expected future pension income (both
in the UK in the years up to the mid-2000s (Portes, state and private). As the IFS notes, the fact that those
2011), as wage growth, while favouring higher earners, now relatively old have high levels of home ownership,
was much more evenly spread, and redistributive tax and and the sharp rise in house prices over the past few
benefit policies, especially in the early 2000s, restrained decades, means that those now young and middle-
the rise in income inequality. However, in recent years, aged expect to inherit considerably more than for past
UK trends have conformed more closely to the US cohorts; but, unsurprisingly, “expected inheritances are
example. Median wages have grown significantly less distributed unequally and are higher for those who are
than per capita GDP (Resolution Foundation, 2013), already wealthier”: well over two-thirds of property
as an increasing proportion of the increase in average wealth belongs to the wealthiest third of the population.
(mean) incomes accrues to those at the top of the income And, crucially, rising property prices do not directly raise
distribution. HMRC data suggest that about a quarter of the consumption of older cohorts unless they realise the
the growth in real pre-tax incomes between 1999–2000 value of their properties via equity release or downsizing;
and 2013–14 accrued to the top 1 per cent of (income) if they simply translate into larger inheritances, then the
taxpayers; almost as much as went to the bottom 50 per redistributive impact is primarily within rather than
cent (HMRC, 2013). between generations. As Portes (2013) puts it:

And indeed the IFS figures show a sharp rise in “There is no doubt that rising house prices redistribute
intragenerational inequality. The 80–20 ratio for those wealth, and in a way that is regressive and damaging
aged 40 has gone from 2.2 for those born in the 1940s, both economically and socially. But the main
to about 2.5 for those born in the 1950s and 1960s, and dimension on which this redistribution takes place is
to about 2.8 for those born in the 1970s (and again this not that of age, but of income and wealth (and to a
is likely to understate the growth in inequality at the lesser extent geography).”
very top of the income distribution). By contrast, even if
we take the current data at face value, those born in the In other words, it is quite wrong to say that inequality
1970s are only about 10 per cent worse off than those between cohorts makes inequalities within cohorts less
born in the 1960s. So it is hardly surprising that younger important; the opposite is the case.
people on low and middle incomes feel that they are
doing rather badly in relative terms, but this is primarily Conclusion
a result of increases in intragenerational inequality that This brief survey has attempted to show that it is possible
have hit them particularly hard. The circumstances to look at the issue of ‘intergenerational fairness’
of your birth and early life (who your parents are, through a number of different lenses; this in turn means
education, gender, ability, effort and just plain luck) still that any conclusions are at least in part subjective.
matter far more – indeed, more so than before – than However, the simple story of coddled pensioners and
when you were born. struggling youth does not really add up: both inequality
Portes Commentary: Intergenerational and intragenerational equity  F11

and redistribution within generations remains much Hood, A. and Joyce, R. (2013), ‘The economic circumstances of
greater than that between generations – and its impact cohorts born between the 1940s and the 1970s’, Institute for
Fiscal Studies.
is growing – while the impact of recent policy decisions Horton, T, and Reed, R. (2011), ‘The distributional consequences
on intergenerational equity is more ambiguous than is of the 2010 Spending Review’, Journal of Poverty and Social Justice,
immediately apparent. 19, 1, February, pp. 63–66.
Institute for Fiscal Studies (2013), Green Budget 2013, February.
Intergenerational Foundation (2013), 2013 Intergenerational Fairness
Index, June.
McCarthy, D., Sefton, J. and Weale, M. (2011), ‘Generational accounts
References for the United Kingdom’, National Institute of Economic and
Auerbach, A.J., Gokhale, J. and Kotlikoff, L.J. (1994), ‘Generational Social Research Discussion Paper No. 377, January.
accounting: a meaningful way to evaluate fiscal policy’, Journal Office for National Statistics (2013), Effects of Taxes and Benefits on
of Economic Perspectives, 8(1), pp. 73–94. Household Income, 1977–2011/12, July.
Browne, J. (2012), ‘A £10,000 personal allowance: who would Office for Budget Responsibility (2013), Fiscal Sustainability Report,
benefit, and would it boost the economy?’, Institute for Fiscal July.
Studies, March. Portes, J. (2011), ‘Poverty and inequality: introduction’, National
Congressional Budget Office (2011), Trends in the Distribution of Institute Economic Review, 218, October, pp. R1–6.
Household Income between 1979 and 2007, October. —(2012), ‘Why pick on rich pensioners’ bus passes’, Independent,
Department for Work and Pensions (2013), Households Below June.
Average Income 2011–12, July. —(2013), ‘Rising house prices help the well-off”, Guardian,
Dillow, C. (2013), ‘The intergenerational question’, Stumbling and October.
Mumbling (blog), October. Resolution Foundation (2013), Squeezed Britain 2013, September.
—(2014), ‘Rising pensions: who gains’, Stumbling and Mumbling Willetts, D. (2010), The Pinch: How the Baby Boomers Took Their
(blog), January. Children’s Future – And Why They Should Give it Back, Atlantic
HMRC (2013), Income Tax Liabilities Statistics, September. Books.

You might also like