Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 3

Iqta'

Iqta‘ (Arabic: ‫ )اﻗﻄﺎع‬was an Islamic practice of tax farming that became common in Muslim Asia during the Buyid dynasty.
The prominent Orientalist Claude Cahen described the Iqta‘ as follows:

a form of administrative grant, often (wrongly) translated by the European word "fief". The nature of the iḳṭāʿ
varied according to time and place, and a translation borrowed from other systems of institutions and conceptions
has served only too often to mislead Western historians, and following them, even those of the East.[1]

Unlike European systems, the Muqtis had no right to interfere with the personal life of a paying person if the person stayed on the
Muqti's land. Also, Iqtas were not hereditary by law and had to be confirmed by a higher authority (like the sultan or the king).
Individual iqta holders in Middle Eastern societies had little incentive to provide public goods to the localities assigned to them.
The overarching theme was state power where the iqta was revocable and uninheritable. Though not an investment in a particular
holding of land, the iqta—as a fiscal device—gave soldiers a vested interest in the regime.

Contents
Muslim tax farming before the Iqta‘
The early Iqta‘
The Buyids reform of Iqta‘
Iqta‘ in the Seljuq era
Iqta‘ in the Mamluk sultanate of Delhi
Iqta‘ and feudalism
See also
References
Further reading
External links

Muslim tax farming before the Iqta‘


As with other feudal-like tax farming systems, Iqta' evolved from the tribal practices. It originated from the need to secure one's
self by paying taxes to the most powerful leader, but later developed into something exchangeable by the landowners like with
the fiefdoms of Europe.

The early Iqta‘

The Buyids reform of Iqta‘


The Buyids codified the already existent system of tax farming. They united the Amirs of Persia and reorganized their land into
Iqtas, whose borders remained largely similar to the predecessor states. Contrary to most other forms of Iqta, it was hereditary,
but the land was divided when there were more sons of age.
Iqta‘ in the Seljuq era
In the Seljuk Empire, the move toward the iqta' system was facilitated by the Persian bureaucrat Nizam al-Mulk "who developed
and systemized the trend towards feudalism that was already inherent in the tax-farming practices of the immediately preceding
period," [2] It is made clear that muqtis hold no claim on the peasants/subjects other than that of collecting from them in a proper
manner the due land tax that has been assigned to them. When the revenue has been realized from them, those subjects should
remain secure from any demands of the muqtis in respect of their persons, wealth, families, lands and goods. The muqtis can't
hold any further claims on them. The subjects can go to the King and address their grievances in case they are being subjugated
by the muqtis. It is thus clear that the muqtis only hold the land under the king, the land in truth belongs to the Sultan. Nizam al-
Mulk emphasizes an important element in the iqta- muqti's right to collect and appropriate taxes.[3] Of course, the muqtis also had
certain obligations to the Sultan. They had to maintain the troops and furnish them at call. The revenues they got from the iqtas
were meant to be resources for him to do the same. The revenue was meant for the muqti's own expenses, payment and
maintenance of the troops and the rest had to be sent back to the king. The muqti was thus a tax collector and army paymaster
rolled into one.

Iqta‘ in the Mamluk sultanate of Delhi


Shamsa ud-din Iltutmish established the "Iqta‘ system" based on Mohammad Gori's ideas. It was very close to the original form
of Iqta' as its main function was only to collect taxes by Muqtis/Iqtedars in India. They had no other right to the subjects apart
from the taxes as long as taxes were paid. The money was used to pay for the landowner's army, which could be called by the
Sultan at any time, making up for a relatively quick mobilisation and highly professional soldiers. A small part of the money was
to be given to the Sultan, but the percentage was usually insignificant compared to the other expenses. Iqtas were given for
exceptional military service or loyalty and were, unlike the original, usually hereditary. The Iqta‘ system was later reorganized by
Balban, who divided his empire into small pieces of land and opposed making Iqta hereditary. His absolutist rule concentrated on
limiting the power of the estates (mainly the nobility and merchants) and securing his supreme authority as the king. He also
dissolved the Council of Forty - Chahalgani, a form of sharing power between the highest nobles and the king. His rule was
supported by the strengthened espionage and counter-espionage system and his personal secret police, called barids.[4] The Iqta'
system was revived by Firuz Shah Tughlaq of the Tughlaq dynasty, having also made the assignments hereditary to please the
nobles.

Iqta‘ and feudalism


Although there are similarities between the Iqta‘ system and the common fief system practiced in the west at similar periods,
there are also considerable differences.

The Iqta‘ holders generally did not technically own the lands, but only assume the right to the revenue of the land, a right that the
government typically reserved the right to change. Many Iqta‘ holders did not hold their Iqta' for life, and at least in most cases
they were not subject to inheritance to the next generation.

Although the subjects attached to the Iqta‘ were still technically free men, in real practice the end result often end up with them
functioning like serfs.

There are significant variances in the actual implementation of Iqta' systems throughout the different periods and in different area,
so it is difficult to completely generalize them.

See also
Tax farming
Pronoia
Kharaj
Jizya

References
1. Claude Cahen, "Iḳṭā'," EI2, Vol. A mechanism had to be devised to collect the surplus from the peasantry and
redistribute it among the members of the ruling class. The crucial element in this mechanism was the iqta that
combined the two functions of collection and distribution without immediately endangering the unity of the political
structure. The iqta was the territorial assignment and its holder was designated muqti 3, p. 1088.
2. Lewis, Bernard. "The Middle East".
3. Iqta's: Distribution of Revenue Resources among the Ruling Class, Irfan Habib
4. Sen, Sailendra (2013). A Textbook of Medieval Indian History. Primus Books. pp. 76–79. ISBN 978-9-38060-734-
4.

Further reading
Cahen, Claude, "Iḳṭā'," Encyclopaedia of Islam, Vol. 3, pp. 1088–1091.
Cahen, Claude, “L’évolution de l’iqṭāʿ du IXe au XIIIe siežcle,” Annales, économies-sociétés-civilisation Vol. 8,
(1953), pp. 25–52.
Duri, A. A., “The Origins of the Iqṭāʿ in Islam,” al-Abḥāṯ Vol. 22 (1969), pp. 3–22.
Küpeli, Ismail: iqta als "islamischer Feudalismus"? (https://www.amazon.com/iqta-als-islamischer-Feudalismus-G
erman/dp/3638749665/) Munich, 2007, ISBN 978-3-638-74966-4

External links
Encyclopædia Iranica (http://www.iranicaonline.org/articles/eqta)

Retrieved from "https://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=Iqta%27&oldid=886997590"

This page was last edited on 9 March 2019, at 22:56 (UTC).

Text is available under the Creative Commons Attribution-ShareAlike License; additional terms may apply. By using
this site, you agree to the Terms of Use and Privacy Policy. Wikipedia® is a registered trademark of the Wikimedia
Foundation, Inc., a non-profit organization.

You might also like