Download as docx, pdf, or txt
Download as docx, pdf, or txt
You are on page 1of 19

c 


  



      !  

c "

In finance, technical analysis is a security analysis discipline for forecasting the direction of prices
through the study of past market data, primarily price and volume

While fundamental analysts examine earnings, dividends, new products, research and h t e like,
technical analysts examine what investors fear or think about those developments and whether or
not investors have the where with all to back up their opinions; these two concepts are called psych
(psychology) and supply/demand. In the M = P/E equation, technicians assess M, the multiple
investors do/may pay - if they have the money - for the fundamentals they envision. Technicians
employ many techniques, one of which is the use of charts. Using charts, technical analysts seek to
identify price patterns and trends in financial markets and attempt to exploit those patterns.
Technicians use various methods and tools, the study of price charts is but one.

Supply/demand indicators monitor investors' liquidity; margin levels, short interest, cash in
brokerage accounts, etc., in an attempt to determine whether they have any money left. Other
indicators monitor the state of psych - are investors bullish or bearish? - and are they willing to
spend money to back up their beliefs. A spent-out bull cannot move the market higher, and a well
heeled bear won't!; investors need to know which they are facing. In the end, stock prices are only
what investors think; therefore determining what they think is every bit as critical as an earnings
estimate.

Technicians using charts search for archetypal price chart patterns, such as the well-known head and
shoulders or double top/bottom reversal patterns, study indicators, moving averages, and look for
forms such as lines of support, resistance, channels, and more obscure formations such as flags,
pennants, balance days and cup and handle patterns.

Technical analysts also widely use market indicators of many sorts, some of which are mathematical
transformations of price, often including up anf down volume, advance/decline data and other
inputs. These indicators are used to help access whether an asset is trending, and if it is, its
probability of its direction and of continuation. Technicians also look for relationships between
price/volume indices and market indicators. Examples include the relative strength index, and
MACD. Other avenues of study include correlations between changes in options (implied volatility)
and put/call ratios with price. Also important are sentiment indicators such as Put/Call ratios,
bull/bear ratios, short interest and Implied Volatility, etc.

There are many techniques in technical analysis. Adherents of different techniques (for example,
candlestick charting, Dow Theory, and Elliott wave theory) may ignore the other approaches, yet
many traders combine elements from more than one technique. Some technical analysts use
subjective judgment to decide which pattern(s) a particular instrument reflects at a given time, and
what the interpretation of that pattern should be. Others employ a strictly mechanical or systematic
approach to pattern identification and interpretation.
Technical analysis is frequently contrasted with fundamental analysis, the study of economic factors
that influence the way investors price financial markets. Technical analysis holds that prices already
reflect all such trends before investors are aware of them. Uncovering those trends is what technical
indicators are designed to do, imperfect as they may be. Fundamental indicators are subject to the
same limitations, naturally. Some traders use technical or fundamental analysis exclusively, while
others use both types to make trading decisions which conceivably is the most rational approach.

Users of technical analysis are often called technicians or market technicians. Some prefer the term
technical market analyst or simply market analyst. An older term, chartist, is sometimes used, but as
the discipline has expanded and modernized, the use of the term chartist has become less popular,
as it is only one aspect of technical analysis.

Ä  

Technicians say that a market's price reflects all relevant information, so their analysis looks at the
history of a security's trading pattern rather than external drivers such as economic, fundamental
and news events. Price action also tends to repeat itself because investors collectively tend toward
patterned behavior ʹ hence technicians' focus on identifiable trends and conditions.

 # $

Based on the premise that all relevant information is already reflected by prices - a dubious concept
in that much is unknown at any point - technical analysts believe it is important to understand what
investors think of that information, known and perceived; studies such as by Cutler, Poterba, and
Summers titled "What Moves Stock Prices?" do not cover this aspect of investing.

Ä $ 

Technical analysts believe that prices trend directionally, i.e., up, down, or sideways (flat) or some
combination. The basic definition of a price trend was originally put forward by Dow Theory.

An example of a security that had an apparent trend is AOL from November 2001 through August
2002. A technical analyst or trend follower recognizing this trend would look for opportunities to sell
this security. AOL consistently moves downward in price. Each time the stock rose, sellers would
enter the market and sell the stock; hence the "zig-zag" movement in the price. The series of "lower
highs" and "lower lows" is a tell tale sign of a stock in a down trend. In other words, each time the
stock moved lower, it fell below its previous relative low price. Each time the stock moved higher, it
could not reach the level of its previous relative high price.

Note that the sequence of lower lows and lower highs did not begin until August. Then AOL makes a
low price that doesn't pierce the relative low set earlier in the month. Later in the same month, the
stock makes a relative high equal to the most recent relative high. In this a technician sees strong
indications that the down trend is at least pausing and possibly ending, and would likely stop actively
selling the stock at that point.

%    !

Technical analysts believe that investors collectively repeat the behavior of the investors that
preceded them. "Everyone wants in on the next Microsoft," "If this stock ever gets to $50 again, I
will buy it," "This company's technology will revolutionize its industry, therefore this stock will
skyrocket" ʹ these are all examples of investor sentiment repeating itself. To a technician, the
emotions in the market may be irrational, but they exist. Because investor behavior repeats itself so
often, technicians believe that recognizable (and predictable) price patterns will develop on a chart.

Technical analysis is not limited to charting, but it always considers price trends. For example, many
technicians monitor surveys of investor sentiment. These surveys gauge the attitude of market
participants, specifically whether they are bearish or bullish. Technicians use these surveys to help
determine whether a trend will continue or if a reversal could develop; they are most likely to
anticipate a change when the surveys report extreme investor sentiment. Surveys that show
overwhelming bullishness, for example, are evidence that an uptrend may reverse ʹ the premise
being that if most investors are bullish they have already bought the market (anticipating higher
prices). And because most investors are bullish and invested, one assumes that few buyers remain.
This leaves more potential sellers than buyers, despite the bullish sentiment. This suggests that
prices will trend down, and is an example of contrarian trading.

O 
  !!c    !!!
  !#&!!

c "

In finance, the efficient-market hypothesis (EMH) asserts that financial markets are "informationally
efficient". That is, one cannot consistently achieve returns in excess of average market returns on a
risk-adjusted basis, given the information publicly available at the time the investment is made.

There are three major versions of the hypothesis: "weak", "semi-strong", and "strong". Weak EMH
claims that prices on traded assets (e.g., stocks, bonds, or property) already reflect all past publicly
available information. Semi-strong EMH claims both that prices reflect all publicly available
information and that prices instantly change to reflect new public information. Strong EMH
additionally claims that prices instantly reflect even hidden or "insider" information. There is
evidence for and against the weak and semi-strong EMHs, while there is powerful evidence against
strong EMH.

The validity of the hypothesis has been questioned by critics who blame the belief in rational
markets for much of the financial crisis of 2007ʹ2010. Defenders of the EMH caution that conflating
market stability with the EMH is unwarranted; when publicly available information is unstable, the
market can be just as unstable.

The (now largely discredited) theory that all market participants receive and act on all of the
relevantinformation as soon as it becomes available. If this were strictly true, no investment strategy
would be better than a coin toss. Proponents of the efficient market theory believe that there is
perfect information in the stock market. This means that whatever information is available about a
stock to one investor is available to all investors (except, of course, insider information, but insider
trading is illegal). Since everyone has the same information about a stock, the price of a stock should
reflect the knowledge and expectations of all investors. The bottom line is that an investor should
not be able to beat the market since there is no way for him/her to know something about a stock
that isn't already reflected in the stock's price. Proponents of this theory do not try to pick stocks
that are going to be winners; instead, they simply try to match the market's performance. However,
there is ample evidence to dispute the basic claims of this theory, and most investors don't believe
it.

# !!

The efficient market hypothesis is related to the random walk theory. The idea that asset prices may
follow a random walk pattern was introduced by Bachelier in 1900. The random walk hypothesis is
used to explain the successive price changes which are independent of each other. Fama (1991)
classifies market efficiency into three forms - weak, semi-strong and strong. In its weak form
efficiency, equity returns are not serially correlated and have a constant mean. If market is weak
form efficient, current prices fully reflect all information contained in the historical prices of the
asset and a trading rule based on the past prices can not be developed to identify miss-priced assets.
Market is semi-strong efficient if stock prices reflect any new publicly available information
instantaneously. There are no undervalued or overvalued securities and thus, trading rules are
incapable of producing superior returns. When new information is released, it is fully incorporated
into the price rather speedily. The strong form efficiency suggests that security prices reflect all
available information, even private information. Insiders profit from trading on information not
already incorporated into prices. Hence the strong form does not hold in a world with an uneven
playing field. Studies testing market efficiency in emerging markets are few. Poshakwale (1996)
showed that Indian stock market was weak form inefficient; he used daily BSE index data for the
period 1987 to 1994. Barua (1987), Chan, Gup and Pan (1997) observed that the major Asian
markets were weak form inefficient. Similar results were found by Dickinson and Muragu (1994) for
Nairobi stock market; Cheung et al (1993) for Korea and Taiwan; and Ho and Cheung (1994) for Asian
markets. On the other hand, Barnes (1986) showed a high degree of efficiency in Kuala Lumpur
market. Groenewold and Kang (1993) found Australian market semi-strong form efficient. Some of
the recent studies, testing the random walk hypothesis (in effect testing for weak form efficiency in
the markets) are; Korea (Ryoo and Smith, 2002; this study uses a variance ratio test and find the
market to follow a random walk process if the price limits are relaxed during the period March 1988
to Dec 1988), China, (lee et al 2001; find that volatility is highly persistent and is predictable, authors
use GARCH and EGARCH models in this study), Hong Kong (Cheung and Coutts 2001; authors use a
variance ratio test in this study and find that Hang Seng index on the Hong Kong stock exchange
follow a random walk), Slovenia (Dezlan, 2000), Spain (Regulez and Zarraga, 2002), Czech Republic
(Hajek, 2002), Turkey (Buguk and Brorsen, 2003), Africa (Smith et al. 2002; Appiah-kusi and Menyah,
2003) and the Middle East (Abraham et al. 2002; this study uses variance ratio test and the runs test
to test for random walk for the period 1992 to 1998 and find that these markets are not efficient).

'%()(*(+,-)c'c" To test historical market efficiency one can look at the pattern of short-
term movements of the combined market returns and try to identify the principal process
generating those returns. If the market is efficient, the model would fail to identify any pattern and
it can be inferred that the returns have no pattern and follow a random walk process. In essence the
assumption of random walk means that either the returns follow a random walk process or that the
model used to identify the process is unable to identify the true return generating process. If a
model is able to identify a pattern, then historical market data can be used to forecast future market
prices, and the market is considered not efficient. There are a number of techniques available to
determine patterns in time series data. Regression, exponential smoothing and decomposition
approaches presume that the values of the time series being predicted are statistically independent
from one period to the next. Some of these techniques are reviewed in the following section and
appropriate techniques identified for use in this study.

Runs test (Bradley 1968) and LOMAC variance ratio test (Lo and MacKinlay 1988) are used to test the
weak form efficiency and random walk hypothesis. Runs test determines if successive price changes
are independent. It is non-parametric and does not require the returns to be normally distributed.
The test observes the sequence of successive price changes with the same sign. The null hypothesis
of randomness is determined by the same sign in price changes. The runs test only looks at the
number of positive or negative changes and ignores the amount of change from mean. This is one of
the major weaknesses of the test. LOMAC variance ratio test is commonly criticised on many issues
and mainly on the selection of maximum order of serial correlation (Faust, 1992). Durbin-Watson
test (Durbin and Watson 1951), the augmented Dickey-Fuller test (Dickey and Fuller 1979) and
different variants of these are the most commonly used tests for the random walk hypothesis in
recent years (Worthington and Higgs 2003; Kleiman, Payne and Sahu 2002; Chan, Gup and Pan
1997). Under the random walk hypothesis, a market is (weak form) efficient if most recent price has
all available information and thus, the best forecaster of future price is the most recent price. In the
most stringent version of the efficient market hypothesis, ɸt is random and stationary and also
exhibits no autocorrelation, as disturbance term cannot possess any systematic forecast errors. In
this study we have used returns and not prices for test of market efficiency as expected returns are
more commonly used in asset pricing literature (Fama (1998). Returns in a market conforming to
random walk are serially uncorrelated, corresponding to a random walk hypothesis with dependant
but uncorrelated increments. Parametric serial correlations tests of independence and non-
parametric runs tests can be used to test for serial dependence. Serial correlation coefficient test is a
widely used procedure that tests the relationship between returns in the current period with those
in the previous period. If no significant autocorrelation are found then the series are expected to
follow a random walk. A simple formal statistical test was introduced was Durbin and Watson
(1951). Durbin-Watson (DW) is a test for first order autocorrelation. It only tests for the relationship
between an error and its immediately preceding value. One way to motivate this test is to regress
the error of time t with its previous value.

ut = ʌut-1 + vt where vt ~ N(0,ʍ2v).

DW test can not detect some forms of residual autocorrelations, e.g. if corr(ut, ut-1) = 0 but corr(ut,
ut-2) т 0, DW as defined earlier will not find any autocorrelation. One possible way is to do it for all
possible combinations but this is tedious and practically impossible to handle. The second-best
alternative is to test for autocorrelation that would allow examination of the relationship between
ut and several of its lagged values at the same time. The Breusch- Godfrey test is a more general test
for autocorrelation for the lags of up to r th order.
Because of the abovementioned weaknesses of the DW test we do not use the DW test in our study.
An alternative model which is more commonly used is Augmented Dickey Fuller test (ADF test).
Three regression models (standard model, with drift and with drift and trend) are used in this study
to test for unit root in the research, (Chan, Gup and Pan 1997; Brooks 2002). In this study we
followed the test methodologies from Brooks (2002) with slight adjustments.

Where: St = the stock price u* and u** = the drift terms T = total number of observations ɸt, ɸt*,
ɸt** = error terms that could be ARMA processes with time dependent variances.

Where St is the logarithm of the price index seen at time t, u is an arbitrary drift parameter, ɲ is the
change in the index and ɸt is a random disturbance term. Equation (3) is for the standard model; (4)
for the standard model with a drift and (5) for the standard model with drift and trend. Augmented
Dickey-Fuller (ADF) unit root test of nonstationarity is conducted in the form of the following
regression equation. The objective of the test is to test the null hypothesis that ɽ = 1 in:

against the one-sided alternative ɽ < 1. Thus the hypotheses to be tested are:

H0: Series contains a unit root against H1: Series is stationary

In this study we calculate daily returns using daily index values for the Mumbai Stock Exchange (BSE)
and National Stock Exchange (NSE) of India. The data is collected from the Datastream data terminal
from Macquarie University. The time period for BSE is from 24th May 1991 to 26th May 2006 and for
NSE 27th May to 26th May 2006. Stock exchanges are closed for trading on weekends and this may
appear to be in contradiction with the basic time series requirement that observations be taken at a
regularly spaced intervals. The requirement however, is that the frequency be spaced in terms of the
processes underlying the series. The underlying process of the series in this case is trading of stocks
and generation of stock exchange index based on the stock trading, as such for this study the index
values at the end of each business day is appropriate (French 1980). Table 1 presents the
characteristics of two data sets used in this study. During the period covered in this study, the mean
return of the NSE index is much lower than that of the BSE, similarly the variance of NSE is lower as
compared with BSE index suggesting a lower risk and a lower average return at NSE as compared
with BSE. It is relevant to note that NSE was established by the government of India to improve the
market efficiency in Indian stock markets and to break the monopolistic position of the BSE. NSE
index is a more diversified one as compared to the same of BSE. This can also be due to the unique
nature of India s equity markets, the settlement system on BSE was intermittent (Badla system up
until 2nd July 2001) and on NSE it was always cash.

Ë.*'" This study conducts a test of random walk for the BSE and NSE markets in India, using
stock market indexes for the Indian markets. It employs unit root tests (augmented Dickey-Fuller
(ADF)). We perform ADF test with intercept and no trend and with an intercept and trend. We
further test the series using the Phillips-Perron tests and the KPSS tests for a confirmatory data
analysis. In case of BSE and NSE markets, the null hypothesis of unit root is convincingly rejected, as
the test statistic is more negative than the critical value, suggesting that these markets do not show
characteristics of random walk and as such are not efficient in the weak form. We also test using
Phillip-Perron test and KPSS test for confirmatory data analysis and find the series to be stationary.
Results are presented in Table 2. For both BSE and NSE markets, the results are statistically
significant and the results of all the three tests are consistent suggesting these markets are not weak
form efficient.

Results of the study suggest that the markets are not weak form efficient. DW test, which is a test
for serial correlations, has been used in the past but the explanatory power of the DW can be
questioned on the basis that the DW only looks at the serial correlations on one lags as such may not
be appropriate test for the daily data. Current literature in the area of market efficiency uses unit
root and test of stationarity. This notion of market efficiency has an important bearing for the fund
managers and investment bankers and more specifically the investors who are seeking to diversify
their portfolios internationally. One of the criticisms of the supporters of the international
diversification into emerging markets is that the emerging markets are not efficient and as such the
investor may not be able to achieve the full potential benefits of the international diversification.

/(0/*.(0-Ä*/c'(0:- This paper examines the weak form efficiency in two of the Indian
stock exchanges which represent the majority of the equity market in India. We employ three
different tests ADF, PP and the KPSS tests and find similar results. The results of these tests find that
these markets are not weak form efficient. These results support the common notion that the equity
markets in the emerging economies are not efficient and to some degree can also explain the less
optimal allocation of portfolios into these markets. Since the results of the two tests are
contradictory, it is difficult to draw conclusions for practical implications or for policy from the study.
It is important to note that the BSE moved to a system of rolling settlement with effect from 2nd July
2006 from the previously used ͣBadla system. The ͣBadla system was a complex system of
forward settlement which was not transparent and was not accessible to many market participants.
The results of the NSE are similar (NSE had a cash settlement system from the beginning) to BSE
suggesting that the changes in settlement system may not significantly impact the results. On the
contrary a conflicting viewpoint is that the results of these markets may have been influenced by
volatility spillovers, as such the results may be significantly different if the changes in the settlement
system are incorporated in the analysis. The research in the area of volatility spillover has argued
that the volatility is transferred across markets (Brailsford, 1996), as such the results of these
markets may be interpreted cautiously. For future research, using a computationally more efficient
model like generalized autoregressive conditional heteroskesdasticity (GARCH) could help to clear
this.

 

1##   !,'& ! 

c "

In finance, the term yield describes the amount in cash that returns to the owners of a security.
Normally it does not include the price variations, at the difference of the total return. Yield applies to
various stated rates of return on stocks (common and preferred, and convertible), fixed income
instruments (bonds, notes, bills, strips, zero coupon), and some other investment type insurance
products (e.g. annuities).
The term is used in different situations to mean different things. It can be calculated as a ratio or as
an internal rate of return (IRR). It may be used to state the owner's total return, or just a portion of
income, or exceed the income.
Because of these differences, the yields from different uses should never be compared as if they
were equal. This page is mainly a series of links to other pages with increased details.

The income return on an investment. This refers to the interest or dividends received from a security
and is usually expressed annually as a percentage based on the investment's cost,its current market
value or its face value.
This seemingly simple term, without a qualifier, can be rather confusing to investors.
For example, there are two stock dividend yields. If you buy a stock for $30 (cost basis) and its
current price and annual dividend is $33 and $1, respectively, the "cost yield" will be 3.3% ($1/$30)
and the "current yield" will be 3% ($1/$33).
Bonds have four yields: coupon (the bond interest rate fixed at issuance), current (the bond interest
rate as a percentage of the current price of the bond), and yield to maturity (an estimate of what an
investor will receive if the bond is held to its maturity date). Non-taxable municipal bonds will have a
tax-equivalent (TE) yield determined by the investor's tax bracket.
Mutual fund yields are an annual percentage measure of income (dividends and interest) earned by
the fund's portfolio, net of the fund's expenses. In addition, the "SEC yield" is an indicator of the
percentage yield on a fund based on a 30-day period.

,'# ,'

The Yield to maturity (YTM) or redemption yield of a bond or other fixed-interest security, such as
gilts, is the internal rate of return (IRR, overall interest rate) earned by an investor who buys the
bond today at the market price, assuming that the bond will be held until maturity, and that all
coupon and principal payments will be made on schedule. Yield to maturity is actually an estimation
of future return, as the rate at which coupon payments can be reinvested when received si
unknown.[1] It enables investors to compare the merits of different financial instruments. The YTM
is often given in terms of Annual Percentage Rate (A.P.R.), but more usually market convention is
followed: in a number of major markets the convention is to quote yields semi-annually (see
compound interest: thus, for example, an annual effective yield of 10.25% would be quoted as
5.00%, because 1.05 x 1.05 = 1.1025).

The yield is usually quoted without making any allowance for tax paid by the investor on the return,
and is then known as "gross redemption yield". It also does not make any allowance for the dealing
costs incurred by the purchaser (or seller).

á? If the yield to maturity for a bond is less than the bond's coupon rate, then the (clean)
market value of the bond is greater than the par value (and vice versa).
á? If a bond's coupon rate is less than its YTM, then the bond is selling at a discount.
á? If a bond's coupon rate is more than its YTM, then the bond is selling at a premium.
á? If a bond's coupon rate is equal to its YTM, then the bond is selling at par.

concept used to determine the rate of return an investor will receive if a long-term, interest-bearing
investment, such as a bond, is held to its maturity date . It takes into account purchase price,
redemption value, time to maturity, coupon yield, and the time between interest payments.
Recognizing time value of money, it is the discount rate at which the present value of all future
payments would equal the present price of the bond, also known as Internal Rate of Return It is
implicitly assumed that coupons are reinvested at the YTM rate. YTM can be approximated using a
bond value table (also called a bond yield table) or can be determined using a programmable
calculator equipped for bond mathematics calculations.

j 
Consider a 30-year zero-coupon bond with a face value of $100. If the bond is priced at an annual
YTM of 10%, it will cost $5.73 today (the present value of this cash flow, 100/(1.1)30 = 5.73). Over
the coming 30 years, the price will advance to $100, and the annualized return will be 10%.
What happens in the meantime? Suppose that over the first 10 years of the holding period,interest
rates decline, and the yield-to-maturity on the bond falls to 7%. With 20 years remaining to maturity,
the price of the bond will be 100/1.0720, or $25.84. Even though the yield-to-maturity for the
remaining life of the bond is just 7%, and the yield-to-maturity bargained for when the bond was
purchased was only 10%, the return earned over the first 10 years is 16.25%. This can be found by
evaluating (1+i) from the equation (1+i)10 = (25.842/5.731), giving 1.1625.
Over the remaining 20 years of the bond, the annual rate earned is not 16.25%, but rather 7%. This
can be found by evaluating (1+i) from the equation (1+i)20 = 100/25.84, giving 1.07. Over the entire
30 year holding period, the original $5.73 invested increased to $100, so 10% per annum was
earned, irrespective of any interest rate changes in between.
Here is another example:
You buy ABC Company bond which matures in 1 year and has a 5% interest rate (coupon) and has a
par value of $100. You pay $90 for the bond.
The current yield is 5.56% ((5/90)*100).
If you hold the bond until maturity, ABC Company will pay you $5 as interest and $100 for the
matured bond.
Now for your $90 investment you made $105 and your yield to maturity is 16.67% [= (105/90)-1] or
[=(105-90)/90]
?
??? ?

?   ? ?? 


? 
??
?
???
? ??
? ? ?
 ?  ?
 ? ? ?   ? 
?
 ? ? 
?
 ?
 ?? ?
? ? ? ?
?
  
?
? ? ?  ?? ?
?
? ?
 ?  ? ? ?  
 ???
? ?

 ? 
? ? ? ? ?? ? ?  ? ?? ?
? ?  ?
? ? ?  ?? ?

?  ? ???  ? ?? ? ?
? ? 
? ? ?
 ?
?
?
   ? ? ? ?  ? ?? ?
? ? ?
? ? ?  ?? ?
?  ? ???
 
? ?? ?  ?
? ? 
? ?
?!? ? ?  ? ?? ?
? ? "?? ?
 ?  ?? ?
? ?? ? "?? ? 
? ? ? " 
?? ?  
?? ??
? ? ?
$?%&'()?*?+'()?
?
?#?
&'()?%?+'()?
?

$?#?$
  ? ? ?

?
? ?? ?
? 
? ?? ?
?
  ?&'()?#? ?  ??
?
?
 ?
?
    ?
+'()?#? 
?  ??
?, ?  ??
?
?#?
 ??  ?
 ?
?   ? ? ?&? - ?  ? ?
?
$?#?./? 
? ?? ?
? ?
 ?
?
    ?
&'()?#?0111?
 ?
?
?    ?
+'()?#?02.1?, ?  ?
?#?!1?

?
0.1?%?0111?*?02.1?
!1?
??#?
0111?%?02.1?
?

#?.3/?
c  2  

1 !   &       #   
c /cÄ  !3#

c "

  
In finance, systematic risk, sometimes called market risk, aggregate risk, or undiversifiable
risk, is the risk associated with aggregate market returns.
Systematic risk should not be confused with systemic risk, the risk of loss from some
catastrophic event that collapses the entire   ?
.
It is the risk which is due to the factors which are beyond the control of the people w orking
in the market and that's why risk free rate of return in used to just compensate this type of
risk in market. Interest rates, recession and wars all represent sources of systematic risk
because they affect the entire market and cannot be avoided thr ough diversification.
Whereas this type of risk affects a broad range of securities, unsystematic risk affects a very
specific group of securities or an individual security. Systematic risk can be mitigated only by
being hedged.Even a portfolio of well -diversified assets cannot escape all risk.

 
Examples of systematic risk include uncertainty about general economic conditions, such as
GNP, interest rates or inflation.
For example, consider an individual investor who purchases $10,000 of stock in 10
biotechnology companies. If unforeseen events cause a catastrophic setback and one or two
companies' stock prices drop, the investor incurs a loss. On the other hand, an investor who
purchases $100,000 in a single biotechnology company would incur ten times the loss from
such an event. The second investor's portfolio has more unsystematic risk than the
diversified portfolio. Finally, if the setback were to affect the entire industry inste ad, the
investors would incur similar losses, due to systematic risk.
Systematic risk is essentially dependent on macroeconomic factors such as inflation, interest
rates and so on. It may also derive from the structure and dynamics of the market.

   !


Given diversified holdings of assets, an investor's exposure to unsystematic risk from any
particular asset is small and uncorrelated with the rest of the portfolio. Hence, the
contribution of unsystematic risk to the riskiness of the portfolio as a whole may become
negligible.
In the capital asset pricing model, the rate of return required for an asset in market
equilibrium depends on the systematic risk associated with returns on the asset, that is, on
the covariance of the returns on the asset and the aggregate returns to the market.
Lenders to small numbers of borrowers (or kinds of borrowers) face unsystematic risk of
default. Their loss due to default is credit risk, the unsystematic portion of which is
concentration risk.

.   
By contrast, unsystematic risk, sometimes called specific risk, idiosyncratic risk, residual risk,
or diversifiable risk, is the company-specific or industry-specific risk in a portfolio, which is
uncorrelated with aggregate market returns.
Unsystematic risk can be mitigated through diversification, and systematic risk can not be.
This is the risk other than systematic risk and which is due to the factors which are
controllable by the people working in market and market risk premium is used to
compensate this type of risk.
Total Risk = Systematic risk + Unsystematic Risk
The risk that is specific to an industry or firm. Examples of unsystematic risk include losses
caused by labor problems, nationalization of assets, or weather conditions. This type of risk
can be reduced by assembling a portfolio with significant diversification so that a single
event affects only a limited number of the assets.
Company- or industry-specific risk as opposed to overall market risk; unsystematic risk can
be reduced through diversification. As the saying goes, ͞Don't put all of your eggs in one
basket.͟ Also known as specific risk, diversifiable risk, and residual ri sk.

 
On the other hand, announcements specific to a company, such as a gold mining company
striking gold, are examples of unsystematic risk.

Ë " .  

We can break down the risk, U, of holding a stock into two components: sy stematic risk and
unsystematic risk:

K 
_   m
 
`   m mV
Ô
  
 `
   
  Ô 
V  
| V    
  Ô 


/cÄ  !" 

á? The model assumes that either asset returns are (jointly) normally
distributedrandom variables or that investors employ a quadratic form of utility. It is
however frequently observed that returns in equity and other markets are not
normally distributed. As a result, large swings (3 to 6 standard deviations from the
mean) occur in the market more frequently than the normal distribution assumption
would expect.
á? The model assumes that the variance of returns is an adequate measurement of risk.
This might be justified under the assumption of normally distributed returns, but for
general return distributions other risk measures (like coherent risk measures) will
likely reflect the investors' preferences more adequately. Indeed risk in financial
investments is not variance in itself, rather it is the probability of losing: it is
asymmetric in nature.
á? The model assumes that all investors have access to the same information and agree
about the risk and expected return of all assets (homogeneous expectations
assumption).
á? The model assumes that the probability beliefs of investors match the true
distribution of returns. A different possibility is that investors' expectations are
biased, causing market prices to be informationally inefficient. This possibility is
studied in the field of behavioral finance, which uses psychological assumptions to
provide alternatives to the CAPM such as the overconfidence-based asset pricing
model of Kent Daniel, David Hirshleifer, and AvanidharSubrahmanyam (2001).
á? The model does not appear to adequately explain the variation in stock returns.
Empirical studies show that low beta stocks may offer higher returns than the model
would predict. Some data to this effect was presented as early as a 1969 conference
in Buffalo, New York in a paper by Fischer Black, Michael Jensen, and Myron Scholes.
Either that fact is itself rational (which saves the efficient-market hypothesis but
makes CAPM wrong), or it is irrational (which saves CAPM, but makes the EMH
wrong ʹ indeed, this possibility makes volatility arbitrage a strategy for reliably
beating the market).
á? The model assumes that given a certain expected return investors will prefer lower
risk (lower variance) to higher risk and conversely given a certain level of risk will
prefer higher returns to lower ones. It does not allow for investors who will accept
lower returns for higher risk. Casino gamblers clearly pay for risk, and it is possible
that some stock traders will pay for risk as well.
á? The model assumes that there are no taxes or transaction costs, although this
assumption may be relaxed with more complicated versions of the model.
á? The market portfolio consists of all assets in all markets, where each asset is
weighted by its market capitalization. This assumes no preference between markets
and assets for individual investors, and that investors choose assets solely as a
function of their risk-return profile. It also assumes that all assets are infinitely
divisible as to the amount which may be held or transacted.
á? The market portfolio should in theory include all types of assets that are held by
anyone as an investment (including works of art, real estate, human capital...) In
practice, such a market portfolio is unobservable and people usually substitute a
stock index as a proxy for the true market portfolio. Unfortunately, it has been
shown that this substitution is not innocuous and can lead to false inferences as to
the validity of the CAPM, and it has been said that due to the inobservability of the
true market portfolio, the CAPM might not be empirically testable. This was
presented in greater depth in a paper by Richard Roll in 1977, and is generally
referred to as Roll's critique 2?
á? The model assumes just two dates, so that there is no opportunity to consume and
rebalance portfolios repeatedly over time. The basic insights of the model are
extended and generalized in the intertemporal CAPM (ICAPM) of Robert Merton,
and the consumption CAPM (CCAPM) of Douglas Breeden and Mark Rubinstein. 
á? CAPM assumes that all investors will consider all of their assets and optimize one
portfolio. This is in sharp contradiction with portfolios that are held by individual
investors: humans tend to have fragmented portfolios or, rather, multiple portfolios:
for each goal one portfolio .

2
1##   &cÄ'-/cÄ 
c "
In economics and finance, arbitrage is the practice of taking advantage of a price difference
between two or more markets: striking a combination of matching deals that capitalize
upon the imbalance, the profit being the difference between the market prices. When used
by academics, an arbitrage is a transaction that involves no negative cash flow at any
probabilistic or temporal state and a positive cash flow in at least one state; in simple terms,
it is the possibility of a risk-free profit at zero cost.
In principle and in academic use, an arbitrage is risk-free; in common use, as in statistical
arbitrage, it may refer to expected profit, though losses may occur, and in practice, there are
always risks in arbitrage, some minor (such as fluctuation of prices decreasing profit
margins), some major (such as devaluation of a currency or derivative). In academic use, an
arbitrage involves taking advantage of differences in price of a single asset or identical cash-
flows; in common use, it is also used to refer to differences between similar assets (relative
value or convergence trades), as in merger arbitrage.
People who engage in arbitrage are called arbitrageurs (IPA: / rb tr r/)Ͷsuch as a
bank or brokerage firm. The term is mainly applied to trading in financial instruments, such
as bonds, stocks, derivatives, commodities and currencies.

/ ! 
Arbitrage is possible when one of three conditions is met:
1. ? The same asset does not trade at the same price on all markets ("the law of one
price").
2. ? Two assets with identical cash flows do not trade at the same price.
3. ? An asset with a known price in the future does not today trade at its future price
discounted at the risk-free interest rate (or, the asset does not have negligible costs
of storage; as such, for example, this condition holds for grain but not for securities).
c  e s s y
ec  y  c e ese  
e  



e   ce  s e e  e 
e  sc s  s cc ‘ u anou‘   v 
e s e    e s  
e s 
  ces y c
e  e  e e e  

 sc s  e c  ee cc e s 
ssee  y  y ss e
sec es
 c   cs
c
ce ee ec c yeve
e
eec
 e 

e eseec e
e ces
e ey
ve vess e 
e es 

e  e  s se e y
v    e  s   e     se  ces c e
eec   s  esec c y e s[ e1]
 
e s es e e y   s   e  e s
 se   
e se  ce 
 
e   e s y  e e  
 
e  ce  
e s e    c   
e s 
  ces  c
se 
e     s      
e  e    se   


e   ce 
s ye   ce   e s 
e  s c     
s s e e e
 es
ec s  s s e s 
e  c s e  e e  es


e ee  e sv ve
e esec es e e  e
 eec
e
  e cc sys e s y y ese  
e 
e 
See    c c  y  eec
cs  
e sc ss 

ec yse es s 
 

e ees   e

j

á? S  se

ee c
e es e  
e ees 
ee c
e
   e5=$10=1000
ee c
e es y  e1000=$12=
6 ve 1000 $12 y c ve 
$12 1200  
     200   e   e  e y 
s   e   e s s 
s e 
    s eve  cc s B   e c  ce e e c
e
  es s c
 s 
e s -     e seee es e  y  e  c

 ec  
á? ãe e e    e v ves 
e e  S c !"c
e  
e 
c 
e c e!"c
e
e
e ce s c 
e S!sc es 
 esc  c 
e! e  syc ec y
e esse"esve e
se  
e ee"esve eBec se
e e eceseee
e ces e
e y   e s       s ve y # 
s c  y e  e   y 

c  e se"  e e   ces  c ye"e cs e

e
e ces e  e 
   ce
ecvy  
e   e sc
e 
s sy 
se 
 
e ses c  e s  
e  s e"e se e
ve  se es  s   e eces 
     e   e   e
v  y
á? !c  ss se 
e e         e   e e    
e eecy 
 c  j s      s 
c
eve  c  y
s 
e es es e 
   ese
s ec
e
e  e se eve   c 
economic development to support industrialization. At present, many such jobs
appear to be flowing towards China, though some which require command of English
are going to India and the Philippines. In popular terms, this is referred to as
offshoring. (Note that "offshoring" is not synonymous with "outsourcing", which
means "to subcontract from an outside supplier or source", such as when a business
outsources its bookkeeping to an accounting firm. Unlike offshoring, outsourcing
always involves subcontracting jobs to a different company, and that company can
be in the same country as the outsourcing company.)
á? Sports arbitrage ʹ numerous internetbookmakers offer odds on the outcome of the
same event. Any given bookmaker will weight their odds so that no one customer
can cover all outcomes at a profit against their books. However, in order to remain
competitive their margins are usually quite low. Different bookmakers may offer
different odds on the same outcome of a given event; by taking the best odds
offered by each bookmaker, a customer can under some circumstances cover all
possible outcomes of the event and lock a small risk-free profit, known as a Dutch
book. This profit would typically be between 1% and 5% but can be much higher.
One problem with sports arbitrage is that bookmakers sometimes make mistakes
and this can lead to an invocation of the 'palpable error' rule, which most
bookmakers invoke when they have made a mistake by offering or posting incorrect
odds. As bookmakers become more proficient, the odds of making an 'arb' usually
last for less than an hour and typically only a few minutes. Furthermore, huge bets
on one side of the market also alert the bookies to correct the market.
á? Exchange-traded fund arbitrage ʹ Exchange Traded Funds allow authorized
participants to exchange back and forth between shares in underlying securities held
by the fund and shares in the fund itself, rather than allowing the buying and selling
of shares in the ETF directly with the fund sp onsor. ETFs trade in the open market,
with prices set by market demand. An ETF may trade at a premium or discount to the
value of the underlying assets. When a significant enough premium appears, an
arbitrageur will buy the underlying securities, convert them to shares in the ETF, and
sell them in the open market. When a discount appears, an arbitrageur will do the
reverse. In this way, the arbitrageur makes a low-risk profit, while fulfilling a useful
function in the ETF marketplace by keeping ETF prices in line with their underlying
value.
á? Some types of hedge funds make use of a modified form of arbitrage to profit.
Rather than exploiting price differences between identical assets, they will purchase
and sell securities, assets and derivatives with similar characteristics, and hedge any
significant differences between the two assets. Any difference between the hedged
positions represents any remaining risk (such as basis risk) plus profit; the belief is
that there remains some difference which, even after hedging most risk, represents
pure profit. For example, a fund may see that there is a substantial difference
between U.S. doll ar debt and local currency debt of a foreign country, and enter into
a series of matching trades (including currency swaps) to arbitrage the difference,
while simultaneously entering into credit default swaps to protect against country
risk and other types of specific risk.

/  &cÄ'-/cÄ
á? APT applies to well diversified portfolios and not necessarily to individual stocks.
á? With APT it is possible for some individual stocks to be mispriced - not lie on the
SML.
á? APT is more general in that it gets to an expected return and beta relationship
without the assumption of the market portfoli o.
á? APT can be extended to multifactor models.
á? Both the CAPM and APT are risk -based models. There are alternatives.
á? Empirical methods are based less on theory and more on looking for some
regularities in the historical record.
á? Be aware that correlation does not imply causality.
á? Related to empirical methods is the practice of classifying portfolios by style e.g.
i? Value portfolio
i? Growth portfolio
á? The APT assumes that stock returns are generated according to factor models such
as:
? ? ? m? ? ? ?? m? 
?
?
?
?
m? ? ? ? ? m?V?
á? As securities are added to the portfolio, the unsystematic risks of the individual
securities offset each other. A fully diversified portfolio has no unsystematic risk.
á? The CAPM can be viewed as a special case of the APT.
á? Empirical models try to capture the relations between returns and stock attributes
that can be measured directly from the data without appeal to theory.
á? Difference in Methodology
Õ? CAPM is an equilibrium model and derived from individual portfolio optimization.
Õ? APT is a statistical model which tries to capture sources of systematic
risk.Relation between sources determined by no Arbitrage condition.
á? Difference in Application
Õ? APT difficult to identify appropriate factors.
Õ? CAPM difficult to find good proxy for market returns.
Õ? APT shows sensitivity to different sources. Important for hedging in portfolio
formation.
Õ? CAPM is simpler to communicate, since everybody agrees upon.
 
 !cÄ'&  !
c "
Arbitrage pricing theory (APT), in finance, is a general theory of asset pricing, that has
become influential in the pricing of stocks.
APT holds that the expected return of a financial asset can be modeled as a linear function
of various macro-economic factors or theoretical market indices, where sensitivity to
changes in each factor is represented by a factor-specific beta coefficient. The model-
derived rate of return will then be used to price the asset correctly - the asset price should
equal the expected end of period price discounted at the rate implied by model. If the price
diverges, arbitrage should bring it back into line.
The theory was initiated by the economist Stephen Ross in 1976.

'cÄ'
Risky asset returns are said to follow a factor structure if they can be expressed as:
?
where
á? j(rj) is the jth asset's expected return,
á? ß is a systematic factor (assumed to have mean zero),
á?
j is the sensitivity of the jth asset to factor , also called factor loading,
á? andɸ j is the risky asset's idiosyncratic random shock with mean zero.
Idiosyncratic shocks are assumed to be uncorrelated across assets and uncorrelated with
the factors.
The APT states that if asset returns follow a factor structure then the following relation
exists between expected returns and the factor sensitivities:

where
á? RPk is the risk premium of the factor,
á? rf is the risk-free rate,
That is, the expected return of an asset j is a linear function of the assets sensitivities to the
n factors.
Note that there are some assumptions and requirements that have to be fulfilled for the
latter to be correct: There must be perfect competition in the market, and the total number
of factors may never surpass the total number of assets (in order to avoid the problem of
matrix singularity).

?
. cÄ'
!! 
As with the CAPM, the factor -specific Betas are found via a linear regression of historical
security returns on the factor in question. Unlike the CAPM, the APT, however, does not
itself reveal the identity of its priced factors - the number and nature of these factors is
likely to change over time and between economies. As a resul t, this issue is essentially
empirical in nature. Several a priori guidelines as to the characteristics required of potential
factors are, however, suggested:
1. ? their impact on asset prices manifests in their unexpected movements
2. ? they should represent undiversifia
le influences (these are, clearly, more likely to be
macroeconomic rather than firm-specific in nature)
3. ? timely and accurate information on these variables is required
4. ? the relationship should be theoretically justifiable on economic grounds
Chen, Roll and Ross (1986) identified the following macro -economic factors as significant in
explaining security returns:
á? surprises in inflation;
á? surprises in GNP as indicated by an industrial production index;
á? surprises in investor confidence due to changes in default premium in corporate
bonds;
á? surprise shifts in the yield curve.
As a practical matter, indices or spot or futures market prices may be used in place of
macro-economic factors, which are reported at low frequency (e.g. monthly) and often with
significant estimation errors. Market indices are sometimes derived by means of factor
analysis. More direct "indices" that might be used are:
á? short term interest rates;
á? the difference in long-term and short-term interest rates;
á? a diversified stock index such as the S&P 500 or NYSE Composite Index;
á? oil prices
á? gold or other precious metal prices
á? Currency exchange rates

!
rj = b j0 + b j1F1 + Φj; j = 1; 2; : : : ; n
wherer j is the rate of return on asset (or portfolio) j, F 1 denotes the factor͛s value, b j0
and b j1 are parameters, and "j denotes an unobserved random error. It is assumed that
E[Φjl F1] = 0, that is, the expected value of the random error, conditional upon the value of
the factor, is zero.
cÄ' 3 !" 

The weight ʄ1 is interpreted as the risk premium associated with the factor, that is, the risk
premium corresponds to the source of the systematic risk.

You might also like