Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 4

Oldrich Vasicek,

"Loan Portfolio Value",


Risk Magazine, 2002
Source (free download):
http://www.risk.net/data/Pay_per_view/risk/
technical/2002/1202_loan.pdf
Cutting edge l Credit portfolio models

Loan portfolio value


Using a conditional independence framework, Oldrich Vasicek derives a useful limiting form
for the portfolio loss distribution with a single systematic factor. He then derives a risk-neutral
distribution suitable for traded portfolios, and shows how credit migration and granularity can
be incorporated into this model too

T
he amount of capital needed to support a portfolio of debt securities of each other, the portfolio loss distribution would converge, by the cen-
depends on the probability distribution of the portfolio loss. Consid- tral limit theorem, to a normal distribution as the portfolio size increases.
er a portfolio of loans, each of which is subject to default resulting in Because the defaults are not independent, however, the conditions of the
a loss to the lender. Suppose the portfolio is financed partly by equity cap- central limit theorem are not satisfied and L is not asymptotically normal.
ital and partly by borrowed funds. The credit quality of the lender’s notes It turns out, however, that the distribution of the portfolio loss does con-
will depend on the probability that the loss on the portfolio exceeds the verge to a limiting form, which we will now proceed to derive.
equity capital. To achieve a certain credit rating of its notes (say Aa on a The variables Xi in Equation (1) are jointly standard normal with equal
rating agency scale), the lender needs to keep the probability of default pair-wise correlations ρ, and can therefore be represented as:
on the notes at the level corresponding to that rating (about 0.001 for the
Xi = Y ρ + Zi 1 − ρ (2)
Aa quality). It means that the equity capital allocated to the portfolio must
be equal to the percentile of the distribution of the portfolio loss that cor- where Y, Z1, Z2, ... , Zn are mutually independent standard normal vari-
responds to the desired probability. ables. (This is not an assumption, but a property of the equicorrelated
In addition to determining the capital needed to support a loan portfo- normal distribution.) The variable Y can be interpreted as a portfolio com-
lio, the probability distribution of portfolio losses has a number of other ap- mon factor, such as an economic index, over the interval (0, T). Then the
plications. It can be used in regulatory reporting, measuring portfolio risk, term Y√ρ is the company’s exposure to the common factor and the term
calculation of value-at-risk, portfolio optimisation, and structuring and pric- Zi√(1 – ρ) represents the company’s specific risk.
ing debt portfolio derivatives such as collateralised debt obligations (CDOs). We will evaluate the probability of the portfolio loss as the expectation
In this article, we derive the distribution of the portfolio loss under cer- over the common factor Y of the conditional probability given Y. This can
tain assumptions. It is shown that this distribution converges with increasing be interpreted as assuming various scenarios for the economy, determin-
portfolio size to a limiting type, whose analytical form is given here. The ing the probability of a given portfolio loss under each scenario and then
results of the first two sections of this paper are contained in the author’s weighting each scenario by its likelihood.
technical notes, Vasicek (1987) and (1991). For a review of recent litera- When the common factor is fixed, the conditional probability of loss
ture on the subject, see, for instance, Pykhtin & Dev (2002). on any one loan is:
 N −1 ( p ) − Y ρ 
The limiting distribution of portfolio losses p (Y ) = P  Li = 1 Y  = N   (3)
 1− ρ 
Assume that a loan defaults if the value of the borrower’s assets at the loan
maturity T falls below the contractual value B of its obligations payable. The quantity p(Y) provides the loan default probability under the given
Let Ai be the value of the i-th borrower’s assets, described by the process: scenario. The unconditional default probability p is the average of the con-
dAi = µ i Ai dt + σ i Ai dxi ditional probabilities over the scenarios.
Conditional on the value of Y, the variables Li are independent equal-
The asset value at T can be represented as: ly distributed variables with a finite variance. The portfolio loss condi-
log Ai (T ) = log Ai + µ iT − 21 σ i2T + σ i T Xi (1)
tional on Y converges, by the law of large numbers, to its expectation p(Y)
as n → ∞. Then:
where Xi is a standard normal variable. The probability of default of the i-
th loan is then: ( )
P [ L ≤ x ] = P  p (Y ) ≤ x  = P Y ≥ p −1 ( x ) = N − p −1 ( x )

pi = P  Ai (T ) < Bi  = P  Xi < ci  = N (ci ) and on substitution, the cumulative distribution function of loan losses on
a very large portfolio is in the limit:
where:  1 − ρN −1 ( x ) − N −1 ( p ) 
P [L ≤ x ] = N   (4)
log Bi − log Ai − µ iT + 21 σ i2T  ρ 
ci =
σi T
This result is given in Vasicek (1991).
and N is the cumulative normal distribution function. The convergence of the portfolio loss distribution to the limiting form
Consider a portfolio consisting of n loans in equal dollar amounts. Let the above actually holds even for portfolios with unequal weights. Let the port-
probability of default on any one loan be p, and assume that the asset val- folio weights be w1, w2, ... , wn with Σwi = 1. The portfolio loss:
ues of the borrowing companies are correlated with a coefficient ρ for any n
two companies. We will further assume that all loans have the same term T. L = ∑ wi Li
i =1
Let Li be the gross loss (before recoveries) on the i-th loan, so that Li
= 1 if the i-th borrower defaults and Li = 0 otherwise. Let L be the portfo- conditional on Y converges to its expectation p(Y) whenever (and this is
lio percentage gross loss: a necessary and sufficient condition):
n
1 n
L= ∑ Li ∑ wi2 → 0
n i =1 i =1

If the events of default on the loans in the portfolio were independent In other words, if the portfolio contains a sufficiently large number of loans

160 RISK DECEMBER 2002 ● WWW.RISK.NET


without it being dominated by a few loans much larger than the rest, the
limiting distribution provides a good approximation for the portfolio loss. A. Values of (Lα – p)/s for the portfolio loss
distribution
Properties of the loss distribution
The portfolio loss distribution given by the cumulative distribution function: p ρ α = 0.9 α = 0.99 α = 0.999 α = 0.9999
 1 − ρN −1 ( x ) − N −1 ( p )  0.01 0.1 1.19 3.8 7.0 10.7
F ( x; p,ρ) = N   (5) 0.01 0.4 0.55 4.5 11.0 18.2
 ρ  0.001 0.1 0.98 4.1 8.8 15.4
is a continuous distribution concentrated on the interval 0 ≤ x ≤ 1. It forms 0.001 0.4 0.12 3.2 13.2 31.8
a two-parameter family with the parameters 0 < p, ρ < 1. When ρ → 0, it Normal 1.28 2.3 3.1 3.7
converges to a one-point distribution concentrated at L = p. When ρ → 1, it
converges to a zero-one distribution with probabilities p and 1 – p, respec- λ = (µM – r)/σM is the market price of risk. The risk-neutral portfolio loss
tively. When p → 0 or p → 1, the distribution becomes concentrated at L = distribution is then given by:

( )
0 or L = 1, respectively. The distribution possesses a symmetry property:
 1 − ρN −1 ( x ) − N −1 p* 
F ( x; p, ρ) = 1 − F (1 − x;1 − p, ρ) P* [ L ≤ x ] = N   (7)
 ρ 
The loss distribution has the density:
 1 2 Thus, a derivative security (such as a CDO tranche written against the
1− ρ
( ) (
1 −1
)
2
f ( x; p, ρ) = exp  − 1 − ρN −1 ( x ) − N −1 ( p ) + N (x)  portfolio) that pays at time T an amount C(L) contingent on the portfolio
ρ  2ρ 2 
loss is valued at:
which is unimodal with the mode at: V = e − rT E * C ( L )
 1 − ρ −1 
Lmode = N  N ( p ) where the expectation is taken with respect to the distribution (7). For in-
 1 − 2ρ  stance, a default protection for losses in excess of L0 is priced at:
when ρ < ½, monotone when ρ = ½ and U-shaped when ρ > ½. This den-
sity is shown in figure 1 for p = 0.02, ρ = 0.1. The mean of the distribution ( ( ( )
V = e − rT E * ( L − L0 )+  = e − rT p* − N 2 N −1 p* , N −1 ( L0 ) , 1 − ρ ))
is E(L) = p and the variance is:
(
s2 = Var L = N 2 N −1 ( p ) , N −1 ( p ) ,ρ − p2 ) The portfolio market value
So far, we have discussed the loss due to loan defaults. Now suppose that
where N2 is the bivariate cumulative normal distribution function. The in- the maturity date T of the loan is past the date H for which the portfolio
verse of this distribution, that is, the α-percentile value of L, is given by: value is considered (the horizon date). If the credit quality of a borrower
Lα = F (α;1 − p,1 − ρ)
deteriorates, the value of the loan will decline, resulting in a loss (this is
often referred to as the loss due to ‘credit migration’). We will investigate
The portfolio loss distribution is highly skewed and leptokurtic. Table A the distribution of the loss resulting from changes in the marked-to-mar-
lists the values of the α-percentile Lα expressed as the number of standard ket portfolio value.
deviations from the mean, for several values of the parameters. The α-per- The value of the debt at time 0 is the expected present value of the
centiles of the standard normal distribution are shown for comparison. loan payments under the risk-neutral measure:
These values manifest the extreme non-normality of the loss distribu-
tion. Suppose a lender holds a large portfolio of loans to firms whose pair-
(
D = e − rT 1 − Gp* )
wise asset correlation is ρ = 0.4 and whose probability of default is p = where G is the loss-given default and p* is the risk-neutral probability of
0.01. The portfolio expected loss is E(L) = 0.01 and the standard devia- default. At time H, the value of the loan is:
tion is s = 0.0277. If the lender wishes to hold the probability of default   log B − log A ( H ) − r (T − H ) + 1 σ 2 (T − H )  
D (H ) = e (
−r T − H )
on his notes at 1 – α = 0.001, he will need enough capital to cover 11.0  1 − GN  2

  σ T−H  
times the portfolio standard deviation. If the loss distribution were normal,
3.1 times the standard deviation would suffice. Define the loan loss Li at time H as the difference between the risk-free
value and the market value of the loan at H:
The risk-neutral distribution
L =e (
−r T − H )
The portfolio loss distribution given by equation (4) is the actual probability i −D H ( )
distribution. This is the distribution from which to calculate the probability This definition of loss is chosen purely for convenience. If the loss is de-
of a loss of a certain magnitude for the purposes of determining the neces- fined in a different way (for instance, as the difference between the ac-
sary capital or of calculating VAR. This is also the distribution to be used in crued value and the market value), it will only result in a shift of the portfolio
structuring CDOs, that is, in calculating the probability of loss and the ex- loss distribution by a location parameter.
pected loss for a given tranche. For the purposes of pricing the tranches, how- The loss on the i-th loan can be written as:
ever, it is necessary to use the risk-neutral probability distribution. The  T H 
Li = aN  b − Xi
T − H 
risk-neutral distribution is calculated in the same way as above, except that
the default probabilities are evaluated under the risk-neutral measure P *:  T−H
 log B − log A − rT + 1 σ 2T  where:
p* = P*  A (T ) < B  = N  2
 T−H
a = Ge (
−r T − H )
 σ T  , b = N −1 ( p ) + λρM
T
where r is the risk-free rate. The risk-neutral probability is related to the
actual probability of default by the equation: and the standard normal variables Xi defined over the horizon H by:
p =N N
*
( −1
( p) + λρM T ) (6) log Ai ( H ) = log Ai + µ i H − 21 σ i2 H + σ i H Xi
where ρM is the correlation of the firm asset value with the market and are subject to equation (2).

WWW.RISK.NET ● DECEMBER 2002 RISK 161


Cutting edge l Credit portfolio models

Let L be the market value loss at time H of a loan portfolio with weights
wi. The conditional mean of Li given Y can be calculated as: 1. Portfolio loss distribution (p = 0.02, ρ = 0.1)
 ρH 
µ (Y ) = E ( Li Y ) = aN  b
T
−Y
 T − ρH T − ρH 
The losses conditional on the factor Y are independent, and therefore the
portfolio loss L conditional on Y converges to its mean value E(LY) =
µ(Y) as Σw2i → ∞. The limiting distribution of L is then:
x ρH 
P [ L ≤ x ] = P µ (Y ) ≤ x  = F  ; N (b ) , (8)
a T 
We see that the limiting distribution of the portfolio loss is of the same
type (5) whether the loss is defined as the decline in the market value or 0 0.02 0.04 0.06 0.08 0.10 0.12
the realised loss at maturity. In fact, the results of the section on the distrib- Portfolio loss
ution of loss due to default are just a special case of this section for T = H.
The risk-neutral distribution for the loss due to market value change is
given by: 2. Simulated loss distribution for an actual
x ρH  portfolio
P* [ L ≤ x ] = F  ; p* , (9)
a T 

1 – cumulative probability
1
Adjustment for granularity
Equation (8) relies on the convergence of the portfolio loss L given Y to its
0.1
mean value µ(Y), which means that the conditional variance Var(L|Y) → 0.
When the portfolio is not sufficiently large for the law of large numbers to
0.01
take hold, we need to take into account the non-zero value of Var(L|Y).
Consider a portfolio of uniform credits with weights w1, w2, ... , wn and put:
0.001
n
δ=∑ wi2
i =1 0.0001
0 2 4 6 8 10
The conditional variance of the portfolio loss L given Y is: Portfolio loss (%)
 
Var ( L Y ) = δa 2  N 2  U ,U ,
(1 − ρ) H  − N 2 U 
( )
  T − ρH   Summary
where: We have shown that the distribution of the loan portfolio loss converges,
T ρH with increasing portfolio size, to the limiting type given by equation (5).
U =b −Y It means that this distribution can be used to represent the loan loss be-
T − ρH T − ρH
haviour of large portfolios. The loan loss can be a realised loss on loans
The unconditional mean and variance of the portfolio loss are E(L) = aN(b) maturing before the horizon date, or a market value deficiency on loans
and: whose term is longer than the horizon period.
The limiting probability distribution of portfolio losses has been derived
Var L = E Var ( L Y ) + Var  E ( L Y ) under the assumption that all loans in the portfolio have the same maturi-
 H  ρH  (10) ty, the same probability of default and the same pair-wise correlation of the
= δa 2 N 2  b, b,  + (1 − δ ) a 2 N 2  b, b, − a 2 N 2 (b )
 T   T  borrower assets. Curiously, however, computer simulations show that the
family (5) appears to provide a reasonably good fit to the tail of the loss
Taking the first two terms in the tetrachoric expansion of the bivariate nor- distribution for more general portfolios. To illustrate this point, figure 2 gives
mal distribution function N2(x, x, ρ) = N2(x) + ρn2(x), where n is the nor- the results of Monte Carlo simulations of an actual bank portfolio. The port-
mal density function, we have approximately: folio consisted of 479 loans in amounts ranging from 0.0002% to 8.7%, with
H ρH δ = 0.039. The maturities ranged from six months to six years and the de-
Var ( L ) = δa 2 n2 (b ) + (1 − δ ) a 2 n2 (b ) fault probabilities from 0.0002 to 0.064. The loss-given default averaged
T T
0.54. The asset returns were generated with 14 common factors. The plot
 
= a 2 N 2  b, b, (ρ + δ (1 − ρ))  − a 2 N 2 (b )
H
shows the simulated cumulative distribution function of the loss in one year
 T (dots) and the fitted limiting distribution function (solid line). ■
Approximating the loan loss distribution by the distribution (5) with the
same mean and variance, we get: Oldrich Alfons Vasicek is managing director at Moody’s KMV. He would
x H like to thank Yim Lee for the computer simulations used for this article.
P [ L ≤ x ] = F  ; N (b ) , (ρ + δ (1 − ρ))  (11) e-mail: oldrich.vasicek@kmv.com
a T
This expression is in fact exact for both extremes n → ∞, δ = 0 and n = 1, REFERENCES
δ = 1. Pykhtin M and A Dev, 2002 KMV Corporation, available at
Equation (11) provides an adjustment for the ‘granularity’ of the port- Credit risk in asset securitisations: an www.kmv.com
analytical model Vasicek O, 1991
folio. In particular, the finite portfolio adjustment to the distribution of the Risk May, pages S16–S20 Limiting loan loss probability distribution
gross loss at the maturity date is obtained by putting H = T, a = 1 to yield: Vasicek O, 1987 KMV Corporation, available at
P [ L ≤ x ] = F ( x; p,ρ + δ (1 − ρ)) (12) Probability of loss on loan portfolio www.kmv.com

162 RISK DECEMBER 2002 ● WWW.RISK.NET

You might also like