Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 41

CAS EC 387 Introduction to Health Economics

L5: Empirical demand studies

Department of Economics

Spring 2020

Boston University () Demand for Health Care Spring 2020 1 / 41


Demand for Care with Insurance Coverage

Insurance terms
Premium

Coinsurance

Deductible

Co-payment

Purpose is to counteract moral hazard by making consumes aware of


the cost

Boston University () Demand for Health Care Spring 2020 2 / 41


Coinsurance

Coinsurance makes demand more inelastic – demand curve rotates


clockwise

Demand w/o insurance is Q0 at price P0 . Coinsurance rate c < 1


makes demand higher at every price level P0 : consumer pays cP0 and
demands Q1

Extra cost is P0 (Q1 Q0 )

Welfare gains and losses – individual does not internalize full cost

Insurance subsidizes care covered by insurance

Boston University () Demand for Health Care Spring 2020 3 / 41


Deductible

Indemnity insurance – …xed reimbursement pre-established in contract


(e.g., hospital stays)

Payment limit (compare deductible)

Most insurance policies are mixed – a deductible, co-payment, and


indemnity plan

Consumer payment ceilings like stop loss and the doughnut hole

Boston University () Demand for Health Care Spring 2020 4 / 41


Empirical Studies

Observational data

Data from randomized control trials (RCTs)

Natural experiments and …eld experiments

RAND HIE

Extensive literature that estimates various formulations of the


Grossman model

Boston University () Demand for Health Care Spring 2020 5 / 41


Elasticities I

Elasticity
The (point) elasticity between two variables x and y is de…ned:

∆y x
εy ,x =
∆x y

Measures responsiveness of y to x

Demand elasticity
Let xi be demand for good i, let pi be price of good i, and let pj be
the price of a good j. Then the demand elasticity is:

∆xi (pi , pj ) xi (pi , pj )


εij =
∆pj pj

Boston University () Demand for Health Care Spring 2020 6 / 41


Elasticities II

If i = j, εij is the own-price elasticity. If i 6= j, εij is the cross-price


elasticity

A good is elastic if jεij j > 1 and inelastic if jεij j < 1

Income elasticity
Let xi be demand for good i and let w be wealth. Then the income
elasticity is:
∆xi (p, w ) w
ηi =
∆w xi (p, w )
Ordinary goods and inferior goods

If η i < 1, i is a necessary good, if η i > 1, i is a luxury good

Boston University () Demand for Health Care Spring 2020 7 / 41


Regression Analysis I
Multiple regression analysis
Standard technique to estimate correlation between observables

Given a set of assumptions, ordinary least squares (OLS) are


e¢ cient for this purpose

Suppose we want to estimate a demand function using n observations


of quantities Q and prices P

A formal relationship is:

Qi = β0 + β1 Pi + εi for i = 1, ..., n

Here, β = ( β0 , β1 ) are coe¢ cients, and ε is an error term accounting


for the stochastic relationship between Q and P

Boston University () Demand for Health Care Spring 2020 8 / 41


Regression Analysis II
OLS is a procedure to …nd the values of the coe¢ cients β that best
match the observed data

The OLS estimator minimizes the sum of the squared errors – it is the
best (linear) …t to the data

Using the demand data, suppose we obtain the regression equation:

Q = 117.12 2.208P

We can test hypotheses about the coe¢ cients:

H0 : β1 < 0 and HA = 0

Note that regression says nothing about causation between variables,


only correlation

Boston University () Demand for Health Care Spring 2020 9 / 41


Regression Analysis III

Our demand regression does not say that a higher price causes or
results in lower demand – only that they move in opposite directions

To capture causal e¤ects we have to look elsewhere (e.g., economic


theory)

Is the simple demand model good? How can it be improved?

Suppose more than one dependent variable – multiple regression:

Qi = β0 + β1 Pi + β2 INCi + β3 FAMi + εi

Major advantage of the regression framework - allows us to control


for various e¤ects (holding them constant)

Boston University () Demand for Health Care Spring 2020 10 / 41


Regression Analysis IV

Interpretation of coe¢ cients

A dummy variable D (an indicator variable) only takes a few values:


D 2 f0, 1, 2, .., n g

Useful when analyzing categorical data – such as gender and ethnicity

Specify a base case against which all other classes are compared

Note that some variables can modeled both as continuous or discrete


(e.g., income, age, or education)

Boston University () Demand for Health Care Spring 2020 11 / 41


Regression Analysis V

Example cholesterol levels


Suppose that we hypothesize that gender, age and income matters:

Ci = β0 + β1 FEMi + β2 AGEi + β3 MINCi + β4 HINCi + εi

Here FEM, MINC , and HINC are discrete variables and AGE is
continuous

The base-case is man with low income – predicted cholesterol level is:

C = β0 + β2 AGE

Similarly, the predicted level for a woman with high income is:

C = β0 + β1 + β2 AGE + β4

Boston University () Demand for Health Care Spring 2020 12 / 41


Regression Analysis VI

What could be a reasonable hypothesis about β4 ?

Note that we can gain information by categorizing a continuous


variable

In OLS, the error is assumed uncorrelated with the regressors

Boston University () Demand for Health Care Spring 2020 13 / 41


Regression Analysis VII

In practice, this assumption is often not satis…ed:


omitted variables (e.g., time preference, dynamics)
misspeci…cation (functional forms)
measurement errors (abound in health studies)
selection bias (is the sample representative?)
jointly determined variables (e.g., education and health investment)

These lead to correlation between the regressors and the error – biased
estimates of the regression coe¢ cients (dynamic considerations)

Often di¢ cult to control for these factors

Boston University () Demand for Health Care Spring 2020 14 / 41


The RAND HIE I

RAND Health Insurance Experiment


Research issues:
how does cost sharing a¤ect demand for personal health care services?
how does cost sharing a¤ect demand for particular services, e.g.,
hospital care, dental services?
does use of personal health care services improve health?
how does a change from fee-for-service payment to capitation a¤ect
demand for personal health care services?

Study design
enrolled 2, 000 non-elderly (< 63) families for 3 5 years

Boston University () Demand for Health Care Spring 2020 15 / 41


The RAND HIE II

families randomly assigned to 1 of 14 insurance plans di¤ering in cost


sharing rates and in maximum dollar expenditures per year (MDE or
stop loss)
at enrollment, families exchanged their existing health insurance policy
for HIE plan— held harmless for medical expenditure higher than they
would have experienced if they had not enrolled in HIE
some participants randomly assigned to capitation plan
participation in HIE voluntary for families

How capitation a¤ect patient and provider incentives?

HIE assigned 1, 149 persons who had been enrolled in fee-for-service


health plans to capitated plan in Seattle WA, also 773 persons who
had been enrolled in this health plan selected as controls

Boston University () Demand for Health Care Spring 2020 16 / 41


RHIE Results I

Boston University () Demand for Health Care Spring 2020 17 / 41


RHIE Results II

Boston University () Demand for Health Care Spring 2020 18 / 41


Demand Curve I

Boston University () Demand for Health Care Spring 2020 19 / 41


Main Conclusions (Gruber) I

The co-insurance rate matters for medical utilization and expenditures

Co-insurance e¤ects are relatively constant across services

Higher co-insurance rates don’t have adverse health consequences for


the average person

Di¤erential e¤ects on the sick and poor

For the typical poor person no evidence that the reduction in


utilization had an adverse impact on health

Boston University () Demand for Health Care Spring 2020 20 / 41


Main Conclusions (Gruber) II

For 94 percent of persons in HIE, not with low income and not in poor
health at baseline, having health insurance coverage had no e¤ect on
health - provocative result, or is this misleading or even wrong?

In sum: higher co-insurance rates, with an out-of-pocket limit, can


signicantly reduce health care use without sacricing health outcomes
for the typical person

What are some limitations of the RAND study?

How relevant are the results today?

Boston University () Demand for Health Care Spring 2020 21 / 41


Kenkel (1995) I

Should you eat breakfast?


Starting point: the Alameda Seven – health practices:
eat breakfast
maintain proper weight
regular physical exercise
sleep 7-8 hours
no smoking
no (or moderate) alcohol consumption
no eating between meals

Additive e¤ects

Boston University () Demand for Health Care Spring 2020 22 / 41


Kenkel (1995) II

Follow up studies - decreasing mortality, better future health

Purpose: study the e¤ects of lifestyle factors on the production of


health, using data from the 1985 US NHIS

Regression framework used to estimate the e¤ects of the


determinants of the health capital

Dependent variable: Self-reported health (1-5 scale), weight, blood


pressure

Independent variables: lifestyle, age, ethnicity, chronic conditions,


schooling

Boston University () Demand for Health Care Spring 2020 23 / 41


Kenkel (1995) III

Individuals are assumed to choose lifestyle based on perceived health


e¤ects and (other) utility e¤ects subject to …nancial and time budget
constraints

Weight, smoking, heavy drinking, insu¢ cient sleep, stress, chronic


condition, age negatively correlated with health stock

Moderate drinking, exercise, schooling positively correlated with


health stock

Behavior/Age translation: e.g., smoking 20 cigs/day equivalent to


13.3 age increase, exercise 150 min/week, 2.2 decrease in age

Boston University () Demand for Health Care Spring 2020 24 / 41


Gerdtham and Johannesson (1995) I

Grossman model
Dependent variable: self - reported health status HS (VAS
categorical), time trade-o¤ (QALYs)

Independent variables: Input prices P, income Y , education E , and a


variable summarizing health depreciation A

Data: 2, 200 adults from the Swedish population

Regression model:

HSt = β0 + β1 Pt + β2 Yt + β3 Et + β4 At + εt

Prices of medical care and time preference excluded in estimation

Boston University () Demand for Health Care Spring 2020 25 / 41


Gerdtham and Johannesson (1995) II

Main results
demand for health and health status increase with income and
education
being obese (BMI > 30), older, male, smoker, and single negatively
correlated with health stock
alcohol positive e¤ect on health
exercise increases health stock

Causality and endogeneity problems give biased estimates – lack of


good instruments

Overall results con…rm predictions from Grossman model

Boston University () Demand for Health Care Spring 2020 26 / 41


Wagsta¤ (1993)
Dynamic Grossman model
Starting point: few dynamic empirical studies – hence, failure to
account for inherent dynamic element in health investment process

Dynamic model more consistent with theory and the data

Panel data where 1, 700 Danish adults followed over 12 months

Dependent var: health indicators FUNLIM, PAH, SAH

Independent vars: FAMINC, school, gender, age, medical use

Results: largely conform with theory: split sample age (> 41):
income and education both positively correlated with health demand,
gender had no e¤ect

Concludes that empirical support for Grossman’s model stems much


from allowing lags in health stock adjustments
Boston University () Demand for Health Care Spring 2020 27 / 41
Sickles and Yazbeck (1998)
Dynamic Grossman model
US data for > 65 year old males

Individuals maximize lifetime expected utility subject to time and


budget constraints and a health production function – incorporates
formal modeling of uncertainty

Panel data. Dep var: weighted health status measures (mobility,


physical and social mobility)

Indep vars: socio economic factors (profession, education) family


status (widow, divorced), ethnicity

Results - health care inputs and health time improve health, health
demand vary with socio-economic factors according to Grossman
prediction - study shows substantial role for dynamics in the health
production
Boston University () Demand for Health Care Spring 2020 28 / 41
Strauss et al (1993)

International comparison
Focus on Jamaica, also includes Bangladesh, Malaysia, and US –
di¤erent cultural and economic environments

Dependent vars: reported health status/mobility, independent var:


depreciation vars, education, gender, income

Findings:
women report signi…cantly more health problem than men, despite
greater longevity
higher education lowers probability of health problems
it matters where you live (quality/accessibility?)
some evidence that income is positively correlated with health status

Boston University () Demand for Health Care Spring 2020 29 / 41


Mwabu et al (1993)
Demand for health care in Kenya
Conventional wisdom: medical care in Africa is of poor quality !
underutilization of health care
Cross section data w information on age, education, income, and
medical/physical attributes
Treatment fees, traveling time, measure of care quality (diagnostic
equipment, drug supply)
Four channels of care: government, missions, private, and traditional
Results
drug shortage can be both positively and negatively correlated with
demand for medical care
increasing income leads to increased substitution from informal to
formal care, especially private and mission care
private and mission care are important care givers in rural areas for
wealthier individuals Demand for Health Care
Boston University () Spring 2020 30 / 41
Health and Socioeconomic Status I

The origin of the health gradient (Case et al, 2002)


How do adult health and income co-vary?

Hypothesis: the family long-run income is an important determinant


of children’s health

Parents’income leads to better food, medical care, safer environment.


Also, children inherit biological factors and behavior

Highlights importance of time dependence and health stock

Traces causality from family income to child health

Boston University () Demand for Health Care Spring 2020 31 / 41


Health and Socioeconomic Status II

The elderly (Adams et al, 2003)


Rich panel data set on US elderly (> 70)

Focus on older population mitigates some income issues

SES and health vary more for mental health/chronic conditions rather
than acute/sudden health problems (Medicare)

Study replicated on UK and Swedish data with similar results

Conclusion: cannot reject hypothesis of no causality from SES to


health

Boston University () Demand for Health Care Spring 2020 32 / 41


Health and Socioeconomic Status III

Birthweight as health indicator (Meara, 2001)


Health: birth weight, SES: income and education

Control vars:
maternal health habits (smoking, drinking, crack use, prenatal care
recipient)
demographics (marital status)
access (income, education, insurance status, distance to provider)
maternal health status (age, BMI, birth-order)

Boston University () Demand for Health Care Spring 2020 33 / 41


Health and Socioeconomic Status IV

Findings:
higher education leads to improved health behavior, and improved
health
however, much of the mechanism between SES and health seems to go
through a third variable

Schooling in Africa (Schultz, 1999)


Africa has the lowest levels of health and education in the world

Health and SES positively correlated


one year of extra schooling leads to 5 10% reduction in child
mortality
poor health is a large constraint on productivity (Fogel)

Boston University () Demand for Health Care Spring 2020 34 / 41


Health and Socioeconomic Status V

returns to education and discount factors (gender di¤erences)

Important to consider the dynamic and long-run interaction between


SES and health

Understanding the causality is important for policy – where to invest


the marginal dollar

Focus on primary education

Boston University () Demand for Health Care Spring 2020 35 / 41


Other Determinants of Health Care Demand I

Time cost
Recall the consumer’s equilibrium choice between health care and
other goods:
price and income changes a¤ect demand
elasticities

State dependent preferences – demand may depend on health status

Time will a¤ect demand like price or income changes

Example: a patient goes to a physician


visit takes 10 minutes and costs $25
traveling takes 30 minutes and costs $5

Boston University () Demand for Health Care Spring 2020 36 / 41


Other Determinants of Health Care Demand II

waiting time is 20 minutes

If patient’s value of time is $10/hour , the real cost is


$25 + $5 + $10 = $40

If time cost changes, demand for health care may change even if
health care price remains constant

If the opportunity cost of time is higher for the rich than the poor,
poor people are willing to wait (or travel) longer

Time costs are not zero: expanding capacity may increase health care
visits also among poor (and/or those with subsidized care)

Boston University () Demand for Health Care Spring 2020 37 / 41


Other Determinants of Health Care Demand III

In countries with nationalized care, time price is an important


rationing device (European countries)

Acton: own time-price elasticity is -0.96 for outpatient visits and


–0.25 for physician visits – time matters

Boston University () Demand for Health Care Spring 2020 38 / 41


Demand and Income Elasticities for Health Care I

Demand elasticities
Price more complicated – elasticity depends on insurance

Di¤erent samples – regional and temporal variations

Price elasticity typically below unity


physicians and hospitals: 0.35 1.5 (Rosett and Huang)
all expenditures: 0.17 0.22 (Manning et al)
physicians 0.35 (good health) 0.16 (poor health) (Wedig)
hospital studies typically report elasticities from 0.14 0.63

Firm-speci…c elasticities larger: 2.80 5.07 for physician services, and


0.74 1.1 for hospitals

Boston University () Demand for Health Care Spring 2020 39 / 41


Demand and Income Elasticities for Health Care II

Income elasticities
Is health care a necessity or a luxury?

Studies suggest that health care is a necessity (except dental services)

all expenditures: 0.25 0.45 (R&H 1973), 1.2 (Silver 1970)


hospital: 0.02 0.04 (admissions, N&P 76)
physician services: 0.01 0.04 (visits, N&P), 0.22 0.85
(expenditures, A&B 70, Silver)
dental services high: 2.40 3.20 (expenditures, Silver)

Boston University () Demand for Health Care Spring 2020 40 / 41


Demand and Income Elasticities for Health Care III

Newhouse (1977) cross country study: 1.15 - 1.31 health care is a


luxury

Result supported also in later studies during 90s

Not necessarily inconsistent with individual income elasticities below


unity and aggregate income elasticities above unity

Boston University () Demand for Health Care Spring 2020 41 / 41

You might also like