Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 14

Journal of International Business Studies (2011) 42, 958–970

& 2011 Academy of International Business All rights reserved 0047-2506


www.jibs.net

RESEARCH NOTE

Rationality vs ignorance: The role of MNE


headquarters in subsidiaries’ innovation
processes

Francesco Ciabuschi1, Abstract


Mats Forsgren1 and Innovation processes in multinational enterprises (MNE) are largely context
specific, and carried out at the subsidiary level. Therefore, corporate head-
Oscar Martı́n Martı́n1,2 quarters (HQ) involvement in these processes becomes a major issue. A typical
1
assumption in international business (IB) theory is that HQ, based on its own
Department of Business Studies, knowledge, makes rational choices about its own involvement. However,
Uppsala University, Uppsala, Sweden;
2 according to some studies, HQ involvement can be assumed to be less rational,
Department of Business Administration,
Public University of Navarre, Pamplona, Spain in the sense that it reflects not HQ knowledge but the normative expectations
associated with the role of HQ as top manager. The purpose of this paper is to
Correspondence: contrast these two perspectives by exploring their implications regarding the
M Forsgren, Department of Business relationship between HQ knowledge about and HQ involvement in innovation
Studies, Uppsala University, Box 513, processes at the subsidiary level, and regarding the impact of this potential
SE-751 20 Uppsala, Sweden. involvement on innovation processes performance. The analysis results in six
Tel: þ 46-18-471 13 84; propositions and an illustrative case. Our contribution to IB research is primarily
Fax: þ 46-18-471 68 10;
theoretical: we bring to the scene an alternative approach – the sheer ignorance
Email: mats.forsgren@fek.uu.se
perspective – with the potential to explain the behavior of key actors in the
MNE. We argue, however, that the theoretical conflict between the two
perspectives should be addressed by empirical research. We conclude with
suggestions for the directions such research might take.
Journal of International Business Studies (2011) 42, 958–970. doi:10.1057/jibs.2011.24

Keywords: bounded rationality; sheer ignorance; headquarters; subsidiary; innovation


processes; performance

INTRODUCTION
It has been recognized that innovation processes in multinational
enterprises (MNEs) are largely context-specific, local activities
carried out at the subsidiary level (e.g., Andersson, Forsgren, &
Holm, 2007; Asakawa, 2001; Birkinshaw & Hood, 1998; Doz &
Prahalad, 1981; Ghoshal & Bartlett, 1988; Hedlund, 1986; Rugman
& Verbeke, 2001). As a consequence, the ability of corporate
headquarters (HQ) to influence these widely dispersed processes
has become a major issue in contemporary research on MNEs.
What is the role of HQ in these processes? To what extent can it
participate in and play an active role in specific innovation
Received: 18 December 2009
Revised: 3 February 2011
processes? What are the performance implications when it gets
Accepted: 27 March 2011 involved? These questions, which have not yet established answers,
Online publication date: 9 June 2011 warrant further research. In addition, studies aimed at finding the
Rationality vs ignorance Francesco Ciabuschi et al
959

answers have not yet debated the validity of conceptualizing the role of HQ in innovation
alternative perspectives related to the knowledge processes at the subsidiary level. The third situa-
asymmetry between the potential participants in tion, in particular, is scarcely acknowledged in
innovation processes. mainstream international business (IB) manage-
It is probably fair to say that, to date, the role of ment literature. It represents a different perspective
HQ in innovation processes at the subsidiary level on the role of HQ and, as we will argue below,
has not been a major concern in mainstream involves a less straightforward relationship between
theories on MNEs. More often than not, it has knowledge and involvement than under the ration-
explicitly or implicitly been taken for granted that ality perspective. In this paper, we call it the sheer
corporate HQ is able to make rational choices ignorance perspective. In line with this perspective,
concerning its own involvement, and that such we will argue that, in certain specific circumstances,
involvement is conducive to the performance of HQ tends to intervene in subsidiary innovation
innovation processes. Some scholars, however, processes despite its lack of knowledge, rather than
have pointed out that both the ability of HQ to because of its possession of relevant knowledge.
contribute to these processes and the effect of its In light of the above, the purpose of this paper is
intended contribution are far from clear (Barner- to explore the value of the rationality and sheer
Rasmussen, Piekkari, Scott-Kennel, & Welch, 2010; ignorance perspectives in the context of innovation
Birkinshaw, Holm, Thilenius, & Arvidsson, 2000; processes at the subsidiary level. Specifically, we
Ciabuschi, Martı́n Martı́n, & Ståhl, 2010; Collis, focus on the implications of these two perspectives
Young, & Goold, 2007; Denrell, Arvidsson, & Zander, on HQ involvement in subsidiary innovation
2004; Foss, 2002; Goodall & Roberts, 2003; Goold & processes, and the impact this has on innovation
Campbell, 2002; Kristensen & Zeitlin, 2001). processes performance. It should be emphasized
Basically, the discrepancy regarding the potential that the sheer ignorance perspective is not posited
contribution of HQ largely mirrors the different here as “better” or more efficient than the bound-
views of what can be called the HQ “knowledge edly rational one. Our objective is rather to bring to
situation”. Some scholars, from a (more or less the fore a perspective that has been largely neg-
bounded) rational perspective, assume that the lected in IB research, and demonstrate that it may,
behavior of HQ, including the decision to become in some situations, be a more fruitful approach to
directly involved in innovation projects at the understanding the role of HQ in MNE management
subsidiary level, reflects the extent of its relevant processes.
knowledge. In other words, if HQ possesses exten- For the sake of clarity, we provide some basic
sive relevant knowledge about a given situation, it definitions. First, following Collis et al. (2007),
will be in a position to determine the appropriate corporate HQ includes staff functions and executive
level of involvement. This also implies that, with- management with responsibility for, or providing
out relevant knowledge, it will possibly reject the service to, the whole of (or most of) the company,
idea of direct involvement or, if possible, will try to excluding staff employed in divisional HQ. In the
obtain it before becoming involved. remainder of the text, the terms “corporate head-
We argue that the relationship between HQ quarters”, “headquarters” and “top manager” will
knowledge and HQ involvement might be more be used interchangeably. Second, Nelson (1993)
complex. Given that the extent of HQ knowledge defines innovation as the processes by which
may vary, we can assume that firms master and put into practice products and
manufacturing processes that are new to them.
(1) it actually possesses specific knowledge of
These innovation processes within the MNE
crucial importance for a particular innovation
often include the development as well as the
process; or
transfer of innovations between subsidiaries. Finally,
(2) it does not possess such knowledge, but still has
innovation processes performance is conceptua-
a fair understanding of what kind of knowledge
lized in terms of both efficiency and effectiveness.
is required; or
Following Daft (1998), we define efficiency as the
(3) the least desirable position, it not only lacks
amount of resources used to produce a unit of output
relevant knowledge but does not know what
(e.g., time and cost), and effectiveness as the degree
knowledge is required.
to which goals are attained (i.e., to what extent
These three “knowledge situations” have dis- the innovation is actually implemented within the
tinct features that are particularly useful when MNE).

Journal of International Business Studies


Rationality vs ignorance Francesco Ciabuschi et al
960

THE HQ “KNOWLEDGE SITUATION” especially uncertainty in combination with oppor-


IN MNE THEORIES tunism, can be handled by the hierarchy (Buckley
Although the role of HQ in the knowledge-creating & Casson, 1991; Hennart, 1982; Williamson,
process has been brought to the fore by the 1985). Williamson proposes that by structuring the
emerging knowledge economy (Foss, 2002; large, complex firm into essentially self-contained
Goodall & Roberts, 2003), it also reflects a tradi- divisions, and vertically separating strategic and
tional watershed between two fundamental theore- operating activities, the impact of uncertainty
tical perspectives on firms and firm management, and complexity on management decisions is sub-
referred to herein as the rationality perspective and stantially reduced (Williamson, 1971). Therefore,
the sheer ignorance perspective. The first of these is by although part of the TCE logics have been ques-
far the most commonly used in theories on MNE, tioned by Verbeke and Greidanus, suggesting that
and has a long tradition.1 From the writings of opportunism is still an issue as a dimension of
Hymer (1976) to the knowledge-based view of the “bounded reliability” within the MNE (Verbeke &
firm, it is assumed, at least implicitly that HQ Greidanus, 2009), it is fair to say that most writers
to some extent understands and controls value- in the TCE tradition claim that bounded rationality
creating processes within the MNE. HQ is at least is a problem that can be handled by HQ. The
boundedly rational. This perspective has its roots in authority of HQ, in combination with its potential
the Coasian perspective on the firm (Coase, 1937; to structure the organization and the information
Foss, 2002). Other perspectives, closer to business systems in an efficient way, will not only make it
network theory or institutionalization theory, have sufficiently knowledgeable about innovation pro-
questioned this assumption by pointing out that cesses in different parts of the MNE, it will also
HQ suffers from radical uncertainty, in the sense enable it, when appropriate, to intervene in these
that knowledge is much more socially embedded processes. It will at least have a sufficient under-
and is therefore not controlled by anyone in its standing of what it does not know about these
entirety. Such perspectives are, to some measure, processes, and will be able to design its own role
rooted in the “Austrian” school of strategy (Foss, optimally in accordance. It has even been argued
2002; Jacobson, 1992; Kirzner, 1997). We take a that a top manager “may be said to behave in a
closer look at the two fundamental theoretical metarational rather than a boundedly rational
perspectives below. way y His behaviour appears superficially to be
boundedly rational because he makes mistakes,
The Rationality Perspective but these mistakes are calculated in the sense that
In Hymer’s writings, HQ access to knowledge their frequency is set at an optimal level” (Casson,
regarding what is going on in different parts of 1999: 114).
the firm is not of major concern (Hymer, 1976; While TCE addresses uncertainty and problem
Yamin & Forsgren, 2006). Or, as Hymer puts it: “in complexity as the most important dimensions of
the giant corporation of today, managers rule from bounded rationality, contingency theory, especially
top of skyscrapers; on a clear day, they can almost the information-processing view, extends the ana-
see the world” (Cohen, Felton, Liere, & Nkosi, 1979: lysis to explicitly include the problem of informa-
43). His overall assessment was that the center is tion-processing capacity, as well as the problem of
not really challenged by the operational level in time constraints on decision-making (Egelhoff,
terms of knowledge and control. HQ is in this sense 1988, 2010).
close to being “unboundedly rational”. The fact that a lot of information would have to
Later theories on the MNE based on transaction be collected and processed by top managers (and
cost economics (TCE) pay more attention to the this is more necessary when the level of uncertainty
problem of bounded rationality. It has been and problem complexity is higher) forces them to
proposed that top managers’ attempts to be rational decentralize some decisions to the subsidiary level,
are limited by uncertainty, problem complexity, where some of that knowledge is located. The
limited information-processing capacity, time con- transfer of “all” knowledge to HQ could not occur
straints on decision-making, and differences among without creating a serious information overload
members of the organization concerning goals and being highly time consuming. However, the
(e.g., Simon, 1959; Verbeke & Greidanus, 2009). theory is clearly distinct on one point: HQ is able to
Therefore managers are boundedly rational. assess, which relevant information the subsidiary
According to TCE, these managerial constraints, possesses that it does not possess itself. On the basis

Journal of International Business Studies


Rationality vs ignorance Francesco Ciabuschi et al
961

of this knowledge about what it does not know, HQ corresponding elements of the employees”. Because
is supposed to be able to design efficient structures, of differences in employees’ knowledge, HQ author-
decision rules and control systems. The environ- ity is a crucial mechanism for the handling of
ment may be uncertain and complex, and the problems. In the knowledge-based view, the ability
ability to process information may be limited, but to combine heterogeneous pieces of knowledge by
top managers are in any case able to assess what is executing authority from above, rather than econ-
required from them in terms of their own role in omizing on opportunism, is the main reason why
the innovation processes at the subsidiary level. firms exist (Conner & Prahalad, 1996).
This conclusion is also valid for the so-called “MNE In Kogut and Zander’s version of the evolutionary
as a differentiated network approach”, which is theory, the MNE is first and foremost a social
basically the information-processing view comple- community. This is the main reason why knowl-
mented by the idea of “shared values” (Ghoshal & edge can be combined and transferred more
Nohria, 1997). The concept of shared values is effectively within the firm than between firms
mostly treated as another, more subtle, control (Kogut & Zander, 1993). As a result, most of the
mechanism at the disposal of top managers. problems typically associated with bounded ration-
So, although the problem of bounded rationality ality are avoided, because units/individuals are not
at HQ level receives more extensive treatment in only supposed to know each other’s competences
the contingency theory than in TCE, the emphasis but also have the ability and willingness to share
is more on rationality than on bounded rationality. them. In this sense, Kogut and Zander view MNEs
Even though access to information, information- as having a characteristic of “metarationality”,
processing capacity, and time constraints are recog- albeit in a general sense rather than directly in
nized as serious problems, this does not seem to association with HQ or any other unit.
have any profound consequences for top managers’ Overall, the approaches discussed above are
possibility to exert satisfactory control. The per- founded on the assumed rationality of HQ in
spective assumes, at least implicitly that HQ is MNEs, although with certain constraints. HQ may
informed of the performance implications of alter- or may not possess specific knowledge of crucial
native innovation processes at least as well as, and importance for a particular innovation process, but
presumably better than, the subsidiaries (Foss, it does have a reasonable understanding of what
2002). kind of knowledge it lacks. Let us now turn to
Papers written from the knowledge-based or approaches that take a different outlook on this
dynamic capability perspective (e.g., Barney, 1991; matter.
Birkinshaw & Hood, 1998; Conner & Prahalad,
1996; Grant, 1996; Kogut & Zander, 1992, 1993;
Spender, 1994) see the HQ “knowledge situation” as The Sheer Ignorance Perspective
being more complicated than suggested in the Although the rationality perspective has dominated
theories discussed above. Knowledge is not only the writings on MNEs, some IB theories seem to be
an existing resource ready for use; it is also the more in line with an alternative perspective on the
outcome of complex processes within the MNE. In HQ knowledge situation: the sheer ignorance per-
other words, the MNE is a repository of embedded spective. This perspective takes into considera-
knowledge (Verbeke, 2003), and causal ambiguity tion the fact that firms are basically distributed
clouds the knowledge on which a firm bases its knowledge systems: they are decentralized systems,
capability (Barney, 1991). The role of HQ in value- lacking an overseeing “mind” (Mintzberg, 1990;
creating processes is therefore also more ambigu- Tsoukas, 1996). This idea, which is more in line
ous, although most of the literature in this tradition with Hayek than with Coase, conceives economics
seems to claim that HQ exercises some form of as “a problem of the utilization of knowledge not
control over these processes. In some studies, the given to anyone in its totality” (Hayek, 1945: 520).
possibility of HQ executing authority over knowl- Such a view avoids what Hayek called the “synoptic
edge-creating processes is in fact a necessary condi- delusion” – that is, the assumption that knowledge
tion for the knowledge-based firm. Conner and can be surveyed by a single mind. It has its corollary
Prahalad (1996: 480), for instance, claim that the in the “Austrian” school of strategy, which main-
firm is created as a result of the fact that “the tains that an enormous amount of ignorance stands
managers’ understanding (present and future) is in the way of coordinating economic decisions and
believed to be of superior value compared with actions (Jacobson, 1992; Kirzner, 1997).

Journal of International Business Studies


Rationality vs ignorance Francesco Ciabuschi et al
962

Examples of IB theories more in line with this turn, implies that a manager’s understanding
perspective are the business network theory (e.g., resides, first and foremost, in the practices in which
Andersson et al., 2007; Forsgren, Holm, & Johanson, he or she participates (Tsoukas, 1996). Third,
2005; Garcia-Pont, Canales, & Noboa, 2009) and knowledge is not only individualistic but also
MNE theories based on institutionalization theory collective (Weick & Roberts, 1993). It is shared by
(e.g., Björkman, 2006; Ferner, Almond, & Colling, many in a complex system, which means that it is
2005; Ghoshal & Westney, 1993; Kostova, 1999; known in its entirety by no one, although portions
Morgan & Whitley, 2003; Rosenzweig & Singh, of it are known differently by all (Tsoukas, 1996).
1991). A cornerstone in business network theory is Fourth, knowledge as a context-specific and action-
that MNE subsidiaries are highly embedded in their oriented phenomenon also implies that managers
local business networks, which makes the MNE not only have incomplete knowledge, but, more
extremely “distributed” when it comes to knowl- fundamentally, do not know what they need to
edge and control. HQ is always an outsider to know. No single mind can specify in advance what
these business networks, with limited possibility to kind of practical knowledge is going to be relevant,
understand, let alone control, processes at the or when, or where (Tsoukas, 1996). In this sense,
subsidiary level. There is no such thing as a “master MNEs lack a cognitive equivalent of a “control
mind” in the embedded MNE. HQ is seen rather as room” (Stacey, 1995).
one player among others in the contest to influence To summarize, in the sheer ignorance perspective,
strategic behavior within the MNE (Forsgren et al., HQ is likely to be “groping in the darkness” when it
2005). comes to managing the innovation processes at the
Although the institutionalism used in IB research subsidiary level, and even when designing its own
is characterized by a diverse set of approaches role in these processes.
rather than one distinctive MNE model (Barner-
Rasmussen et al., 2010), there are some common THE IMPACT OF HQ INVOLVEMENT ON THE
characteristics. One is that the MNE is portrayed as PERFORMANCE OF INNOVATION PROCESSES
a loosely coupled organization, owing to the AT THE SUBSIDIARY LEVEL
different institutional worlds the MNE subsidiaries We argue that when it comes to HQ involvement in
inhabit. Local isomorphism (Westney, 1993), orga- innovation processes at the subsidiary level (in
nizational distance (Goodall & Roberts, 2003; terms of both the development and the transfer of
Kostova & Zaheer, 1999) and local rationalities innovation) and its impact on the performance of
(Morgan & Whitley, 2003) are crucial dimensions of these processes, the two knowledge situations and
the institutional perspective. To a large extent, perspectives lead to different predictions. Given the
therefore, the MNE is seen as a “contested social fact that HQ knowledge of a certain innovation
space” (Morgan & Kristensen, 2006), in which HQ process can vary considerably (depending, among
action suffers not only from lack of knowledge but other things, on contextual factors, such as the
also from lack of legitimacy in relation to the MNE degree of innovation novelty), the rationality
subsidiaries. This perspective differs radically from perspective holds HQ involvement to be based
those we have labeled “rational”, both in terms of on a realistic understanding of its own expertise
the relationship between the environment and the (or lack thereof). The sheer ignorance perspective,
MNE, and in terms of the role played by HQ. It has in contrast, implies that HQ not only suffers from
been suggested that HQ is more of an “absentee a lack of knowledge about a specific innovation
landlord” than a “managerial apex” (Barner- process at the subsidiary level, but also lacks a
Rasmussen et al., 2010; Kristensen & Zeitlin, 2001). genuine possibility to assess its own level of
The proposition that MNEs are distributed knowl- knowledge. Therefore it is unable to make a rational
edge systems, in the strong sense, contains several decision regarding the extent of its possible inter-
interrelated sub-themes. First, knowledge is context vention. If HQ decides to intervene, it may be
specific and action oriented (Giddens, 1984; Weick counterproductive if based on false premises in
& Roberts, 1993). Consequently, it is difficult to terms of the expertise it is able to contribute.
separate knowledge as a resource from the local In the following subsections, we discuss the
context in which knowledge-related activities are relationships between HQ knowledge of innovation
carried out. Second, the fact that knowledge is processes at the subsidiary level, HQ involvement
action oriented implies that activities not only use in these processes, and innovation processes per-
knowledge but also produce knowledge. This, in formance. We also present some considerations

Journal of International Business Studies


Rationality vs ignorance Francesco Ciabuschi et al
963

regarding the influence of the degree of innovation innovation process. Among the various potential
novelty on the relationship between HQ involve- factors, the literature has often reported innovation
ment and innovation processes performance. novelty as one of the most critical (Anderson &
Through six different propositions concerning these Tushman, 1990). It reflects the disruptiveness of
relationships, we claim that the reasoning behind the innovation: that is, the degree to which it
the two perspectives leads to different predictions. changes existing skills, products and processes. The
distinction between incremental and radical inno-
Applying the Rationality Perspective vations is commonly associated with the novelty
Under the rationality perspective, HQ is assumed to of the innovation (Garcia & Calantone, 2002).
have the ability to assess the character of its There is no consensus regarding exactly what
knowledge and lack of knowledge and, conse- constitutes a radical innovation, but it is always
quently, the ability to determine what role it should modeled as the “degree of discontinuity in
play to make the innovation processes as efficient marketing and/or technological factors” (Garcia &
and effective as possible. If HQ decides to become Calantone, 2002: 112).
actively involved in developing and transferring The more radical and novel the subsidiary’s
innovations at the subsidiary level, it is because it innovation, the stronger the dependency of the
has an accurate understanding of how this will innovation process on a wider range of internal and
enhance the performance of these processes. If, on external expertise. This means it is also more
the other hand, HQ decides to adopt a “hands-off” difficult to know ex ante what expertise is needed
approach, it is because it has judged its own level in this type of innovation as opposed to the
of knowledge to be so limited as to make non- incremental type. This applies to managers at the
intervention the best option. In general, the subsidiary level as well as to those at HQ. However,
rationality perspective leads to the following in line with the rationality perspective, the extent
proposition regarding the relationship between of HQ intervention in such a process is determined
HQ knowledge of and involvement in a specific by the crucial knowledge it possesses, which is not
innovation process: accessible from any other source. Furthermore, it
has been pointed out that support in the form of
Proposition 1: HQ knowledge about a subsidiary active involvement by HQ is particularly important
innovation process is positively related to HQ for radical projects (McDermott & O’Connor,
involvement in the process. 2002). Consequently, given that HQ is able to
evaluate its knowledge situation, the rational
The rationality perspective implies that HQ perspective leads us to propose the following:
expertise matters: that is, its knowledge will con-
tribute positively to the performance of the innova- Proposition 3: The more novel the innovation,
tion processes at the subsidiary level. Furthermore, the more positive the impact of HQ involvement
HQ involvement can guarantee greater innovation on the performance of a subsidiary’s innovation
legitimacy and guidance for the subsidiary, and process.
increase overall commitment to the project
(Birkinshaw, Hood, & Jonsson, 1998; McDermott
& O’Connor, 2002; Quinn, 1985). Through these Applying the Sheer Ignorance Perspective
means, HQ involvement will lead to better results In a situation of sheer ignorance, HQ not only lacks
(Brown & Eisenhardt, 1995; Clark & Fujimoto, knowledge; it also suffers from incomplete infor-
1991; Poppo, 2003). Consequently, and strictly in mation about what knowledge it lacks. Under this
line with the rationality argument, we formulate perspective, HQ is truly an outsider vis-à-vis the
the following proposition: operational context of each subsidiary, fundamen-
tally lacking the means to assess what expertise is
Proposition 2: HQ involvement in a subsidiary needed, and possibly in possession of valuable
innovation process is positively related to the expertise of which it is unaware. Some scholars
performance of the process. have argued that this is what creates the character-
istic tension between center and periphery in
It is reasonable to expect that the impact of HQ MNEs (Regnér, 1999), or actually constitutes a pre-
involvement may also be contingent on other requisite for entrepreneurship at the subsidiary level
factors related to the specific context of a given (Mudambi & Navarra, 2004; Yamin, 2002). Note

Journal of International Business Studies


Rationality vs ignorance Francesco Ciabuschi et al
964

that lack of information on the part of HQ about apparent risk that HQ involvement in the
the subsidiaries’ innovation processes is not the processes, after some time, will prove meaningless,
main problem, since, according to the rationality and wrong and that its legitimacy to intervene will
argument, it can be solved by means of appropriate be partly lost (Kristensen & Zeitlin, 2001). HQ
action. The fundamental problem stems rather involvement, among other things, also increases
from the fact that HQ is often essentially un- project visibility and reporting requirements, thus
aware of what its subsidiaries are doing, or why adding to the cost and extending the timescale for
(Birkinshaw et al., 2000). This in turn implies the implementation of the innovation by the
that HQ has limited capability to determine what subsidiary (e.g., Birkinshaw, Bouquet, & Ambos,
information to collect, let alone to decide what role 2007; Björkman, Barner-Rasmussen, & Li, 2004).
to play in innovation processes. The coordination costs of innovation projects
This problem might not be too serious if HQ in which HQ is actively involved are likely to be
simply adapts its degree of involvement to its level higher, as more people and locations become
of knowledge and capacity, as assumed under the involved. Moreover, direct involvement of HQ, as
rationality perspective. However, the view of the an outsider, will make the innovation project less
MNE as a highly distributed knowledge system also likely to benefit from existing routines, since HQ is
implies that HQ bases its behavior within the unlikely to have as much (if any) specific knowl-
organization on the normative expectations asso- edge of the particular context. In such circum-
ciated with its role as a top manager, past socializa- stances, HQ involvement runs the risk of becoming
tion into this role, and the context of social activity dysfunctional, and thus more likely to destroy
within which the normative expectations and value than to create it (Barner-Rasmussen et al.,
past socialization are activated (Tsoukas, 1996). 2010; Goold & Campbell, 2002). This line of reason-
The normative expectations include demands from ing has some equivalence with the “bounded
different stakeholders, as well as a demand for reliability problem” identified by Verbeke and
leadership and the exercise of authority. The past Greidanus (2009), i.e., that HQ relationships with
socialization of top managers will most probably subsidiaries, apart from opportunism, also include
strengthen these role expectations. Therefore, even changes and scale-backs in HQ commitments vis-à-vis
if HQ suffers from sheer ignorance, it may tend to subsidiaries during the innovation processes (Verbeke
interfere in innovation processes at the subsidiary & Greidanus, 2009). Consequently, from a sheer
level, simply because the organization and its ignorance perspective, we propose the following:
stakeholders expect it to. It may in fact be a
case of HQ acting on signals from subsidiaries. Proposition 5: HQ involvement in a subsidiary
Thus subsidiaries sometimes attract the attention innovation process is negatively related to the
(Ambos, Andersson, & Birkinshaw, 2010; Bouquet, performance of the process.
Morrison, & Birkinshaw, 2009) of (an ignorant) HQ,
which gets involved despite its ignorance, since The reasoning that HQ involvement tends to
it is expected to take action and make decisions. have a detrimental impact on innovation processes
Therefore, contrary to the knowledge situation performance is founded on two assumptions: one
characterized by bounded rationality, in which that there is a wide gap between the reality of the
HQ involvement is the result of a rational choice local context in which the innovation processes are
reflecting its possession of knowledge, in the sheer carried out and HQ knowledge of that context; and,
ignorance scenario its involvement reflects norma- two that HQ lacks the ability to assess the actual
tive expectations associated with its role irrespective width of the gap. The difficulty of the situation,
of its knowledge. Thus the sheer ignorance perspec- however, might depend on the type of innovation.
tive leads to the following proposition: It is reasonable to expect that the more radical
and novel the innovation, the wider and more
Proposition 4: HQ knowledge about a subsidiary difficult it is to assess the knowledge gap. For more
innovation process is not related to HQ involve- radical and novel innovations, it is especially
ment in the process. difficult to estimate ex ante what practical knowl-
edge will be required, or to acquire it during the
If HQ interferes in the subsidiary innovation innovation processes. HQ ignorance, therefore, is
processes despite its lack of relevant knowledge, it more acute in processes concerning radical and
will probably complicate the situation. There is an novel innovations than in those dealing with

Journal of International Business Studies


Rationality vs ignorance Francesco Ciabuschi et al
965

incremental innovations. Its intervention may customers, albeit occasionally, and their customers
therefore have a more negative impact in the were not yet considered as a different type of
former. The sheer ignorance perspective, therefore, business. Thus the idea of transferring TSB technol-
leads to the following proposition: ogy and know-how to these units began to emerge.
A TSB manager commented: “When traveling to
Proposition 6: The more novel the innovation, meet representatives of the European organization
the more negative the impact of HQ involvement we got to know some of the projects that were
on the performance of a subsidiary’s innovation going on overseas. Particularly, we detected a great
process. potential for competence synergies”. However, at
that time, none of the other packaging units ever
To further illustrate the difference between the contacted TSB, or showed interest in TSB business
two perspectives and, particularly, to show the and competence. This was also true for the top
relevance of the sheer ignorance perspective, a real management, as indicated by a TSB manager: “SCA
case of a specific technology transfer from the USA top management does not see that they already
to Europe is presented below. have a sort of raw TSB business in Europe which
could be easily pulled together, shaped up and
THE CASE OF SVENSKA CELLULOSA rendered as an official business segment”.
AKTIEBOLAGET (SCA) AND THE THERMOSAFE Thus TSB managers seeking to grow outside the
BRANDS (TSB) SUBSIDIARY2 US started to meet with some local subsidiary
SCA is one of the largest pulp and paper producers managers of SCA Packaging in Europe and tried to
in the world, with annual sales of over h11 billion promote the idea that a temperature assurance
and about 50,000 employees. One of its business business should be formed within Europe. Accord-
divisions, SCA Packaging, is a leading producer of ing to TSB managers, local European SCA managers’
corrugated board and containerboard in Europe, reactions were not positive. Some managers,
and one of the world leaders in customized despite agreeing with the idea, did not want to be
packaging solutions, delivering about 40 million involved. Others claimed that there was not
packaging units daily from more than 250 plants enough business in the region. Some were simply
worldwide. In 2003, SCA Packaging set up a US unit against change of any kind. One TSB manager
specializing in temperature assurance solutions further commented: “European subsidiaries seem to
(e.g., gels, insulation, and containers), the TSB have their own issues and they don’t tell us what
unit.3 TSB is the US market leader in its segment, these issues are”.
with total sales of over US$100 million. TSB is a Therefore, TSB turned to SCA corporate HQ and
subsidiary of SCA Packaging Division, and reports asked for a direct intervention. Since the creation of
to the SCA Packaging HQ in Brussels. TSB through the acquisition of four US companies,
TSB’s technology and competence is unique corporate HQ has not been involved with the TSB
within the SCA group. In fact, the temperature business. According to managers at corporate HQ,
assurance business was new to SCA, and many of its TSB has never been at the top of the priority list,
customers and competitors are not regular custo- since it is profitable in their business, and SCA had
mers (or competitors) of any other SCA unit. This to face other issues much more urgent. As corporate
also means that TSB is not competing directly HQ did not react to TSB’s request, the Packaging
with its sister units. Moreover, with respect to the HQ in Brussels was contacted. SCA Packaging HQ
other SCA packaging units, TSB’s business model is did not respond immediately. However, in 2005 the
also unique. Typical packaging units have a B2B CEO of SCA Packaging finally decided to support
approach, and packaging solutions are generally the idea of somehow transferring TSB competence
marketed as commodities, whereas TSB has a B2C to Europe. Although not familiar with TSB and its
approach based on strong branding and higher business, the CEO felt the pressure to act on the TSB
value-added. These circumstances contributed to request, since this was becoming an increasingly
the fact that, although HQ was aware of TSB’s critical issue for TSB’s potential growth and, hope-
unique competence, it did not assign to it any clear fully, an opportunity for the other packaging units.
strategy or role. Although championed by the CEO in Brussels,
However, TSB realized soon after its start-up that the process of exploiting TSB competence in the
some of the SCA Packaging units in Europe were wider organization was not taking shape. Brussels
already serving potential temperature assurance HQ was finally supporting TSB, but the European

Journal of International Business Studies


Rationality vs ignorance Francesco Ciabuschi et al
966

packaging units continued to put up strong resis- This case illustrates the difference between the
tance. The CEO in Brussels became concerned, and rationality perspective and the sheer ignorance
did not want to damage the existing equilibrium in perspective. The former offers a limited explanation
the European packaging organization. TSB trusted of HQ’s behavior in the real case scenario. The
Brussels to channel it into Europe, but in the end rationality perspective proposes that HQ involves
they never actually succeeded. As a TSB manager itself in the transfer processes at the subsidiary level
commented: “People in Brussels have been pro- only to the extent that it possesses knowledge
mising support, but during the years we never relevant to the project. A straightforward relation-
succeeded in making any concrete step to bring TSB ship can be expected between HQ’s knowledge and
technology and products overseas”. the degree and character of its active involvement.
After some time, TSB decided to act autono- Nevertheless, HQ took an active part in the transfer
mously, using only its own resources. The acquisi- process despite its apparent lack of knowledge
tion of a local firm within the temperature about the temperature assurance field and the
assurance business would avoid direct contact and core technology associated with this business. The
potential problems with the existing European SCA TSB case demonstrates that there are situations in
organization. In 2006, TSB acquired Cool Logistics, which there is no direct relationship between
a UK-based company with operations in both the HQ knowledge and HQ involvement. It further
UK and France. At first, TSB’s cooperation with demonstrates that involvement might be a conse-
sister units overseas remained limited. The presi- quence of the expectations placed on HQ by others.
dent of TSB commented: “Probably the most risky TSB insisted that the divisional HQ should use its
thing that we at TSB have ever done is to move authority and intervene, which, finally, it did.
somewhat against the SCA organization and take The rationality perspective also tells us that when
the first step into Europe through an acquisition HQ chooses to intervene, innovation processes will
and by aiming at making TSB a global venture”. In benefit. This is inferred from the basic assumption
this way, TSB managed to market its temperature that HQ designs its role to fit the competence it is
assurance business through its UK subsidiary, and it able to contribute. There are ample indications in
also started to negotiate with some of the other the TSB case, in contrast that HQ’s involvement not
SCA units regarding potential opportunities to only proved useless; it also delayed the process.
cooperate in some niches of the temperature When TSB eventually took independent initiative,
assurance business. with no interference from the SCA organization,
To summarize, TSB launched the idea that its the transfer of the new technology from TSB into
innovations in the temperature assurance business Europe became a reality.4
should be transferred to and exploited within SCA’s
European units. Corporate or divisional HQ was FINAL COMMENTS
expected to be a driving force by taking an active In this paper we have brought to the scene a rather
part in the transfer process. However, HQ’s knowl- neglected perspective, which we have called the
edge about the business was extremely limited. It sheer ignorance perspective. By comparing it with
had no practical or any other experience of TSB the dominant perspective in the mainstream
competence in the temperature assurance business. literature – the rationality perspective – we have
At first, HQ was hesitant to deal with the issue. TSB discussed its main features as it applies to the role
insisted, and HQ eventually decided to intervene played by HQ in subsidiary innovation processes.
by attempting to persuade the European units At the core of the reasoning is the impossibility of
to develop their competence in the field. The HQ to assess ex ante what role to play in a specific
European units, however, showed no interest in innovation process.
the temperature assurance business, and HQ failed Does our reasoning involve, in line with the sheer
to convince them of the potential benefits. In time, ignorance perspective, HQ keeping its hands off
HQ became increasingly concerned by the resis- innovation processes at the subsidiary level? Not
tance of the sister units, and eventually abandoned necessarily. Authority exercised by HQ can still be
its attempts to play an active role as a facilitator in rational, even in a sheer ignorance scenario. First,
the transfer process. On realizing that HQ had one might argue that HQ may learn over time how
given up the transfer project, or at least its own role much and in what way to intervene. However, the
in it, TSB decided to exploit its competence in more radical and novel the innovation, the less
Europe on its own behalf. applicable the practical experience gained from

Journal of International Business Studies


Rationality vs ignorance Francesco Ciabuschi et al
967

previous projects. Second, when several research Another way of comparing the two perspectives
projects are in progress simultaneously, a centra- would be to investigate the relationship bet-
lized authority may be necessary to set priorities, ween HQ degree of involvement in specific innova-
even if its knowledge about the projects is scant. tion projects at the subsidiary level and the
HQ may have an important role to play in the efficiency and effectiveness of these projects, in
resolution of conflicts arising from disagreements terms both of development and of transfer. The two
within a specific project, between different ones, or perspectives lead to opposing predictions concern-
among subsidiaries (Goold & Campbell, 2002). HQ ing this relationship, and an investigation would
might be able to play such a role even when cast new light on the issue of the relevance of the
suffering from radical uncertainty about the pro- rationality perspective vs the sheer ignorance
jects as such. Third, when the need for decisions perspective. If the findings show a negative sig-
and action is urgent, somebody has to decide nificant relationship between involvement and
(Foss, 2002). The MNE, as a distributed knowledge performance, the dominance of the rationality
system, implies that nobody (neither HQ nor its perspective in IB research should be an issue of
subsidiaries) has a complete overview of the situa- particular concern.
tion, or the possibility to assess which competences
will be relevant in the future. In such a situation,
HQ might decide to intervene simply to make NOTES
1
decisions and get things done, even if nobody On this issue, IB research does not deviate from
knows whether this is the right decision. Fourth, research on organizations in general. As pointed out
following this line of thought, it could also be by March and others, the preeminence of rationality as
argued that involvement by HQ in a situation of an interpretation of human action in organizations
sheer ignorance might lead to a low performance in has a long tradition (March, 2006; Olsen, 1976).
terms of efficiency, but eventually to a better March suggests three main reasons for this. One is the
performance in terms of effectiveness. usual assumption of the pre-existence of purpose.
The purpose of this paper was to contrast two The second is what has been called the necessity of
perspectives in order to better understand HQ consistency, namely, that the organization is seen as a
behavior and its potential value-adding role. This hierarchy with the obligation to coordinate and
analysis has deliberately emphasized the differences control. The third reason is the primacy of rationality,
between the two perspectives, and may have i.e., the assumption that people consequentially
somewhat simplified the broad spectrum, which associate outcomes to their behavior rather than
would range from “pure” rationality, through dif- acting without fully understanding why (March,
ferent forms of bounded rationality, to “pure” igno- 1976).
2
rance. To some extent, the two perspectives also This study was conducted within a large Swedish-
reflect different research traditions and differences based MNE (SCA) by examining one specific subsidiary
in empirical contexts (Barner-Rasmussen et al., 2010). (TSB) of its American venture. Interviews were con-
It is critical to recognize, however, that a theoretical ducted with top executives at the HQ, and with the
conflict between perspectives can be addressed by subsidiary managers at TSB and other American units.
empirical research. This paper urges the pursuit of A semi-structured interview guide was used, and
this type of research. For instance, empirical ana- modified as new insights were gathered. A total of
lyses of the relationship between HQ actual knowl- 20 interviews were conducted in the United States and
edge and its involvement would shed light on the Sweden. Interviews ranged from one to several hours
theoretical merits of the two perspectives. One way in length. Respondents were informed of the purpose
of carrying out this kind of research would be to of the research before the interview. A “courtroom”
examine HQ actual experience of the local context procedure was used, in which the questions focused
of subsidiaries (as an indicator of HQ knowledge) in on facts and events rather than on respondents’
relation to its degree of involvement in innovation interpretations, especially of the actions of others
processes at the subsidiary level. Under the ration- (Eisenhardt, 1989). All interviews were tape-recorded
ality perspective, we would expect to find the rela- and transcribed. Follow-up questions were asked via
tionship to be positive. From the sheer ignorance phone and email, particularly when clarification was
perspective, in contrast, we would expect a non- necessary. Interviews ended when the researcher
significant (or weaker) relationship, and factors determined that a satisfactory level of understanding
other than knowledge to influence HQ behavior. had been reached for the purpose of the research.

Journal of International Business Studies


Rationality vs ignorance Francesco Ciabuschi et al
968

4
Upon completion of the interview series, the collected There are of course alternative lenses through
information was transformed into a case history. which the case could be looked at, in particular
3
TSB was formed in 2003 from the acquisition of resource dependency theory and dynamic stakeholder
four US independent ventures (ISC Labs, Polyfoam management theory, which some scholars may con-
Packers, Mid-Lands Chemicals, and H&R Industries). sider more relevant in terms of explanatory power.

REFERENCES
Ambos, T., Andersson, U., & Birkinshaw, J. 2010. What are the Clark, K. B., & Fujimoto, T. 1991. Product development
consequences of initiative-taking in multinational subsidiaries? performance. Boston: Harvard Business School Press.
Journal of International Business Studies, 41(7): 1099–1118. Coase, R. H. 1937. The nature of the firm. Economica,
Anderson, P., & Tushman, M. L. 1990. Technological disconti- 4(16): 386–405.
nuities and dominant designs: A cyclical model of technolo- Cohen, R. B., Felton, N., Liere, J., & Nkosi, M. 1979. The
gical change. Administrative Science Quarterly, 35(4): 604–633. multinational corporation: A radical approach – Papers by
Andersson, U., Forsgren, M., & Holm, U. 2007. Balancing Stephen Hymer. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.
subsidiary influence in the federative MNC: A business Collis, D. J., Young, D., & Goold, M. 2007. The size, structure,
network view. Journal of International Business Studies, 38(5): and performance of corporate headquarters. Strategic
802–818. Management Journal, 28(4): 383–405.
Asakawa, K. 2001. Organisational tension in international R&D Conner, K. R., & Prahalad, C. K. 1996. A resource-based theory
management: The case of Japanese firms. Research Policy, of the firm: Knowledge versus opportunism. Organization
30(5): 735–757. Science, 7(5): 477–501.
Barner-Rasmussen, W., Piekkari, R., Scott-Kennel, J., & Welch, C. Daft, R. L. 1998. Organization theory and design. Cincinnati, OH:
2010. Commander-in-Chief or absentee landlord? Key South-Western College Publishing.
perspectives on headquarters in multinational corporations. Denrell, J., Arvidsson, N., & Zander, U. 2004. Managing know-
In U. Andersson & U. Holm (Eds), Managing the contemporary ledge in the dark: An empirical study of the reliability of capability
multinational: 85–105. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar. evaluations. Management Science, 50(11): 1491–1503.
Barney, J. 1991. Firm resources and sustained competitive Doz, Y. L., & Prahalad, C. K. 1981. Headquarters influence
advantage. Journal of Management, 17(1): 99–120. and strategic control in MNCs. Sloan Management Review,
Birkinshaw, J., & Hood, N. 1998. Multinational subsidiary 23(1): 15–30.
evolution: Capability and charter change in foreign-owned Egelhoff, B. 1988. Organizing the multinational enterprise: An
subsidiary companies. Academy of Management Review, information-processing perspective. Cambridge, MA: Ballinger
23(4): 773–795. Publishing Company.
Birkinshaw, J., Hood, N., & Jonsson, S. 1998. Building firm- Egelhoff, B. 2010. Evaluating the role of parent HQ in a
specific advantages in multinational corporations: The role contemporary MNC. In U. Andersson & U. Holm (Eds),
of subsidiary initiative. Strategic Management Journal, 19(3): Managing the contemporary multinational: 106–122.
221–241. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.
Birkinshaw, J., Holm, U., Thilenius, P., & Arvidsson, N. 2000. Eisenhardt, K. M. 1989. Building theories from case study
Consequences of perception gaps in the headquarters– research. Academy of Management Review, 14(4): 532–550.
subsidiary relationship. International Business Review, 9(3): Ferner, A., Almond, P., & Colling, T. 2005. Institutional theory
321–344. and the cross-border transfer of employment policy: the case
Birkinshaw, J., Bouquet, C., & Ambos, T. C. 2007. Managing of “workforce diversity” in US multinationals. Journal of
executive attention in the global company. MIT Sloan International Business Studies, 36(3): 304–321.
Management Review, 48(4): 39–45. Forsgren, M., Holm, U., & Johanson, J. 2005. Managing the
Björkman, I. 2006. International human resource manage- embedded multinational: A business network view. Cheltenham,
ment research and institutional theory. In G. K. Stahl & UK: Edward Elgar Publishing.
I. Björkman (Eds), Handbook of research in international human Foss, N. J. 2002. Coase vs Hayek: Economic organization and the
resource management: 463–474. Cheltenham, UK: Edward knowledge economy. International Journal of the Economics of
Elgar. Business, 9(1): 9–35.
Björkman, I., Barner-Rasmussen, W., & Li, L. 2004. Managing Garcia, R., & Calantone, R. 2002. A critical look at technological
knowledge transfer in MNCs: The impact of headquarters innovation typology and innovativeness terminology:
control mechanisms. Journal of International Business Studies, A literature review. Journal of Product Innovation Management,
35(5): 443–455. 19(2): 110–132.
Bouquet, C., Morrison, A., & Birkinshaw, J. 2009. International Garcia-Pont, C., Canales, J. I., & Noboa, F. 2009. Subsidiary
attention and multinational enterprise performance. Journal of strategy: The embeddedness component. Journal of Manage-
International Business Studies, 40(1): 108–131. ment Studies, 46(2): 182–214.
Brown, S. L., & Eisenhardt, K. M. 1995. Product development: Ghoshal, S., & Bartlett, C. 1988. Creation, adoption, and
Past research, present findings, and future directions. Academy diffusion of innovations by subsidiaries of multinational
of Management Review, 20(2): 343–378. corporations. Journal of International Business Studies, 19(3):
Buckley, P., & Casson, M. 1991. The future of the multinational 365–388.
enterprise, (2nd edn) London: Macmillan. Ghoshal, S., & Nohria, N. 1997. The differentiated MNC:
Casson, M. 1999. The organization and evolution of the Organizing multinational corporation for value creation. San
multinational enterprise: An information cost approach. Francisco, CA: Jossey-Bass.
Management International Review, 39(1): 77–121. Ghoshal, S., & Westney, D. E. 1993. Organization theory and the
Ciabuschi, F., Martı́n Martı́n, O., & Ståhl, B. 2010. Headquarters’ multinational corporation. New York: St Martins.
influence on knowledge transfer performance. Management Giddens, A. 1984. The constitution of society. Cambridge:
International Review, 50(4): 471–491. Cambridge University Press.

Journal of International Business Studies


Rationality vs ignorance Francesco Ciabuschi et al
969

Goodall, K., & Roberts, J. 2003. Repairing managerial Rosenzweig, P. M., & Singh, J. V. 1991. Organizational
knowledge-ability over distance. Organization Studies, 24(7): environments and the multinational enterprise. Academy of
1153–1175. Management Review, 16(2): 340–361.
Goold, M., & Campbell, A. 2002. Parenting in complex Rugman, A. M., & Verbeke, A. 2001. Subsidiary-specific
structures. Long Range Planning, 35(3): 219–243. advantages in multinational enterprises. Strategic Management
Grant, R. M. 1996. Toward a knowledge-based theory of the Journal, 22(3): 237–250.
firm. Strategic Management Journal, 17(Winter special issue): Simon, H. 1959. Theories of decision-making in economics
109–122. and behavioural science. American Economic Review, 49(3):
Hayek, F. A. 1945. The use of knowledge in society. The 253–283.
American Economic Review, 35(4): 519–530. Spender, J. C. 1994. Organizational knowledge, collective
Hedlund, G. 1986. The hypermodern MNC: A heterarchy. practice, and Penrose rents. International Business Review,
Human Resource Management, 25(1): 9–35. 3(4): 353–367.
Hennart, J. -F. 1982. A theory of multinational enterprise. Ann Stacey, R. H. 1995. The science of complexity: An alternative
Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press. perspective for strategic change processes. Strategic Manage-
Hymer, S. 1976. International operations of national firms: A study ment Journal, 16(6): 477–495.
of foreign direct investment. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Tsoukas, H. 1996. The firm as a distributed knowledge system:
Jacobson, R. 1992. The “Austrian” school of strategy. Academy of A constructionist approach. Strategic Management Journal,
Management Journal, 17(4): 782–807. 17(Winter special issue): 11–25.
Kirzner, I. M. 1997. Entrepreneurial discovery and the compe- Verbeke, A. 2003. The evolutionary view of the MNE and the
titive market process: An Austrian approach. Journal of future of internalization theory. Journal of International Business
Economic Literature, 35(1): 60–85. Studies, 34(6): 498–504.
Kogut, B., & Zander, U. 1992. Knowledge of the firm, Verbeke, A., & Greidanus, N. S. 2009. The end of the
combinative capabilities, and the replication of technology. opportunism vs trust debate: Bounded reliability as a new
Organization Science, 3(2): 383–397. envelope concept in research on MNE governance. Journal
Kogut, B., & Zander, U. 1993. Knowledge of the firm and the of International Business Studies, 40(9): 1471–1495.
evolutionary theory of the multinational corporation. Journal of Weick, K. E., & Roberts, K. H. 1993. Collective mind in
International Business Studies, 24(4): 625–645. organizations: Heedful interrelating on flight decks. Academy
Kostova, T. 1999. Transnational transfer of strategic organiza- of Science Quarterly, 38(3): 357–381.
tional practices: A contextual perspective. Academy of Manage- Westney, D. E. 1993. Institutionalization theory and the multi-
ment Review, 24(2): 308–324. national corporation. In S. Ghoshal & D. E. Westney (Eds),
Kostova, T., & Zaheer, S. 1999. Organizational legitimacy under Organizational theory and the multinational corporation: 53–76.
conditions of complexity: The case of the multinational New York: St Martin’s Press.
enterprise. Academy of Management Review, 24(1): 64–81. Williamson, O. E. 1971. Managerial discretion, organization
Kristensen, P. H., & Zeitlin, J. 2001. The making of a global firm: form and the multidivisional hypothesis. In R. Marris & A.
Local pathways to multinational enterprise. In G. Morgan, Wood (Eds), The corporate economy growth, competition and
P. H. Kristensen, & R. Whitley (Eds), The multinational firm: innovative power: 343–386. London: Macmillan.
Organizing across institutional and national divides: 172–195. Williamson, O. E. 1985. The economic institutions of capitalism.
Oxford: Oxford University Press. New York: The Free Press.
March, J. G. 1976. The technology of foolishness. In J. G. March Yamin, M. 2002. Subsidiary entrepreneurship and the advan-
& J. Olsen (Eds), Ambiguity and choice in organizations: 69–81. tage of nationality. In V. Havila, M. Forsgren, & H. Håkansson
Bergen: Universitetsförlaget. (Eds), Critical perspectives on internationalization: 133–150.
March, J. G. 2006. Rationality, foolishness, and adaptive London: Elsevier.
intelligence. Strategic Management Journal, 27(3): 201–214. Yamin, M., & Forsgren, M. 2006. Hymer’s analysis of the
McDermott, C. M., & O’Connor, G. C. 2002. Managing radical multinational organization: Power retention and the demise
innovation: An overview of emergent strategy issues. The of the federative MNE. International Business Review, 15(2):
Journal of Product Innovation Management, 19(6): 424–438. 166–179.
Mintzberg, H. 1990. The design school: Reconsidering the basic
premises of strategic management. Strategic Management
Journal, 11(3): 171–195. ABOUT THE AUTHORS
Morgan, G., & Kristensen, P. H. 2006. The contested space of Francesco Ciabuschi is an Associate Professor
multinationals: Varieties of institutionalism, varieties of capit-
alism. Human Relations, 59(11): 1469–1490. in International Business at Uppsala University
Morgan, G., & Whitley, R. 2003. Introduction to special issue on (Sweden). He has published in many international
the changing multinational firm. Journal of Management journals, and his current research focuses on
Studies, 40(3): 609–616.
Mudambi, R., & Navarra, P. 2004. Is knowledge power? corporate strategy, management of multinationals,
Knowledge flows, subsidiary power and rent-seeking within firms’ internationalization, knowledge and innova-
MNCs. Journal of International Business Studies, 35(5): 385–406. tion management. He is a citizen of Italy, where
Nelson, R. R. 1993. National innovation systems: A comparative
analysis. New York: Norton. he was born, and of Sweden, which has been his
Olsen, J. 1976. Choice in an organized anarchy. In J. G. March & home for the last 15 years. He can be reached at
J. Olsen (Eds), Ambiguity and choice in organizations: 82–139. francesco.ciabuschi@fek.uu.se.
Bergen: Universitetsförlaget.
Poppo, L. 2003. The visible hands of hierarchy within the M-
form: An empirical test of corporate parenting of internal Mats Forsgren is Professor Emeritus in Interna-
product exchanges. Journal of Management Studies, 40(2):
403–430. tional Business at Uppsala University, and perma-
Quinn, J. B. 1985. Managing innovation: Controlled chaos. nent visiting professor at LUISS Business School in
Harvard Business Review, 53(3): 73–84. Rome. His main research topics are management of
Regnér, P. 1999. Strategy creation in the periphery: Inductive
versus deductive strategy making. Journal of Management multinational firms, theories of internationaliza-
Studies, 40(1): 57–82. tion and business network theory. He has published

Journal of International Business Studies


Rationality vs ignorance Francesco Ciabuschi et al
970

several articles in international journals. He is a an Associated Researcher at Uppsala University


citizen of Sweden. He can be reached at mats (Sweden). His research focuses on three main areas:
.forsgren@fek.uu.se. the internationalization process of firms, country of
origin, and MNEs. Born in and a citizen of Spain,
he has published in journals such as the Journal of
Oscar Martı́n Martı́n is an Assistant Professor Management Studies, International Marketing Review,
at the Public University of Navarre (Spain) and and International Business Review.

Accepted by Alain Verbeke, Area Editor, 27 March 2011. This paper has been with the authors for three revisions.

Journal of International Business Studies


Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.

You might also like