The Economics of Enteric Infections: Human Foodborne Disease Costs

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 12

GASTROENTEROLOGY 2009;136:1851–1862

The Economics of Enteric Infections: Human Foodborne Disease Costs

Jean C. Buzby Tanya Roberts*


US Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service, Washington, DC

The World Health Organization estimates that in 2005, estimate by Mead et al4 at the Centers for Disease Con-
1.5 million people died, worldwide, from diarrheal dis- trol and Prevention (CDC) is that 76 million foodborne
eases. A separate study estimated that 70% of diarrheal illnesses occur annually in the United States, resulting in
diseases are foodborne. The widely cited US estimate is 325,000 hospitalizations and 5200 deaths.
that there are 76 million foodborne illnesses annually, Every illness has an economic cost. For the practitio-
resulting in 325,000 hospitalizations and 5200 deaths. ner, such costs have bearings if they influence decisions
However, there are epidemiologic and methodologic to diagnose or to treat, either consciously or uncon-
challenges to accurately estimate the economic burden sciously. Global macroeconomic consequences of such
of foodborne disease on society, either in terms of mon- illnesses do not, however, influence daily practice. None-
etary costs or non-monetary units of measurement. theless, infections of the gastrointestinal tract, and, most
Studies on the economic burden of foodborne disease particularly, those that are foodborne and theoretically
vary considerably: some analyze the effects of a single preventable exact considerable expense worldwide. Be-
pathogen or a single outbreak, whereas others attempt cause of the role of gastroenterologists in the manage-
to estimate all foodborne disease in a country. Differ- ment of affected patients, and as advocates for patients
ences in surveillance systems, methodology, and other and populations who wish not to acquire these infec-
factors preclude meaningful comparisons across exist- tions, we take the opportunity of this review to present
ing studies. However, if it were possible to completely large-scale implications of foodborne illnesses.
estimate the societal costs for all acute foodborne dis- On a per patient scale, foodborne disease costs can be
eases and their chronic sequelae worldwide, on the basis considerable, particularly for the more severe cases. For
of currently available data, worldwide costs from these example, Table 1 presents total cost estimates for STEC
illnesses would be substantial. Moreover, foodborne O157 (ie, Shiga toxin-producing Escherichia coli O157) and
infections are largely manifested as intestinal illnesses shows how average estimated costs per case vary by se-
and are largely preventable. Total costs of foodborne verity level. The estimated average cost for STEC O157 is
disease would be much smaller in the United States and $6256 per case.5
the world if economic incentives for industry to pro- Much of the US data on foodborne disease are from
duce safer food were improved. However, costs of im- the Foodborne Diseases Active Surveillance Network
plementing new food safety prevention and control
rules must be weighed against the estimated benefits of *Dr Roberts is retired from the US Department of Agriculture, Eco-

reducing foodborne disease to determine net benefits so nomic Research Service, Washington, DC.
that governments have information to efficiently allo- Abbreviations used in this paper: CDC, Centers for Disease Control
and Prevention; CEA, cost-effectiveness analysis; COI, cost-of-illness;
cate funds among competing programs.
DALY, disability-adjusted life year; ERS, Economic Research Service;
FDA, Food and Drug Administration; FoodNet, Foodborne Diseases
Active Surveillance Network; GBS, Guillain-Barré syndrome; HALY,

T he World Health Organization (WHO) estimates


that 1.5 million people died, worldwide, from diar-
rheal diseases in 2005.1 A separate study estimated that
health-adjusted life year; HUS, hemolytic uremic syndrome; OMB,
Office of Management and Budget; PR/HACCP, Pathogen Reduction/
Hazard Analysis and Critical Control Program; STEC O157, Shiga toxin-
70% of diarrheal diseases are foodborne.2 Data on the producing Escherichia coli O157; USDA, US Department of Agriculture;
WHO, World Health Organization; WTP, willingness-to-pay.
extent of foodborne illnesses and associated deaths are © 2009 by the AGA Institute
incomplete and understate the problem in both devel- 0016-5085/09/$36.00
oped and developing countries.3 The widely cited US doi:10.1053/j.gastro.2009.01.074
1852 BUZBY AND ROBERTS GASTROENTEROLOGY Vol. 136, No. 6

Table 1. Estimated STEC O157 Costs, From All Sources, 2007 Dollars
Severity level Total cases (n) Total costs ($) Average cost per case ($)
Not hospitalized
Did not visit physician; survived 57,656 1,645,024 29
Visited physician, survived 13,656 7,045,354 516
Hospitalized
Did not have HUS; survived 1797 12,438,459 6922
Had HUS but not ESRD; survived 300 11,608,420 38,695
Had HUS and ESRD; survived 10 58,687,607 5,868,761
Did not have HUS; died 23 103,657,247 4,506,837
Had HUS, died 38 264,625,382 6,963,826
Total 73,480 459,707,493 6256

NOTE: Although these figures are for STEC O157 illnesses from all sources, average foodborne illness costs are usually considered to be the
same as costs for those illnesses from non-foodborne sources.
ESRD, end-stage renal disease; HUS, hemolytic uremic syndrome, which is characterized by red blood cell destruction, kidney failure, and
neurologic complications, such as seizures and strokes;
Source: Economic Research Service.5

(FoodNet), which is a collaborative effort between the estimates of the burden of foodborne disease are cur-
CDC, the US Department of Agriculture (USDA), the rently being developed. Snowdon et al9 speculated that
Food and Drug Administration, and 10 participating the economic consequences of foodborne disease are
state health departments.6,7 FoodNet performs active, substantial in both industrialized and developing na-
population-based laboratory surveillance in selected sites tions, although the consequences may be greater in
around the United States and covers a select group of developing countries because of high incidence of in-
pathogens (ie, Campylobacter, Cryptosporidium, Cyclospora, fant mortality, malnutrition, and chronic diarrhea.
Listeria monocytogenes, STEC O157, STEC non-O157, Sal- Foodborne illness generates costs that are borne by
monella, Shigella, Vibrio, and Yersinia enterocolitica).6,7 Food- households whose members become ill, the food in-
Net augments surveillance information with surveys of dustry, and the regulatory and public health sectors
clinical laboratories and the general public to better un- (Figure 1). The array of societal costs of foodborne
derstand the burden of disease. Population demograph- illnesses in these 3 main groups is shown in Table 3.
ics from FoodNet find that the young are more likely to Analyses that estimate the costs of foodborne disease
be infected with a foodborne pathogen, yet those older often include only the medical costs of individuals or
than 70 years are more likely to die of the illness (Table 2). household, costs of lost productivity, and premature
Collectively, foodborne diseases pose enormous fi- death and exclude others costs (eg, pain and suffering,
nancial costs on communities, individual nations, and institutional care) because of lack of adequate data.
the world. For example, US foodborne costs for 6 The WHO defines the burden of disease as “the inci-
bacterial pathogens and 1 parasite were estimated at dence and prevalence of morbidity, disability, and mor-
$6.5 billion to $34.9 billion annually,8 which is an tality associated with acute and chronic manifestations
underestimate of total foodborne disease costs because of diseases.”10 Here, we take this one step further and are
there may be ⬎200 microbiologic agents that cause interested in the economic burden of foodborne disease,
foodborne disease.4 Other countries have also esti- meaning that we are interested in translating the differ-
mated annual costs for foodborne diseases, and global ent outcomes or effect of foodborne disease into a com-

Table 2. Illnesses, Hospitalizations, and Deaths in FoodNet as a Result of Pathogens Commonly Transmitted Through Food
by Age, 2001–2005
Age

0–14 y 15–69 y ⱖ70 y

Case severity Total cases (n) n % n % n %


Illnessesa 63,422 25,821 41 35,263 55 2338 4
Required hospitalization 15,420 4828 31 8444 55 2148 14
Death from foodborne illness 368 36 10 158 43 174 47

NOTE: The illness severity categories are mutually exclusive and include the pathogens covered by FoodNet.
aPersons who have visited a doctor because of an illness, a stool sample has been taken, and the infection is confirmed and is in the FoodNet
database.
Source: Age breakdown of FoodNet data (Ida Rosenblum, FoodNet CDC, e-mail communication April 2007).
May 2009 HUMAN FOODBORNE DISEASE COSTS 1853

ΠComparing benefits and costs of alternative patho-


gen prevention and control programs and strategies
to find cost-effective interventions so that resources
are appropriately allocated.
ΠMonitoring and evaluating food safety measures
over time. They can also give countries a sense of
what to expect in terms of the disease burden in
the future.10

Epidemiologic Challenges
There are 5 main epidemiological challenges when
estimating the economic burden of foodborne disease.
Estimating the Number of Illnesses
Estimating the annual number of illnesses each
year caused by a particular pathogen is difficult. This is a
challenge because some unknown portion of ill people
never see a doctor, many visits do not result in a diag-
nosable pathogen because the specimen is not obtained,
or the laboratory testing does not seek or identify the
causative agent.11 Figure 2 illustrates the steps that must
Figure 1. Costs of foodborne illness are borne by households whose
occur for a person who becomes ill to be identified as a
members become ill, the food industry, and the regulatory and public
health sectors. laboratory-confirmed case that is reported to public
health surveillance.
In 2007, FoodNet identified a total of 17,883 labora-
mon unit of measurement, such as monetary costs or a tory-confirmed cases of foodborne infection.12 This esti-
non-monetary unit of measurement. mate represents those laboratory-confirmed cases in
Why is it important to estimate the economic burden which an illness is linked to a specific pathogen and
of a foodborne disease? These estimates can be used in reported to the CDC. As previously mentioned, FoodNet
the following multiple ways: uses a variety of tools to make its estimates. Information
from active surveillance and the FoodNet surveys of clin-
● Evaluate the economic burden of all or a group of
ical laboratories and the general population are used to
foodborne diseases.
estimate the total number of foodborne illnesses in the
● Provide justification for the need to strengthen sup- population. With this information, Mead et al4 estimated
port for increased surveillance and prevention of that 76 million foodborne disease cases occur annually in
foodborne diseases by national or by international the United States. FoodNet now covers 15% of the US
organizations, such as the WHO. population6,7; FoodNet also conducts a variety of epide-
miologic studies, including case– control studies for spo-
● Provide input to a benefit– cost analysis of a proposed
radic cases from specific pathogens.6
food safety rule or a cost-effectiveness analysis (CEA),
One particular difficulty in estimating the total cost of
to obtain information needed in policy making. From
foodborne disease is that the causes of most cases of
an economic perspective, the societal benefits of a food
gastrointestinal distress are never identified. Because of
safety regulation are the costs of foodborne disease
the mild nature of most of these illnesses, the causes are
that would be prevented if the regulation was put in
usually not investigated, and, as a result, they are fre-
place, such as savings in disease prevention and miti-
quently excluded from cost studies. Mead et al4 found
gation expenditures, increases in worker productivity,
that unknown agents accounted for approximately 81%
and reductions in medical costs, pain and suffering.
of foodborne illnesses in the United States and 64% of
● Aid comparisons and other analyses, such as for: deaths. Hence, the actual spectrum of all causes of food-
ΠComparing the estimated costs for different food- borne disease is not definitive, and, as a result, the overall
borne diseases. Although this information can help economic analysis will be similarly restricted. Total esti-
determine the order for targeting pathogen preven- mated costs of foodborne disease will be underestimated
tion and control efforts toward the most costly dis- if the economic studies do not include the unknown
eases, information on prevention and control costs pathogens from Mead et al4 or other sources, particularly
is also needed to determine whether and where there the more severe cases. Frenzen13 estimated that gastro-
are positive net benefits from implementing food enteritis of unknown cause was responsible for 4400
safety programs. deaths in the United States each year but found no direct
1854 BUZBY AND ROBERTS GASTROENTEROLOGY Vol. 136, No. 6

Table 3. Societal Costs of Foodborne Illness Table 3. Continued


Costs to individuals or householdsa Reduced product demand because of outbreak:
Human illness costs Generic animal product, all firms affected
Medical costs Reduction for specific firm at wholesale or retail level
Physician visits Increased advertising or consumer assurances after outbreak
Laboratory costs Regulatory and public health sector costs for foodborne pathogens
Hospitalization or nursing home Disease surveillance costs to
Drugs and other medications Monitor incidence or severity of human disease by foodborne
Ambulance or other travel costs pathogens
Income or productivity loss for Monitor pathogen incidence in the food chain
Ill person or person dying Develop integrated database from farm to table for foodborne
Caregiver for ill person pathogens
Other illness costs Research to
Travel costs to visit ill person Identify new foodborne pathogens for acute and chronic human
Home modifications illnesses
Vocational/physical rehabilitation Establish high-risk products and production and consumption
Child care costs practices
Special educational programs Identify which consumers are at high risk for which pathogens
Institutional care Develop cheaper and faster pathogen tests
Lost leisure time Risk assessment modeling for all links in the food chain
Psychological costs Outbreak costs
Pain and other psychological suffering Costs of investigating outbreak
Risk aversion Testing to contain an outbreak (eg, serum testing and
Averting behavior costs administering immunoglobulin in persons exposed to
Extra cleaning or cooking time costs hepatitis A)
Extra cost of refrigerator, freezer, etc Costs of cleanup
Flavor changes from traditional recipes (especially meat, milk, Legal suits to enforce regulations that may have been violatedc
egg dishes) Other considerations:
Increased food cost when more expensive but safer foods are Distributional effects in different regions, industries, etc
purchased Equity considerations, such as special concern for children
Altruism (willingness to pay for others to avoid illness)
aWillingness-to-pay estimates for reducing risks of foodborne disease
Industry costsb
Costs of animal production is a comprehensive estimate of all these categories (assuming that
Morbidity and mortality of animals on farms the individuals have included employer-funded sick leave and medical
Reduced growth rate or feed efficiency and increased time to programs in their estimates). The estimate is comprehensive and
market covers reduced risks for everyone: those who will become ill as well as
Costs of disposal of contaminated animals on farm and at those who will not.
bSome industry costs may fall with better pathogen control, such as
slaughterhouse
Increased trimming or reworking at slaughterhouse and reduced product spoilage, possible increases in product shelf-life,
processing plant and extended shelf-life, permitting shipment to more distant markets
Illness among workers because of handling contaminated or lowering shipment costs to nearby markets.
cIn adding up costs, care must be taken to assure that product liability
animals or products
Increased meat product spoilage because of pathogen costs to firms are not already counted in the estimated pain and
contamination suffering cost to individuals. However, the legal and court expenses
Control costs for pathogens at all links in the food chain incurred by all parties are societal costs.
New farm practices (age-segregated housing, sterilized feed, etc)
Altered animal transport and marketing patterns (animal
identification, feeding or watering) evidence that unknown foodborne agents were a main
New slaughterhouse procedures (hide wash, knife sterilization, cause of these deaths.14
carcass sterilizing)
New processing procedures (pathogen tests, contract Attributing Foodborne Disease to Particular
purchasing requirements) Foods
Altered product transport (increased use of time or
temperature indicators) Information about the share of illnesses that are a
New wholesale or retail practices (pathogen tests, employee result of specific foods is limited. Economic analyses need
training, procedures) this information to estimate the number of foodborne
Risk assessment modeling by industry for all links in the food disease cases that might be prevented by a proposed
chain
regulation. For example, the official regulatory impact
Price incentives for pathogen-reduced product at each link in
the food chain analysis of the Pathogen Reduction/Hazard Analysis and
Outbreak costs Critical Control Program (PR/HACCP) for federally in-
Herd slaughter or product recall spected meat and poultry slaughter and processing
Plant closings and cleanup plants required assumptions about what portion of all
Regulatory fines
cases of salmonellosis, campylobacteriosis, and other se-
Product liability suits from consumers and other firms
lect foodborne disease cases were due to meat and poul-
try.15 The proportion attributed to foodborne transmis-
May 2009 HUMAN FOODBORNE DISEASE COSTS 1855

and literature on that pathogen. A variety of analytical


approaches and data sources are used to attribute illness
to particular foods, such as case– control studies and
microbial subtyping.17

Estimating Acute Illness Outcome Severity


For most pathogens, data are limited on the dis-
tribution of outcome severity. A thorough economic eval-
uation requires information on the severity of illness, the
duration, and outcomes, ranging from regaining full
health to death. Although FoodNet collects information
on 3 illness severities (Table 2), it covers only a handful of
pathogens.
Figure 2. FoodNet surveillance, burden of illness pyramid. Adapted Estimating Chronic Complications
from CDC. Available at: www.cdc.gov/foodnet/surveillance_pages/
burden/pyramid.htm. Accessed September 4, 2008. A fourth challenge is that most foodborne patho-
gens cause one or more chronic complications that can
have lifetime health consequences or cause premature
sion varies greatly, from 1% for rotaviruses to 100% for death. These chronic sequelae include paralysis, kidney
Bacillus cereus.4 FoodNet conducted case– control studies failure, irritable bowel syndrome, Guillain–Barré syn-
to determine the foods that cause sporadic illnesses. The drome (GBS), and arthritis. Reactive arthritis is a good
best information linking pathogens to specific foods are example of a chronic sequela because it is an autoim-
from foodborne disease outbreak data. However, Mead et mune disease caused in response to infections, such as by
al4 estimated that only 0.008% of all foodborne illness many foodborne bacterial pathogens. The disease out-
cases in the United States are identified in an outbreak, come tree (Figure 3) shows the range of lifetime out-
and more recent research suggests that in sporadic cases comes, starting with reactive arthritis, in approximately
vehicles can differ considerably from those implicated in 8% of cases of foodborne disease (ie, this is the best
outbreaks.16 For estimation purposes, the share of a par- estimate, with the ranges given).18 It is important to
ticular foodborne disease to a particular food vehicle is include chronic sequelae in cost studies because they can
often obtained from expert opinion or targeted studies result in high average and total costs. For example, Max-

Figure 3. Disease outcome tree of arthropathies (acute foodborne disease [FBD] after exposure to bacterial foodborne pathogens. Adapted from
Raybourne et al.18
1856 BUZBY AND ROBERTS GASTROENTEROLOGY Vol. 136, No. 6

ion–Bergemann et al19 estimated per patient costs for cost-of-illness [COI], willingness-to-pay [WTP]) and non-
irritable bowel syndrome and concluded that it is an monetary methods (eg, versions of the health-adjusted
expensive and common disorder. Estimated annual total life years [HALYs] method) for translating the different
US costs of Campylobacter-associated GBS linked to food outcomes or effect of foodborne disease into a common
were $136.0 million to $1.3 billion in 1995.20 unit of measurement. A detailed description of these
Additional epidemiologic challenges methods is beyond the scope of this article, but Figure 4
provides a brief outline of the main advantages and
Most foodborne illnesses do not result in chronic disadvantages and provides some information as context
complications or loss of life. However, acute and chronic
for discussing the remaining methodologic challenges.
complications from a given exposure to a foodborne
The method of choice depends on the goal. If the goal
pathogen can vary and can be difficult to measure and
is a benefit– cost analysis of a potential food safety regu-
compare across countries for the following reasons:
lation to determine whether it is worthwhile to imple-
● Immune system variability between individuals. ment, then economic theory suggests estimating the ben-
Some individuals have a better immune response to efits of the regulation using the WTP method.26 A
pathogens than others. benefit– cost analysis weighs the pros (ie, benefits) and
● Pathogen strain variability. Some strains of food- cons (ie, costs) of a proposed regulation against a base-
borne disease exhibit greater ease of interpersonal line (ie, the best assessment of the current state without
transmission, such as STEC O157.21 In addition, the regulation). The Office of Management and Budget
some strains are associated with more severe out- (OMB) “best practices” document states that WTP is the
comes. For example, O157:H7 has the strongest as- preferred approach when valuing reductions in fatality
sociation with hemolytic uremic syndrome (HUS) risks that are expected by implementing a proposed reg-
worldwide among STEC.22 ulation.29 In general, benefits and costs should be ideally
expressed in monetary terms, which makes it easier to
● Pathogen variability under different conditions. calculate net benefits. Positive net benefits means that the
A study on STEC found that antibiotics can trigger
regulation may be a good use of public spending whereas
a response that increased toxin production by ⱕ140-
negative net benefits means that it is not. In addition,
fold.23
expressing net benefits in dollars means that the cost of
● Treatment variability. Physicians use different the proposed regulation can be compared with other
treatments that create different outcomes for their options for public expenditures.
patients. For example, intravenous volume expan- The OMB recommends that all major rule making be
sion may be used to treat illness from STEC supported by both a benefit– cost analysis and a CEA
O157:H7 before the development of HUS, to lessen wherever possible29; a CEA provides complementary in-
the severity of renal injury or failure.24 formation to a benefit– cost analysis for decision makers,
● Prevention actions. The incidence and severity of a by identifying the most cost-effective means to attain a
foodborne disease is also affected by the effect of specific health target, such as lowering the suicide rate of
actions in the public health sector to limit the teenagers. In essence, CEA is an approach that compares
spread. For example, Werber et al21 found that ⱖ2 programs that address a particular problem by look-
household transmission of STEC O157 might be ing at the “number” of adverse outcomes averted per
prevented by separating siblings at the first signs of dollar spent on a regulation(s). CEA may be less useful
illness. when there are multiple health outcomes that have to be
described and counted in multiple dimensions, such as
In summary, there is great uncertainty about the
the typical foodborne pathogen that can cause a mild
course of a foodborne illness. The economic costs, how-
illness, premature death, or chronic sequelae.
ever, are greatest for the minority of cases that result in
If the goal is to value foodborne disease costs, then
chronic sequelae or death. Greater information on dis-
the COI method is the preferred approach. The COI
ease variability and treatment will increase the precision
of the estimates of the economic burden of disease, either method can also be used to value the benefits of an-
in monetary terms or in non-monetary measures. ticipated reductions of foodborne disease after the im-
plementation of a food safety regulation. Although
Economic Methodologic Challenges monetization of the main benefits and costs is preferred,
Four methodologic challenges confront attempts sometimes monetization is not possible because of
to estimate the economic burden of foodborne disease. analytical limitations, ethical issues, and other factors.
This is when non-monetary methods, such as HALYs that
Choosing the Method look at health-related quality of life, in healthy-time
The first methodologic challenge is that analysts equivalents, are used. HALYs are also sometimes used
must decide which method to use among monetary (eg, in a CEA.
May 2009 HUMAN FOODBORNE DISEASE COSTS 1857

Monetary Methods
(1) Cost-of-Illness (COI) method is an accounting or tally of the annual dollars spent on the following:
● Direct medical costs (eg, physician and hospital services, supplies, medications, and special procedures required for a specific foodborne
illness)
● Direct non-medical costs (eg, transportation to health care, relocation expenses, special education, residential care)
● Indirect costs such as the dollars of employment compensation that are foregone as a result of morbidity or mortality (eg, lost productivity
because workers were ill and either missed work, performed poorly at work, were unable ever to return to work, or died prematurely).

In general, a COI analysis for a particular foodborne disease traditionally starts with estimates of the annual number of cases and then
divides this number into severity groups, such as those who (1) only had mild illnesses, (2) sought the advice of a physician, (3) were
hospitalized, and (4) died prematurely because of their illness (See Buzby et al25 for detailed food safety examples). Total costs for each
severity group are then estimated. Additional analysis may identify what portion of these costs could potentially be averted by a proposed
regulation.

COI Advantages
● Provides easy to understand monetary measure of foodborne disease costs or the benefits of a program that reduces foodborne disease
● Represents real costs to society

COI Disadvantages
● May not be a good measure of disease severity because estimates are influenced by income, education, and other factors.
● Estimating direct medical expenses can be difficult because of the intricacies of disease coding and insurance arrangements.
● Estimating lost productivity costs may also be difficult because of the various forms of compensation available to employees and because
large portions of the US population are not in the workforce, such as children, retirees, or homemakers and home caregivers.
● Provides a partial estimate of economic costs because it excludes more difficult to measure costs to individuals or households, industry,
and the regulatory or public health sector (eg, pain, suffering, lost leisure time, loss of business, liabilities from lawsuits [to the food
industry] and most chronic complications associated with foodborne disease). Therefore, estimates may underestimate the actual benefits
of a proposed food safety policy.

(2) Willingness-to-Pay (WTP) “approach measures the resources individuals are willing and able to give up for a reduction in the
probability of encountering a hazard that will compromise their health.”26 WTP estimates are often the result of labor market studies, which
evaluate the small statistical risk of premature death and the increase in wages to compensate for taking this risk.

Advantages
● Reflects individual preferences for risk reduction
● Theoretically superior measure
● Includes valuation of pain and suffering, lost leisure time, and other costs

Disadvantages
● Estimates are sensitive to the study populations, type of risk, and level of risk so they may not be applicable if used in a different study.
● May not be practical to have a study focused on the risk being evaluated.
● Has some measurement difficulties, especially for nonfatal outcomes. As a result, some analysts prefer simpler, non-monetary methods.

Non-Monetary Methods
Other evaluation methods are non-monetary methods and look at health-related quality of life, such as in healthy-time equivalents,
that are useful in cost-effectiveness analyses. Health-adjusted life years (HALY) is an umbrella group of non-monetary methods that measure
the years of full health lost because of living with a morbidity. Two methods within this group are quality-adjusted life years (QALYs) and
disability-adjusted life years (DALYs).27 Some analyses monetize the estimates in a separate step. For example, the US Food and Drug
Administration has been monetizing QALYs in their benefit– cost analyses.

Disability-Adjusted Life Years (DALYs)


According to the WHO, “the DALY measure combines the years of life lost due to premature death (YLL) and the years lived with
disability (YLD) for varying degrees of severity, making time itself a common metric for death and disability. One DALY is a health measure,
equating to 1 year of healthy life lost.”10

DALY Advantages
● Is an internally consistent common metric
● Can develop and incorporate downstream effects on agricultural, social, and trade costs that are traditionally missing from a cost or global
burden analysis
● Can segregate comorbidity (ie, when several pathologies coexist and contribute and compete for the cause of death)
● Uses the same value of a human life in rich and poor countries and also levels the playing field between acute and chronic disease because
it takes into account the duration of the syndrome and its severity28

DALY Disadvantages
● Poorly represents some social costs (eg, reduced production and trade of cattle because of a food safety issue)
● Still requires subjective value judgments on how to weight or discount for age of onset, disability weights, and future losses

Figure 4. Monetary and non-monetary methods to estimate the costs and burdens of foodborne disease.
1858 BUZBY AND ROBERTS GASTROENTEROLOGY Vol. 136, No. 6

Selecting the Value of Statistical Life model specifications and values of key variables to ac-
The second methodologic challenge lies in selecting count for this and other types of uncertainty. Economists
the dollar or point estimate(s) of the value of a statistical life often rely on risk assessors and epidemiologists for this
to use. This is a particularly crucial challenge because the technical information.
valuation of death can be the largest component of total
estimated costs in a proposed regulation. What is clear is Some Estimates of the Costs of
that, although the method for how economists value pre- Foodborne Disease
mature deaths has evolved over time, WTP is now the “gold
Golan et al31 reviewed the history of cost estimates
standard” among economists as equating to benefits. What
of foodborne illness. The Economic Research Service
is less clear is which WTP dollar or point estimate(s) to use
(ERS) of the USDA conducted some of the earliest stud-
as a value of a statistical life. This choice matters when
ies on the economic costs of foodborne illness in the
estimating total anticipated benefits and net benefits of
United States (eg, Roberts, 198934; Roberts and Pinner,
implementing a food safety rule. For example, Roberts et
199035; Roberts and Frenkel, 199036). Over time, ERS
al30 performed a sensitivity analysis of using either a value of
updated and expanded these analyses with improved es-
statistical life estimate of $12,000 –$1,585,000, depending
timation methods and better data. Each series of ERS
on age, or a $5 million value per statistical life in their
estimates incorporated better information on disease in-
benefit– cost analysis of the HACCP for meat and poultry.
cidence, more detailed data on the health consequences
Estimates of maximum potential benefits of HACCP over
of foodborne illness, and advances in the economic meth-
20 years varied dramatically between these 2 scenarios.
Members of different parts of the US federal government ods for valuing health outcomes. The initial estimates
use different WTP point estimates of the value of a statis- reflected the limited information then available about the
tical life.31 incidence of foodborne illness and used the COI method
to tally expenditures on medical care and lost productiv-
Deciding Whether to Adjust for Age or ity because of nonfatal illness and premature death.
Preexisting Health Status Figure 5 presents an example of a disease-outcome tree
The third methodologic issue under debate is for an ERS COI study on STEC O157. The initial acute
whether the WTP value of statistical life estimate(s) illnesses (all cases, not just foodborne) are subdivided by the
should be adjusted for age or preexisting health status. severity of the outcome over the patients’ lifetime. The most
That is, there is controversy whether WTP for mortality severe complication in this example is HUS. Some HUS
risk reductions should be calculated on the expected cases develop end-stage renal disease. Although only a small
remaining years of life lost as a result of the premature share of cases develop HUS, the results are severe, are long-
death or if it should account for the preexisting health lasting, and have higher per capita costs than those with
status.32 For example, the elderly may be more suscepti- milder illnesses. Recently, ERS’s online Foodborne Illness
ble to a foodborne illness because they are more likely to Cost Calculator began providing information on the as-
have a comorbidity that affects their ability to respond. sumptions behind foodborne illness cost estimates for Sal-
In theory, there is no reason to suspect that individuals monella and STEC O157, giving Internet users a chance to
(ie, particularly of different ages) would all have the same make their own assumptions and to calculate cost estimates
WTP. The practical questions are whether such differ- themselves.37,38
ences really exist, and can these differences be accounted Several studies around the world were published about
for when estimating WTP. The analysis of STEC O157 foodborne disease costs, mostly in developed countries
infections by Frenzen et al33 is one example of a study where better incidence and other data are available. A
that adjusted for age. Estimated costs of premature death sample of published cost estimates for foodborne disease
ranged from $1.8 million for an adult older than 85 years both from the United States and other countries are
to $9.3 million for an infant. Deaths were grouped into provided in Table 4. Study coverage varied considerably.
5-year intervals for age. In some cases, estimates were for a single pathogen or a
single outbreak, and, in other cases, estimates were for all
Estimating the Anticipated Effect of a foodborne disease in a country. Estimated costs also
Proposed Rule varied considerably. WTP, COI, and disability-adjusted
A fourth methodologic challenge is to estimate life years (DALYs) are used in the studies presented in
the number of foodborne disease cases that would be Table 4 (see Figure 4 for details on each method).
prevented if a proposed food safety rule were imple- In a study that used the DALY method (Figure 4),
mented. Given the uncertainty of predicting the outcome Havelaar et al43 estimated the average burden, in terms of
of a proposed rule, there is variability in the economic DALYs, during 1990 –1995 of Campylobacter-associated
analysis, and the economic benefits of the foodborne illness in The Netherlands. The study included acute
disease reduction can be overestimated or underesti- gastroenteritis, gastroenteritis-related mortality, and re-
mated. Often sensitivity analyses use a plausible range of sidual symptoms of GBS. The study is an example that
May 2009 HUMAN FOODBORNE DISEASE COSTS 1859

Figure 5. ERS distribution of estimated annual US STEC O157 cases by disease outcomes.

shows that the health burden would have been underes- future earnings foregone because of the illness) at AU$2.5
timated if only diarrheal illness was accounted for. million when the data were not age specific; otherwise the
Using the COI method, Abelson et al47 estimated that study converted this amount to an annual figure for use
the annual cost of foodborne illness in Australia was for each year of life lost (ie, $108,000).
AU$1249 million. This estimate includes costs to indi- Intercountry extrapolations and comparisons of food-
viduals (eg, productivity losses, premature mortality), borne disease cases, deaths, and costs are hindered by
business (eg, food safety recalls), health care services, differences in surveillance systems, estimation methods,
government foodborne illness surveillance and investiga- variations in pathogens included in studies across coun-
tion, and maintenance of food safety systems. Costs were tries, and the structure of databases on foodborne dis-
based on foodborne illness as a result of gastroenteritis, eases and treatments. For example, if estimated costs of
invasive listeriosis, toxoplasmosis, hepatitis A, and select lost productivity are based on real wages, differences in
sequelae (HUS, irritable bowel syndrome, GBS, and reac- the average income level between developing and devel-
tive arthritis). The study used a human capital valuation oped countries would prohibit a reasonable comparison
of a life lost (ie, estimates that represent the value of and may be deemed unethical by some. These are some of

Table 4. Sample of Estimated Costs of Foodborne Diseases


Study Estimated
Study method Foodborne disease cost Country costs/burden
Yule et al, 198839 COI Poultry-borne salmonellosis outbreak) Scotland £200,000–£900,000
Todd, 198940 COI Acute bacterial FBD Canada ⬍$1.1 billion
United States ⬍$7 billion
Roberts, 198934 COI All bacterial FBD United States $4.8 billion
Roberts and Pinner, 199035 COI Listeria monocytogenes United States $480 million
Roberts and Frenkel, 199036 COI Congenital toxoplasmosis United States $0.4–$8.8 billion
Razem and Katusin–Razem, 199441 COI All reported FBD Croatia ⬎$2 million
Roberts and Upton, 200042 COI STEC O157:H7 outbreak United Kingdom £11,930,347
Buzby and Roberts, 19978 COI 6 bacteria, 1 parasite United States $6.5–$34.9 billion
Havelaar et al, 200043 DALY Campylobacter sp. Netherlands 1400 DALY per case
Scott et al, 200044 COI All FBD New Zealand $55.1 million
Lindqvist et al, 200145 COI FBD Sweden $123 million
Abe et al, 200246 COI STEC O157:H7 outbreak Japan ¥82,686,000
Frenzen et al, 200533 COI STEC O157 United States $344 million
Abelson et al, 200647 COI All FBD Australia AU$1,249 million
Roberts, 200748 WTP All FBD United States $1.4 trillion

COI, cost-of-illness; DALY, disability-adjusted life year; FBD, foodborne disease; STEC O157, Shiga toxin-producing Escherichia coli O157; WTP,
willingness-to-pay.
1860 BUZBY AND ROBERTS GASTROENTEROLOGY Vol. 136, No. 6

the reasons for the trend toward using DALYs instead of meet certain conditions.29,51,52 In particular, the eco-
monetary measures. In addition, the use of different nomic analysis requires agencies to provide a detailed
values of statistical life estimates can lead to dramatic benefit– cost analysis for all regulatory action that is
differences in the per capita costs in the total cost esti- likely to result in a rule that could have an annual effect
mates, which might preclude meaningful comparisons. on the economy of ⱖ$100 million.29 In short, US policy
For example, the value of statistical life of AU$2.5 million makers usually need cost estimates for ⱖ1 specific food-
used by Abelson et al47 in Australia is much less than the borne diseases, at a minimum, to put efficient, appropri-
$5.4 million currently used as the default in the ERS cost ate, and targeted programs in place to prevent or reduce
calculator for deaths from salmonellosis, even after ac- foodborne disease.
counting for the exchange rate.37 Although surveillance No blueprint is available for conducting an economic
systems will never be the same for all countries (eg, analysis, and different regulations may call for different
different coverage of foodborne diseases and their analytical approaches and emphases.29 OMB’s Circular
chronic complications), the more similar they are, the A-4 (2003) provides greater detail on the purpose of these
more defensible the intercountry comparisons of food- economic analyses and the elements that most economic
borne cases and associated deaths. analyses should include.29 The economic analysis should
As an extension of the WHO consultation to esti- include a benefit– cost analysis, in which the estimated
mate the Global Burden of Foodborne Disease initia- costs of a foodborne illness are often incorporated, to
tive, the Foodborne Disease Burden Epidemiology represent the benefits that might accrue if a proposed
Reference Group was established.49 This group is fol- program reduces or prevents foodborne illnesses and
lowing through on a set of recommendations and a associated deaths. In general, governments are increas-
strategic framework that were developed in September ingly required to make greater use of benefit– cost anal-
2006. These recommendations included elements of a yses to evaluate policy changes, because of increased
standard protocol for conducting the studies in coun- demand for regulatory accountability.3
tries around the world to obtain estimates for all major
causes of foodborne disease, including microbial, par- Discussion
asitic, and chemical contamination of food. The study To completely estimate the societal costs for all
builds on existing protocols in countries and modifies foodborne diseases worldwide, all foodborne diseases would
them according to regional or national capacities. The need to be included in the analysis. Such a study would
initiative encourages countries with limited data to include all known viral, bacterial, parasitic, and non-micro-
estimate their foodborne disease burden because these biologic agents and the gastrointestinal foodborne diseases
estimates can catalyze valuable research and can assist of unknown causes as well as all of the chronic sequelae
policy development.10 Countries are encouraged to caused by acute foodborne infection. Such a study would
translate the effect of each disease into a single mea- also account for all of the costs to individuals or house-
sure, the DALY. Preliminary incidence estimates have holds, industry, and the regulatory and public health sector
been developed in some countries, but at the time of listed in Table 3 for each disease transmitted through food.
writing this article, published DALYs from this study To date, the empirical evidence is noncomparable and piece-
were not available. meal.3 But if such a study were possible, the worldwide costs
could be substantial. Roberts48 estimated the annual cost of
US Policy Evaluations all foodborne diseases in the United States to be $1.4 tril-
Different US agencies have estimated foodborne lion; this value might be too high because of factors such as
disease costs when this information is required, and some protest bids, but there are also reasons why this study might
of these estimates have been used in food safety rule have underestimated the total costs, such as the chronic
making. For example, Buzby et al50 provide a detailed sequelae that were not included. If instead, we consider the
explanation of 3 food safety rules that incorporated the more modest cost estimate for 6 foodborne bacteria and 1
costs of foodborne illnesses in their economic analyses: parasite in the United States of $6.5–$34.9 billion as a base
(1) USDA’s Food Safety and Inspection Service PR/ from which to informally extrapolate to a global estimate of
HACCP rule for meat and poultry in 1996, (2) the Salmo- foodborne disease,8 we would then need to consider that
nella Enteritidis rule for shell eggs in 2000, and (3) FDA’s there may be ⬎200 other microbiologic agents that cause
proposed rule for ready-to-eat meat and poultry prod- foodborne disease and that there are ⬎200 other countries
ucts. Golan et al31 also provided examples of US federal that also incur foodborne disease costs.
agencies’ evaluations of the benefits of food safety pro- Developing estimates of the cost or burden of disease,
grams which estimated the value of reductions in food- either nationally or globally, is challenging because data
borne health risks. on foodborne disease and their chronic sequelae are fre-
In the United States, Executive Order 12866 (and the quently only partially available or fragmented.10 Collec-
updated version, Executive Order 13422) directs agencies tively, the epidemiologic and methodologic challenges
to conduct an economic analysis of all regulations that discussed here weaken the ability of analysts to provide
May 2009 HUMAN FOODBORNE DISEASE COSTS 1861

federal regulators with accurate information needed for 2. Käfferstein FK. Food safety as a public health issue for develop-
efficient and effective decision making on food safety ing countries. In: Unnevehr LJ, ed. Food safety in food security
and food trade. Brief 2 of 17. Washington DC: International Food
policies and public health priorities. All aspects of the
Policy Research Institute, September 2003.
economic analyses for food safety regulations could ben- 3. Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development
efit from better epidemiologic data and more refined (OECD), World Health Organization (WHO). Foodborne disease in
methods that are more widely supported. Despite these OECD countries: present states and economic costs. Paris,
data limitations and challenges, understanding the eco- France: OECD, 2003.
nomics behind foodborne disease, particularly total 4. Mead PS, Slutsker L, Dietz V, et al. Food-related illness and death
in the United States. Emerging Infect Dis 1999;5:607– 625.
costs, can enhance our understanding of food safety 5. Economic Research Service, US Department of Agriculture. Food-
issues and how best to control them. However, costs of borne illness cost calculator: STEC O157. Washington, DC:
implementing new food safety prevention and control Economic Research Service, US Dept of Agriculture, 2008. Avail-
rules must be weighed against the estimated benefits of able at: www.ers.usda.gov/Data/FoodborneIllness/ecoli_Intro.
reducing foodborne disease (ie, costs of adverse health asp. Accessed October 8, 2008.
outcomes averted because of the rule) to determine net 6. Jones TF, Scallan E, Angulo FJ. FoodNet: overview of a decade of
achievement. Foodborne Pathog Dis 2007;4:60 – 66.
benefits so that governments have information to effi- 7. Scallan E. Activities, achievements, and lessons learned during
ciently allocate funds among competing programs. the first 10 years of foodborne diseases active surveillance net-
Foodborne diseases are preventable. The incidence of work: 1996 –2005. Clin Infect Dis 2007;44:718 –725.
some foodborne diseases has diminished during the past 8. Buzby JC, Roberts T. Economic costs and trade impacts of mi-
decade because food safety regulations and improve- crobial foodborne illness. World Health Stat Q 1997;50:5– 66.
9. Snowdon JA, Buzby JC, Roberts T. Epidemiology, cost, and risk of
ments in the food industry’s food safety practices and
foodborne disease. In: Cliver D, Riemann H. eds. Foodborne
processes were implemented. If the food production and diseases. 2nd ed. Amsterdam, The Netherlands: Elsevier Press,
marketing chain supplied meals to consumers virtually 2002:31–51.
free of pathogens, there would be very little foodborne 10. World Health Organization (WHO). WHO consultation to develop a
disease. To produce food virtually free of pathogens, the strategy to estimate the global burden of foodborne diseases:
food industry and the government would have to take taking stock and charting the way forward. Geneva, Switzerland:
WHO, September 25–27, 2006.
additional actions to prevent contamination with food-
11. US Centers for Disease Control and Prevention (CDC). Foodborne
borne pathogens. illness. Atlanta, GA: CDC, 2008. Available at: www.cdc.gov/ncidod/
Much better pathogen control could be produced at dbmd/diseaseinfo/foodborneinfections_g.htm. Accessed Septem-
low cost if industry were given stronger economic incen- ber 3, 2008.
tives to produce safer food, particularly by government. 12. US Centers for Disease Control and Prevention (CDC). Prelimi-
For a number of economic reasons discussed in Golan et nary FoodNet data on the incidence of infection with pathogens
transmitted commonly through food—10 States, 2007. MMWR
al,31 the food industry has weak incentives to supply the
Morb Mortal Wkly Rep 2008;57,14;366 –370.
optimal level of food safety for society. Buzby et al53 13. Frenzen PD. Mortality due to gastroenteritis of unknown etiology
found that the risk of court-awarded compensation from in the United States. J Infect Dis 2003;187:441– 452.
lawsuits for microbial foodborne illness creates only 14. Frenzen PD. Deaths due to unknown foodborne agents. Emerging
weak economic incentives for firms to produce safer Infect Dis 2004;10:1536 –1543.
food. One use of information on the economic costs of 15. Pathogen reduction; hazard analysis and critical control point
(HACCP) systems, final rule. Fed Reg July 25, 1996;61(144):
foodborne disease is to help government set priorities for 38805–3989.
foodborne disease prevention and control. In turn, using 16. Denno DM, Keene WE, Hutter CM, et al. Tri-county comprehen-
information is one way that the government could pro- sive assessment of risk factors for sporadic bacterial enteric
vide stronger economic incentives for industry to provide infections in children. J Infect Dis 2009;199:467– 476.
safer food. For example, if the government required that 17. Batz MB, Doyle MP, Morris JG, et al. Attributing illness to food.
Emerging Infect Dis 2005;11:993–999.
more pathogen testing be done weekly for each food
18. Raybourne RB, Williams KM, Roberts T. Food poisoning: eco-
plant and required that these tests be publicly available nomic implications. In: Encyclopedia of food sciences and nutri-
(such as posted on the Internet), companies would have tion. Vol 1, Iss 1. London, United Kingdom: Elsevier Science Ltd,
much stronger incentives to invest in new food safety 2003:2672–2682.
innovations and adopt existing methods to provide safer 19. Maxion-Bergemann S, Thielecke F, Abel F, et al. Costs of irritable
food. These methods include more sensitive tests, new bowel syndrome in the UK and US. Pharmacoeconomics 2006;
24:21–37.
equipment, as well as new management systems. For
20. Buzby JC, Roberts T, Mishu Allos B. Estimated annual costs of
many foodborne diseases, it is preferable to implement Campylobacter-associated Guillain-Barré Syndrome. Washington,
several prevention steps simultaneously.54 DC: US Dept of Agriculture, Economic Research Service, July
1997. Publication AER-756. Available at: www.ers.usda.gov/
References publications/Aer756/. Accessed April 6, 2009.
1. World Health Organization (WHO). Food safety and foodborne 21. Werber D, Mason BW, Evans MR, et al. Preventing household
illness. Geneva, Switzerland: WHO, 2008. Available at: www. transmission of Shiga toxin-producing Escherichia coli O157 in-
who.int/mediacentre/factsheets/fs237/en/. Accessed Septem- fection: promptly separating siblings might be the key. Clin Infect
ber 22, 2008. Dis 2008;46:1189 –1196.
1862 BUZBY AND ROBERTS GASTROENTEROLOGY Vol. 136, No. 6

22. Tarr PI, Gordon CA, Chandler WL. Shiga-toxin-producing Esche- 40. Todd ECD. Preliminary estimates of costs of foodborne disease
richia coli and haemolytic uraemic syndrome. Lancet 2005;365: in Canada and costs to reduce salmonellosis. J Food Prot 1989;
1073–1086. 52:586 –594.
23. Kimmitt PT, Harwood CR, Barer MR. Toxin gene expression by 41. Razem D, Katusin-Razem B. The incidence and costs of food-
Shiga toxin-producing Escherichia coli: the role of antibiotics and borne diseases in Croatia. J Food Prot 1994;57:746 –752.
the bacterial SOS response. Emerging Infect Dis. 2000;6:458 – 42. Roberts JA, Upton PA. E. coli O157: an economic assessment of
465. an outbreak. Edinburgh, United Kingdom: Lothian Health Board,
24. Ake JA, Jelacic S, Ciol MA, et al. Relative nephroprotection during 2000.
Escherichia coli O157:H7 infections: association with intrave- 43. Havelaar AH, De Wit MAS, Van Koningsveld R, et al. Health
nous volume expansion. Pediatrics 2005;115:e673– e680. burden in the Netherlands due to infection with thermophilic
25. Buzby JC, Roberts T, Lin CTJ, et al. Bacterial foodborne disease: Campylobacter spp. Epidemiol Infect 2000;125:505–522.
medical costs and productivity losses. Washington, DC: US Dept 44. Scott WG, Scott HM, Lake RJ, et al. Economic cost to New
of Agriculture, Economic Research Service, August 1996. Publi- Zealand of foodborne infectious disease. N Z Med J 2000;113:
cation AER-741. 281–284.
26. Kuchler F, Golan E. Assigning values to life: comparing methods 45. Lindqvist R, Andersson Y, Lindbäck J, et al. A one-year study of
for valuing health risks. Washington, DC: Economic Research foodborne illnesses in the municipality of Uppsala, Sweden.
Service, US Department of Agriculture, 1999. Publication AER- Emerging Infect Dis 2001;7(3 Suppl):588 –592.
784. 46. Abe K, Yamamoto S, Shinagawa K. Economic impact of an Esch-
27. Gold MR, Stevenson D, Fryback DG. HALYs and QALYs and erichia coli O157:H7 in Japan. J Food Prot 2002;65:66 –72.
DALYS, oh my: similarities and differences in summary measures 47. Abelson P, Forbes MP, Hall G. The annual cost of foodborne
of population health. Annu Rev Public Health 2002;23:115–134. illness in Australia. Commonwealth of Australia: Australian Gov-
28. Carabin H, Budke CM, Cowan LD, et al. Methods for assessing ernment Department of Health and Ageing, March 2006.
the burden of parasitic zoonoses: echinococcosis and cysticer- 48. Roberts T. WTP estimates of the societal cost of US food-borne
cosis. Trends Parasitol 2005;21:327–333. illness. Am J Agric Econ 2007;5:1183–1188.
29. Office of Management and Budget (OMB). Circular A-4, regula- 49. Stein C, Kuchenmüller T, Hendrickx S, et al. The global burden of
tory analysis. Washington, DC: OMB, September 17, 2003. disease assessments—WHO is responsible? PLoS Negl Trop Dis
Available at: www.whitehouse.gov/omb/circulars/a004/a-4. 2007;1:e161.
50. Buzby J, Spinelli F, Nardinelli C. Evaluating US food safety regu-
html. Accessed October 1, 2008.
lations which use benefit and cost information. In: Roberts, J, ed.
30. Roberts T, Buzby J, Ollinger M. Using benefit and cost information
The economics of infectious disease. Oxford: Oxford University
to evaluate a food safety regulation: HACCP for meat and poultry.
Press, 2006:299 –325.
Am J Agric Econ 1996;78:1297–1301.
51. Office of Management and Budget (OMB). Economic analysis of
31. Golan E, Buzby J, Crutchfield S, et al. The value to consumers of
federal regulations under executive order 12866. Washington
reducing foodborne risks. In: Hoffmann S, Taylor M, eds. Toward
DC: OMB, January 11, 1996. Available at: www.whitehouse.gov/
safer food: perspectives of risk and priority setting. Washington,
omb/inforeg/riaguide.html. Accessed November 6, 2001.
DC: Resources for the Future, 2005.
52. Office of Management and Budget (OMB). Executive order: further
32. Alberini A, Cropper M, Krupnick A, et al. Does the value of a
amendment to executive order 12866 on regulatory planning and
statistical life vary with age and health status? Evidence from the
review. Washington, DC: OMB, January 18, 2007. Available at:
US and Canada. J Environ Econ Manage 2004;48:769 –792.
www.whitehouse.gov/news/releases/2007/01/20070118.html.
33. Frenzen PD, Drake A, Angulo, FJ, and the Emerging Infections
Accessed October 15, 2008.
Program FoodNet Working Group. Economic cost of illness due to
53. Buzby JC, Frenzen PD, Rasco B. Product liability and microbial
Escherichia coli O157 infections in the United States. J Food
foodborne illness. Washington, DC: US Dept of Agriculture, Eco-
Prod 2005;68:2623–2630. nomic Research Service, April 2001. Publication AER 799. Avail-
34. Roberts T. Human illness costs of foodborne bacteria. Am J Agric able at: www.ers.usda.gov/publications/aer799/. Accessed
Econ 1989;71:468 – 474. April 6, 2009.
35. Roberts T, Pinner R. Economic impact of disease caused by 54. Tauxe RV. Emerging foodborne disease: an evolving public health
Listeria monocytogenes. In: Miller, AJ, Smith JL, Somkuti GA, challenge. Emerging Infect Dis 1997;3:425– 434.
eds. Foodborne listeriosis. Amsterdam, The Netherlands:
Elsevier Science Publishing Co, 1990:137–149.
36. Roberts T, Frenkel JK. Estimating income losses and other pre- Received October 31, 2008. Accepted January 13, 2009.
ventable costs caused by congenital toxoplasmosis in people in
the United States. J Am Vet Med Assoc 1990;196:249 –256. Reprint requests
37. Economic Research Service, US Dept of Agriculture. Foodborne Address requests for reprints to: Jean C, Buzby, PhD, Economic
illness cost calculator. Washington, DC: Economic Research Ser- Research Service, 1800 M Street NW, Room S2080, Washington,
vice, US Dept. of Agriculture, 2008. Available at: www.ers.usda. D.C. 20036-5831. e-mail: jbuzby@ers.usda.gov; fax: (202) 694-5688.
gov/Data/FoodborneIllness/. Accessed August 18, 2008.
38. Frenzen PD. An online cost calculator for estimating the eco- Acknowledgments
nomic cost of illness due to Shiga toxin-producing E. coli (STEC) The views expressed here are those of the authors and may not
O157 infections. Washington, DC: US Dept of Agriculture, Economic be attributed to the Economic Research Service or the US
Research Service, September 2007. Publication EIB-28. Department of Agriculture.
39. Yule BF, Macleod AF, Sharp JC, et al. Costing of a hospital-based
outbreak of poultry-borne Salmonellosis. Epidemiol Infect 1988; Conflicts of interest
100:35– 42. The authors disclose no conflicts.

You might also like