Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 15

Channel Evolution: A Framework

for Analysis

Arun Sharma
University of Miami

Luis V. Dominguez
University of Miami

This article proposes a comprehensive model for analyz- This paper presents a conceptual framework based on
ing the environmental forces that affect channel length. The transactional cost analysis (Williamson 1975, 1981)which
marketing literature regards channel length as a succinct, suggests how a nation s economic evolution affects channel
key measure of channel structure. Transactional cost analy- length, a key aspect of channel structure. Channel length is
sis offers an integrative explanation of the seemingly con- defined as the configuration of institutions, agencies, and
tradictory phenomena and varied interpretations found in establishments through which products move to their final
the channels literature. The central thesis of this article is users (Stern and E1-Ansary 1988). The proposed framework
that the developmental process alters the balance between makes several contributions. First, it resolves a number of
performing channel tasks externally and internally and inconsistencies found in the literature on channel length.
thereby channel structure. The article also interprets from a Second, and perhaps most importantly, the framework en-
transactional cost perspective how selected cultural, politi- compasses the range of partial explanations for channel
cal, and urban market concentration factors account for length found in the literature, integrating them within a
enduring differences in channel structure among nations at make-or-buy transactional cost framework. Third, in con-
similar levels of development. trast with prior research, which has tacitly assumed a uni-
directional and universal evolution of channels, the frame-
work accounts for: (a) factors that may accelerate, slow, or
even reverse thre evolution of channel length; and (b) evolu-
INTRODUCTION tionary patterns specific to countries with certain environ-
ments. Finally, whereas most transactional cost analysis has
Understanding the factors that give rise to and affect the focused on micro-level decisions of individual firms, the
proposed framework extends transactional cost analysis to
evolution of channel structure is considered among the fun-
the macro or societal level.
damental tasks of channel research. In recent years there has
been a rekindling of interest in channels research. However, The article begins with a discussion of the importance of
most studies have taken the perspective of the individual channel length in the marketing literature. This is followed
by an examination of the range of alternative findings and
firm's strategy. Very little is known about the factors that
explanations of the relationship between economic develop-
shape a nation's channel system: "Apparently, the relation-
ship between a country's channel structure and its environ- merit and channel length. The third section presents a trans-
actional cost explanation of how the major forces associated
merit remains largely undefined. How else to explain the
channels of distribution in a country remains a matter of with the developmental process affect channel length. The
speculation" (Jain 1990, p. 488). next two sections explain how transactional costs affect the
evolution of channel length in developing and developed
countries, respectively. The following section explains how
Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science ISSN: 0092-0703 key cultural and political factors as well as urban market
Volume 20, Number 1, pages 1-15. concentration account for enduring differences in channel
Copyright 9 1992 by Academy of Marketing Science. structure among nations at similar levels of development.
All rights of reproduction in any form reserved. The final section discusses implications for channel policy
This article was accepted by the previous editor. and research.

JAMS 1 WINTER, 1992


CHANNEL EVOLUTION:A FRAMEWORKFOR ANALYSIS SHARMA AND DOMINGUEZ

IMPORTANCE OF THE TOPIC tries . . . . newly industrialized countries . . . . and com-


munist countries."
It is expected that increased global competition will ac- Understanding the factors that give rise to differences in
celerate the evolution of channels of distribution around the channel structure among countries and the forces that may
world as multinational firms achieve closer and more inte- induce or hinder channel evolution is considered among the
grated relationships with their final clients (Terpstra 1987, fundamental tasks of channel research (Anderson 1985;
p. 58). Buyers and sellers are reportedly entering into long- Dwyer and Welsh 1985; John and Weitz 1988; Klein,
term contractual relationships and strategic alliances that in Frazier, and Roth 1990; Stern and Reve 1980). Market
effect restructure channels of distribution and internalize structure has been described as the configuration or length
transactions (Arndt 1979). Countervailing this tendency to- of the channel (i.e., the number of channel members in-
ward increased vertical integration is the greater investment volved) and the allocation of functions among channel
in financial and managerial resources involved in managing members (Rosenbloom 1987, pp. 155-158; Stern and E1-
foreign channels in unknown settings (Anderson and Ansary 1988, pp. 10-11). Channel configuration (i.e.,
Coughlan 1987). length) represents the complexity of the channel system,
Moreover, vertical integration decisions are akin to fixed reflecting the external environment of the channel and influ-
capital investments in that once made, they are difficult to encing as well as being influenced by its internal polity, i.e.,
reverse. For example, firms tend to pyramid new products its centralization, formalization, and participation in the al-
into existing channels (Anderson and Coughlan 1987). location of channel functions (Dwyer and Welsh 1985;
Managers need frameworks not only for understanding the Dwyer and Oh 1988; John and Reve 1982). Thus, channel
present costs of alternate degrees of vertical integration but length is a concise and influential characteristic of channel
also to envision the direction in which channel structures structure.
will evolve in different countries around the world and the Shorter channels suggest some degree of vertical integra-
forces inducing or impeding change, so that they can design tion and the presence of large scale intermediaries, most
channels that will remain efficient over a long planning likely wholesalers (Bucklin 1970a) or large multinational
horizon. enterprises engaging in forward integration (Anderson and
A decade ago, responding to institutional research which Coughlan 1987; Klein 1986, 1989). Vertical integration oc-
he termed "primarily descriptive and classificatory rather curs when channel members feel that they can increase effi-
than explanatory and theoretical," Arndt (1981, pp. 36-37) ciency of or control over channel functions by circumvent-
called for a new institutionalism, based on the political ing other channel members (Anderson 1985; Day and Klein
economy approach (Stern and Reve 1980; Zald 1970), shed- 1987; Etgar and Zusman 1982; John and Weitz 1988;
ding the assumptions of pure competition, perfect informa- McGuire and Staelin 1983a, 1983b). On the other hand,
tion, and costless transactions found in the neoclassical longer channels indicate that a larger number of firms are
model and its concern with equilibrium states. Rather, he involved in the distribution function. This suggests that in-
believed that institutionalism should be intimately involved termediaries are being integrated into wider geographic net-
with transaction costs and the processes of change (Arndt works (Bromley 1971) or that channel functions are being
1981, p. 39). Much progress has been made since then in spun off to additional intermediaries (Mallen 1975) because
gaining a better understanding of the forces shaping channel increased market size permits greater specialization in the
structure. Transactional cost studies have examined vertical open market. These intermediaries are being added be-
integration decisions from the standpoint of market failure. cause of their specialized skills, e.g., for their ability to
Under pure competition and perfect information, channel efficiently serve large urban centers (Dannhauser 1981;
functions are most efficiently performed in the open market; Forman and Riegelhaupt 1970; Guiltinan 1974; Kaynak
transaction costs are incurred only when market imperfec- 1982, pp. 162-165).
tions make it necessary to monitor and enforce the behavior Channel length is also an important public policy issue.
of channel members, opening the possibility that firms Governments in many developing countries have instituted
might perform some or all of those functions more effi- centrally administered vertical distribution systems, bypass-
ciently (e.g., Anderson and Coughlan 1987; Anderson and ing traditional channels. These efforts have not been suc-
Gatignon 1986; John 1984; John and Weitz 1988; Klein cessful in many instances because policy makers over-
1989). looked the value of individual entrepreneurship and the
Unfortunately, this research has remained rather narrow forces that created indigenous channels in the first place
in scope, focusing on domestic or export channels of (Dahringer 1983; Etgar 1983; FAO 1982; Kumcu and Kum-
developed-country firms. There have been few exceptions cu 1987; Savitt 1988) and because the ramifications of pub-
(e.g., Etgar 1983; Frazier, Gill, and Kale t989; Kale 1986; lic policy decisions were not anticipated (Dholakia and
Klein 1986). Frazier, Gill, and Kale (1989, pp. 66-67) have Kurana 1983; Riley and Statz 1981). Striking the proper
argued that "increased attention must be directed in the balance among economic and social goals, vertical coor-
future to international channel issues to promote progress in dination, and entrepreneurial initiative has been a continu-
the channels area. Continuing to study domestic channels ing theme of policy-oriented channel studies, particularly
almost exclusively will yield little, if any, insight into how for essential consumption items (e.g., Dholakia and Kurana
channel relationships operate in foreign countries. Addition- 1983; E1-Ansary 1984; Meissner 1987; Slater 1970; Slater
al research on channels in developed countries is needed, et al. 1969; Varadarajan 1984).
but such research is also needed in underdeveloped coun- Channel length has also been regarded as a major focal

JAMS 2 WINTER, 1992


CHANNEL EVOLUTION:A FRAMEWORKFOR ANALYSIS SHARMA AND DOMINGUEZ

point of comparative analysis of marketing systems; it is derson and Coughlan 1987; Dwyer and Welsh 1985; John
often cited in the comparative literature as a succinct indica- and Weitz 1988; Klein 1989; Klein, Frazier and Roth 1990).
tor of channel structure (Boddewynn 1981; El-Ansary and Also excluded, because of their limited scope, are studies
Liebrenz 1982; Kaynak 1982, pp. 112-116; Kaynak and which deal with individual channel dyads found only in
Hudanah 1987; Mallen 1975). certain industries or activities, e.g., insurance agencies
Finally, channel length is an important strategic decision (Etgar 1974, 1978) or hardware cooperatives and voluntary
for the firm. Much of the literature on channel length ad- groups (Dwyer and Oh 1988). Similarly excluded are stud-
dresses the conditions under which vertical integration re- ies addressing the number of outlets of a certain type within
duces costs or improves profitability (e.g., Anderson and a channel level, since they do not deal with channel length
Coughlan 1987; Bhasin and Stem 1982; Buzzell 1983; per se (e.g., Corstjens and Doyle 1979).
Dwyer and Welsh 1985; Klein, Frazier and Roth 1990; Two channel studies in Table 1 employ mathematical
Stem and Reve 1980). In the international arena, global analyses to derive propositions about the effects of the de-
firms are seeking closer linkages with channels and with velopmental process on channel structure under certain re-
9final customers that will allow faster introduction of suc- strictive assumptions (Bucklin 1970b; Preston 1970). Two
cessful brands into other countries (Business Week 1990a, other papers by McGuire and Staelin (t983a, 1983b) and a
1990b; Terpstra 1987). subsequent generalization and empirical test by Coughlan
In summary, channel length is strategically significant at (1985) are included as tangentially relevant to the effects of
the micro level to individual finns and hierarchies attempt- development on channel length. 1 McGuire and Staelin
ing to enhance profits and lower costs. It is important at the (1983a, 1983b) employ game theoretic approaches assum-
macro level to researchers and public policy officials trying ing certain restrictive channel conditions (i.e., one-level
to better understand the forces that shape the organization of channel, bilateral monopoly, retailers sell exclusively one
the exchange system. This article is primarily concerned manufacturer's or wholesaler's product, no scale or scope
with macro level issues. Its goal is to develop a framework economies, and no transaction costs) to test the effect of
that spans the patterns of differences and regularities found product substitutability on individual or collective profit
in different nations' channel structures. It is concerned with maximization. Their models and a subsequent extension
such questions as: Why have channels shortened in some and empirical verification by Coughlan (1985) conclude
nations, e.g., Australia (Layton 1989)? Why have some that high substitutability makes it more desirable for man-
studies (e.g., Wadinambiaratchi 1965) suggested that chan- ufacturers to work through contracted retail outlets than to
nels lengthen as countries develop? Why are Japanese chan- own company stores. Channel disintegration is favored in
nels longer than those found in the U.S., despite the fact highly price-competitive environments on the ground that it
that both nations are at comparable levels of development isolates producers (or wholesalers) from end-market price
(Shimagushi and Lazer 1979)? competition (Coughlan 1985). Although McGuire-Staelin-
Coughlan do not directly address the developmental pro-
cess, discussion later in this article argues that more intense
AN ASSESSMENT OF THE LITERATURE competition and a wider range of product alternatives are
ON CHANNEL LENGTH conditions associated with buyers' markets (Frazier, Gill,
and Kale 1989; Kale 1986) found in highly developed
Consistent with the goals of the study, the relevant litera- market economies. It could therefore be reasoned from
ture is that which seeks to explain how external environ- McGuire-Staelin-Coughlan that channels should lengthen as
mental forces affect the internal structure of the channel and economies develop, contrary to most of the empirical evi-
more specifically, channel length. However, as Stem and dence from developed countries presented in Table 1.
Reve (1980) argue, external forces are best understood As can be seen in Table 1, the studies make divergent
when they are related to the manner in which they affect and predictions. Some conclude that channels lengthen as na-
work through the internal political economy of the channel. tions develop; others conclude just the opposite; still a third
Therefore, the discussion particularly emphasizes the inter- group asserts that channels first lengthen, then shorten. Fur-
nal mechanisms through which environmental influences ther examination of the literature raises additional issues
effect differences in channel length. which underlie these contradictory claims.
Table 1 describes each of the studies, its predicted rela- The nature of the evidence. About half of the studies are
tionship between development and channel length, whether conceptual developments not subjected to any formal test;
focusing on developed or developing countries, and the sup- the rest employ widely different methodologies, ranging
porting evidence and/or theoretical explanation for channel from field observation to game theory. Among the studies
length. Selection of studies was guided by two criteria: (a) that employ any statistical measurement or analysis,
the studies either focused on the channel system of one or Wadinambiaratchi (1965) selects only less developed coun-
more countries or on a prototypical channel environment; tries (LDCs); Livesay and Porter (1969) study the U.S.; and
and (b) the studies focused on the configuration of the entire Douglas (1971) and Layton (1989) span both developed
channel, rather than on a particular dyad. countries and LDCs. Of those studies, only Layton's (1989)
Table 1 therefore excludes studies of vertical integration and Livesay and Porter's (1969) analyze time-series data.
which take the perspective of a single finn's strategy, since Such differences in methodology may account for the appar-
they do not address evolution or cross-national differences ent differences in empirical findings (Boddewyn 1981; E1-
in aggregate marketing channels (e.g., Anderson 1985; An- Ansary and Liebrenz 1982).

JAMS 3 WINTER, 1992


CHANNEL EVOLUTION: A FRAMEWORK FOR ANALYSIS SHARMA AND DOMINGUEZ

TABLE 1
Relationship Between Channel Lengths and Economic Development
Level of
Development
Claims/ Addressed/
Author Results Theoretical Support Empirical Test
Bucklin (1970b) Lengthen* Specialization of functions due to increases in volume; number of services All levels/No empirical
performed; opportunity costs of performing alternate activities; breadth of analysis.
product assortment; market decentralization and heterogeneity.
McGuire and Staelin Lengthen Product substitutability; channel disintegration isolates producers from retail Not specified/Tested
(1983a, 1983b); competition. against U.S. sample
Coughlan (1985) by Coughlan (1985).
Wadinambiaratchi Lengthen Separation of functions; emergence of large-scale retailing; decline in the LDCs/Cross-sectional
(1965) role of traditional merchants. data on eight
countries.
Livesay and Porter Shorten Forward integration of manufacturers brought about by intensified Historical records of
(1969) competition and by failure of open market transactions to provide matched set of
broadened distribution; need for greater technical support to customers; vertically integrated
need to provide consumer credit. and nonintegrated
U.S. finns.
Shimagushi and Shorten Factors that propel shorter channel of distribution: large-scale retail chains; Interviews with
Lazer (1979) expanding capacity of manufacturers. Japanese and foreign
Factors that arrest channel evolution: geographic market fragmentation; executives in Japan.
prevalence of small retailers; political clout of small retailers; financial
role of trading houses and interlocking system of mutual obligations; role
of harmony and tradition.
Preston (1970) Shorten Aggregate market size; larger firm sizes; market decentralization and All levels/No empirical
heterogeneity; increased product-related services; shift towards analysis.
bureaucratic management structures; larger size of channel members.
Fonnan and Inverted Marketing systems built around major distribution centers and urban Tracing of production
Riegelhaupt (1970) U-shape population will ultimately lead to restructuring of agricultural production and distribution of
systems. basic food stuffs in
Factors lengthening the channel: concatenation of local distribution systems; Northern Brazil.
use of middlemen at distribution fairs.
Factors shortening channels: middlemen go to source in order to buy in
larger quantities; high degree of middleman capitalization; reliance on
large-sale producers.
Douglas (1971) Inverted U- Limited market opportunities and small size of firms lead to predominantly All levels/Analysis of
shape/ local markets with wholesalers playing a dominant role. cross-sectional data
Found no Channels lengthen with increased market size, larger firms, sellers' market on six countries.
relation- conditions.
ship
Guiltinan (1974) Inverted Evolving competitive objectives of channel members. Not empirical/U.S.
U-shape Factors lengthening channel: increasing customer contact and market historical experiences
coverage. and perspective.
Factors shortening channel: reducing channel costs and increased monitoring
of channel services lead to administered channels; need to further reduce
costs and need for more coordinated effort ultimately lead to vertical
integration.
Layton (1989) Inverted Entropy in channels: tendency of exchange systems to evolve toward greater Time-series data on
U-shape degree of internal organization, trade flows in
Australia and Java.
Mallen (1975); Inverted Functional spin-off theory based on Stigler ( 1951). All levels/Not
Carson (1967) U-shape Factors lengthening channel: market size allows firms to spin off functions empirical.
to specialists.
Factors shortening channel: at high levels of demand and throughput, large
merchants begin to reintegrate.
Mittendorf (1978)** Inverted Theory based on magnitude of consumer demand, size of urban market All levels/Not
U-shape demand, scale advantages of large supermarket chains, empirical.
Factors lengthening channel: increases in income and size of urban market
lead to specialization and increasing advantage of large supermarkets.
Factors shortening channel: achievement of economies of scale and
competitive advantage of supermarkets lead to more direct channels.

*To be read: direction of the relationship between channel length and degree of economic development; as an economy develops, channel will lengthen.
**As reported in other sources.

JAMS 4 WINTER, 1992


CHANNEL EVOLUTION: A FRAMEWORK FOR ANALYSIS SHARMA AND DOMINGUEZ

Lack of a unifying framework. There seems to be univer- make a case that LDCs should encourage domestic firms to
sal consensus that (a) changes in the size of market demand integrate backward into the import channel.
have much to do with the extent of specialization and the
evolution of channel length; (b) efficiency (low-cost perfor- Channel Transaction Costs and the Development
mance of functions) and effectiveness (market coverage, Process
assured delivery of a desired level of service) are key con-
siderations in the choice of intermediary; and (c) channels There is a growing body of transactional cost analysis of
of distribution are highly complex organizational forms that domestic channels (Anderson 1985; Day and Klein 1987;
are expressive not only of the degree of economic develop- Dwyer and Oh 1988; Dwyer and Welsh 1985; Heide and
ment achieved in a nation but of a host of other social, John 1988; John and Weitz 1988) and international channels
political, and historic factors. However, each study suggests (Anderson and Coughlan 1987; Anderson and Gatignon
its own array of variables that somehow intervene to facili- 1986; Bello and Williamson 1985; Etgar 1983; Klein 1986,
tate or impede the evolution of marketing channels. No one 1989; Klein, Frazier, and Roth 1990). Channel decisions
study offers a comprehensive framework that reconciles all may be regarded as a make-or-buy choice that hinges on
of the seemingly different forces shaping channel evolution. transactional costs (Anderson and Coughlan 1987; William-
Teleological assumption. A number of the studies imply son 1981). The decision for a channel member is to either
a unidirectional and deterministic model of evolution to- perform that function internally (make) or to add an external
ward a certain channel organization, e.g., as a society be- channel member (buy). The channel make-or-buy decision
comes more developed, there will be fewer intermediaries ranges from hierarchical to open-market structures with
and channels will shorten. However, there is evidence that firms placing channel decisions on this continuum (Ander-
this unidirectional evolution may be reversed or in fact need son and Coughlan 1987; Klein 1989; Williamson 1981).
not hold. As an example, a study of several decades of The underlying principle is that a firm will perform a task
evolution of distribution channels for electrical appliances internally if it has a total cost advantage over the mar-
in the Philippines found that the channel lengthened, short- ketplace. Transactional cost analysis explicitly recognizes
ened and again lengthened in response to the shifting bal- governance costs in addition to distribution costs. Distribu-
ance of forces for import liberalization and domestic indus- tion costs are those associated with the performance of
try protection (Dannhauser 1981). What is lacking is an channel functions, e.g., transportation, credit, and transfer
explanation of the general set of forces that might bring of title. Governance or "control" costs are those associated
about such a reversal. with planning, executing, and monitoring performance of
channel functions. The make-or-buy decision hinges on the
balance between internal and external costs in these two
CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK categories, i.e.,

Transactional cost analysis offers an integrative theoreti- AC = Internal distribution costs - External distribution
cal explanation of the seemingly contradictory phenomena costs
and wide-ranging relationships found in the channels litera-
ture. Transactional cost analysis examines "the comparative AG = Internal governance costs - External governance
costs of planning, adapting, and monitoring task completion costs
under alternative governance structures" (Williamson 1983,
p. 104). The central thesis of this article is that the develop- When the sum of these categories is positive, i.e., when
mental process alters the balance between performing chan-
nel tasks externally and internally. Shifts in the relationship AC + AG > 0
between external and internal transaction costs explain why
channel length does not grow monotonically with develop- it will be more costly to assume channel functions; those
ment. A number of studies have shown that channel struc- will be assigned to the marketplace. However, when the
ture in some countries (e.g., in Japan) shows a longevity sum is negative, i.e., when
which cannot be explained solely by economic develop-
ment. The paper also incorporates socio-political, cultural, AC + AG < 0
and market concentration factors to explain, within the
transactional cost framework, why channels may evolve at a firms will internalize channel functions.
faster pace in some countries and remain more invariant in Since channel functions are generally performed more
others. The discussion results in a series of verifiable propo- efficiently by the marketplace (Anderson and Coughlan
sitions. The methodological appendix reviews measurement 1987; Williamson 1981), it is expected that AC > 0. Hence,
approaches to verifying the propositions. channels will lengthen as long as AG is either positive or not
The analysis proceeds from the micro level to an explana- sufficiently negative for AC + AG to be negative.
tion of the aggregate implications of individual behaviors. Three factors related to the developmental process drive
Although such aggregation entails some ambiguities (Ven- the value of AC + AG and hence the direction of change in
katesh and Dholakia 1986), it is more than compensated by channel length. They are asset specificity, volume, and ex-
the richness of understanding that it yields on how forces ternalities of "quality debasement" or product/service quali-
within and outside the channel shape its evolution. For ex- ty control (Williamson 1983). Their effects are explained
ample, Klein (1986) employed transactional cost analysis to next.

JAMS 5 WINTER, 1992


CHANNEL EVOLUTION:A FRAMEWORKFOR ANALYSIS SHARMA AND DOMINGUEZ

The first is asset specificity. Intermediaries have certain The spread of the market system, linking local markets
specialized tangible and intangible assets that are critical to into regional networks, increases the separation between
a manufacturer (Anderson and Coughlan 1987; Williamson producer and ultimate consumer. It also provides an oppor-
1983). These specialized assets are advantageous site or tunity for astute producers to increase sales by expanding
location, specialized physical facilities (e.g., repair/ the number of people and communities reached. This corre-
maintenance/service facilities), and human assets (e.g., sponds to what Guiltinan (1974) terms the coverage/
sales personnel with specialized skills). When assets are capacity stage of channel evolution.
very non-specific, producers can easily replace intermedi- In the initial stages of development, marketers will re-
aries, and the latter can turn to alternate sources of supply. spond to the widening scope and rising purchasing potential
The more specific assets required, the lower the value of AC of the domestic market by employing a wider network of
+ AG, giving the marketer an incentive to perform the intermediaries rather than by performing those distribution
function internally (Williamson 1981). The reasons for this functions themselves, e.g., storing, transporting, financing,
are: the cost of specific assets cannot be shared with other wholesaling, and retailing (Mallen, 1977). Increased vol-
products, thereby reducing the cost advantage of the mar- ume also means that firms can achieve significant econo-
ketplace; and specific assets increase the need for control, mies through specialization, so that functions will be spun
increasing the cost of external governance. Recent studies off to specialized intermediaries (Mallen 1975; Stigler
have found that asset specificity leads to increased internal- 1951). As a result of increased volume and opportunities for
ization of channel functions (Anderson 1985; Anderson and greater economies through the use of intermediaries, chan-
Coughlan 1987; John and Weitz 1988; Klein, Frazier, and nels will lengthen (Carson 1967, p. 482; Mallen 1977, pp.
Roth 1990). 1t7-120). This phenomenon has been observed in Africa
The second factor is channel volume. Increased channel (Hill 1963), Jamaica (Katzin 1959), India and Mexico (FAO
volume stimulates internalization of functions (Anderson 1982), and other developing countries (Wadinambiaratchi
1985; Klein, Frazier, and Roth 1990). Transactional cost 1965).
analysis accounts for this phenomenon through two mecha- Transactional cost analysis provides an integrative expla-
nisms: (a) with increasing volume, individual firms can at- nation of the various forces lengthening the channel. There
tain sufficient economies of scale that the difference be- are well documented reasons to expect that the cost of per-
tween internal and external distribution costs diminishes, forming distribution functions internally will be much high-
thereby reducing AC (Klein, Frazier, and Roth 1990; er than the cost of delegating them to intermediaries, and
Williamson 1981); and (b) economies of scale reduce the hence that AC will be highly positive. First, numerous small
cost of internal governance (Anderson 1985). intermediaries are available to perform functions at very
Quality debasement externalities arise with branded prod- low cost. As a small intermediary, barriers to entry into
ucts that are expensive and complex, requiring specialized distribution within primitive societies are quite low (FAO
service, installation, and technical expertise. It is much 1982; Katzin 1959; Kaynak 1982, pp. 20-21); hence dis-
more difficult to monitor intermediaries' compliance with tribution serves as an employer of last resort, attracting the
producers' service standards. As a result, external gover- unemployed and marginally employed, who earn little more
nance costs will rise for those products (Anderson 1985; than average wages for their activities (Harrison et al. 1974;
Bowen and Jones 1986; John and Weitz 1988), thereby re- Kaynak 1982, pp. 108-110; Keegan 1974, p. 344; Slater et
ducing the value of AG, and thus AC + AG. Hence, chan- al. 1969, p. 74). Second, intermediaries will be in a better
nels of distribution are expected to shorten and become position than producers to achieve volume economies. The
more vertically integrated with increasing demand for goods reason is that intermediaries can readily increase volume by
that involve high asset specificity and quality debasement widening their scope (variety of goods handled). William-
externalities. son argues from a transactional cost perspective that a man-
The tendency for channels to first lengthen and then ufacturer is more likely to diversify into production of other
shorten as development proceeds can be explained in terms products--where its expertise lies--than to both integrate
of the relative importance of asset specificity, channel vol- forward and handle a wider variety of goods as an inter-
ume, and quality debasement externalities. The next two mediary (Williamson 1983, pp. 106, 109-113; also see
sections discuss their roles in developing and developed Douglas 1971). Extensive evidence from early American
economies, respectively. industrialization supports this point (Chandler 1977; Live-
say 1979; Porter and Livesay 1971).
On the other hand, z~G is expected to have a small posi-
CHANNEL LENGTH IN DEVELOPING ECONOMIES tive or negative value. Low asset specificity and low quality
debasement externalities are expected in early stages of de-
In the initial stages of a primitive economy, communities velopment. Complex and highly technical products repre-
are largely self sufficient, consuming for the most part what sent a relatively small portion of the total demand for con-
they produce and having very little need for middlemen. sumer and producers' goods, so that the requirements for
With further development, monetary units are introduced specialized assets--specialized capital goods, personnel,
and there is increasing division of labor. Craftsmen and and skills--and problems of adequate dealer support for
small businessmen increase their sales by trading beyond complex, service-intensive products are kept to a small sec-
their own communities. Small trading centers emerge, with tor of the total economy. Furthermore, competition is limit-
communities selling to as well as provisioning from other ed by the scarcity of goods and typically prevailing sellers'
communities and urban centers. market conditions. Since most goods enjoy little differentia-

JAMS 6 WINTER, 1992


CHANNEL EVOLUTION: A FRAMEWORK FOR ANALYSIS SHARMA AND DOMINGUEZ

tion in early stages of development, effective management


FIGURE 1
of the marketing mix aimed at consistent product differ-
Economic Development and Channel Length
entiation is not a major concern of the producer. Whatever
control losses might be experienced by relinquishing mar-
keting activities to intermediaries are offset by the pro-
ducers' own limited managerial resources. r
Hence a high positive value of AC and low positive or c
negative value of AG will result in AC + AG > 0; channels
are expected to lengthen in early stages of development.
...J

t-
/
t-
t-
Proposition 1: In a developing economy, channel O
length will increase as a country develops
economically.
EconomicDevelopment

CHANNEL LENGTH IN ADVANCED ECONOMIES

As countries industrialize, firms have access to higher


Environment
technology, better transportation and communication facili- Developing Economies Developed Economies

ties, greater financial resources, and more sophisticated hu- 9 LOW Volume of 9 High Volume of
man resources (Carson 1967; Mallen 1977). Competition Transactions Transactions
9 Small number of Suppliers 9 Large Number of Suppliers
intensifies as hitherfore regional and local marketers be- (Sellers ~ Market) (Buyers' Market)
come fully integrated into a unified market system. In the 9 Low Customer Service 9 Higher Customer Service
Expectations
Expectations
face of greater supply, increased choice, and more discre- 9 Marginal-Wage Earning 9 Sophisticated Transport
Retailers and Communication
tionary demand, firms which can more effectively control 9 Deficient Transport and Infrastructure
channel functions stand to achieve significant competitive Communication 9 Easy Availability of
Infrastructure Financial Resources
advantages by offering better service to their customers 9 Restricted Availability of
(Guiltinan 1974), i.e., characteristics associated with the Financial Resources

transition from a preponderance of sellers' to one of buyers'


market conditions (Frazier, Gill, and Kale 1989; Kale
1986). A number of studies have reported shorter channels
in industrialized or industrializing nations--in Europe Transactional Costs
(Arndt 1972); Australia (Layton 1989); the U.S. (Davidson
IAC+AG>0 [ aC+AG<0
1970; Livesay and Porter 1969; Moore 1972); Japan (Busi-
ness Week 1988a and 1988b; Dowd 1959; Shimagushi and
Lazer 1979); and Venezuela (Dominguez and Vanmarcke
1987).
Transactional cost analysis provides a comprehensive in- Distribution Costs
tegrative framework that incorporates both distribution and AC is High and Positive AC is Low end Positive
control cost considerations working toward channel reduc- 9 LOW Volume--No 9 High Volume--Economies
tion. First, AC, the difference between internal and external Economies of Scale of Scale
9 Retailer Willing to Work 9 Increased Retail Margins
distribution costs, is reduced. This is because the size of the with Slim Margins 9 High Customer Service
market allows firms to achieve considerable economies of 9 Low Customer Service Expectations
Expectations 9 High Asset Specificity
scale, so that distributive functions can be performed at 9 Low Asset Specificity Requirements
costs comparable to those of intermediaries in the open Requirements

market. Performance of these specialized functions also re-


suits in greater asset specificity which reduces the value
of AC.
Second, greater product complexity and heightened com- Governance Costs
petition increase the need to exercise control over all facets AG is Positive AG is Negative
of the marketing mix in order to avoid quality debasement
Major Objective--Market 9 Major Objective--
externalities. Independent channels increase the costs of 9

Coverage Competitive Advantage


channel governance because intermediaries handle other 9 LOW Product Differentiation 9 Sophisticated
9 Large Number of Small Competitions
products, and incentives have to be provided in order to Intermediaries available 9 Product Differentiation
carry out a marketer's policies. Long channels worsen the and used 9 High Degree of Control
9 Low need for control needed
situation because of the added costs of controlling and 9 High Internal Monitoring 9 Organizational
Costs due to deficient Infrastructure Allows Easy
motivating a labyrinthic network of independent-minded in- Organizational Internal Monitoring
termediaries. Use of such channels in buyers' markets im- infrastructure 9 High Quality Debasement
9 Low Quality Debasement Externalities
plies loss of sales due to inconsistent or poorly implemented Externalities
marketing practices. Further, better technology and greater
availability of financial and human resources reduce inter-

JAMS 7 WINTER, 1992


CHANNEL EVOLUTION: A FRAMEWORK FOR ANALYSIS SHARMA AND DOMINGUEZ

nal control costs, while increased volume reduces the cost recession will have offsetting effects on AG: intensified
of internal governance (Anderson 1985). Thus, AG, the competition for dwindling demand will increase external
difference between internal and external governance costs, control costs while a reduction in channel volume will re-
becomes highly negative, so that AC + AG becomes in- duce internal economies of scale. Therefore, AC + AG is
creasingly negative, making consolidation of channel func- expected to be positive during a prolonged recession (be-
tions increasingly attractive. Several studies of indus- cause of the rise in AC), so that channels will tend to length-
trialized economies have found direct evidence of a en once again.
relationship between increased external governance costs The preceding example illustrates how channel evolution
and reduced channel length (Anderson 1985; Anderson and may be arrested or even reversed in response to a reversal of
Coughlan 1987; John and Weitz 1988; Klein, Frazier, and economic development. But even if economic development
Roth 1990). 2 proceeds, or when comparing nations at similar stages of
A proposition regarding the relationship between devel- development, there wilt be deviations from the standard
opment and channel length for advanced economies can be pattern predicted by Propositions 1 and 2. Cultural, politi-
stated as the following. cal, and geographic factors are among the most widely cited
determinants of channel structure (Kaynak 1986). Each of
Proposition 2: In an advanced economy, channel the following sections first discusses the importance of each
length will decrease as a country develops selected factor, then traces its effect on distribution and
economically. governance costs, and concludes with a proposition on its
relationship to channel length. The major emphasis is on
The relationship between development and channel environmental determinants that would leave channel length
length suggested by Propositions 1 and 2 is akin to an invariant as nations move to advanced stages of
inverted "U". Channels first lengthen and then shorten with development.
further development. The point where the direction of
change in channel length is reversed occurs when a society Cultural Factors
has begun to achieve a high level of income and wealth
accumulation and has moved from sellers' to buyers' market Cultural values may significantly foster or delay adoption
conditions so that issues related to the governance of com- of new distributive institutions and practices. Two major
petitive strategy and customer service take precedence over elements of culture explored in the literature are the shop-
distribution cost issues, and a marketer's internal scale ping behavior of consumers and the decision-making cul-
economies and managerial controls operate more efficiently ture of organizations.
and at a higher level of customer service than through open-
market transactions. Propositions 1 and 2 are summarized in Shopping Behavior
Figure 1. Shopping behavior in a country affects retail institutions
and thereby channel length. Irrespective of development, in
many countries, small stores are seen to provide products
DEVIATIONS FROM THE PATTERN and services that larger stores cannot. As a result there is a
OF CHANNEL EVOLUTION preponderance of small neighborhood stores. For example,
Turkish homemakers visit local stores for their fresh pro-
Deviations from the standard pattern of channel evolution duce (Kaynak 1978), credit, bargaining (Kumcu and Kum-
will be detected when comparing a nation's channel system cu 1987), and the "they know me" factor (Yavas, Kaynak
over time, and when comparing nations that have attained and Borak 1982). The desire for daily fresh produce in a
similar levels of development. For example, after experi- location close to the shopper is one explanation for the
encing increased vertical integration, distribution channels dominance of small retailers in Japan (Shimagushi and
in a newly-industrialized nation may once again lengthen, Lazer 1979). In such environments, there is less propensity
contrary to Proposition 2. Such a phenomenon was ob- to reduce channel length than predicted by Proposition 2
served in a number of industrializing Latin American na- alone.
tions that sustained a loss of income and employment during Transactional cost analysis makes it possible to trace the
the 1980s. They experienced a parallel rise in the impor- effects of culturally-bound shopping behavior on both dis-
tance of informal distribution, which implies that their tribution and governance costs. The preference of con-
channels once again lengthened. This has been attributed to sumers for shopping at neighborhood stores reduces volume
the fact that distributive activities are often a source of per outlet and thus diminishes the potential for realizing
income of last resort to the chronically unemployed and economies of scale through vertical integration. Neighbor-
underemployed. hood retailers operate at very small margins (e.g., Kaynak
Transactional cost analysis provides a more comprehen- 1982, pp. 140-141; Keegan 1974). As a result, the internal
sive explanation. A prolonged recession marked by sus- costs of distribution are higher than those of distribution
tained losses in real income and demand reduces channel through independent retailers; AC can be expected to be
throughput, severely lessening internal economies of scale. highly positive.
At the same time, the costs of external distribution are re- Cultural preferences for small stores also raise internal
duced by the availability of people who are willing to per- governance costs. Highly idiosyncratic customer behavior
form these functions at little above minimal wages. As a complicates the task of understanding local preferences and
result, AC will become much more positive. A prolonged customs; quality debasement losses may be incurred. The

JAMS 8 WINTER, 1992


CHANNELEVOLUTION:A FRAMEWORKFOR ANALYSIS SHARMAAND DOMINGUEZ

difficulty of translating those differences into coherent pol- 1974; Izraeli, Izraeli and Zif 1977; Slater et al. 1969). There
icies and procedures is one of the reasons why forward is growing recognition among international agencies that
integration was discouraged in a number of key retail sec- distribution policy can affect not only physical distribution
tors in the U.S. (Williamson 1983). Retailers' ability to itself but production growth and income distribution
personalize efforts and add customer services (e.g., liberal (Meissner 1987; Riley and Statz 1981).
returns or credit) can act as a powerful deterrent to forward It is well accepted that severe market imperfections
integration (Dannhauser 1981; Heide and John 1988). It characterize the exchange systems of underdeveloped na-
remains a major hurdle for U.S. exporters wishing to side- tions (i.e., deviations from the classical economic model of
step Japan's labyrinthic channel system (Lazer, Murata and pure competition and perfect flow of information and re-
Kosaka 1985). sources) (e.g., Frazier and Kale 1988; Klein 1986). Public
It is expected that preference for traditional retailers will policy has sought to regulate away the effects of market
make AG highly positive and hence AC + AG lessening the imperfections that may result in supply shortages, excessive
tendency to consolidate. profits, or "excessive consumption" of some goods, e.g.,
imported luxuries (Sorensen 1978). Price support programs
Proposition 3: The more culturally entrenched tra- and state-run processing and manufacturing plants turn gov-
ditional shopping behavior in a country, the more ernments into owners of large stocks of goods which they
likely that long channels will persist as a country must sell; as a result, governments often enter directly into
develops. distribution (Dholakia and Kurana 1983). In addition, as
buyers, sellers, and allocators of resources, governments
Organizational Culture indirectly alter channel structures (Aharoni 1977).
Comparative management studies show that national cul- Policy decisions, of course, are not solely guided by
tural characteristics can give rise to important cross-national economic efficiency considerations; the government's social
differences in organizational structure and processes (Desh- agenda must be considered as well (e.g., Dahringer 1983;
pande and Webster 1989; Kogut and Singh 1988; Pascale Etgar 1983). Since the distributive trades are labor-intensive
and Athos 1981; Slocum 1971; Yau 1988). Where consen- employers of last resort, states often intervene to preserve
sual management values prevail, longer channels of dis- traditional labor-intensive distributive institutions (Riley
tribution will be found. For example, in Japan very strong and Statz 1981). Legislation supporting small retailers is
channel ties have allowed traditional long channels of dis- popular and widespread. Small retailers have successfully
tribution to continue to play a major role despite the inroads lobbied to restrict the operation of supermarkets in a number
of innovative firms (Czinkota 1985; Ross 1983; Shimagushi of LDCs such as Turkey (Kumcu and Kumcu 1987) and
and Lazer 1979). And, in Australia, self-service stores were even in advanced countries, e.g., in Italy, Norway, and
adopted slowly because there were "social pressures against Sweden (Cateora 1985). In some countries, taxes are im-
strong business competition and a history of cooperative posed on large retailers to help small retailers, as in the case
action among retailers and manufacturers to oppose changes of Switzerland (Cateora 1985).
that might change the status quo" (Cundiff 1965). Transactional cost analysis provides a unified framework
Organizational culture will affect governance costs. Con- for tracing the possible effects of different types of state
sensual management styles emphasizing the attainment of intervention on distribution and governance costs. Govern-
common goals tie parties into a web of loyalties, norms, and ment regulation and intervention can reduce the volume of
behaviors that effectively reduce the scope of opportunism, throughput in private sector channels, reducing the oppor-
moderating the costs of enforcing compliance with man- tunity for internal distribution costs to approximate those of
ufacturer policies (John 1984), i.e., reducing quality de- the open market. It does this by limiting promotion and
basement losses from external governance. Also, to main- price competition that may stimulate demand for certain
tain their viability, consensual groups work to raise the costs goods, by diverting demand and supply to state-controlled
of entry to outsiders (Tse et al. 1988, pp. 82-83). In other channels, and by diverting sales to small retailers (as ex-
words, consensual management styles raise the costs of plained in the previous section, the presence of many small
internal governance and lower those of external gover- retailers reduces scale economies). As a result, AC is ex-
nance. As a result, AG is expected to be highly positive in pected to be higher in more highly regulated economies.
consensual cultures, and long channels will tend to persist. Internal governance costs are also adversely affected.
From this discussion, the following proposal ensues. Limits on the scope of competitive activity reduce the op-
portunity for product differentiation. As already explained,
Proposition 4: The more consensually oriented the quality debasement externalities that encourage internal dis-
management style of a society, the more likely long tribution exist to the extent that there is intense competition
channels will persist as a country develops. and products can be differentiated (Williamson 1983). Leg-
islation that prevents firings or maintains artificially high
Distribution Policy wages in the distributive sector discourages vertical integra-
tion. Not only does it raise internal distribution costs; it also
There is a tong standing recognition in the marketing raises the costs of monitoring, supervising, and motivating
literature of the importance of channel policy to the devel- the labor force. It may also have a detrimental effect on the
opment process. Researchers have argued that government quality of service that may be expected.
policy can have a significant role in determining the evolu- Lastly, a complex and changing web of regulations raises
tion of marketing systems (Dahringer 1983; Harrison et al. the level of uncertainty (e.g., Riley and Statz 1981). Em-

JAMS 9 WINTER, 1992


CHANNEL EVOLUTION: A FRAMEWORK FOR ANALYSIS SHARMA AND DOMINGUEZ

pirical studies have shown consistently that environmental In summary, it is expected that the presence of large
instability discourages vertical integration when channel urban markets will spur the growth of large scale intermedi-
members must invest in highly specific assets (Dwyer and aries and of shorter channels, where there is already a suffi-
Welsh 1985; John and Weitz 1988; Klein 1989). cient level of development and competition.
As a result, it is expected that market regulation will raise
AG, further discouraging vertical integration. In the follow- Proposition 7: Compared to other nations at similar
ing propositions, we separate market regulation and protec- levels of development, those with a greater prepon-
tion of small retailers. derance of large urban markets will possess shorter
channels of distribution.
Proposition 5: The more pervasive and unpredict-
able state intervention into channel pricing, market- Note, of course, that other environmental factors will
ing, and labor hiring and firing practices, the more help determine the impact of large urban centers. Specifi-
likely it is that long channels of distribution will cally, culturally-entrenched shopping patterns, consensual
persist. management styles, and government regulation will miti-
gate the effects of urban concentration. Conversely, where
Proposition 6: The more that government policies these factors have played a minor role, e.g., in the United
favor small retailers, the more likely it is that long States, the distributive system evolved in the direction pre-
channels of distribution will persist. dicted by Proposition 7 from the early stages of industrializ-
ation beginning in the latter half of the nineteenth century
Urbanization (see Chandler 1977; Porter and Livesay 1971; Williamson
1983).
The rapid pace of urbanization is one of the most signifi-
cant aspects of contemporary economic geography, particu-
larly so in the developing areas. In 1960, there were t10 DISCUSSION
cities of more than 500,000 people in low- or middle-
income countries. By 1980, there were 278. Likewise, by The issues raised in this article address an important but
1980 the number of people living in cities of more than inadequately developed topic. From its inception, market-
500,000 had risen to 44 percent of the population of low and ing has regarded the enhancement of exchanges as one of its
middle-income countries; the percentages are higher still in central concerns. Transaction-related issues, including the
Asia and Latin America (World Bank 1990). Urbanization is efficiency and effectiveness of channel systems, are there-
expected to continue at a rapid pace (United Nations 1989). fore at the core of marketing scholarship. Channel length is
Many factors account for this (Byerlee 1974; Sabot 1982). a parsimonious and widely used indicator of market
In most developing areas, rural-urban migration has ac- structure.
counted for nearly half of all urban population growth. It is The channel literature has offered incomplete and
generally agreed that rural-urban wage differentials are the seemingly contradictory explanations of changes in channel
main contributor. Urban wage rates have risen at a much length. Transactional cost analysis can significantly in-
faster rate than agricultural wages. Enduring wage rate dif- crease the explanatory insight and predictive ability of stud-
ferentials are abetted by protection of domestic industry, ies of channel evolution. Applying a make-or-buy frame-
which allows wage raises to be passed on to consumers, and work that focuses primarily on asset specificity, channel
by labor policies favoring unionization and minimum sal- volume, and quality debasement externalities, it has been
aries for unskilled jobs while neglecting agricultural wages shown why the relationship between economic development
(Meier 1984, pp. 193-195). and channel length is nonmonotonic. Channels lengthen in
Urbanization, and more specifically, concentration of the early stages of development and tend to shorten after-
population in large cities, has significant transactional cost ward. The reason for this reversal is a fundamental shift in
implications. Large urban centers pose distribution chal- the balance of forces determining internal and external dis-
lenges and opportunities that small ones do not. Small urban tribution and governance costs.
centers can be provisioned directly from surrounding areas, The analysis also identified country-specific conditions
whereas large cities require a vast array of producers from that help define, accelerate, or even reverse channel evolu-
farther distances (e.g., Forman and Riegelhaupt 1970). tion. These factors include consumer shopping behavior,
Large urban centers afford producers and intermediaries the organizational culture, governmental intervention, and ur-
opportunity to achieve sufficient economies of scale that banization. These forces account for important and
their internal distribution costs will approximate those of the seemingly intractable differences among countries that are
marketplace. High urban concentration accentuates the ad- not explained by development alone.
vantages of internal governance to large producers and in- Nations concerned with their global competitiveness and
termediaries. Large intermediaries are no longer content to export ability are well advised to examine the structure and
rely on small suppliers; they prefer to work directly with efficiency of their channel systems. Economists have
large producers and intermediaries in order to be assured of pointed out that to the extent that exporter firms must rely
supply continuity (Forman and Riegethaupt 1970). Large on domestically supplied inputs (Balassa 1980), inefficien-
urban centers make it easier to reduce quality debasement cies of internal market systems amount to a tax on exports
externalities through internal governance. and potential exporters. Governmental intervention in chan-

JAMS 10 WINTER, 1992


CHANNEL EVOLUTION: A FRAMEWORK FOR ANALYSIS SHARMA AND DOMINGUEZ

nel systems, especially in the Third World, is widespread. to the combined role of labor growth, quality of human capital,
This has had unfortunate results in many instances, largely real capital formation, international competitiveness, and political
because marketing considerations have been unanticipated instability. In addition to being more up to date, the Scholing-
or altogether ignored. The propositions in this article afford Timmermann model has the advantage that it employs secondary
data from published sources. The authors ranked 70 nations; others
a better understanding of the forces with which policy
can be ranked using their causal equations.
makers must contend in effecting channel change. Those
A number of marketing authors have also developed their own
forces impact not only traditional distribution costs, but estimation procedures of economic development (Douglas 1971;
governance costs, whose important role in the dynamics of Liander et al. 1967; Mentzer and Samli 1981; Wadinambiaratchi
channel evolution has been emphasized throughout the 1965). Kaynak and Hudanah's (1987) study is noteworthy for its
discussion. emphasis on advertising and retailing measures. It ranks countries
Although the propositions advanced in this article are on the basis of several macro-marketing indicators: per capita pro-
consistent with the patterns of regularity and variation re- motion expenditures, retail employment, per capita R&D expendi-
ported in the literature, their validation requires empirical tures, and supermarkets per thousand people. In general, some
testing. The Appendix suggests specific measures of differ- care needs to be exercised when utilizing the measures of develop-
ment found in the marketing literature. Some are very old; others
ent constructs. Hopefully, the article will encourage much
lack the extensive validation procedures employed by the leading
needed rigorous testing of an important underlying charac-
economic studies described above. On balance, Rummel's (1972)
teristic o f channel systems. and Scholing and Timmermann's (1988) are recommended.
Strictly speaking, the length of a nation's aggregate channel
system is the composite of all channel lengths. As a result, direct
APPENDIX measurement is infeasible. Layton (1989) has suggested a method
for estimating aggregate channel length based on trade flow meth-
Measurement of Constructs odology. The approach originates from Cox et al.'s (1965) use of
input-output tables to measure trade flows from/to producers,
There are some difficulties associated with measuring the con- wholesalers, intermediaries, and households. Layton has shown
structs employed in this article. Development of more precise that channel length corresponds to the ratio of all intermediate
estimators would be a significant contribution to the literature. transactions to all final transactions as derived from input-output
Nonetheless, adequate measures of each are available. The Appen- tables. The accuracy of this method depends on the availability of
dix suggests appropriate methods. The discussion is keyed to each transaction values measured in producers' prices at intermediate
proposition. and final consumption levels, so that distortions due to margins
can be eliminated. Layton has conducted a number of replications
Propositions 1 and 2 in Australia and Java (Layton 1981; 1989).
The constructs of economic development and channel length are Other, less accurate approaches are available. One is to employ
the most crucial, since the former is featured in many of the proxies for channel length. For example, the percentage of pro-
propositions and the latter in all of them. Both constructs present ducers' total sales that is accounted for by direct-to-retailer sales is
some measurement difficulties, the former because of its multidi- an indicator of the extent to which intermediaries are being by-
mensionality, the latter because, at least in principle, it encom- passed. Another method is to measure the average size of man-
passes all domestic channel transactions. ufacturing, wholesaling and retailing firms (Douglas 1971).
Gross Domestic Product (GDP) per capita is the simplest mea-
sure of development. It is employed by the World Bank to categor- Proposition 3
ize nations (World Bank 1990). Two problems are associated with This proposition concerns the effects of adherence to culturally-
it. First, GDP fails to take into account other aspects of economic entrenched shopping values and behavior. A number of objective
development, e.g., degree of industrialization and diversity of and subjective predictors of adoption of non-traditional retailing
economic activity. A number of studies have devised multidimen- institutions have been employed. Among the objective measures
sional measures of development. These include telephones per are Goldman's (1982) correlates of adoption of supermarkets. He
thousand people, agricultural and manufacturing shares of employ- related supermarket shopping to consumers' average distance to
ment, manufacturing share of GDP, energy consumption per supermarkets, automobile ownership, educational level, house-
capita, and number of TV sets per thousand, in addition to GDP hold socioeconomic status, and number of family members per
per capita. room. Barnes (1980) suggested that the importance of certain retail
A second objection, which is shared by a number of marketing institutions (e.g., supermarkets) is a function of their number and
scholars, is that development is not solely an economic phenome- selling space per thousand people. Kaynak and Hudanah (1987)
non; political and socio-cultural dimensions must be considered as proposed a number of additional measures.
well (Barnes 1980; E1-Ansary and Liebrenz 1982; Liander et al. "Subjective" measures gauge consumers' perceptions of the ex-
1967; Savitt 1988). Factors such as ethnic and religious hetero- tent to which traditional retail institutions offer unique services,
geneity, female labor force participation, and availability of health e.g., fresher products (Kaynak 1978; Shimagushi and Lazer
and educational services are included in these approaches. Adel- 1979), credit, and the opportunity to bargain (Kumcu and Kumcu
man and Morris (1968, 1973)employed factor analysis to group 1987), and personal knowledge and attention (Yavas et al. 1982).
twenty-four measures of the political and socio-cultural environ- A scale may be constructed to measure consumers' belief of the
ment. Many of their measures were derived from a cross-national availability of these services, and their importance to the
sample of experts. Three factors representing attitudinal and in- consumer.
stitutional change, political decentralization/liberalization, and
commitment to change were closely correlated with GDP level and Proposition 4
growth. More recently, Scholing and Timmermann (1988) utilized As discussed in the text, a number of studies have argued that
causal analysis to derive factors related to economic growth and consensual management style affects channel characteristics and
development. Their model may be used to rank nations according evolution. Two basic approaches may be used to measure consen-

JAMS 11 WINTER, 1992


CHANNEL EVOLUTION: A FRAMEWORK FOR ANALYSIS SHARMA AND DOMINGUEZ

sual s t y l e - - o r other organizational cultural characteristics (Desh- ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS


pande and Webster 1989). Ethnographic or phenomenological re-
search employs a two-stage process. In the first stage, cases which T h e a u t h o r s g r a t e f u l l y a c k n o w l e d g e the h e l p f u l c o m -
embody the phenomenon under study are identified (e.g., indus-
m e n t s o f M i c h a e l Levy, H o w a r d M a r m o r s t e i n , W a l t e r Z i n n
tries or companies that employ long channels). The second stage
a n d t w o a n o n y m o u s r e v i e w e r s . T h i s r e s e a r c h was partly
constitutes an in-depth analysis of performance and decision mak-
ing within the companies involved. This approach was employed f u n d e d b y a S u m m e r A w a r d in B u s i n e s s a n d Social Sci-
by Porter (1990a, 1990b) to study innovativeness. e n c e s , U n i v e r s i t y of M i a m i .
As its name indicates, the cross-sectional approach is to mea-
sure a wide-ranging sample of managers on a number of charac-
teristics and to compare these across nations or cultures. NOTES
Hofstede's (1980) studies of work-related values among employ-
ees of a multinational corporation in forty countries exemplifies Several other mathematical modeling papers tangentially address
this approach. Hofstede's scales pertaining to autocratic vs. con- channel length. However, they offer no propositions that are di-
sensual management styles are directly pertinent to Proposition 3, rectly relevant to the relationship between economic development
as are Kelly et al.'s (1987) measures. A variant of the cross- and channel length. Richartz (1970) proposed a general game the-
sectional approach is Tse et al.'s (1988) in-basket simulation of oretic framework for predicting channel length, indicating condi-
tions under which Nash equilibrium structures might be obtained.
management situations. They presented executives with risky de-
The paper stopped short of deriving specific predictions on channel
cision making scenarios which a cross-cultural panel had validated length. The same is true of a number of decision optimization
as addressing specific cultural characteristics. A similar approach models (e. g., Rangan 1987). Other papers have analyzed the impor-
might be employed to measure consensual management tance of role uncertainty and information (Zusman and Etgar 1981)
preferences. and vertical coordination (Jeuland and Shugan 1983; Norton 1987)
in maximizing channel profits. However, these studies assumed a
given channel configuration and hence offer no propositions on
Proposition 5 channel length, except to hypothesize that the more intertwined and
Government policies on state intervention into channel pricing, inseparable manufacturers and intermediaries' production, cost, and
marketing, and hiring and firing practices are very hard to measure demand functions become, the greater the incentive to vertically
because of the difficulty of assessing the myriad of regulations, integrate (Norton 1987). A more recent paper by Moorthy (1988) is
particularly if this is to be performed in a manner that makes the discussed in note 2.
data comparable across nations (World Bank 1988, p.45). How- 2. McGuire-Staelin-Cougblan argue that under high product/brand
ever, surrogate measures are available. A recent study measured substitutability, manufacturers would be better off relying on inde-
state intervention as the ratio of public sector expenditures to the pendent retailers. Their argument only looks at the advantage to
manufacturers from isolating themselves from retail competition; on
value of domestic production. This measure was correlated with a the surface, this would support the contention that channels would
number of descriptors of economic progress (World Bank 1988). A be longer in sellers' markets. However, two factors mitigate against
more specific measure of intervention was employed by Agarwala this argument. Firstly, and most importantly, they explicitly assume
(1983). The study compared variations in real wages (adjusted for away governance costs and quality debasement externalities under
changes in terms of trade) versus variations in labor productivity. consideration (Coughlan 1985, p. 128). Secondly, a recent exten-
Based on this ratio, the study estimated the cost of government sion of McGuire-Staelin adds key limiting conditions to their claim
intervention in terms of additional labor costs. (Moorthy 1988). The relevant condition for our purposes is that
disintegration makes sense for a manufacturer only if substitute
products' or brands' prices are expected to rise or fall in unison with
Proposition 6 said manufacturer's. Moorthy does not speculate on the conditions
Examples abound of government policies favoring small re- that may bring this about. One would be when a market leader is
tailers. As with Proposition 5, no direct measures were found of able to exercise oligopolistic control over prices and supply. An-
the magnitude of such government policies. The support for the other condition, most likely to be associated with early stages of
ruling party among specific constituencies, e.g., small retailers' development, is that of sellers' markets. Essentially, under sellers'
market conditions, manufacturers derive little advantage from price
support for Japan's LDP party (Kacker 1988), is indicative of the
competition, since demand is assured; there is little incentive to
extent of their influence, It has been suggested that the degree of lower prices under conditions of supply scarcity. However, should a
political influence which can be exercised by a constituency such manufacturer raise prices, the competition would likely follow suit.
Thus, channel disintegration makes the most sense in the early
as small retailers is a function of the size of the group, the degree
stages of development (sellers' marke~ conditions, low product dif-
of mobilization of support within this group, and its social rank or ferentiation and asset specificity, low quality debasement exter-
prestige (Hutt et al. 1986). The potential influence of small re- nalities, and negligible external governance costs). Conversely, un-
tailers along these three dimensions can be gauged by means of a der buyers" market conditions, the circumstances would not favor
cross-national expert opinion panel. The panel might also be asked channel disintegration.
to assess the severity and degree of enforcement of specific stat-
utes that might be deemed protective of small retailers. Either the
panel's numerical ratings or content analysis of their comments REFERENCES
(Kassarjian 1977; Krippendorf 1980) may be used to rank
countries. Adelman, I. and C. T. Morris_ 1968. "An Econometric Model of Socio-
Economic and Political Change in Underdeveloped Countries.'" The
Proposition 7 American Economic Review 58 (December): 1184-1218.
Adelman, I. and C. T, Morris. 1973. Economic Growth and Social Equity
Urbanization is the most easily measurable construct. The
in Developing Countries. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.
United Nations and a number of other institutions regularly update Agarwala, R. 1983. Price Distortions and Growth in Developing Econo-
estimates of the number of major urban centers and their popula- mies. New York: Oxford University Press.
tion. Accurate measures from the most primitive societies may be Anderson, Erin. 1985. "The Salesperson as Outside Agent or Employee: A
a problem. Transaction Cost Analysis." Marketing Science 4 (Summer): 234-254.

JAMS 12 WINTER, 1992


CHANNEL EVOLUTION: A FRAMEWORK FOR ANALYSIS SHARMA AND DOMINGUEZ

Anderson, Erin and Ann T. Coughlan. 1987. "International Market Entry Channel Integration in the Philippines." Economic Development and
and Expansion Via Independent or Integrated Channels of Distribution." Cultural Change 29 (April): 577-578.
Journal of Marketing 51 (January): 71-82. Davidson, William9 1970. "Changes in Distributive Institutions9 Journal
Anderson, Erin and Hubert Gatignon. 19869"Modes of Foreign Entry: A of Marketing 34 (January): 7-10.
Transaction Cost Analysis and Propositions." Journal of International Day, George S. and Saul Klein9 1987. "Cooperative Behavior in Vertical
Business Studies 17 (Fall): 1-26. Markets: The Influence of Transaction Costs and Competitive Strat-
Aharoni, Yair. 1977. Markets, Planning and Development9 Cambridge, egies." In Review of Marketing. Ed. Michael J. Houston. Chicago:
MA: Ballinger. American Marketing Association, 39-66.
Arndt, Johan. 1972. "Temporal Lags in Comparative Retailing." Journal of Deshpande, Rohit and Frederick E. Webster. 1989. "Organizational Cul-
Marketing 36 (October): 40-45. ture and Marketing: Defining the Research Agenda9 Journal of Market-
- - . 1979. "Toward a Concept of Domesticated Markets9 Journal of ing 53 (January): 3-15.
Marketing 43 (Fall): 69-75. Dholakia, Nikhilesh and Rakesh Kurana. 1983. "Public Policy Toward
- - . 1981. "The Political Economy of Marketing Systems: Reviving Essential Consumption Items: Generalizations from the Indian Experi-
the Institutional Approach." Journal of Macromarketing 1 (Fall): 36- ence." Journal of Public Policy and Marketing 2: 171-1829
47. Dominguez, Luis V. and Cristina Vanmarcke. 1987. "Market Structure and
Balassa, Bela. 1980. "The Process of Industrial Development and Alterna- Marketing Behavior in LDCs: The Case of Venezuela9 Journal of Mac-
tive Development Strategies." Essays in International Finance, No. romarketing 7 (Spring): 4-16.
141. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Douglas, Susan P. 1971. "Patterns and Parallels of Marketing Structures in
Barnes, W. N. 1980. "International Marketing Indicators." European Jour- Several Countries." MSU Business Topics 19 (Spring): 38-48.
nal of Marketing 14 (2): 90-1369 Dowd, Lawrence P. 1959. "Wholesale Marketing in Japan." Journal of
Bello, Daniel C. and Nicholas C. Williamson. 1985. "Contractual Ar- Marketing 23 (January): 257-262.
rangements and Marketing Practices in the Indirect Export Market." Dwyer, Robert F. and Sejo Oh. 1988. "A Transaction Cost Perspective on
Journal of International Business Studies 16 (Summer): 65-82 9 Vertical Contractual Structure and Interchannel Competitive Strategies."
Bhasin, Ajay and Louis W. Stern. 1982. "Vertical Integration: Consider- Journal of Marketing 52 (April): 21-349
ations of Efficiency, Risk and Strategy." In Marketing Channels: Do- Dwyer, Robert F. and M. Ann Welsh. 1985. "Environmental Relationships
mestic and International Perspectives9 Eds, Michael G. Harvey and of the Internal Political Economy of Marketing Channels." Journal of
Robert F. Lusch. Norman: University of Oklahoma, 1-4. Marketing Research 22 (November): 397-4149
Boddewyn, Jean J. 1981. "Comparative Marketing: The First Twenty-Five E1-Ansary, Adel. 1984. "Strategies for Reforming Food Marketing Sys-
Years." Journal of International Business Studies 17 (Spring-Summer): tems in Developing Countries." Paper presented at the Ninth Mac-
61-79. romarketing Conference, Arlie, Virginia.
Bowen, David E. and Gareth R. Jones. 1986. "Transaction Cost Analysis E1-Ansary, Adel and Marilyn L. Liebrenz. t982. "A Multistage Approach
of Service Organization Customer Exchange." Academy of Management to Comparative Marketing Analysis." Journal of Macromarketing 2
Review 11 (April): 428-441. (Fall): 59-659
Bromley, R. J. 1971. "Markets in Developing Countries: A Review." Ge- Etgar, Michael9 1974. "An Empirical Analysis of the Motivations for the
ography 56 (April): 124-132. Development of Centrally Coordinated Vertical Marketing Systems: The
Bucklin, Louis P. 1970a. "National Income Accounting and Distributive Case of Property and Casualty Insurance Industry." Dissertation. School
Trade Cost." Journal of Marketing 34 (April): 14-22. of Business Administration. University of California, Berkeley.
9 1970b. "Macro Models of Vertical Marketing Systems." In Verti- 9 1978. "The Effect of Forward Vertical Integration on Service
cal Marketing Systems9 Ed. Louis P. Bucklin. Glenview, IL: Scott, Performance of a Distributive Industry." Journal of Industrial Econom-
Foresman and Company, 116-134. ics 26 (March): 249-253.
Business Week. 1988a. "Now, Japan is Feeling the Heat from the Gray 9 1983. "A Failure in Marketing Technology Transfer: The Case of
Market." March 14: 50-51 9 Rice Distribution in the Ivory Coast." Journal of Macromarketing 3
- - . 1988b. "Campbell's Taste of the Japanese Market is mm-mm (Spring): 59-68 9
Good." March 28: 42. Etgar, Michael and Pinhas Zusman. 1982. "The Marketing Intermediary as
- - . 1990a. "How CPC is Getting Fat on Muffins and Mayonnaise." an Information Seller: A New Approach." Journal of Business 55'(4):
April 16: 46-47. 505-515.
- - . 1990b. "Can Colgate Import its Success Overseas?" May 7:11. FAO (Food and Agricultural Organization)9 1982. The Private Marketing
Buzzell, Robert D. 1983. "Is Vertical Integration Profitable?" Harvard Entrepreneur and Rural Development. Rome: FAO.
Business Review 61 (January/February): 92-103. Forman, Shepard and Joyce F. Riegelhaupt. 1970. "Market Place and
Byerlee, Derek. 1974. "Rural-Urban Migration in Africa: Theory, Policy Marketing System: Toward a Theory of Peasant Economic Integration."
and Research Implications." International Migration Review 8 (Winter): Comparative Studies in Society and History 12 (January): 188-2129
543-566. Frazier, Gary L., J. Gill, and Sudhir H. Kale. 1989. "Dealer Dependence
Carson, David9 1967. International Marketing: A Comparative Systems Levels and Reciprocal Actions in a Channel of Distribution in a Devel-
Approach. New York: John Wiley and Sons. . oping Country." Journal of Marketing 53 (January): 50-699
Cateora, Philip R. 1985. Strategic International Marketing9 Homewood, Frazier, Gary L. and Sudhir H. Kale. 1988. "Manufacturer-Distributor
IL: Dow Jones-lrwin. Relationships: A Sellers' versus Buyers' Market Perspective." Interna-
Chandler, Alfred D. 1977. The Visible Hand. Cambridge, MA: Belknap. tional Marketing Review 6 (6): 7-25.
Corstjens, Marcel and Peter J. Doyle. 1979. "Channel Organization in Goldman, Arieh. 1982. "Adoption of Supermarket Shopping in a Develop-
Complex Marketing Systems9 Management Science 25 (October): ing Country: The Selective Adoption Process9 European Journal of
1014-10259 Marketing 16 (1): 17-26.
Coughlan, Anne T. 1985. "Competition and Cooperation in Marketing Guiltinan, Joseph P. 1974. "Planned and Evolutionary Changes in Dis-
Channel Choice: Theory and Application." Marketing Science 4 tribution Channels." Journal of Retailing 2 (Summer): 79-919
(Spring): 110-129. Harrison, Kelly et al. 1974. Improving Food Marketing Systems in Devel-
Cox, Reavis, Charles S. Goodman, and Thomas C9 Fichandler9 1965. oping Countries: Experience from Latin America. East Lansing, MI:
Distribution in a High Level Economy. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Latin American Studies Center, Michigan State University9
Hall. Heide, Jan B. and George John. 19889 "The Role of Dependence Balan-
Cundiff. Edward W. 1965. "Concepts in Comparative Retailing9 Journal cing in Safeguarding Transaction-Specific Assets in Conventional Chan-
of Marketing 29 (January): 59-63. nels." Journal of Marketing 52 (January): 20-359
Czinkota, Michael R. 1985. "Distribution in Japan: Problems and Pros- Hill, Polly. 1963. "Markets in Africa." The Journal of Modern African
pects." Columbia Journal of World Business 10 (Fall): 65-71. Studies 1 (4): 441-453.
Dahringer, Lee. 1983. "Public Policy Implications of Reverse Channel Hofstede, Geert. 1980. Culture's Consequences: International Difference
Mapping for Lesotho." Journal ofMacromarketing 3 (Spring): 69-75. in Work Related Values9 Beverly Hills: Sage.
Dannhauser, Norbert. 19819 "Evolution and Devolution of Downward Hutt, Michael D., Michael P. Mokwa, and Stanley J. Shapiro. 1986. "The

JAMS 13 WINTER, 1992


CHANNEL EVOLUTION: A FRAMEWORK FOR ANALYSIS SHARMA AND DOMINGUEZ

Politics of Marketing: Analyzing the Parallel Political Marketplace." A Literature Overview." International Journal of Physical Distribution
Journal of Marketing 50 (January): 40-51. and Materials Management 5 (5): 230-237.
Izraeli, Dov, Dafna N. Izraeli, and Jehiel Zif. 1977. "'Integrative Processes 9 1977. Principles of ChannelManagement. Lexington, MA: Lex-
in Agricultural Marketing Channels9 Journal of the Academs of Mar- ington Books.
keting Science 5 (Summer): 203-2209 McGuire, Timothy W. and Richard Staelin. 1983a. "An Industry Equi-
Jain, Subhash C. 1990. International Marketing Management. Boston: librium Analysis of Downstream Vertical Integration." Marketing Sci-
Kent-PWS Publishing. ence 2 (Spring): 161-191.
Jeuland, Abel P. and Steven M. Shugan. 1983. "Managing Channel Prof- McGuire, Timothy W. and Richard Staelin. 1983b. "The Effects of Chan-
its." Marketing Science 2 (Summer): 239-272, nel Member Efficiency on Channel Structure." In Productivity"and Effi-
John, George. 1984. "An Empirical Investigation of Some Antecedents of ciency in Distribution Systems. Ed. David A. Gauschi. New York:
Opportunism in a Marketing Channel.'" Journal of Marketing Research Elsevier Science Publishing, 3-15.
21 (August): 278-289. Meier, Gerald M. 1984. Leading Issues in Economic Development9 New
John, George and Torger Reve. 1982. "Reliability and Validity of Key York: Oxford University Press9
Informant Data from Dyadic Relationships in Marketing Channels" Meissner, Frank. 19879 "Agricultural Marketing Policies and Activities of
Journal of Marketing Research 19 (November): 517-524. the Inter-American Development Bank." Food Policy 12 (August): 255-
John, George and Barton Weitz. 1988. "Forward Integration into Distribu- 263.
tion: Empirical Test of Transactional Cost Analysis." Journal of Lab, Mentzer, John T. and A. Coskun Samli. 1981. "A Model for Marketing in
Economics, and Organization 4 (Fall): 121-139. Economic Development." Columbia Journal of World Business 16
Kacker, Madhav. 1988. "International Flow of Retailing Know-How: (Fall): 91-101.
Bridging the Technology Gap in Distribution." Journal of Retailing 64 Mittendorf, Hans J. 1978. "The Challenge of Organizing Food Marketing
(Spring): 41-67. Systems in Developing Countries." Zeitschrift fiir Auslandische Land-
Kale, Sudhir. 1986. "'Manufacturers" and Distributors" Power Within a wirtschaft 17 (October-December): 323-34l.
Distribution Channel in a Developing Country." Journal o)" Marketing Moore, J. R. 1972. "Structural Dynamics of Marketing Channels." Disser-
Research 23 (November): 387-393. tatiom University of Illinois.
Kassarjian, Harold H. 1977. "Content Analysis in Consumer Research." Moorthy, K. Sridhar. 1988 "Strategic Decentralization in Channels." Mar-
Journal of Consumer Research 4 (June): 8-18. keting Science 7 (Fall): 335-355.
Katzin, Margaret Fisher. 1959. "The Jamaican Country Higgler.'" Social Norton, Seth W. 19879 "The Coase Theorem and Suboptimization in Mar-
and Economic Studies 1 (December): 421-440. keting Channels." Marketing Science 6 (Summer): 268-285.
Kaynak, Erdener. I978. "'Changes in the Food Retailing Institutions of Pascale, R. T. and A. Athos. I98i. The Art of Japanese Management.
Urban Turkey." Studies in Development I8 (Winter): 63. New York: Simon and Schuster.
1982. Marketing in the Third WorM. New York: Praeger Porter, Michael E. t990a_ "'The Competitive Advantage of Nations." Har-
Scientific. vard Business Review 2 (March-April): 73-93.
- - . 1986. Marketing and Economic Development. New York: Praeger 9 1990b. The Competitive Advantage of Nations. New York: Free
Scientific. Press.
Kaynak, Erdener and Ben Issa Hudanah 1987. "Operationalizing tbe Re- Porter, Patrick G. and Harold Livesay. 1971. Merchants and Manufac-
lationship Between Marketing and Economic Development: Some In- turers. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press.
sights from Less Developed Countries.'" European Journal of Marketing Preston, Lee E. 1970. "Marketing Organization and Economic Develop-
21 (1): 48-65. ment: Structure, Products and Management." In Vertical Marketing Sys-
Keegau, Warren J. 1974. Multinational Marketing Management. Second tems. Ed. Louis P. Bucklin. Glenview, IL: Scott, Foresman and Com-
Edition. Englewood Cliffs, N J: Prentice Hall. pany, 116-134.
Kelly, Lane, Arthur Whatley, and Reginald Worthley. 1987. "Assessing the Rangan, V. Kasturi. 1987. "The Channel Design Decision: A Model and
Effects of Culture on Management Attitudes: A Three-Culture Test. `9 Application." Management Science 2 (Spring): 156-1819
Journal of International Business Studies 19 (Summer): 17-32. Richartz, Leon E. 1970. '% Game Theoretic Formulation of Vertical Mar-
Klein, Saul. 1986. "Fostering Development through Backward Integration ker Structures." In Vertical Marketing Systems. Ed. Louis P. Bucklin.
of Channels." Journal of Macromarketing 6 (Spring): 17-27. Glenview, IL: Scott Foresrnan and Company, 180-204.
- - . 1989. "A Transaction Cost Explanation of Vertical Integration in Riley, Harold and John Statz. 1981. "Food System Organization Problems
International Markets." Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science 17 in Developing Countries." Report No. 23. New York: Agricultural De-
(Summer): 253-260. velopment Council.
Klein, Saul, Gary Frazier, and Victor J. Roth. 1990. "'A Transactional Cost Rosenbloom, Bert. 1987. Marketing Channels. Third Edition. Chicago:
Model of Channel Integration in International Markets." Journal of Mar- Dryden.
keting Research 17 (May): 196-208. Ross, Rolph E. 1983. "Understanding the Japanese Distribution System:
Kogut, Bruce and Harbir Singh. 1988. "The Effect of National Culture on An Explanatory Framework." European Journal of Marketing 17 (1): 5 -
the Choice of Entry Mode." Journal oflnternational Business Studies 20 13.
(Fall): 411-432. Rummel, R. J. 1972. The Dimension of Nations. Beverly Hills, CA: Sage
Krippendorf, Klaus. 1980. Content Analysis. Beverly Hills, CA: Sage. Publications.
Kumcu, Erdogan and M. Ercan Kumcu. 1987. "Determinants of Food Sabot, Richard H. 1982. Migration and the Labor Markets in Developing
Retailing in Developing Countries: The Case of Turkey." Journal of Countries9 Boulder, CO: Westview Press.
Macromarketing 7 (Fall): 26-40. Savitt, Ronald. 1988. "The State of the Art in Marketing and Economic
Layton, Roger A. 1981. "Trade Flows in Macromarketing Systems." Jour- Development." In Research in Marketing, Supplement 4. Ed. Erdogan
nal ofMacromarketing 1 (Spring): 35-48. Kumcu, Ercan Kumcu, and Mehmet Karafakioglu. Greenwich, CT: JAI
~ . 1989_ "Measures of Structural Change in Macromarketing Sys- Press, 11-37.
tems." Journal ofMacromarketing 9 (Spring): 5-15. Scholing, Eberhard and Vincent Timmermann. 1988. "'Why LDC Growth
Lazer, William, Shoji Murata, and Hiroshi Kosaka. 1985. "Japanese Mar- Rates Differ: Measuring Unmeasurable Differences." Worm Develop-
keting: Towards a Better Understanding." European Journal of Market- ment 16 (11): 1271-1294.
ing 49 (2): 69-81. Shimagushi, Mitsuaki and William Lazer. 1979. "Japanese Distribution
Liander, Bertil et al. 1967. Comparative Analysis for International Mar- Channels: Invisible Barriers to Entry." MSU Business Topics 27 (Win-
keting. Marketing Science Institute. Boston: Allyn and Bacon. ter): 49-62.
Livesay, Harold C. 1979. American Made: Men Who Shaped the American Slater, Charles C. 1970. "Market Channel Coordination and Economic
Economy. Boston: Little and Brown. Development." In Vertical Marketing Systems. Ed. Louis P. Bucklin.
Livesay, Harold C. and Patrick G. Porter. 1969. "Vertical Integration in Glenview, IL: Scott Foresman and Company, 135-157.
American Manufacturing, 1899-1948." Journal of Economic History.' 29 Slater, Charles C. et al. 1969. "Market Processes in the Recife Area of
(September): 494-500. Northeast Brazil." Research Report No. 2. Latin Studies Center, Michi-
Mallen, Bruce. 1975. "Marketing Channels and Economic Development: gan State University9

JAMS 14 WINTER, 1992


CHANNEL EVOLUTION: A FRAMEWORK FOR ANALYSIS SHARMA AND DOMINGUEZ

Slocum, John W. 1971. "A Comparative Study of the Satisfaction of Yavas, Ugur, Erdener Kaynak, and E. Borak. 1982. "Food Shopping Ori-
American and Mexican Operatives." Journal of the Academy of Man- entations in Turkey." Food Policy (May): 133-140.
agement 14 (March): 89-98. Zald, Mayer N. 1970. "Political Economy: A Framework for Comparative
Sorensen, Olav Jull. 1978. "A Conceptual Framework for an Analysis of Analysis." In Power in Organizations. Ed. Mayer N. Zald. Nashville,
Government Intervention in Distributive Trade in Ghana." Working Pa- TN: Vanderbilt University Press, 221-261.
per, University of Ghana School of Administration. Zusman, P. and Michael Etgar. 1981. "Marketing Channel as an Equi-
Stern, Louis and Adel E1-Ansary. 1988. Marketing Channels. Third Edi- librium of Contracts." Management Science 27 (March): 284-302.
tion. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall.
Stern Louis W. and Torger Reve. 1980. "Distribution Channels as Political
Economies." Journal of Marketing 44 (Summer): 52-64.
Stigler, George J. 1951. "The Division of Labor is Limited by the Extent of
the Market." Journal of Political Economy 59 (June): 185-193. ABOUT THE AUTHORS
Terpstra, Vern. 1987. "The Evolution of International Marketing." Interna-
tional Marketing Review 4 (Summer): 47-59. Arun Sharma is Assistant Professor of Marketing in the
Tse, David K. et al. 1988. "Does Culture Matter?" Journal of Marketing School of Business at the University of Miami. He received
52 (October): 81-95.
United Nations. 1989. Prospects of World Urbanization. New York. his Ph.D. in Marketing from the University of Illinois at
Varadarajan, Rajan. 1984. "Marketing in Developing Countries: The New Urbana-Champaign. Professor Sharma's current areas of in-
Frontier." Long Range Planning 17 (December): 118-126. terest are in organizational decision making, sales manage-
Venkatesh, Alladi and Nikhilesh Dholakia. 1986. "Methodological Issues ment, and international marketing. He has published in the
in Macromarketing." Journal of Macromarketing 6 (Fall): 36-52.
Wadinambiaratchi, George H. 1965. "Channels of Distribution in Devel-
Journal of Personal Selling and Sales Management, Indus-
oping Economies." The Business Quarterly 30 (Winter): 74-82. trial Marketing Management, and the International Journal
Williamson, Oliver E. 1975. Markets and Hierarchies. New York: Free of Physical Distribution and Logistics Management.
Press.
- - . 1981. "The Economics of Organizations: The Transaction Cost
Approach." American Journal of Sociology 87 (3): 548-577.
Luis V. Dominguez is Professor of Marketing in the School
~ . 1983. "Organizational Innovation: The Transactional Cost Ap-
proach." In Entrepreneurship. Ed. Joshua Ronen. Lexington, MA: Lex- of Business at the University of Miami. He received his
ington Books. Ph.D. in Marketing from Northwestern University. His re-
World Bank. 1988. Worm Bank Report. New York: Oxford University search interests are in the areas of international marketing
Press. and marketing strategy. His most recent publications have
~ . 1990. World Development Report. New York: Oxford University
Press. appeared in the Journal of Advertising Research, the Jour-
Yau, Oliver H. M. 1988. "Chinese Cultural Values: Their Dimensions and nal of Macromarketing, and the Journal of Global Mar-
Marketing Implications." European Journal of Marketing 22 (5): 44-57. keting.

JAMS 15 WINTER, 1992

You might also like