Download as docx, pdf, or txt
Download as docx, pdf, or txt
You are on page 1of 13

University of Swansea, Student No: 570886

MSDM04: Political Economy of Media


Word Count: 4902

Intellectual property laws institute a market economy in


information. Critically discuss.

Introduction

In this paper, I aim to discuss whether intellectual property laws institute a market
economy in information i.e. to consider the impact of intellectual property laws on the
constitution of a market economy in information. To do justice to this broad topic in a
limited amount of space and time, I will conduct a broad examination of the relations
between intellectual property laws and the market economy, using several approaches
from the field of political economy. Political economy, as “the study of social
relations, particularly the power relations, that mutually constitute the production,
distribution, and consumption of resources” (Mosco 2009:2), highlights the forces at
work that bring about the law and the processes in the marketplace, to reveal any
inequalities. The “resources” are the tangible products of intellectual property owners
in physical media and technology, and the intangible, including software code, linked
to the institutions – of producers, publishers and manufacturers, wholesalers,
distributors and retailers, and end customers or consumers.

In a political economy where knowledge is not only power but also a source of profits
in modern global markets (Drahos and Braithwaite 2002), the role of intellectual
property law, the rights conferred to whom and for what, has become a critical
undertaking. In this respect, I am highlighting specific arguments raised in the book
Information Feudalism: Who owns the knowledge economy? (Drahos and Braithwaite
2002) on the impact of intellectual property laws and the key role played by the
institutions operating behind intellectual property regimes. My hope is to broaden the
debate on the political economy in intellectual property laws and update some of these
discussions.

1
Due to a lack of space, broader topics involving intellectual property laws and the
market economy, which are also important to the overall consideration of the political
economy of information, will not be covered in this paper. Particularly - (1) the broad
context of intellectual property laws1 having a profound global impact on global
political economy2 in the last three decades (Braga, Fink, and Paz Sepulveda 2000: 3-
32; Maskus 2000) and (2) the continuing inroads that intellectual property laws will
continue to make into new advances and developments in digital technology and
biotechnology3 (Goujon 2007: 123) into the future.

Firstly, I will discuss the market economy of information, or better known as the
information society (Section 1). Secondly, I will address the impact of intellectual
property laws on society as an investigation of the relationship between law and
society (Section 2). Thirdly, I will discuss some of the arguments raised in the book
Information Feudalism and provide an updated reading with a few recent examples
(Section 3). This will be followed by a brief conclusion.

Section 1: The market economy of information

A market economy in information is a reference to “the information society” (May


2002: 6) (Mattelart 2003: 1)4 – a term which has fallen into common usage to explain
“a shift in Western economies from the production of goods to the production of
innovation” (Berry 2008: 43).

1
There is a long history of intellectual property laws impacting the global market economy - “In 1984,
the United States designated inadequate protection of patents, trademarks, and copyrights as an unfair
trade practice that could invoke retaliation under Section 301 of the Trade Act of 1974. In the ensuing
16 years, intellectual property rights (IPRs) have moved from an arcane area of legal analysis and a
policy backwater to the forefront of global economic policymaking. Indeed, the world is witnessing
the greatest expansion ever in the international scope of intellectual property rights.” (Maskus 2000:1)
2
Based on World Bank figures, the global foreign direct investment (FDI) stock - a measure of the
investment underlying international production – increased fourfold between 1982 and 1994; over the
same period, it doubled as a percentage of world gross domestic product to 9 percent. In 1996, FDI
flows to developing countries amounted to $110 billion – corresponding to roughly one-third of world
total FDI inflows, although the FDI flows were concentrated among a few countries. (Braga, Fink, and
Paz Sepulveda: 3-32)
3
Multiple sources from different fields are available to support the profound impact of intellectual
property laws in our lives – “...the introduction of new standards of intellectual property protection
during the last twenty years, has had a profound impact on the sharing of data and resources in the field
of life sciences”. (Goujon 2007: 123)
4
Armand Mattelart’s Information Society: An Introduction is an excellent review of the discourse
around the idea of “information society” and the promises of democracy and freedom, the assumptions
of economic reward and the geopolitical construction that surrounds it. (Mattelart 2003: 1-4, 129-159)

2
It is argued that the shift described is an effective transition from a Fordist5 industrial
mass-production economy to a post-Fordist6 digital information and technology based
economy (Hardt and Negri 2000: 290). It is characterized by a shift to the production
of low-cost, high volume commodities based on information that has created a surplus
of goods and services; which in turn creates a market economy in the consumption of
information, communication and knowledge (Berry 2008; Drahos and Braithwaite
2002; Mattelart 2003; May 2002; Tonkiss 2006). Consequently, it is argued that
society has moved from a labor theory of value to a knowledge theory of value
(Mattelart 2003: 78). This shift creates a tension that is exhibited in various ways – in
the polarizing skills of high tech and routine production or, the value of off-shoring as
compared to mass commodity production by exploited workers (Tonkiss 2006: 104).

The idea of the post-industrial society, where “social structure can become post-
industrial regardless of political regime or cultural configuration” (Waters 1996: 108),
is support for the argument of a returning to a feudal or tribal post-industrial society
(Drahos and Braithwaite 2002: 201). The skeptics view is that the promise of the
changes to society due to an information society by governments and politicians is not
based on empirical evidence (Berry 2008: 47), that the idea of the information society
makes it easy to slip into technological determinism (May 2002: 27), and the public is
being “sold” the information society construct of a hegemonic economic system. It is
argued that the information society in the cultural logic of the final throes of late
capitalism (Jameson 1999: 87) or the lapse into information feudalism (Drahos and
Braithwaite 2002: 201). However, there is some common ground that “quantitative
changes in information are bringing into being a qualitatively new sort of social
system” (Webster 1995: 9). Equally, the common mistake is to put the promise of the
information society before the idea of an information society. The result is failing to
consider the complex amalgam of technological, economic, occupational, spatial,
cultural and qualitative or quantitative elements of the information society (Webster
1995: 8-9).

5
Mass production in a Fordist era meant there was a certain reliance on sufficiency of demand, and the
need to received feedback from the market to improve production was limited. (Hardt and Negri 2000:
290)
6
Post-Fordist era is based on the Toyota model where the planning for production involves
communication with the markets constantly and immediately (Hardt and Negri 2000: 290)

3
The question being asked, about the role of intellectual property law, the changes
precipitated by intellectual property law, and the impact of legal changes to the world
economy, has also become an increasingly important debate (Berry 2008; Drahos and
Braithwaite 2002; May 2002). The legal changes are built on the passage of global
intellectual property laws, regulations and multilateral treatises, and the rise of a
global intellectual property regime that has promised a new economy based on high
technology, knowledge creation and innovation. Law and technology makes strange
bedfellows since this optimism for a new information economy has tended to draw
upon arguments with a tendency towards technological determinism to justify its own
predictions and prescriptions (Berry 2008; May 2002) without the necessary empirical
evidence or due diligence required to deliver the promises of an information society.
The danger of this myopic perspective is the unintended consequences of introducing
technology for the sake of technology on an empty promise of economic reward.

Section 2: The impact of Intellectual Property Laws on Society

E.P. Thompson sums up the relationship between law and the market economy:

The greatest of all legal fictions is that the law itself evolves, from case to
case, by its own impartial logic, true only to its own integrity, unswayed by
expedient considerations (Thompson and Great 1975: 250).

Intellectual property refers to patents, copyrights, trademarks and trade secrets which
are employed to protect the intangible fruits of intellectual labor either as industrial
(patents protect the idea), and literary or artistic (copyrights protects the expression of
an idea) works (Cotter 2003: 1-6)7. Knowledge, usually intangible and incorporeal,
becomes subject to ownership through intellectual property rights, and treated like
material property. An analytical category of “immaterial goods”(Berry 2008: 54;
Hardt and Negri 2000: 290) is useful to distinguish the manipulation and organization
of information through enclosing techniques, such as intellectual property rights,
encryption technology or digital locks (Berry 2008: 54).

7
This is the modern legal definition of intellectual property found in most law textbooks. Intellectual
property was called “industrial property” prior to the emergence of the modern term. (Cotter 2003: 1)

4
Intellectual property laws are arguably a mode of organization in an environment,
where “immaterial” goods or services (Hardt and Negri 2000: 290) are not afforded
the same protection of intellectual property laws afforded to material goods due to
potentially infinite resources from the universal digitization of information and that
price is not the dominant factor with the plethora of free products and services
competing with material goods and services. The old model of scarcity (May 2002:
79) and price is thrown out of the window. The control over scarcity (May 2002: 79)
has become an increasingly important factor to consider in an information society.

One perspective of social change is the examination of “how power is used to shape
the production, distribution, and use of information as a commodity”(Mosco and
Wasko 1988: 3). In a capitalist society, the motive of profit from the sale of
commodities in the market is a primary driving force. The institutions and actors
involved in the many stages of this process also exert their own power over the entire
system, which in the case of intellectual property is a global regime. Broadly
speaking, there are two main justifications for the capitalist ownership of knowledge -
the promotion of the efficient use of resources (May 2002: 167) and as the reward for
intellectual property labor (Jones 2001: 785). In an industrial age, intellectual
property rights have in itself become specialized forms of knowledge, and have come
to embody the hegemonic means by which the use of knowledge is captured in
corporeal forms (Jones 2001: 884).

Prior to the existence and rise of intellectual property laws, what did we do with the
fruits of our intellectual labor? It is helpful to have a historical reference point for the
pre-modern construction of intellectual property as “mental or creative labor”
(Sherman and Bently 2000: 3). Prior to the 1850s, there was no clear consensus in
pre-modern law as to the mode of organization for mental or creative labor. While
property rights in mental labor existed, its nature or category was questionable. The
pre-modern legal treatment of property rights in mental labor was “largely determined
passively in response to the environment in which law operated” (Sherman and Bently
2000: 3). Using this historical context, it is argued that the consequence of modernity
is the legal treatment of intellectual property shifted, from the labor it produced, to the
consequential impact of the labor.

5
The significance of this subtle shift is that the law is no longer concerned about legal
interpretations and language construction, but instead “employed the resources of the
political economy and utilitarianism” (Sherman and Bently 2000: 4). If the drafting
and eventual passing of intellectual property laws are bound tightly to the creation of
a political economy in digital media and technology, then it becomes even more
critical to understand how the law is impacting social relations. This coincides with
the line of argument going back to Heidegger that “technology is a special form of
knowledge – a form of truth or disclosure” (Berry 2008, preface xi).

If law is focused on the consequential impact of the labor, what does this look like?
The global harmonization of intellectual property laws is a good example of the
economic base overtaking the autonomy of the superstructure of law and government
(Horkheimer and Adorno 2002: 234). Global organizations such as the World Trade
Organization (WTO) and the World Intellectual Property Organization (WIPO), using
the TRIPS induced quasi-governmental powers to harmonize legislation within its
signatory states and across national boundaries, had resulted in intellectual property
rights that “are recognized only when knowledge has the potential to generate profits,
through economic activity” (Jones 2001: 785).

To follow through the argument, the superstructure is colonized by the economic base
and turned into the culture industry (Horkheimer and Adorno 2002: 32). Intellectual
property rights are standardized through the TRIPS process globally, and it creates a
market for the protection and enforcement of intellectual property right in return for
patent fees, trade mark registrations and copyright filings received by the state.
Where the private colonizes the public, work and leisure is subject to the same
conformity due to an industrialized logic, described as the “social totality”
(Horkheimer and Adorno 2002: 234). We can argue further that intellectual property
rights is analogous to a new bureaucracy except, it is a global bureaucracy aimed at
the commoditization of knowledge, ideas and innovations, located in the public realm
(or intellectual commons), into private rights.

6
The imbalance between private reward and public interest is criticized (Drahos and
Braithwaite 2002: 165), and sometimes identified as intellectual enclosure (Ertuna
2009: 1-7)8, when socially available (public or traditional) knowledge is incorporated
into new products, and subjected to ownership rights (Jones 2001: 785). This “social
totality” big picture view is helpful in exposing intellectual property law and the
institutions involved, as the pervasive power of industrial logic. From this analysis,
one can see the attraction of the argument in favor of an Hobbesian interventionist
sovereign state (Jones 2001: 689) to redress the imbalance between private interest
and public reward. It has been argued that intellectual property laws and its global
regime have arguably created a global information mercantilism9 (Macdonald 1998:
31), and the argument for the direct intervention by the state in the economic sphere to
promote state interests, can be made as a result.

Section 3: Information Feudalism

In their book “Information Feudalism” (Drahos and Braithwaite 2002), the authors
draws our attention to the central role played by intellectual property laws to create of
entrenched intellectual property regimes resulting in global inequalities, enforced by
global organizations such as the World Trade Organization (WTO) and the World
Intellectual Property Organization (WIPO), wielding TRIPS (the Agreement on Trade
Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights) as a blunt instrument in cohort with
the vested interests of governments and multinationals. It is argued that the impact
can be seen in developing countries, being kept in a state of medieval feudalism
(Drahos and Braithwaite 2002: 1-2, 198-199, 219) and the stalling of the progress
from industrial to post-industrial stages of development. Intellectual property laws
are employed as tools of the intellectual property owner to lock up critical access to
knowledge on education, software, genetic and plant varieties, when such access to
information is crucial in a knowledge society (Drahos and Braithwaite 2002: 17).

8
Irmak Ertuna in her online article Digital Pirates and the Enclosure of the Intellect examines the
space of contestation between amateurs, artists and students of digital technologies to develop new
tools to share and distribute knowledge with actors of capitalist governance such as the WTO, and trade
organizations representing the dominant copyright industries of music, film and software.
9
An example of information mercantilism is the national security export controls employed by
Western countries, especially in the United States, to prevent the acquisition of technology with both
military and commercial application by the Soviet bloc. (Macdonald 1998: 31)

7
It is argued that condition that is “information feudalism” (Drahos and Braithwaite
2002: 198) puts development countries at a serious disadvantage. This is achieved
and maintained through the hegemony of international standards of intellectual
property and the rigorous policing of these standards, with the promise of more local
investment and innovation. Drahos and Braithwaite points to the increased term for
patents, from life of the author plus 50 years, to 70 years, as one example of
intellectual property owners and governments extending the monopoly of patents,
without any corresponding benefit for innovation or opportunity for more investment
(Drahos and Braithwaite 2002: 11). The cost to Australia of extending the patent term
may be as much as Aus$3.8 billion (Drahos and Braithwaite 2002: 11). Even those
who have put up a spirited defense of intellectual property based on arguments of
economic pragmatism, and natural law and justice, have acknowledged that laws such
as the Copyright Term Extension Act have overreached in recent years and has gone
too far (Spinello 2009: 2).

The attraction of Draho and Braithwaite’s arguments is based on the simple notion
that the entrenched power of intellectual property regimes is due to globalization
forces. The basis of this argument is entirely dependent on the north-south divide –
the western world against the developing countries and the impact on the global south
(Drahos and Braithwaite 2002: 209). While this helps to explain the effects of
entrenched powers, it does not explain how the power arose in the first place, why
power became to be entrenched and ignores the complex processes and systems
involved in the negotiation and implementation of TRIPS. This has opened up their
arguments to be criticized because “it does not elaborate on the strategies,
mechanisms and processes through which these groups secure their interests in the
international trading system (Pugatch 2004: 4)”. The fact that there are powerful
lobby groups acting for intellectual property groups to push for stronger protection of
global intellectual property rights, takes the argument no further than to highlight the
existence of processes and systems (TRIPS) as part of an global intellectual property
forum and arena (WTO/WIPO) as part of the “as is” situation. It is argued that this
does not explain why power is entrenched in a global process and system and the role
of the various actors and players.

8
The use of “information feudalism” is intentionally polemic and stirs controversy by
painting intellectual property owners with the same brush as feudal landlords and
reminding us of the injustice of the medieval system in the redistribution of property
rights (i.e. land), and therefore, the potential abuse of power in society (Drahos and
Braithwaite 2002: 201). By simplifying the argument, the accuser may be guilty of
the same misconceptions as the accused. The argument made by Jameson of the
integration of aesthetic and commodity production leads to a convergence of the
structure, function and position which directly impact on the nature of innovation and
experimentation sheds more light on the entrenched position of intellectual property
regimes in a knowledge economy (Jameson 1999: 56).

Therefore, it can be said that intellectual property laws and their constituent regimes
are arguably a reflection of postmodernism, or more specifically, intellectual property
laws are arguably the cultural logic of late capitalism (Jameson 1999: 56). The
purpose of TRIPS, in setting minimum standards for intellectual property laws for
member countries to meet their obligations, is to commoditize cultural products
towards promoting certain economic and social objectives. While TRIPS encourages
nations to pursue their own goals in intellectual property rights, the major constraint
imposed on nation states is that they “cannot discriminate against foreign interests and
cannot seriously prejudice the exploitation of IPRs [Intellectual Property Rights] by
foreign firms (Maskus 2000: 176).” It is argued that the colonization of the global
cultural sphere through the capitalist infrastructure of global intellectual property
regime is certainly more chilling of an effect, than the return to feudalism. Feudalism
can be dealt with by the ouster of landlords, but postmodernism or the cultural logic
of late capitalism is a much more complex animal to decipher, dissect and disrupt.

There are clear signs of a backlash against the hegemony of the global intellectual
property regime, raising questions about the efficiency argument and the growing
dissent based on unfairness and injustice in the application of this capitalist mode of
organization. A case in point is the Special 301 process, implemented by the United
States Trade Representative (USTR), as an extension of the Executive Office of the
President, responsible for bilateral and multilateral trade negotiations.

9
The USTR basically maintains a list of foreign countries on a “watch list” for
intellectual property piracy, based on data provided by the US copyright industries
(music, movies, software, books, entertainment, etc). Employing “a mechanism of
enforced coercion” (Drahos and Braithwaite 2002: 93), the USTR pursues a relentless
agenda of bilateral trade negotiations. The industry data is compiled by the
International Intellectual Property Alliance (IIPA), currently more than 40 countries,
and it makes recommendations on which country goes up or down the “watch-list”
and who is favored or not (Smith 2010b). This is invariably a legalistic, technical,
bilateral process of little interest to anyone else.

Quite surprisingly, the IIPA raised the hackles of the blogosphere (Anderson 2010;
Guadamuz 2010) through its Feb 2010 filings to the USTR related to the issuance of
an Indonesia government circular on the “Utilization of Legal Software and Open
Source Software (OSS)”. IIPA argued that the circular is an unfair preference for the
use and adoption of open source software within the Indonesian government (Smith
2010a) in the context of organization piracy. The position taken by IIPA is a clear
sign that the IIPA, the USTR and the US copyright industries are out of touch with
current trends, considering that the UK government procurement policy for open
source software takes the same position as the Indonesian government, as per Tom
Watson MP, Minister for Digital Engagement:

Open source software is not a cure-all remedy and is not the only solution to IT
questions. However, by levelling the playing field and allowing Open Source
to be as competitive as possible we can ensure that taxpayers get maximum
value for money from Government IT, something that is more important than
ever during the worldwide financial climate (Cabinet Office 2009).

The inability of organizations such as IIPA, WTO or WIPO to keep pace with free
culture and open source movements is compounded by the criminal actions brought
against Swedish bit torrent website, The Pirate Bay in 1998 (Kravets 2008). At the
height of the lawsuit against The Pirate Bay, the overall consensus in the mainstream
news and blogosphere is that this is yet another missed opportunity by US copyright
industries to adapt to a new media climate, due to the inflexibility of its position on a
file-sharing as a legitimate business model (Riley 2009).
10
More recently, the debate on the UK Digital Economy Bill, originally aimed to
improve the abysmal nationwide broadband network speeds in the UK, degenerated
into the UK government’s capitulation to the lamentations of Feargal Sharkey (among
others) in favor of addressing file-sharing and “piracy” (Naughton 2010). These
debates show a growing dissent based on a public recognition of the entrenched
preference given to copyright holders who are free riding on government granted
monopolies without due consideration given to the changes and needs of a new media
society. This imbalance is raising questions about unfairness and injustice resulting
from a longstanding hegemonic capitalist mode of production.

Conclusion

There are many views of the relations between law and the market economy. One can
argue that the law is not merely superstructure and it is not possible to separate law
from the base of the market economy, and consequently, law and productive relations
are ‘imbricated’ or overlapping (May 2002). In this respect, intellectual property laws
are able to structure productive relations and to legalize commoditization. It is also
argued that intellectual property law and multilateral agreements (such as TRIPS)
creates an entrenched position for their owners with huge profits for US multinational
corporation through the use of strong-arming tactics in a global political and
economic sphere (Drahos and Braithwaite 2002).

One of the recent perspectives offered is that “an information-based society arises as a
material formation through conscious political action and government commitment on
the one hand and corporate activities on the other (Berry 2008)” – in short, the idea of
the information economy (or what is described by Mosco as Pushbutton Fantasies
(Mosco and Wasko 1988: 4)) has taken hold in society, and being transplanted into
the fabric of the new information society through public discourse blinded by
technological determinism and the changes made by law to ideas of ownership of
knowledge, and the utilization of information.

11
All of these views are making a critical contribution to an ongoing debate, in which
the outcomes or conclusions are yet to be foretold. While we are certainly in the
course of creating an information market economy, but this may not necessarily
represent an information society – since the price to be paid for the information
society being promised by governments, politicians, and policymakers may involve an
unfair and unjust exchange in terms of individual control, ownership and freedom.

In a capitalist mode of production, the idea of the information society is the ownership
of knowledge and the utilization of information. The role of intellectual property and
its constituent global regimes is the capture of intangible ideas, including ephemeral
ideas floating in the intellectual commons, and commoditizing such ideas as tangible
property for economic profit. Therefore, it is fair to say that intellectual property laws
not only institute a market economy in information, but it is a unique political
economy that plays a critical role in the constitution of a market economy in
information society and the future of ideas in the marketplace.

Bibliography

Anderson, Bobbie. 2010. "When using open source makes you an enemy of the state."
in Technology Blog: Guardian.co.uk.
Berry, David M. 2008. Copy, rip, burn : the politics of copyleft and open source.
London: Pluto Press.
Braga, Carlos Alberto Primo, Carsten Fink, and Claudia Paz Sepulveda. 2000.
Intellectual property rights and economic development. Washington, DC:
World Bank.
Cabinet Office, UK. 2009. "Government levels the playing field for Open Source." in
Cabinet Office News 2009, edited by U. Government.
Cotter, Anne-Marie Mooney. 2003. Intellectual property law. London: Cavendish.
Drahos, Peter and John Braithwaite. 2002, "Information feudalism who owns the
knowledge economy?", (http://www.netlibrary.com/urlapi.asp?
action=summary&v=1&bookid=81169).
Ertuna, Irmak. 2009. "Digital Pirates and the Enclosure of the Intellect." Pp. 1-7 in
Darkmatter Journal. London, UK.
Goujon, Philippe. 2007. The Information Society: Innovation, Legitimacy, Ethics and
Democracy : proceedings of the Conference "Information Society:
Governance, Ethics and Social Consequences", University of Namur,
Belgium, 22 - 23 May 2006. Berlin: Springer US.
Guadamuz, Andres. 2010. "Encouraging open source could land you in trouble." in
Technollama.
Hardt, Michael and Antonio Negri. 2000. Empire. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard
University Press.

12
Horkheimer, Max and Theodor W. Adorno. 2002. Dialectic of enlightenment
philosophical fragments. Stanford, Calif: Stanford Univ. Press.
Jameson, Fredric. 1999. Postmodernism or, the cultural logic of late capitalism.
Durham: Duke University Press.
Jones, R. J. Barry. 2001, "Entries G-O" Routledge Encyclopedia of International
Political Economy, (http://site.ebrary.com/lib/librarytitles/Doc?
id=10016945).
Kravets, David. 2008. "Pirate Bay Future Uncertain After Operators Busted." in
Privacy, Crime and Security Online, edited by W. Magazine.
Macdonald, Stuart. 1998. Information for innovation : managing change from an
information perspective. Oxford [u.a.: Oxford Univ. Press.]
Maskus, Keith E. 2000. Intellectual property rights in the global economy.
Washington, DC: Inst. for Internat. Economics.
Mattelart, Armand. 2003. The information society : an introduction. London [u.a.]:
SAGE.
May, Christopher. 2002. The information society : a sceptical view. Cambridge [u.a.:
Polity Press.]
Mosco, Vincent. 2009. The political economy of communication. Los Angeles: Sage
Publications.
Mosco, Vincent and Janet Wasko. 1988. The Political economy of information.
Madison, Wis.: University of Wisconsin Press.
Naughton, John. 2010. "Shame Peter Mandelson didn't download some common
sense." in The networker, edited by G. c. u. T. Observer.
Pugatch, Meir Perez. 2004. The international political economy of intellectual
property rights. Cheltenham [u.a.: Elgar.]
Riley, Jack. 2009. "This trial has only made torrent sites much stronger." in The
Independent Commentators, edited by T. Independent.
Sherman, Brad and Lionel Bently. 2000. The making of modern intellectual property
law : The British experience, 1760-1911. [Cambridge]: Cambridge University
Press.
Smith, Eric H. 2010a, "Indonesia 2010 Special 301 Report on Copyright Protection
and Enforcement ", Retrieved April, 26, 2010
(http://www.iipa.com/rbc/2010/2010SPEC301INDONESIA.pdf).
Smith, Eric H. 2010b, "Special 301: Comments regarding the Identification of
Countries Under Section 182 of the Trade Act of 1974; Request for Public
Comment ("Special 301"), and Request to Testify at the Public Hearing, 75
Fed. Reg. 2578 (January 15, 2010)", Retrieved April, 26, 2010
(http://www.iipa.com/2010_SPEC301_TOC.htm).
Spinello, Richard A. 2009. A defense of intellectual property rights. Cheltenham, UK;
Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar.
Thompson, E. P. and Britain Great. 1975. Whigs and hunters : the origin of the Black
act. New York: Pantheon Books.
Tonkiss, Fran. 2006. Contemporary economic sociology : globalisation, production,
inequality. London; New York: Routledge.
Waters, Malcolm. 1996. Daniel Bell. London; New York: Routledge.
Webster, Frank. 1995. Theories of the information society. London and New York:
Routledge.

13

You might also like