Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 6

1

Integrated Energy and Transmission Pricing


Shri Ram Vaishya, Student Member, IEEE and Vaskar Sarkar, Member, IEEE

Abstract—This paper introduces the concept of transmission 𝑿𝒇 𝒍𝒓 (𝐿 × 1) variable vector representing the cleared
side bidding for availing power transmission services through a amounts towards reverse line flow capacity offers.
market mechanism. The transmission side bidding, in essence, 0𝒙 (𝑥 × 1) vector of all zeros.
refers to the direct market participation of transmission line
owners for selling their line capacities with appropriate price 1𝒙 (𝑥 × 1) vector of all ones.
offers. The transmission offers are submitted to the centralized (.)𝑚𝑎𝑥 Maximum value of variable (.).
auction conducted by the independent system operator for car- (.)∗ The optimal solution of a primal or dual variable.
rying out dispatch scheduling or for the issuance of transmission
rights. Those are jointly cleared along with other bids and offers,
and bid-consistent prices are established by means of marginal I. I NTRODUCTION
pricing. The uncertainty that gets involved in revenues or pay-
ments of market players because of the conventional transmission The transmission pricing is a long debated issue since the
pricing is, therefore, eliminated. By recognizing the criticality inception of power system deregulation. Unlike nodal quanti-
of power flow interactions between different transmission lines, ties (i.e., active and reactive power injections), the power flows
the auction participation of transmission line owners is suitably over transmission lines are bound by certain laws of nature.
regulated. The issuance of financial transmission rights (FTRs)
is supplemented by assigning counterflow flowgate rights to the As a consequence, the simple flow conservation principle
transmission line owners so as to ensure revenue adequate FTR between nodal quantities and line flows is not sufficient to
settlement. Detailed case studies are performed to verify the prepare the power transportation plan. In addition, the power
utility of the proposed transmission pricing methodology. transportation should be instantaneous leading the capacity
Index Terms—Centralized auction, counterflow flowgate rights, concerns of transmission corridors. The complexities involved
financial transmission right, marginal pricing, transmission bid- in power transportation led to the motivation of creating mar-
ding, transmission pricing. ket only among the nodal entities (i.e., generators and loads).
Furthermore, the original practice was to have a completely
N OMENCLATURE separate energy market, only based upon the demand-supply
balance, for fulfilling the power requirements of load entities.
𝜖 Offset term in the linear expression of the total Therefore, there was a single market clearing price throughout
network loss. the system in the case of a centralized market [1]. There
𝜂 Total number of energy bids and offers. could also be complementary markets for the management
𝝀 (𝑁𝐵 × 1) nodal LMP vector in the energy market. of network loss and congestion [2]. In any way, the entire
𝝆𝒇 (𝐿 × 1) forward TMP vector in the energy market. cost involved in power transportation had to be recovered (as
𝝆𝒓 (𝐿 × 1) reverse TMP vector in the energy market. additional charges) through a regulatory procedure from the
Ψ (𝐿 × 𝑁𝐵 ) DC power flow-based branch-node power trades that took place in the energy market. The subsequent
flow sensitivity matrix. developments led to the incorporation of transmission loss and
𝑲 (𝑁𝐵 × 1) loss distribution vector for the aggregated congestion aspects in the energy market itself by establishing
network loss. locational marginal prices (LMPs) [3]-[4]. Therefore, the costs
𝐿 Total number of transmission lines. incurred in power transportation because of network loss
𝑳𝑭 (𝑁𝐵 × 1) vector of nodal loss factors. and congestion are not to be separately recovered. However,
𝑁𝐵 Number of network buses. the costs incurred by transmission line owners (in terms
𝑃𝑙𝑜𝑠𝑠 Variable representing aggregate network loss. of establishment, operation, and maintenance) in providing
𝒇 𝒊𝒙
𝑷𝒍𝒐𝒂𝒅 (𝑁𝐵 ×1) parameter vector representing the net nodal power transportation services are still not accounted in the
fixed loads in the energy market. energy market. Therefore, the transmission pricing (which ba-
𝒇 𝒕𝒓
𝑷𝒊𝒏𝒋 (𝑁𝐵 ×1) vector of net nodal power injections caused sically deals with recovering the costs of transmission service
by the physical equivalents of active FTRs. providers) has been left as a regulatory procedure till date.
𝑊 (.) Social-welfare function. The conventional transmission pricing approaches are built
𝑊 𝑜𝑝𝑡 (∗) Optimal social-welfare as the function of *. upon three main regulatory decisions with regard to the issues,
𝑿𝒆𝒏𝒓 (𝜂 × 1) variable vector representing the cleared namely, 1) quantifying the transmission system usages made
amounts towards energy bids and offers. by nodal entities, 2) usage discrimination, and 3) pricing
𝑿𝒇 𝒍𝒇 (𝐿 × 1) variable vector representing the cleared the usage of a transmission resource. There are two basic
amounts towards forward line flow capacity offers. paradigms for defining the usage of the transmission system.
In one category, the usage of the transmission system is
Shri Ram Vaishya (email: ee13p1013@iith.ac.in) and Vaskar Sarkar (email:
vaskar@iith.ac.in) are with the Department of Electrical Engineering, Indian defined by means of a scalar with a consolidated view of
Institute of Technology Hyderabad, Kandi, Sangareddy 502285, India. the entire network, e.g., postage stamp and the MW-Mile
978-1-5090-3646-2/16/$31.00 ⃝2016
c IEEE
2

methodologies. The other paradigm of transmission system of having markets for similar entities such as reactive power
usage attribution takes a separate view of each individual compensators and hydro plants. The concept of transmission
transmission line. Those are, 1) the principle of DC power market originally appears in the contract path theory [2]. How-
flow (DCPF) [5], 2) the principle of current flow [6], 3) the ever, the contract path methodology or any other decentral-
principle of proportional sharing [7]-[8], and 4) the principle ized transmission market approach is practically inapplicable
of optimality [9]. There is also a mixed paradigm in which a because it neither obeys the physical laws of line flows nor
final scalar assessment is made based upon an initial vector recognizes the necessity of a power pool. The implementation
assessment. The power flow based MW-Mile methodology of the transmission market needs close co-ordination with
[10], [11] and MVA-Mile methodology [12] falls under this the energy market through a centralized mechanism. The
category. specific contribution of this paper is to design an integrated
There can be price discrimination between different en- energy and transmission market based upon the principle
tities for the transmission system usages. For example, the of LMP [3]-[4]. The transmission pricing methodology in-
transmission system usages made by a generating entity and troduced differs from the traditional concept of incremental
a load entity may be charged at different rates [7], [13]. transmission pricing [10], [15] in that the transmission revenue
Another form of usage differentiation can happen with regard requirements (TRRs) are explicitly taken into account in the
to the treatment of counterflows. The issue of counterflows dispatch scheduling. The financial transmission right (FTR)
arises in the case of DCPF and current flow based power market is consistently designed ensuring revenue adequate
tracings. In one approach, counterflow usages of a transmission FTR settlement. It is to be noted that a similar transmission
line are charged at the same rate as that for the loading bidding concept was proposed in [16]. There, the transmission
usages, whereas, in the other approach, those are treated non- bidding is, however, performed only for controlled transmis-
chargeable [10], [11]. The transmission pricing can be carried sion lines. In addition, no FTR related issues are taken into
out ex-post or ex-ante [13]. In the case of ex-post pricing, the account in [16]. On the other hand, the framework developed
network tariffs are determined based upon the actual power in this paper is generalized enough to consider both controlled
flow profile obtained after clearing the market. On the other and uncontrolled transmission lines while maintaining perfect
hand, the ex-ante pricing [13] sets network tariffs based upon compatibility with the FTR mechanism.
the estimation of the future power flow profile. The rest of the paper is organized as follows: The dispatch
The main shortcoming of the existing transmission pricing scheduling under integrated energy and transmission pricing
methodologies is that those generate certain forms of price is explained in Section II. The implementation of FTRs in the
uncertainty. In the case of ex-post pricing, the network tariffs new market environment is discussed in Section III. In Section
are imposed in the form of uplift charges leading to price IV, case studies are performed to illustrate the functionality,
uncertainty for generating and load entities. In [7], it was practicality, and benefit of market based transmission pricing.
suggested that only load entities should be liable to pay Finally, the paper is concluded in Section V.
network tariffs. The particular approach can definitely mitigate
the price uncertainty issue of the conventional transmission II. D ISPATCH S CHEDULING
pricing provided all the loads are completely price-insensitive. Conventionally, the dispatch schedules are determined only
However, with the thrust on the efficient consumer load based upon the bids and offers from nodal entities. The
management in the smart grid era [14], price-sensitive load transmission line flows can be freely adjusted upto the physical
requests in the wholesale market are likely to be unavoidable. loadability limits. However, for the proposed market frame-
For ex-ante pricing, price uncertainty is observed by the work, transmission line capacities are to be purchased by the
transmission line owners since the actual power flow profile independent system operator (ISO). The dispatch schedules
may not always closely match the estimated power flow should be prepared in a way so that the power flow over a
profile. This can specifically happen since the generating and line does not exceed the line capacity that is purchased. The
load entities modify their offer and bid prices by taking forward and reverse line capacities are purchased by inviting
into account the network tariffs to be paid. The mismatch separate capacity offers for forward and reverse direction from
between estimated and actual power flow profiles may lead transmission line owners. In this paper, the dispatch scheduling
to insufficient collection to fulfill the revenue requirements of is carried out by employing the reference independent lossy
transmission line owners as per the actual line usages. Finally, DC optimal power flow (DCOPF) model proposed in [4]. The
there is still no clear basis to determine best of all the available line capacities are expressed in terms of lossless flows. It is
transmission pricing methodologies. The particular assessment assumed that there are sufficient reactive power supports at
could be made only based upon some empirical ground. all the buses to maintain a fixed bus voltage profile of one
In this paper, a concept of market based transmission pricing per unit. The dispatch schedules are, as usual, obtained by
is introduced. The shortcomings of the existing transmission maximizing the social welfare or minimizing the social cost.
pricing methodologies can be overcome by creating a market However, the social welfare or cost function must include the
for procuring transmission services. That is, there can be costs of transmission line owners. The dispatch scheduling
capacity offers from the transmission line owners, based upon problem can, therefore, be formulated as follows.
which the line flows should be scheduled. Although there { }
minimize 𝑍 = − 𝑊 (𝑿𝒆𝒏𝒓 , 𝑿𝒇 𝒍𝒇 , 𝑿𝒇 𝒍𝒓 ) (1)
is no variable cost associated with a transmission line, the
concept of transmission market is justified on the background such that
3

𝒇 𝒊𝒙
𝒈1 : Ψ{𝑨𝑿𝒆𝒏𝒓 −𝑷𝒍𝒐𝒂𝒅 −𝑲𝑃𝑙𝑜𝑠𝑠 }−𝑿𝒇 𝒍𝒇 −𝑷𝒇𝒇𝒍𝒇
𝒊𝒙
≤ 0𝑳 (2) A generating entity is paid and a load entity is charged ac-
𝒇 𝒊𝒙 cording to the LMPs at the respective locations. For a bilateral
𝒈2 : Ψ{𝑷𝒍𝒐𝒂𝒅 +𝑲𝑃𝑙𝑜𝑠𝑠 −𝑨𝑿𝒆𝒏𝒓 }−𝑿𝒇 𝒍𝒓 −𝑷𝒇𝒇𝒍𝒓 𝒊𝒙
≤ 0𝑳 (3) transaction, a congestion-cum-loss charge is applicable, which
( 𝒇 𝒊𝒙 )
ℎ1 : 1𝑵𝑩 𝑇 𝑨𝑿𝒆𝒏𝒓 − 𝑷𝒍𝒐𝒂𝒅 − 𝑃𝑙𝑜𝑠𝑠 = 0 (4) is given by the LMP difference between its sink and source
( 𝒇 𝒊𝒙 )
ℎ2 : 𝑃𝑙𝑜𝑠𝑠 − 𝑳𝑭 𝑇 𝑨𝑿𝒆𝒏𝒓 − 𝑷𝒍𝒐𝒂𝒅 −𝜖=0 (5) locations. In the same line, the transmission line owners are
𝒎𝒂𝒙 to be paid according to transmission marginal prices (TMPs)
𝒒1 : 𝑿𝒆𝒏𝒓 − 𝑿𝒆𝒏𝒓 ≤ 0𝜼 (6)
for the line capacities that they provide. The TMP vectors are
𝒒2 : −𝑿𝒆𝒏𝒓 ≤ 0𝜼 (7) obtained as follows.
𝒒3 : 𝑿𝒇 𝒍𝒇 − 𝑿𝒇𝒎𝒂𝒙
𝒍𝒇 ≤ 0𝑳 (8) { ( 𝒇 𝒊𝒙 }
𝒊𝒙 ) 𝑇
∂𝑊 𝑜𝑝𝑡 𝑷𝒍𝒐𝒂𝒅 , 𝑷𝒇𝒇𝒍𝒇
𝒊𝒙
, 𝑷𝒇𝒇𝒍𝒓
𝒒4 : −𝑿𝒇 𝒍𝒇 ≤ 0𝑳 (9) 𝝆𝒇 = = 𝝁1 ∗ (14)
𝒒5 : 𝑿𝒇 𝒍𝒓 − 𝑿𝒇𝒎𝒂𝒙 ∂𝑷𝒇𝒇𝒍𝒇
𝒊𝒙
𝒍𝒓 ≤ 0𝑳 (10)
{ ( 𝒇 𝒊𝒙 }
𝒊𝒙 ) 𝑇
𝒒6 : −𝑿𝒇 𝒍𝒓 ≤ 0𝑳 . (11) ∂𝑊 𝑜𝑝𝑡 𝑷𝒍𝒐𝒂𝒅 , 𝑷𝒇𝒇𝒍𝒇
𝒊𝒙
, 𝑷𝒇𝒇𝒍𝒓
𝝆𝒓 = = 𝝁2 ∗ . (15)
Here, 𝑿𝒆𝒏𝒓 , 𝑿𝒇 𝒍𝒇 and 𝑿𝒇 𝒍𝒓 are the decision variables, ∂𝑷𝒇𝒇𝒍𝒓
𝒊𝒙

and 𝑃𝑙𝑜𝑠𝑠 is the other variable. Constraints (2) and (3) en-
For each line, a pair of TMPs are calculated (for forward
sure that the line flows caused by the scheduled loads and
and reverse flow directions, respectively), which are applicable
generations will not exceed the forward and reverse flow
only for the owner of the respective transmission line. The
capacities, respectively, purchased from the transmission line
TMP can never be negative since 𝝁1 ∗ and 𝝁2 ∗ are always
owners. The 𝑿𝒆𝒏𝒓 vector is converted into nodal injections
non-negative according to the KKT necessary conditions of
by means of the (𝑁𝐵 × 𝜂) incidence matrix 𝑨. The base
optimality [18]. Therefore, there is no threat of negative
capacity vectors 𝑷𝒇𝒇𝒍𝒇
𝒊𝒙
and 𝑷𝒇𝒇𝒍𝒓
𝒊𝒙
are the line capacities that are
payment towards a offered transmission capacity.
already purchased. For example, in a multi-settlement system,
the line capacities purchased in the day-ahead (DA) market Further, according to the KKT necessary conditions of
will add to the base line capacities in the hour-ahead (HA) optimality, the LMP vector can be decomposed as follows [4].
market. Similarly, the line capacities purchased upto the HA 𝝀𝒆 = −𝜅2 ∗ 1𝑵𝑩 (16)
market, will add to the base line capacities in the real-time
(RT) market. Constraint (4) is the power balance constraint 𝝀𝒍𝒐𝒔𝒔 = 𝜅2 ∗ 𝑳𝑭 (17)
that, in essence, ensures zero slack power requirement [3]. 𝝀𝒄 = {(𝝁1 ∗ − 𝝁2 ∗ )𝑇 Ψ𝑲}1𝑵𝑩 − Ψ𝑇 (𝝁1 ∗ − 𝝁2 ∗ ). (18)
The network loss caused by a particular generation and load
schedule (with respect a certain energy reference) is found Here, 𝝀𝒆 , 𝝀𝒍𝒐𝒔𝒔 , and 𝝀𝒄 are the energy, loss, and congestion
through (5). The other constraints simply ensure that the components of the 𝝀, respectively. The net congestion collec-
cleared quantities towards bids and offers will not exceed tion (NCC) and the net loss collection (NLC) of the ISO from
the specified limits. It is to be noted, although a particular nodal entities can be derived as follows.
energy reference is to be chosen to find out Ψ, 𝑳𝑭 and 𝜖,
NCC = 𝝁1 ∗ 𝑇 (𝑿𝒇 𝒍𝒇 ∗ +𝑷𝒇𝒇𝒍𝒇
𝒊𝒙
)+𝝁2 ∗ 𝑇 (𝑿𝒇 𝒍𝒓 ∗ +𝑷𝒇𝒇𝒍𝒓
𝒊𝒙
) (19)
the final results are always reference independent [4]. For the
sake of simplicity, the controlled transmission lines are not 𝒇 𝒊𝒙
explicitly considered here. In addition, the security constraints NLC = −(𝝀𝒆 + 𝝀𝒍𝒐𝒔𝒔 )𝑇 (𝑨𝑿𝒆𝒏𝒓

− 𝑷𝒍𝒐𝒂𝒅 ) = 𝜅2 ∗ 𝜖. (20)
are also not included. However, controlled transmission lines
can be easily accommodated into the above formulation by Equation (19) reveals that the net congestion collection of the
representing those in the form of bilateral transactions [17]. ISO perfectly balances the net payment to the transmission line
In the case the security constraints are included, the owner of owners. Therefore, the congestion components of locational
a transmission line should be paid mainly for the capacity that marginal prices in effect represent transmission prices for
is procured for the normal system operation. nodal entities. The net loss collection in the DA market is
The Lagrangian function of the optimization problem (1)- usually positive [19]. The loss collection of the ISO can be
(11) can be written as, used to partially compensate the revenue shortfall (that can
practically happen because of the simultaneous feasibility test
2
∑ 6
∑ model mismatch) in the FTR settlement. Alternatively, it can
Λ=𝑍+ 𝑇
(𝝁𝒋 𝒈𝒋 + 𝜅𝑗 ℎ𝑗 ) + 𝝑 𝒊 𝑇 𝒒𝒊 (12)
also be paid to the transmission line owner for lowering the
𝑗=1 𝑖=1
future transmission capacity offer prices.
where, all 𝝁𝒋 , 𝜅𝑗 , and 𝝑𝒊 are the Lagrangian multipliers. The In the case of the HA and RT markets, the generations and
LMP at a node is defined as the rate of the decrease of optimal loads that have already been scheduled, and the line capacities
social welfare with respect to the fixed (or inelastic) load that have already been purchased are to be kept outside the
increase at that node. Therefore, from the theory of sensitivity market settlement. So far as there is no change in the network
analysis [18], model from the DA market to the HA or RT market, the NLC
{ ( 𝒇 𝒊𝒙 }
𝒊𝒙 ) 𝑇
∂𝑊 𝑜𝑝𝑡 𝑷𝒍𝒐𝒂𝒅 , 𝑷𝒇𝒇𝒍𝒇
𝒊𝒙
, 𝑷𝒇𝒇𝒍𝒓 in each of those markets will be zero and the additional line
𝝀 = − 𝒇 𝒊𝒙 capacities purchased can be adequately paid from the NCC.
∂𝑷𝒍𝒐𝒂𝒅 It is to be noted that similar analytical results are obtained in
= −𝜅1 ∗ 1𝑵𝑩 + 𝜅2 ∗ 𝑳𝑭 − Ψ𝑇 (𝝁1 ∗ − 𝝁2 ∗ ). (13) the case the matrix loss distribution model [20] is employed.
4

III. FTR I MPLEMENTATION are to be enforced [as in (8)-(11)]. In the case any controlled
Financial transmission rights are useful tools to guard for- transmission line is present, it has to be represented as an
ward contracts from the uncertainty of spatial LMP variation obligation FTR. As for the energy market, the net collection
[21], [22]. The owner of an FTR is paid according to the from the FTR issuance perfectly balances the net payment
congestion component of the day-ahead LMP difference over towards transmission line owners in the FTR auction.
its FTR path. Conventionally, FTR payments are funded from In order to verify the net position of a transmission line
the net congestion collection of the ISO in the DA market. owner over energy and FTR markets, two different situations
However, as was shown in the previous section, the net can be considered. In the case the day-ahead TMP is lower
congestion collection is to be fully consumed to pay the than the TMP in the FTR auction, the capacity payment re-
transmission line owners in the case of integrated energy and ceived from the FTR auction overcompensates the counterflow
transmission pricing. Therefore, some other funding source is FGR liability. In the other case, the day-ahead TMP may have
required to make hourly FTR payments. One option to fund higher value; however, this can happen only when a capacity
FTR payments is to assign counterflow flowgate rights (FGRs) offer is fully selected (i.e., the maximum limit constraint on the
to transmission line owners. A counterflow FGR is similar to capacity offer becomes active) in the DA market. Therefore,
the conventional option FGR; however, instead of being paid, the counterflow FGR liability can be perfectly compensated
the owner of a counterflow FGR has to pay the hourly value of by using the payment for a portion of the capacity sold in the
the respective FGR. The hourly values of FGRs are calculated DA market. The DA payment lost is substituted by the bid-
according to TMP. It is to be noted that the TMPs are, in consistent payment for the same MW from the FTR auction.
effect, similar to flowgate shadow prices. The collection from Therefore, for both the above cases, the net payment received
counterflow FGRs can be used to pay the FTR owners. by the transmission line owner is no lower than the revenue
In order to assign counterflow FGRs to transmission line requirement for the capacity sold in the DA market. Additional
owners, it is required to purchase line capacities for the bid-consistent payments may be received by selling capacities
issuance of FTRs. The line capacities purchased for the FTR in HA and RT markets. It is to be noted that a transmission
issuance are to be treated as counterflow FGRs in the DA line owner is assumed to quote a flat rate in its capacity offer.
market. Let, the forward and reverse line flow capacities Moreover, the same price is quoted in the FTR auction as well
purchased to issue FTRs be indicated by 𝑷𝒇𝒇𝒍𝒇 𝒕𝒓
and 𝑷𝒇𝒇𝒍𝒓
𝒕𝒓
, as in the energy market.
respectively. Therefore, the net FGR collection (NFC) of the
ISO would be as follows. IV. C ASE S TUDY
𝒇 𝒕𝒓 𝒇 𝒕𝒓 𝒇 𝒕𝒓 𝒇 𝒕𝒓 Two different case studies are performed. In the first case
NFC = 𝝆𝑻 𝑻 ∗𝑻 ∗𝑻
𝒇 𝑷𝒇 𝒍𝒇 + 𝝆𝒓 𝑷𝒇 𝒍𝒓 = 𝝁1 𝑷𝒇 𝒍𝒇 + 𝝁2 𝑷𝒇 𝒍𝒓 . (21) study, the net position of a transmission line owner over the
The total target payment (TTP) towards FTRs can be calcu- FTR and energy markets is numerically illustrated. The second
lated as follows. case study is performed to demonstrate the benefits of market
𝒇 𝒕𝒓 𝒇 𝒕𝒓 based transmission pricing over the conventional regulatory
TTP = −𝝀𝒄 𝑇 𝑷𝒊𝒏𝒋 = (𝝁1 ∗ − 𝝁2 ∗ )𝑇 Ψ𝑷𝒊𝒏𝒋 . (22) transmission pricing. The base MVA for all the case studies
Therefore, the surplus amount (SA = NFC - TTP) left with is taken to be 100. The base case system state for the loss
the ISO after the FTR settlement is given by, linearization is established through an initial lossless DCOPF
calculation. The loss distribution vector 𝑲 is also determined
SA = 𝝁1 ∗ 𝑇 (𝑷𝒇𝒇𝒍𝒇
𝒕𝒓 𝒇 𝒕𝒓
−Ψ𝑷𝒊𝒏𝒋 )+𝝁2 ∗ 𝑇 (𝑷𝒇𝒇𝒍𝒓
𝒕𝒓 𝒇 𝒕𝒓
+Ψ𝑷𝒊𝒏𝒋 ). (23) based upon the aforementioned base case system state. The
The FTRs are issued by satisfying the following power flow base case line losses are initially distributed in 1:1 ratio over
the respective terminal buses in the form of additional loads.
constraints.
−𝑷𝒇𝒇𝒍𝒓
𝒕𝒓 𝒇 𝒕𝒓
≤ Ψ𝑷𝒊𝒏𝒋 ≤ 𝑷𝒇𝒇𝒍𝒇
𝒕𝒓
. (24) A. Case Study 1: Demonstration of the market settlement for
It is to be noted that a lossless network model is employed for transmission line owners
𝒇 𝒕𝒓
the FTR issuance (therefore, 1𝑵𝑩 𝑇 𝑷𝒊𝒏𝒋 = 0). Condition (24) Consider a four-bus and five-line system. The line informa-
together with the non-negativity condition of 𝝁(.) ∗ ensures tion of the particular system is provided in Table I. Here, the
non-negativity of the surplus amount derived in (23). There- line loadability is assumed to be the same in each direction.
fore, there will certainly be revenue adequacy if the FTRs In addition, both forward and reverse capacities are offered at
of simultaneously feasible within the line capacities that are the same price. The results of an FTR auction are produced
purchased. However, since line capacities are to be purchased in Tables II and III. The FTR auction conducted here is a
even for the FTR issuance, FTRs can be issued only through single-round FTR auction and all the FTRs issued have the
auctions. That is, the direct allocation of FTRs is not possible same validity period and time-of-use. In addition, there is no
under integrated energy and transmission pricing. The FTR self-scheduled or previously issued FTR in the particular FTR
auction problem can be formulated in the traditional way [22]. auction. The acronyms “Op” and “Ob” stand for “option” and
Only the capacity offers from the transmission line owners are “obligation”, respectively. Tables IV and V produce the market
to be included in the objective function and the network limits clearing results of a subsequent DA market. Apart from the
are to be specified in terms of purchased capacities [as in (2) bids and offers shown in Table IV, a fixed load request of 50
and (3)]. In addition, the limits on the line capacity offers MW at Bus 2 is also considered in the DA market.
5

TABLE I TABLE VI
L INE I NFORMATION OF THE 4-B US S YSTEM (C ASE S TUDY 1) N ET P OSITIONS OF T RANSMISSION L INE OWNERS (C ASE S TUDY 1)

Line From To Impedance Loadability Offer price LineAuction revenue ($/h) FGR Net Target
id. (p.u.) (MW) ($/MWh) no. FTR DA liability ($/h) revenue ($/h) revenue ($/h)
TL1 2 3 0.01+𝑗0.15 100 1 TL1 99 45.23 99 45.23 45.23
TL2 3 4 0.02+𝑗0.15 51 2 TL2 178.5 90.17 102 166.67 90.17
TL3 4 1 0.01+𝑗0.1 95 1 TL3 95 25.21 95 25.21 25.21
TL4 4 2 0.02+𝑗0.2 36 2 TL4 126 0.21 72 54.21 0.21
TL5 1 2 0.015+𝑗0.1 25 1.5 TL5 34.5 172.65 158.84 48.31 37.5

TABLE II
FTR I SSUANCE R ESULTS (C ASE S TUDY 1) B. Case Study 2: Demonstration of the benefit of market based
transmission pricing
FTR Path Type Requested Bid Cleared Clearing
no. quantity price quantity price The particular case study is performed on the IEEE 118-
(MW) ($/MWh) (MW) ($/MWh)
FTR 1 1-3 Ob. 120 3.5 118 3.5
bus system. The generator, load, and transmission line data
FTR 2 2-3 Ob. 100 2.5 32 2.5 of the IEEE 118-bus system are provided in [23]. For the
FTR 3 2-4 Ob. 80 2 80 0.5 sake of simplicity, however, the minimum MW limits of the
FTR 4 1-4 Op. 50 1.5 0 1.5 generators are set to zero. In addition, the R/X ratio of each
line is taken as 0.1 for ensuring power flow accuracy in the
TABLE III DCOPF calculation. The line reactances are maintained at the
L INE C APACITY P URCHASE R ESULTS : FTR AUCTION (C ASE S TUDY 1)
original values. The price quoted by a generator is equal to
Line no. Capacity purchased (MW) TMP ($/MWh) its marginal cost of production. The full generation capacities
Forward Reverse Forward Reverse are offered in the energy market. All the loads are assumed
TL1 99 0 1 0 to be price insensitive. No bilateral transaction is considered
TL2 0 51 0 3.5
TL3 0 95 0 1 for this case study. The price quoted by a transmission line
TL4 0 36 0 3.5 owner is considered to be 2000 times of the ratio between
TL5 23 0 1.5 0 respective line reactance (p.u.) and line loadability (MW). No
TRR recovery is made for the unutilized line capacity.
TABLE IV The system load profile is assumed to exhibit monthly
DA M ARKET R ESULTS FOR N ODAL E NTITIES (C ASE S TUDY 1)
variations. The load data provided in [23] is treated as the
Bid Type Bus/ Requested Bid Cleared Clearing mean load profile for a particular time block of a day.
id. path quantity price quantity price The load profiles (pertaining to the above mentioned time
(MW) ($/MWh) (MW) ($/MWh) block) for different months are randomly generated from the
GB1 Generator 1 100 20 50.29 20
GB2 Generator 2 150 25 90.49 25 Gaussian distribution with a diagonal covariance matrix. The
TL1 Load 3 90 30 90 25.93 load standard deviation at a node is taken as 5% of the mean
TB1 Transaction 4-2 20 5 20 1.79 load. Fig. 1 shows the LMP profiles for the first six months
with transmission bidding.
TABLE V
L INE C APACITY P URCHASE R ESULTS : DA M ARKET (C ASE S TUDY 1)

Line no. Capacity purchased (MW) TMP ($/MWh)


Forward Reverse Forward Reverse
TL1 45.23 0 1 0
TL2 0 45.08 0 2
TL3 0 25.21 0 1
TL4 0 0.11 0 2
TL5 25 0 6.91 0

The final positions of the transmission line owners after


the DA market are summarized in Table VI. The revenue or Fig. 1. LMP profile under market based transmission pricing.
liability is aggregated over forward and reverse directions. The
target revenue corresponds to the minimum revenue that is In order to carry out the conventional transmission pricing,
expected from the line capacity sold in the DA market. The the usage dependent pricing approach and the proportional
target revenue is calculated on the basis of the offer price. sharing principle are followed. The usage of a transmission
In the case of Lines 1, 2, 3 and 4, the FTR auction TMPs line is defined with respect to the receiving end flow. The
are greater than or equal to day-ahead TMPs. In contrast, power loss in a transmission line is represented by means an
the TMP for Line 5 is higher in the DA market. However, it equivalent load at the sending end bus. Counterflow usages are
can be seen that the net revenue of a transmission line owner assumed to be non-chargeable. For the sake of simplicity in
is no lower than the target revenue irrespective of the TMP illustration, network usages made by loads are also assumed to
difference between the FTR auction and the DA market. be non-chargeable. The revenue requirement of a transmission
6

line owner is kept the same as in the case of transmission issuance of incremental FTRs is not possible. Although there
bidding. may be higher spatial variation of LMPs in the case of the
The transmission prices are charged on monthly basis. For market based transmission pricing, it is shown in another case
the first month, the transmission pricing is carried out ex- study that LMPs are much more volatile for the conventional
post. However, for the subsequent months, the ex-ante pricing and purely regulatory transmission pricing.
is performed. As mentioned previously, a generating entity
will modify its cost function by including the network tariff R EFERENCES
component. However, for the first month, the original cost [1] D. Kirschen and G. Strbac, Fundamentals of power system economics.
functions are retained. The resultant LMP profiles for the first England: John Willey & Sons, 2004.
six months are shown in Fig. 2. The specific observation that [2] B. J. Kirby, J. W. V. Dyke, C. Martinez, and A. Rodriguez, “Congestion
management requirements, methods and performance indices,” Oak
can be made here is the higher volatility of locational marginal Ridge Nat. Lab., Oak Ridge, TN, Rep. ORNL/TM-2002/119, Jun. 2002.
prices although the spatial LMP variation is less compared [3] T. Wu, Z. Alaywan, and A. D. Papalexopoulos, “Locational marginal
to that with transmission bidding. However, compared to the price calculations using the distributed-slack power-flow formulation,”
IEEE Trans. Power Syst., vol. 20, no. 2, pp. 1188-1190, May 2005.
spatial price variation, the price volatility (or temporal price [4] E. Litvinov, T. Zheng, G. Rosenwald, and P. Shamsollahi, “Marginal
variation) may be more harmful for the society. The situation loss modeling in LMP calculation,” IEEE Trans. Power Syst., vol. 19,
may worsen in the case of ex-post pricing since an entity no. 2, pp. 880-888, May 2004.
[5] F. D. Galiana, A. J. Conejo, and H. A. Gil, “Transmission network cost
will then have to anticipate the network tariff to modify its allocation based on equivalent bilateral exchanges,” IEEE Trans. Power
cost function. It can be seen that the overall range of spatial- Syst., vol. 18, no. 4, pp. 1425-1431, Nov. 2003.
cum-temporal price variation is almost the same for both the [6] A. J. Conejo, J. Contreras, D. A. Lima, and A. Padilha-Feltrin, “𝑍𝑏𝑢𝑠
transmission network cost allocation,” IEEE Trans. Power Syst., vol. 22,
existing and proposed market systems. However, the problem no. 1, pp. 342-349, Feb. 2007.
of temporal price variation is get rid of by converting it into the [7] J. Bialek, “Allocation of transmission supplementary charge to real and
less problematic spatial price variation through transmission reactive loads,” IEEE Trans. Power Syst., vol. 13, no. 3, pp. 749-754,
Aug. 1998.
bidding. [8] D. Kirschen and G. Strbac, “Tracing active and reactive power between
generators and loads using real and imaginary currents,” IEEE Trans.
Power Syst., vol. 14, no. 4, pp. 1312-1319, Nov. 1999.
[9] A. R. Abhyankar, S. A. Soman, and S. A. Khaparde, “Optimization
approach to real power tracing: an application to transmission fixed cost
allocation,” IEEE Trans. Power Syst., vol. 21, no. 3, pp. 1350-1361,
Aug. 2006.
[10] T. Krause, “Evaluation of transmission pricing methods for liberalized
markets,” EEH Power Syst. Lab., ETH Zurich, Zurich, Jul., 2003.
[11] J. W. M. Lima, “Allocation of transmission fixed charges: an overview,”
IEEE Trans. Power Syst., vol. 11, no. 3, pp. 1409-1418, Aug. 1996.
[12] S. Nojeng, M. Y. Hassan, D. M. Said, M. P. Abdullah, and F. Hussin,
“Improving the MW-mile method using the power factor-based approach
for pricing the transmission services,” IEEE Trans. Power Syst., vol. 29,
no. 5, pp. 2042-2048, Sep. 2014.
[13] A. R. Abhyankar and S. A. Khaparde, “Electricity transmission pricing:
Fig. 2. LMP profiles under proportional sharing based transmission pricing. tracing based point-of-connection tariff,” Int. J. Elec. Power and Energy
Syst., vol. 31, no. 1, pp. 59-66, Jan. 2009.
[14] P. Palensky and D. Dietrich, “Demand side management: demand
response, intelligent energy systems, and smart loads,” IEEE Trans. Ind.
V. C ONCLUSION Informat., vol. 7, no. 3, pp. 381-388, Aug. 2011.
[15] C. W. Yu and A. K. David, “Pricing transmission services in the context
The conventional transmission pricing methodologies can of industry deregulation,” IEEE Trans. Power Syst., vol. 12, no. 1,
pp. 503-510, Feb. 1997.
create price uncertainty for nodal entities or transmission [16] R. P. O’Neil, R. Baldick, U. Helman, M. H. Rothkoph, and W. Stewart,
line owners as well as are disputable with regard to making Jr., “Dispatchable transmission in RTO markets,” IEEE Trans. Power
a choice of overall superiority. To resolve those issues, an Syst., vol. 20, no. 1, pp. 171-179, Feb. 2005.
[17] V. Sarkar and S. A. Khaparde, “Implementation of LMP-FTR mecha-
auction based mechanism is proposed for the procurement nism in an AC-DC system,” IEEE Trans. Power Syst., vol. 23, no. 2,
of transmission services. Therefore, the dispatch scheduling pp. 737-746, May 2008.
problem is reformulated by including capacity offers from the [18] S. Boyd and L. Vandenberghe, Convex Optimization. Cambridge, U.K.:
Cambridge Univ. Press, 2004.
transmission line owners. The principle of locational marginal [19] V. Sarkar and S. A. Khaparde, “Introduction to loss-hedging financial
pricing is followed. The line flows should be scheduled only transmission rights,” IEEE Trans. Power Syst., vol. 24, no. 2, pp. 621-
within the capacities that are purchased. The transmission 630, May 2009.
[20] V. Sarkar and S. A. Khaparde, “DCOPF-based marginal loss pricing
line capacities purchased are paid by using the fund of net with enhanced power flow accuracy by using matrix loss distribution,”
congestion collection from nodal entities. The issuance of IEEE Trans. Power Syst., vol. 24, no. 3, pp. 1435-1445, Aug. 2009.
FTRs also requires capacity offers from transmission line [21] W. W. Hogan, “Contract networks for electric power transmission,” J.
Reg. Econ., vol. 4, pp. 211-242, Sep. 1992.
owners. Therefore, FTRs can be issued only through auctions. [22] V. Sarkar and S. A. Khaparde, “A comprehensive assessment of the
The line capacities purchased in the FTR auction are used as evolution of financial transmission rights,” IEEE Trans. Power Syst.,
counterflow FGRs in the DA market to pay the hourly values vol. 23, no. 4, pp. 1783-1795, Nov. 2008.
[23] [Online]. Available: motor.ece.iit.edu/data/JEAS IEEE118.doc.
of FTRs. Thus, a transmission line owner is bid-consistently
paid only for the line capacity that is purchased in the energy
market. Since FTRs can be issued only through auctions, the

You might also like