Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 11

JPMA-01631; No of Pages 11

Available online at www.sciencedirect.com

ScienceDirect
International Journal of Project Management xx (2014) xxx – xxx
www.elsevier.com/locate/ijproman

The effectiveness of contractual and relational governances in


construction projects in China
Lu Ping, Guo Shuping, Qian Lamei, He Ping, Xu Xiaoyan ⁎
School of Management, University of Science and Technology of China, Hefei 230026, China

Received 22 March 2013; received in revised form 28 February 2014; accepted 6 March 2014
Available online xxxx

Abstract

Based on the transaction cost economics, this article addresses the effectiveness of contractual and relational governances in improving project
performance and restricting opportunism in construction. Ten hypotheses are presented. Using data from construction project in China, we adopt
Partial Least Squares (PLS) to test and verify our hypothesis. The results show that the contractual and relational governances are important to
improve project performance, and these two factors function as complements rather than substitutes. The contractual governance is more effective
in improving performance while relational governance is more powerful in restricting opportunism. The opportunism does not have a direct
negative impact on project performance.
© 2014 Elsevier Ltd. APM and IPMA.

Keywords: Construction project; Contractual governance; Relational governance; Project performance; Opportunism

1. Introduction mance (e.g., Lee and Cavusgil, 2006; Poppo and Zenger, 2002).
The mechanisms reported most in the literature can be
For a long time, the low efficiency and poor performance in grouped into two types. One is contractual governance (Lusch
construction industry have been perplexing the practitioners and Brown, 1996), which emphasizes the importance of the
and researchers (Briscoe and Dainty, 2005; Cox and Ireland, formal rules of compliance and contracts between transaction
2002; Love et al., 2004; Bankvall et.al., 2010; Vrjhoef and partners (Lumineau et al., 2011; Reuer and Ariño, 2007). The
Koskela, 2000). other is relational governance (Heide and John, 1992; Lusch and
In China, the profit rates in construction industry from 2005 to Brown, 1996; Macneil, 1980), which stresses the significance of
2011 are 2.62%, 2.87%, 3.06%, 3.55%, 3.54%, 3.55% and 3.56%, the relationship among all the partners and the clients. Table 1
respectively (National Bureau of Statistics of China, 2012), which summarizes some recent studies in the contractual and relational
are lower than those in the other industries. The important reason governances. However, these studies are mainly focused on the
for these problems is the lack of coordination among participants developed countries and the industries other than construction.
(e.g. Lars et al., 2010; Love et al., 2004), which in turn originates The effectiveness of contractual and relational governances
mainly from opportunistic behaviors (Willaimson, 1985). Accord- on performance is not context-free (Jap and Anderson, 2003;
ing to the transaction cost economics (TCE), some governance Tangpong et al., 2010). Compared with other industries, cons-
mechanisms could prevent opportunism (e.g., Caniëls and truction is more complex and has a high degree of fragmen-
Gelderman, 2010; Liu et al., 2009; Lui and Ngo, 2004; tation characteristics (Dainty et al., 2001a, 2001b). A project
Willaimson, 1981) and significantly enhance operational perfor- created by contract could be regarded as a temporary coalition
of some firms together with the clients (Winch, 1989). It is
⁎ Corresponding author. temporary, unique and heterogeneous, of short-term orientation
E-mail address: xxy204@ustc.edu.cn (X. Xu). and lacks organizational routines. These characteristics pose

http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ijproman.2014.03.004
0263-7863/00/© 2014 Elsevier Ltd. APM and IPMA.

Please cite this article as: P. Lu, et al., 2014. The effectiveness of contractual and relational governances in construction projects in China, Int. J. Proj. Manag. http://
dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ijproman.2014.03.004
2 P. Lu et al. / International Journal of Project Management xx (2014) xxx–xxx

Table 1
Overview of prior literature related to governance strategies.
Authors/years Focus Country/type of Survey Findings
exchange
Cannon et al. Contracts governance US and others Emails • Contracts and social norms were both found to be effective in enhancing
(2000) Norms governance Buyers–suppliers 443 (23%) supplier performance individually or in the plural form.
• Increasing the relational content of a governance structure containing
contractual agreements enhances performance (the plural form) when
transactional uncertainty is high, but not when it is low.
Poppo and Formal contracts US Email • Formal contracts and relational governance function as complements.
Zenger (2002) Relational governance Information service 152 (6%) • This interdependence underlies the ability to generate improvements in
exchanges exchange performance.
Kalnins and Contract North American and Text • Site-specific measures of relationship lead to a preference for low-powered
Mayer (2004) Relationship others 394 contracts T&M contracts (i.e., substitute).
IT service • Hybrid contracts are more likely to be used at intermediate levels of ex
ante cost uncertainty and ex post quality measurement difficulty.
Ferguson et al. Governance US/Can/Mex Experimental • Relational governance is the predominant governance mechanism
(2005) mechanisms Commercial banking 160 dyads connected to exchange performance.
·Relational • Contractual governance is also positively associated to exchange
·Contractual performance, but to in a lesser degree.
Carson et al. Volatility and US and others Survey • Formal contracts will be robust to ambiguity but not to volatility, whereas
(2006) ambiguity R&D outsourcing 125 (31%) relational contracts will be robust to volatility but not to ambiguity.
Contractual governance • Relational and formal contracts each have advantages and disadvantages in
Relational governance specific situations and are not simply substitutes.
Lee and Relational-based US Survey • Relational-based governance as opposed to contractual-based governance
Cavusgil governance Technology-intensive 184 (66.7%) is more effective and influential in strengthening the interfirm partnership,
(2006) Contractual-based stabilizing the alliance, and facilitating knowledge transfer between alliance
governance partners.
• Under high pressure of environmental turbulence the positive effects of
relational-based governance are enhanced.
Yu et al. (2006) Formal governance China Taiwan Survey • Both formal and relational governance mechanisms affect suppliers'
Relational governance manufacturing 77 (83%) tendencies to make specialized investments.
• Calculative trust acts as a moderating factor in the relationship between
transaction-specific investments and formal governance mechanisms.
Liu et al. (2009) Transactional China Survey • Transactional mechanisms are more effective in restraining opportunism,
Mechanisms Household appliance 225 dyads (25%) while in improving relationship performance relational mechanisms are more
Relational Mechanisms manufacturer powerful.
• When two mechanisms are used together, it will be greater benefits than
when they are used separately.
Hoetker And Alliance German Survey • The optimal of governance mechanisms depends on the assets involved in
Mellewigt Formal governance Telecommunications 83 (32%) an alliance, with relational mechanisms best suited to knowledge-based
(2009) Relational governance industry alliances assets and formal governance best suited to property-based assets.
• A mismatch between asset type and governance mechanisms can be harm
to the performance of the alliance.
Ryall and Formal contracting US Text • Complementarity between formal and relational contracts.
Sampson Relational mechanisms Telecommunications 52 contracts • A firm's contracts are more detailed and more likely to include penalties
(2009) and microelectronics when it engages in frequent deals (whether with the same or different
partners).
Goo et al. (2009) Formal contracts South Korea Survey • Formal contracts and relational governance function as complements,
Relational governance IT outsourcing 92 (62.3%) instead of as substitutes.
• Well-structured service level agreements have significant positive
influence on the various aspects of relational governance in IT outsourcing
relationships.

some specific challenges to management (Hanisch and Wald, performance (Lee and Cavusgil, 2006; Liu et al., 2009; Luo,
2011). For instance, the opportunism often occurs (e.g., Lau 2002; Poppo and Zenger, 2002).
and Rowlinson, 2009; Lo et al., 2007) and the collaboration in In this paper, we try to address the effectiveness of the
the coalition could be difficult (Phelps et al., 2009). The governance mechanisms in construction industry in China, by
previous research on project governance mainly focused on the means of an empirical analysis. Specifically, we intend to verify
governance structures, diverse project governance framework the effects of both contractual governance and relational gover-
and models in project-based organization, and the governance nance on the opportunism and project performance. Furthermore,
of project process (e.g. Miller and Hobbs, 2005; Turner and we also want to identify the relationship between contractual and
Keegan, 1999, 2000, 2001; Winch, 2001), but did not involve relational governances, and the relationship between opportun-
the governance mechanisms, which are closely related to ism and project performance. This study could be helpful to guide

Please cite this article as: P. Lu, et al., 2014. The effectiveness of contractual and relational governances in construction projects in China, Int. J. Proj. Manag. http://
dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ijproman.2014.03.004
P. Lu et al. / International Journal of Project Management xx (2014) xxx–xxx 3

the project management and improve project performance in generally are organized into distinct firms which are related to
construction. each other through transactions governed by contractual relation
The rest of this paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, (Winch, 1989), i.e., the contracting is chosen as a governance
we provide the knowledge background of contractual and mechanism.
relational governances, and propose our model and hypotheses. A contract is the agreements reached by the participants in
In Section 3, we describe the experiment setting, including the a project, including natural persons, legal entities and other
sampling and data collection procedures, the measures and organizations (Project Management Research Committee of
instruments. In Section 4, we present the results and analysis on China, 2009). The contractual governance emphasizes the use
these results. In Section 5, we discuss some interesting findings of a formalized, legally-binding agreement to specialize the
from our study. Finally, in Section 6, we give the conclusion of inter-organization trading partnership (Ferguson et al., 2005;
this paper. Lusch and Brown, 1996). Formal contracts represent the
promises or obligations of performing particular actions in the
future (Macneil, 1978).
2. Theory background and hypotheses
A construction project contract determines the outcomes or
outputs to be delivered within the given time and budget. It gives
Governance refers to the formal and informal rules of exchange
a thorough description of the roles and responsibilities of each
between partners (Nickerson et al., 2001). It is essential to the
party, and specifies the monitoring procedures and default
stability of buyer–supplier relationships (Benton and Maloni,
penalties. A typical project contract usually includes three parts.
2005). Project governance sets the objectives of the project, and
The first part is the fundamental elements, which specify the key
determines the means to attain those objectives and monitor the
principles and agreements among the parties, e.g. delivery
performance of the project (Turner and Keegan, 2001). Project
deadline, quality standards and budget of the project. The second
governance involves a set of relationships among partners,
part is the contractual terms associated with provisions specifying
including sponsor, contractor, client and other stakeholders.
principles, tactics, organization structures and processes for
Contractual governance and relational governance are two
settling unforeseeable events. The third part is the contractual
mechanisms in the inter-organizational exchanges. Fig. 1 illus-
terms associated with governance elements specifying the ways
trates the conceptual framework that proposes several hypothe-
to maintain the relationships through a clear statement of the
sized relation: (1) the direct impact of contractual and relational
measurements, penalties and incentives (Ouchi, 1979), to claim
governances on project performance and opportunism; (2) the
and give the termination of an agreement, and to resolve disputes
complement relationship between them; and (3) the relationship
among parties. Roehrich and Lewis (2010) concluded that
between opportunism and performance.
contracts can reduce uncertainties by providing a clear specifi-
cation of what is allowed and what is not, and can minimize the
2.1. Contractual governance risk of opportunism by enforcing legal rules and standards.
Ferguson et al. (2005) and Judge and Dooley (2006) recognized
A project is a complex dynamic system, which involves that the contract can enhance the performance of the exchange due
participants and their interdependencies (Jaafari, 2001). The to restraining opportunistic behaviors. Luo (2002) also gave the
typical processes of an engineering construction project usually result that contracts are associated with the performance and
include geological exploration, architectural design, construction contract completeness drive firms' performance. Thus, we propose
work, equipment installation and debugging. According to the our first hypothesis as follows:
TCE theory, in response to exchange hazards, firms either draw
H1. Contractual governance positively affects project performance.
complex contracts or choose to be vertically integrated when
contracts are too costly to enforce. The various project processes
2.2. Relational governance

Although contracts play an important role in project gover-


Contractual H1(+)H3 Project nance, the parties who draw up the contracts cannot foresee all
Governance Performance possible conditions due to the Bound Rationality of human beings,
H6(-) especially for the projects that are unique and one-off. Thus a
contract is usually incomplete for a construction project. It is not
H4b(+)

H4a(+)

H5(-)
enough to rely on contractual governance. Heide and John (1992)
H2(+) suggested that contractual governance has deficiencies owing to
the omission of a key social element.
Relational Some scholars have observed that the inter-organizational
Opportunism
Governance H7(-)H8
exchanges are typically the repeated exchanges embedded in social
Notes:
relationships (Dwyer and Schurr, 1987; Lusch and Brown, 1996).
+ = Positive relationship, support for Complements (H4a, H4b) Individuals would never be able to act independently of society.
Trade practices are to some extent influenced by social rules and
Fig. 1. Conceptual framework and hypotheses. value system. Governance emerging from the values and agreed-

Please cite this article as: P. Lu, et al., 2014. The effectiveness of contractual and relational governances in construction projects in China, Int. J. Proj. Manag. http://
dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ijproman.2014.03.004
4 P. Lu et al. / International Journal of Project Management xx (2014) xxx–xxx

upon processes are also found in social relationships (Heide a formal and legally-binding agreement which attempts to
and John, 1992; Macneil, 1980). Another governance approach, reduce the risk and uncertainty in exchange relationships
i.e. relational governance, was thus suggested by scholars. (Lusch and Brown, 1996) and to provide a safeguard for ex post
Macneil (1980) first differentiated two kinds of exchanges, i.e. performance. On the contrary, the relational governance is
discrete exchange and relational exchange. During making a informal and non-binding. Second, despite its incompletion,
discrete exchange, communication is limited and the identity is contracts can still provide a structural system to respond to
neglected. During making a relational exchange, the exchange is unforeseen disturbances. Contracts are also preferred to relational
examined from the past to future. However, even the simplest mechanisms in offering a formal framework (Poppo and Zenger,
model of discrete exchange must have some relational elements 2002). The level of contractual completeness is a good indicator
(Dwyer and Schurr, 1987). That is, almost every exchange may of parties' scope of ex post actions (Liu et al., 2009). Third,
contain some relational factors to harmonize the behaviors among contracts are helpful to build initial institutional trust for firms or
parties. individuals from temporary coalitions (Mcknight et al., 1998).
Relational governance regards relational norms as a form of Thus, we propose our third hypothesis as follows:
informal governance (Heide and John, 1992; Macneil, 1980).
Relational norms specify the permissible limits on behavior, H3. Contractual governance is more effective than relational
and hence serve as a general protective device against abnormal governance in improving project performance.
behavior (Heide and John, 1992).
Relational norms traditionally involve information sharing, As to the relationship between contractual governance and
flexibility and solidarity (e.g., Heide and John, 1992; Lusch and relational governance, two viewpoints arise in the existing
Brown, 1996). Information sharing decreases information literature. One suggests that the contractual governance and
asymmetry, promotes conflict and problem solution within the relational governances are substitutes (Corts and Singh, 2004;
exchange. Flexibility facilitates the project's adaptation to Dyer and Singh, 1998; Kalnins and Mayer, 2004). It is said that
unforeseeable events (Poppo and Zenger, 2002). Developing relational governance can produce informal self-enforcing agree-
solidarity shifts the focus away from self-centered behavior ments and replace contractual governance through the social
towards the behavior that foster unity to arise common respon- processes. Relational governance may also minimize transaction
sibilities and interests (Rokkan et al., 2003). If the parties promise costs compared with formal contracts (Dyer and Singh, 1998). It is
such norms, mutual benefit and cooperation will be achieved. reported that detailed contractual specifications indicate a signal of
Trust is also a substantial part of relational governance. Trust distrust in the construction project (Kadefors, 2004). The other
is regarded as a key indicator in supply chain relationships and viewpoint suggests that the contractual and relational governances
can improve project performance in construction (Kadefors, are mutual complements (e.g., Li et al., 2010; Poppo and Zenger,
2004; Meng, 2012). Trust has been identified as one of the 2002; Ryall and Sampson, 2009). The reason is that contract
deterministic factors to reduce the negotiation cost, decrease the provides an institutional framework guiding the course of cooper-
monitoring cost, and increase the possibility to attain mutually ation, while relational governance overcomes the adaptive limits
beneficial agreements (Khalfan et al., 2007). of contracts (Luo, 2002).
The relational governance has received much attention in the According to Poppo and Zenger (2002), if contacts are more
buyer–supplier relationship over the last two decades. Many customized, then the levels of established and developed norms
firms have begun to adopt this approach in their exchange become higher; levels of relational governance are higher, and
relationships to help govern the behaviors of the exchange the contractual complexity are all increased. This interdepen-
partners. Chen and Partington (2004) show that Chinese project dence underlies their ability to generate improvement in project
managers prefer to develop and maintain a good, even personal, performance. Jointly using both contractual and relational
relationship with their clients. This is considered to be an governances will improve the performance more significantly
essential attribute of being a good project manager. As a result, than using them separately (Liu et al., 2009).
good relationships with all involved parties are absolutely A well-specified contract is viewed as a major instrument
critical for resolving conflicts friendly. that protects specific investment from opportunistic behavior
Relational governance from social processes, including rela- (Willaimson, 1985). The process of setting a contract requires
tional norms, trust, etc., can mitigate the exchange hazards targeted information exchange, flexibility and solidarity among parties.
by formal contracts (Poppo and Zenger, 2002), and minimize On the contrary, with relational establishment and development,
transaction costs compared with the formal contracts (Dyer and previous experience could be reflected in contract revision, and
Singh, 1998). Thus, we propose our second hypothesis as follows: thus the contract could be improved.
In a word, contractual governance can provide institutional
H2. Relational governance positively affects project performance.
framework for construction project, and the relational governance
can eliminate contract limitations. They function as mutual
2.3. Relationship between contractual and relational governances complements, instead of substitutes. Thus, we propose the fourth
hypothesis, which consists of three parts as follows:
Despite that both contractual and relational governances are
considered to positively affect project performance, there is H4a. Relational governance positively affects the level of
some difference between these two effects. First, the contract is contractual governance.

Please cite this article as: P. Lu, et al., 2014. The effectiveness of contractual and relational governances in construction projects in China, Int. J. Proj. Manag. http://
dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ijproman.2014.03.004
P. Lu et al. / International Journal of Project Management xx (2014) xxx–xxx 5

H4b. Contractual governance positively affects the level of can reduce the monitoring cost by increasing the transparency of
relational governance. relationships (Reuer and Ariño, 2002).
In fact, a contract cannot identify every potential
H4c. Contractual governance and relational governance will
contingency (Macneil, 1980), and only provide the limited
function as complements in improving the performance of a
protection (Willaimson, 1985). As a result, the participants
project.
may rely on relational governance to adjust partners'
behavior. By sharing norms and values, partners' opportunism
2.4. Opportunism and project performance is restricted (Brown et al., 2000). The effectiveness of relational
norms and trust is most prominent on opportunistic behavior
According to Willaimson (1985), opportunism was (Caniëls and Gelderman, 2010). They can facilitate the alignment
defined as the self-interest seeking with guile. Opportunism of partners' interests (Atkinson et al., 2006). Some researches
is inherent in any inter-firm exchange (Willaimson, 1985). confirmed that trust positively affects a wide range of behaviors,
Because of inherent asymmetries during construction project such as collaborative communication (Lusch and Brown, 1996),
processes, the practice of opportunism is potentially high conflict resolution, and flexibility in responding to unanticipated
and tempting (Lau and Rowlinson, 2009). Firms and circumstances (Dyer and Chu, 2003). Fostering trust is recognized
individuals from temporary coalitions sometimes seek to as one of the most effective means to suppress opportunism
reap profits at the expense of others. There are some typical (Walker, 2003). Thus, we propose the following hypotheses:
behaviors of opportunism, such as hiding firm's qualifica-
H6. Contractual governance negatively affects opportunism.
tion, undertaking projects in unreasonably low price, illegal
sub-contracting, jerry-building, and false declaration of H7. Relational governance negatively affects opportunism.
quantity and price.
These kinds of behavior hurt the relationship satisfaction Although both contractual and relational governances are
and trust (Jap and Anderson, 2003). A firm with a high level considered to be able to restrain opportunism, we suggest that
of opportunism tends to lack candor or honesty in exchanges relational governance is relatively more effective than contractual
(Willaimson, 1985) and makes a lower level of commitment governance in restraining opportunism for construction projects,
to the bilateral relationship (Wang and Yang, 2013). So due to three reasons.
opportunism negatively affects the factors to improve the First, a construction project has a larger uncertainty in task,
performance, such as trust, commitment, and satisfaction. natural, organization and contracting (Winch, 1989). Drawings
(Carr and Pearson, 1999; Villena et al., 2011). Some scholars and specifications of a construction project always contain errors
even insist that opportunism directly negatively affects the and omissions. Weather and soil conditions may also alter the
performance (Crosno and Dahlstrom, 2008; Wang and Yang, priorities of project processes. Changes are also frequently made
2013). in contract documents during its lifecycle. These may give a door
In the bidding and contracting stage of a construction to opportunism behavior.
project, clients need to pay a lot of attention to prevent Second, although contracts are formal and legally-binding
malicious bidders. In the construction stage of a project, agreements, the more complicated the contract is designed, the
opportunistic behaviors (e.g. jerry-building, adulterating and less the opportunism behavior appears when uncertainty is
others) can result in overrun of time and costs. These behaviors present. Drawing up a detailed and explicit formal contract can
could influence project performance. Thus, we propose the be costly and time consuming. Even if an explicit contract
following hypothesis: exists, the firms in coalition often fail to seek legal sanctions
when disputes arise among parties. If they do that, not only the
H5. Opportunism negatively affects project performance.
cost and time are high but also the consequences may be
undesirable.
2.5. Governance mechanisms and opportunism Third, through socialization processes, both passive and
active opportunistic behaviors are mitigated in the exchanges
The existing literature on TCE theory (e.g., Morgan et al., (Wathne and Heide, 2000). Relationships characterized by
2007; Willaimson, 1985) suggests three common approaches to relational norms provide a foundation for restricting oppor-
control opportunism: the contractual governance, the hierarchy tunism in exchange relationships (Carson et al., 2006). Low
approach and the relational governance. For construction relational norm relationships tend to be competitive, while
projects, the hierarchy approach can be excluded, thus is not high relational norm relationships tend to be cooperative
discussed in this paper. (Tangpong et al., 2010). According to Tangpong et al. (2010),
Contracts play an important role in restricting opportunism. relational norms and agent cooperativeness interact with each
An explicit contract specifies acceptable behaviors and unac- other in restricting opportunism and this interaction yields
ceptable behaviors (Lui and Ngo, 2004), and can mitigate better results in opportunism. Thus, we propose our last
opportunistic behavior (Poppo and Zenger, 2002). Lui and Ngo hypothesis as follows:
(2004) argued that contracts can curb opportunism through two
mechanisms. First, contracts can change the payment structure by H8. Relational governance is more effective than contractual
increasing the cost of opportunistic behavior. Second, contracts governance in restraining opportunism.

Please cite this article as: P. Lu, et al., 2014. The effectiveness of contractual and relational governances in construction projects in China, Int. J. Proj. Manag. http://
dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ijproman.2014.03.004
6 P. Lu et al. / International Journal of Project Management xx (2014) xxx–xxx

3. Research setting A considerable literature concerns the impact of trust on


successful project management. Several alternative models have
3.1. Sampling and data collection procedures been proposed. Pinto et al. (2009) suggest Hartman's model of
integrity, competence, and intuitive forms of trust because it is
Data for this study is obtained through a survey from clients, purposely developed to address trust within a project setting to a
contractors, supervisors and designers, who are principal and greater degree than the theoretical works. Six trust items, adapted
familiar with the engineering construction projects. from Chow et al. (2012), Hartman (2002) and Pinto et al. (2009)
More than twenty firms were chosen from the 2011 List of are used in our study. The Cronbach's α value is 0.882.
Large and Medium-sized Enterprises in Engineering Construc-
tion in three cities (Hefei, Tongling and Maanshan) in Anhui 3.2.3. Project performance
province, China. Each firm gets less than 20 questionnaires. The traditional way of judging project success is the so-called
Totally 300 questionnaires were sent out and 230 questionnaires iron-triangle of time, budget and required quality, which are
were returned. The response rate is 76.7%. Some questionnaires widely reviled in late years. Many studies have expanded the
used the matched survey to the client, contractor, supervisor and project success criteria by adding other aspects, such as
designer around the project. The process lasted for three months. stakeholders' satisfaction, customer's benefit, and future poten-
After removing null responses, we have 225 valid questionnaires, tial to organization (Jugdev and MÜller, 2005; Nixon et al.,
which are from 67 clients, 74 contractors, 30 supervisors, 48 2012). Based on the work of Pinto et al. (2009) and our field
designers and 6 others, with the proportion of 29.8%, 32.9%, practitioner interview, six items are developed to measure the
13.3%, 21.3%, and 2.7%, respectively. project performance. The Cronbach's α value is 0.749.
Among the 225 informants, 35 persons have been working in
their current position for 1–3 years, 56 persons for 4–8 years, 58 3.2.4. Opportunism
persons for 9–14 years, 44 persons for 15–20 years and 32 Opportunism is measured by four items which were drawn
persons for more than 20 years, with the proportion of 15.6%, from Heide et al. (2007). The Cronbach's α value is 0.889.
24.9%, 25.8%, 19.6% and 14.2%, respectively. In the 225 All items are specified in Appendix A.
responses which are related to project budget, 50.2% projects
have the total investments more than 100 million RMB (about 4. Results and analysis
16 million US dollars).
4.1. Model evaluation and hypothesis testing
3.2. Measure
We use the Structure Equation Modeling (SEM) method,
To make the measures valid, we select many instruments from which is able to simultaneously process multiple dependent
the literature. For ease of understanding, the English version of variables and comparison of different models, and is widely used
the instruments was first developed and then translated into in social, economic and management science. Data analysis is
Chinese, and finally was back-translated into English for conducted with Partial Least Square (PLS) technique, which is
accuracy. In the absence of any existing entry, new items were well suitable for small data samples, skewed distribution
created based on the literature and refined by our pilot test. (Hulland, 1999), and the latent constructs to be modeled with
Subjects responded to each questionnaire item using the 1–5 formative indicators (Chin, 1998). It is appropriate to adopt PLS
scale (i.e., 1 = Strongly Disagree and 5 = Strongly Agree). method in our study, because there are formative indicators in
Before issuing the questionnaires, three specialists who latent constructs.
work in construction industry from the positions of client, The reliability and validity of all constructs used for our
contractors and supervisions for at least 15 years were invited research were checked. The reliability is reflected by internal
to examine our scales, to make sure that the questionnaire are consistency reliability, called Cronbach's α value. Generally,
coincident with the reality. it is necessary to let the Cronbach's α value be greater than 0.7.
In this study, the Cronbach's α value of each multi-item
3.2.1. Contractual governance variable is greater than 0.7, which implies high internal
Three variables from Goo et al. (2009) in measuring contracts consistency.
are for our reference. The first part is the fundamental elements Composite Reliability (CR) and Average Variance Extracted
with four items. The second part is the change elements with three (AVE) were used to estimate the convergent validity. It is
items. The third part is the governance elements with three items. necessary that CR value is greater than 0.7 and AVE value is
The Cronbach's α values of three variables used to measure greater than 0.5. It can be seen from Table 2 that for each
contracts are 0.880, 0.746 and 0.881 respectively. variable, the CR values range from 0.832 to 0.927, and the
AVE values range from 0.624 to 0.809. All of them are higher
3.2.2. Relational governance than the required level.
Based on Griffith and Myers (2004), relational norms involve Discriminant validity is another value that is considered to
information exchange (3 items), solidarity (3 items) and flexibility be able to distinguish constructs. It could be obtained from the
(2 items). Their Cronbach's values α are 0.822, 0.825 and 0.731, comparison of the square root of an AVE with the absolute
respectively. value of the correlative coefficients of the other latent variables.

Please cite this article as: P. Lu, et al., 2014. The effectiveness of contractual and relational governances in construction projects in China, Int. J. Proj. Manag. http://
dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ijproman.2014.03.004
P. Lu et al. / International Journal of Project Management xx (2014) xxx–xxx 7

As shown in Table 3, the minimum in the square root of AVE is 4.4. Opportunism influencing project performance
bigger than the maximum in absolute values of correlative
coefficients. Thus discriminant validity is satisfied. Hypothesis H5 predicts that opportunism will hurt the project
performance. However, as shown in Fig. 2, opportunism doesn't
have a significant negative impact on project performance
4.2. Governance influencing project performance (b = − 0.041, p N 0.05). The result suggests that decreasing
opportunism cannot significantly improve project performance.
Regarding the hypotheses H1 and H2, we checked the Hence, hypothesis H5 is not supported.
influence of two governances on project performance. The
corresponding results are shown in Fig. 2. It is found that there 4.5. Contractual and relational governances restraining
were significant positive relationships between contractual opportunism
governance and project performance (b = 0.325, p b 0.001)
and between relational governance and project performance As shown in Fig. 2, relational governance has a significant
(b = 0.268, p b 0.05). These findings support the hypotheses negative effect on opportunism (b = − 0.311, p b 0.001). This
H1 and H2. Obviously, the path coefficients of these two implies that the increases in relational governance will signifi-
governance mechanisms are different. According to Chin's cantly reduce opportunism. The result supports hypothesis H7.
(2003) equation which is an adaptation of the t-test for However contractual governance has no obvious effect on
comparing regression coefficients between independent sam- opportunism. That means a more complete contract, which
ples, we test the difference between the two paths. Contractual contains the detailed promises, obligations, and processes for
governance (b = 0.325) has a stronger impact on project dispute resolution, could not effectively restrain opportunism.
performance compared to relational governance (b = 0.268) Hypothesis H6 is not supported. Thus, relational governance is
(T = 7.243, p b 0.001). Hypothesis H3 is therefore supported. more effective than contractual governance in restraining
opportunism. The hypothesis H8 is supported.
4.3. Relation between contractual and relational governances We use an independent-sample t-test to analyze the difference
between clients and contractors in performance and opportunism.
In this section, we intend to find out the relationship between Interestingly, we find that clients (M = 2.780) are greater than
contractual governance and relational governance themselves: contractors (M = 2.517) in opportunism (T = 1.929, p b 0.1).
mutual complements or substitutes. As shown in Fig. 2, the The results are shown in Table 4.
contractual governance positively influences the relational
governance (b = 0.613, p b 0.001). That means there will be 5. Discussions
stronger relational governance when contractual governance is
higher. In other words, the increases in the level of relational Our analysis has confirmed the effectiveness of contractual
governance are associated with the greater levels of contractual governance and relational governance on the project perfor-
governance. Similarly, relational governance positively influ- mance, supported TCE theory and shown the theory's relevance
ences the contractual governance (b = 0.578, p b 0.001). The in explanation construction project governance. If the firm seeks
positive coefficients support hypotheses H4a and H4b. There to improve project performance, contractual and relational
exists the evidence of a complementary effect on performance, governances can be emphatically used to achieve this goal.
if both contractual and relational governances positively Some studies argue that the relational governance, as opposed
influence the project performance, and positively influence to the contractual governance, is more effective in alliance
each other themselves (Poppo and Zenger, 2002). Thus, we can performance (Lee and Cavusgil, 2006) or relationship perfor-
conclude that relational governance and contractual governance mance (Liu et al., 2009), but our results show that the contractual
are complements, rather than substitutes. Hypothesis H4c is governance has a stronger impact on project performance than the
thus supported. relational governance. The reason could be that the effectiveness
of contractual and relational governances is closely related to the
construction context.
Previous researchers proposed two competing views for the
Table 2 relationship between contractual and relational governances,
Values of reliability and convergent validity.
substitutes or complements. Our results are in agreement with
Variables Cronbach's alpha Composite reliability AVE the conclusion that contractual and relational governances
Project performance (PP) 0.749 0.840 0.636 function as complements. These findings indicate that complex
Opportunism (OP) 0.889 0.923 0.750 contract has always much to do with the greater levels of
Fundamental elements (FE) 0.880 0.918 0.736
relational governance, and the higher relational governance
Change elements (CE) 0.746 0.832 0.624
Governance elements (GE) 0.881 0.927 0.809 tends to employ perfect contract.
Information exchange (IE) 0.822 0.882 0.651 Surprisingly, our results show that opportunism is not related
Solidarity (SD) 0.825 0.883 0.654 significantly to project performance. Unlike some scholars (e.g.,
Flexibility (FB) 0.731 0.880 0.785 Chen and Lien, 2012; Morgan et al., 2007), we don't confirm the
Trust (TR) 0.882 0.910 0.629
direct negative impact of opportunism on performance. Brown et

Please cite this article as: P. Lu, et al., 2014. The effectiveness of contractual and relational governances in construction projects in China, Int. J. Proj. Manag. http://
dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ijproman.2014.03.004
8 P. Lu et al. / International Journal of Project Management xx (2014) xxx–xxx

Table 3
Correlations of latent variables and the values of discriminant validity (n = 225).
Mean SD 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9
1 PP 3.733 0.488 0.797
2 OP 2.597 0.820 − 0.287 0.866
3 FE 3.979 0.542 0.405 − 0.201 0.858
4 CE 3.510 0.550 0.307 − 0.249 0.328 0.790
5 GE 3.871 0.515 0.387 − 0.250 0.555 0.403 0.899
6 IE 3.790 0.595 0.393 − 0.324 0.298 0.432 0.459 0.807
7 SD 3.779 0.540 0.414 − 0.303 0.473 0.355 0.560 0.554 0.809
8 FB 3.656 0.551 0.281 − 0.292 0.303 0.435 0.319 0.561 0.518 0.886
9 TR 3.644 0.534 0.440 − 0.314 0.361 0.337 0.421 0.575 0.687 0.544 0.793
Note: PP = project performance; OP = opportunism; FE = fundamental elements; CE = change elements; GE = governance elements; IE = information exchange;
SD = solidarity; FB = flexibility; TR = trust.

al. (2009) argue that opportunism is more relevant to relationship Based on the survey of engineering construction projects in
satisfaction rather than operation performance. Although oppor- China, our research shows that client has greater opportunism
tunism behaviors may not directly decrease performance, they are than contractor has. The status of construction market in China
likely to undermine the relationship satisfaction. Some studies indicates that the client is at a strong position, while the contractor
argue that the impact of opportunism on performance is mainly is at a weak position. Illegal behaviors from clients account for
through some mediate variables, such as trust, commitment, 70% of all illegal behaviors in construction (Sha, 2009).
conflict, and satisfaction (Wang and Yang, 2013). Opportunism
may indirectly have a negative impact on project performance by 6. Conclusions
influencing these factors.
How to reduce opportunism is one of major topics that have This paper attempts to identify the effectiveness of
been studied in various buyer–supplier contexts. According to contractual and relational governances in construction projects.
TCE theory, formal contractual and relational governances can Using construction projects in China as the empirical setting,
substantially curb opportunism. But our analysis does not show we have five major findings. First, both contractual governance
effectiveness of contractual governance in restricting opportun- and relational governance are important in improving project
ism. Recent research on the mitigation of opportunism among performance and contractual governance is more effective than
parties mainly focuses on relational governance, e.g., relational relational governance. Second, contractual governance and
norms (Tangpong et al., 2010). By sharing norms and values relational governance function as complements, rather than
among exchange partners, opportunism can be effectively substitutes. Third, opportunism does not significantly influence
restrained. Our results show that relational governance is project performance. Fourth, relational governance plays an
effective in restricting opportunism. If the firms seek to reduce important role in mitigating opportunism, but contractual
opportunism, inter-firm trust and relational norms are important governance does not. Fifth, different stakeholders in coalition
means. Chinese project managers prefer to develop and maintain are not alike in opportunism. Clients have greater opportunism
a good, even personal relation, with clients (Chen and Partington, than contractors in engineering construction.
2004). Good relationships with all parties involved are effective These outcomes provide several insights in construction
in resolving any problem. project governance. First, higher level contractual governance
plays an important role in improving performance. Detailed
contractual specifications don't signal a climate of distrust, but
increase the level of relational governance. From the managerial
perspective, contracts should also be further improved, but
Contractual Project cannot decrease opportunism in construction exchange. Second,
0.325***
Governance Performance the project participants, such as clients, contractors, subcontrac-
R²=0.421 R²=0.302
-0.108
tors and construction supervisors may also have potential

0.613*** 0.578*** -0.041 Table 4


Independent-sample t-test results.
0.268*
Relational Variables Work unit Mean SD T values
Opportunism
Governance -0.311*** Project performance Client 3.662 0.465 − 1.251
R²=0.150
R²=0.384
Contractor 3.759 0.457 − 1.251
Note *p<0.05;**p<0.01;***p<0.001 Opportunism Client 2.780 0.811 1.929 +
Contractor 2.517 0.806 ⁎,⁎⁎ 1.929 +
Fig. 2. Governance structural model with path coefficient. +
p b 0.10.

Please cite this article as: P. Lu, et al., 2014. The effectiveness of contractual and relational governances in construction projects in China, Int. J. Proj. Manag. http://
dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ijproman.2014.03.004
P. Lu et al. / International Journal of Project Management xx (2014) xxx–xxx 9

opportunism. Although the opportunism behaviors don't harm ▪ We sometimes take advantage of “holes” in our contracts or
project performance in our results, they are likely to decrease the agreements to further our own interests.
satisfaction. Relational governance, including relational norm ▪ We do not always act in accordance with our contracts or
and trust, can effectively restrain the parties' opportunistic agreements.
action.
Several limitations exist in this study. First, this research Contractual governance
does not take antecedent variables into account, such as the Fundamental elements (4 items, alpha = 0.880, derived
uncertainty of surrounding, complexity, and leaves some other from Goo et al., 2009; Luo, 2002)
factors, such as past cooperation, cooperation length of time,
contract duration and person characteristics. Future research may ▪ Our relationship with the other parties is governed primarily
address these issues. Second, this study does not systematically by written contracts.
investigate the impacts of relational norms, trust, contractual ▪ The contract has detailed the obligations and rights of every
foundation elements and change elements on the project party.
performance and opportunism. The joint effect of contractual and ▪ The contract has a clear statement of the time, place and the
relational governances on project performance has not been way of project fulfillment.
measured. Future work can study this in-depth. Third, this paper ▪ The contract has described the safety management require-
uses the samples from only one province to test our hypotheses, ments, quality standards, contract price and its payment to
and does not cover the other regions. Governance mechanisms manage the agreements among parties.
may depend on Chinese context. Certainly China cannot represent
Change elements (3 items, alpha = 0.746, derived from Goo
all emerging economies. Future research could extend our model to
et al., 2009; Luo, 2002)
the other national settings. The difference in economic and
institutional conditions could induce various governance strategies.
▪ The contract has specified major principles or guidelines for
Conflict of interest handling unanticipated contingencies as they arise.
▪ The contract has provided alternative solutions for responding
We declare that we have no conflict of interest with other to various contingencies that are likely to arise.
people or organizations. ▪ The contract has allowed us to respond quickly to match
evolving client requirements.
Acknowledgments
Governance elements (3 items, alpha = 0.881, adapted
from Goo et al., 2009)
The authors thank the editor and anonymous referees for
helpful comments and suggestions on the manuscript. This ▪ We have a clear expression of the default definitions and
work was supported by the National Natural Science
formula.
Foundation of China (No. 71001094, 71371176).
▪ The contract has a detailed description of conditions under
which termination may occur.
Appendix A. List of items
▪ The contract has specified the procedures and methods for
disputes.
Project performance (6 items, alpha = 0.749, taken from
Pinto et al., 2009) Relational governance
Trust (6 items, alpha = 0.882, derived from Chow et al.,
▪ The project results, or deliverables, are in line with client 2012; Pinto et al., 2009)
objectives.
▪ This project has come in on budget. ▪ We believe the other party can keep their word throughout
▪ This project has come in on schedule. the life of the project.
▪ We are satisfied with the project outcomes. ▪ We feel confident that the other parties have high levels of
▪ The construction quality and the deliverables quality accord integrity and honest.
with the standard. ▪ We believe the project engineers and other technical people
▪ This project has qualified acceptance and successful delivery are competent at what they are doing.
by one-time. ▪ We trust that the project participants are able to fulfill
contractual agreements.
Opportunism (4 items, alpha = 0.889, taken from Heide ▪ We are certain that the other parties have the ability to
et al., 2007) perform their tasks.
▪ We believe that the other parties could meet the require-
▪ On occasion, we lie about certain things in order to protect ments of the project in technology and management.
our interests.
▪ We sometimes promise to do things without actually doing Relational norms (based on Griffith and Myers, 2004)
them later. Information exchange (3 items, alpha = 0.822)

Please cite this article as: P. Lu, et al., 2014. The effectiveness of contractual and relational governances in construction projects in China, Int. J. Proj. Manag. http://
dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ijproman.2014.03.004
10 P. Lu et al. / International Journal of Project Management xx (2014) xxx–xxx

▪ Exchange of information among the parties takes place Chow, P.T., Cheung, S.O., Chan, K.Y., 2012. Trust-building in construction
frequently. contracting: mechanism and expectation. Int. J. Proj. Manag. 30, 927–937.
Corts, K.S., Singh, J., 2004. The effect of repeated interaction on contract
▪ We keep each other informed about events or changes that choice: evidence from offshore drilling. J. Law Econ. Org. 20, 230–260.
may affect the other parties. Cox, A., Ireland, P., 2002. Managing construction supply chains: the common
▪ The parties established a good contact with each other, sense approach. Eng. Constr. and Archit. Manag. 9, 409–418.
avoiding the possible misunderstandings. Crosno, J.L., Dahlstrom, R., 2008. A meta-analytic review of opportunism in
exchange relationships. J. Acad. Mark. Sci. 36, 191–201.
Dainty, A.R., Briscoe, G.H., Millett, S.J., 2001a. Subcontractor perspectives on
Solidarity (3 items, alpha = 0.825) supply chain alliances. Const. Manag. and Econ. 19, 841–848.
Dainty, A.R., Millett, S.J., Briscoe, G.H., 2001b. New perspectives on construction
supply chain integration. Supply Chain Manag.: An Int. J. 6, 163–173.
▪ The parties are consistent with the expectations of this Dwyer, F.R., Schurr, P.H., 1987. Developing buyer–seller relationships. J.
project. Mark. 51, 11–27.
▪ The project overall plan and the implementation scheme are Dyer, J.H., Chu, W., 2003. The role of trustworthiness in reducing transaction
costs and improving performance: empirical evidence from the United
shared by every party.
States, Japan, and Korea. Organ. Sci. 14, 57–68.
▪ Parties involved in this project regard each other as major Dyer, J.H., Singh, H., 1998. The relational view: cooperative strategy and
partners. sources of interorganizational competitive advantage. Acad. Manag. Rev.
23, 660–679.
Ferguson, R.J., Paulin, M., Bergeron, J., 2005. Contractual governance,
Flexibility (2 items, alpha = 0.731) relational governance, and the performance of interfirm service exchanges:
the influence of boundary-spanner closeness. J. Acad. Mark. Sci. 33,
▪ We believed that the parties were willing to cooperate to 217–234.
Goo, J., Kishore, R., Rao, H.R., Nam, K., 2009. The role of service level
work out solutions if some unexpected situations arise. agreements in relational management of information technology
▪ The parties expected to be able to make adjustments in the outsourcing: an empirical study. MIS Q. 33, 119–145.
ongoing relationship to cope with changing circumstances. Griffith, D.A., Myers, M.B., 2004. The performance implications of strategic fit
of relational norm governance strategies in global supply chain relation-
ships. J. Int. Bus. Stud. 36, 254–269.
References Hanisch, B., Wald, A., 2011. A project management research framework
integrating multiple theoretical perspectives and influencing factors. Proj.
Atkinson, R., Crawford, L., Ward, S., 2006. Fundamental uncertainties in Manag. J. 42, 4–22.
projects and the scope of project management. Int. J. Proj. Manag. 24, Hartman, F.T., 2002. In: Slevin, D., Cleland, D., Pinto, J. (Eds.), The Role of Trust in
687–698. Project Management. Project Management Institute, Newtown Square.
Bankvall, L., Bygballe, L.E., Dubois, A., Jahre, M., 2010. Interdependence in Heide, J.B., John, G., 1992. Do norms matter in marketing relationships? J.
supply chains and projects in construction. Supply Chain Manag.: An Int. J. Mark. 56, 32–44.
15, 385–393. Heide, J.B., Wathne, K.H., Rokkan, A.I., 2007. Interfirm monitoring, social
Benton, W.C., Maloni, M., 2005. The influence of power driven buyer/seller contracts, and relationship outcomes. J. Mark. Res. 44, 425–433.
relationships on supply chain satisfaction. J. Oper. Manag. 23, 1–22. Hoetker, G., Mellewigt, T., 2009. Choice and performance of governance
Briscoe, G., Dainty, A., 2005. Construction supply chain integration: an elusive mechanisms: matching alliance governance to asset type. Strateg. Manag. J.
goal? Supply Chain Manag. An Int. J. 10, 319–326. 30, 1025–1044.
Brown, J.R., Dev, C.S., Lee, D.J., 2000. Managing marketing channel Hulland, J., 1999. Use of partial least squares (PLS) in strategic management
opportunism: the efficacy of alternative governance mechanisms. J. Mark. research: a review of four recent studies. Strateg. Manag. J. 20, 195–204.
64, 51–65. Jaafari, A., 2001. Management of risks, uncertainties and opportunities on
Brown, J.R., Crosno, J.L., Dev, C.S., 2009. The effects of transaction-specific projects: time for a fundamental shift. Int. J. Proj. Manag. 19, 89–101.
investments in marketing channels: the moderating role of relational norms. Jap, S.D., Anderson, E., 2003. Safeguarding interorganizational performance
J. Mark. Theory Pract. 17, 317–334. and continuity under ex post opportunism. Manag. Sci. 49, 1684–1701.
Caniëls, M.C., Gelderman, C.J., 2010. The safeguarding effect of governance Judge, W.Q., Dooley, R., 2006. Strategic alliance outcomes: a transaction-cost
mechanisms in inter‐firm exchange: the decisive role of mutual opportun- economics perspective. Br. J. Manag. 17, 23–37.
ism. Br. J. Manag. 21, 239–254. Jugdev, K., Müller, R., 2005. A retrospective look at our evolving
Cannon, J.P., Achrol, R.S., Gundlach, G.T., 2000. Contracts, norms, and plural understanding of project success. Proj. Manag. J. 36, 19–31.
form governance. J. Acad. Mark. Sci. 28, 180–194. Kadefors, A., 2004. Trust in project relationships—inside the black box. Int. J.
Carr, A.S., Pearson, J.N., 1999. Strategically managed buyer–supplier Proj. Manag. 22, 175–182.
relationships and performance outcomes. J. Oper. Manag. 17, 497–519. Kalnins, A., Mayer, K.J., 2004. Relationships and hybrid contracts: an analysis of
Carson, S.J., Madhok, A., Wu, T., 2006. Uncertainty, opportunism, and contract choice in information technology. J. Law Econ. Org. 20, 207–229.
governance: the effects of volatility and ambiguity on formal and relational Khalfan, M.M.K., McDermott, P., Swan, W., 2007. Building trust in
contracting. Acad. Manag. J. 49, 1058–1077. construction projects. Supply Chain Manag. An Int. J. 12, 385–391.
Chen, C., Lien, N., 2012. Technological opportunism and firm performance: Lau, E., Rowlinson, S., 2009. Interpersonal trust and inter-firm trust in
moderating contexts. J. Bus. Res. 66, 2218–2225. construction projects. Constr. Manag. Econ. 27, 539–554.
Chen, P., Partington, D., 2004. An interpretive comparison of Chinese and Lee, Y., Cavusgil, S.T., 2006. Enhancing alliance performance: the effects of
Western conceptions of relationships in construction project management contractual-based versus relational-based governance. J. Bus. Res. 59, 896–905.
work. Int. J. Proj. Manag. 22, 397–406. Li, Y., Xie, E., Teo, H., Peng, M., 2010. Formal control and social control in
Chin, W.W., 1998. Commentary: issues and opinion on structural equation domestic and international buyer–supplier relationships. J. Oper. Manag.
modeling. MIS Q. vii–xvi. 28, 333–344.
Chin, W.W., 2003. A permutation procedure for multi-group comparison of Liu, Y., Luo, Y., Liu, T., 2009. Governing buyer–supplier relationships through
PLS models. PLS and Related Methods: Proceedings of the International transactional and relational mechanisms: evidence from China. J. Oper.
Symposium PLS, 3, pp. 33–43. Manag. 27, 294–309.

Please cite this article as: P. Lu, et al., 2014. The effectiveness of contractual and relational governances in construction projects in China, Int. J. Proj. Manag. http://
dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ijproman.2014.03.004
P. Lu et al. / International Journal of Project Management xx (2014) xxx–xxx 11

Lo, W., Lin, C.L., Yan, M.R., 2007. Contractor’s opportunistic bidding Reuer, J., Ariño, A., 2002. Contractual renegotiations in strategic alliances. J.
behavior and equilibrium price level in the construction market. J. of Constr. Manag. 28, 47–68.
Eng. and Manag. 133, 409–416. Reuer, J., Ariño, A., 2007. Strategic alliance contracts: dimensions and
Love, P.E., Irani, Z., Edwards, D.J., 2004. A seamless supply chain determinants of contractual complexity. Strateg. Manag. J. 28, 313–330.
management model for construction. Supply Chain Manag.: An Int. J. 9, Roehrich, J.K., Lewis, M.A., 2010. Towards a model of governance in complex
43–56. (product–service) inter‐organizational systems. Constr. Manag. Econ. 28,
Lui, S.S., Ngo, H., 2004. The role of trust and contractual safeguards on 1155–1164.
cooperation in non-equity alliances. J. Manag. 30, 471–485. Rokkan, A.I., Heide, J.B., Wathne, K.H., 2003. Specific investment in
Lumineau, F., Fréchet, M., Puthod, D., 2011. An organizational learning marketing relationships: expropriation and bonding effects. J. Mark. Res.
perspective on the contracting process. Strateg. Organ. 9, 8–32. 40, 210–224.
Luo, Y., 2002. Contract, cooperation, and performance in international joint Ryall, M.D., Sampson, R., 2009. Repeated interaction and contract structure:
ventures. Strateg. Manag. J. 23, 903–920. evidence from technology development contracts. Manag. Sci. 55,
Lusch, R.F., Brown, J.R., 1996. Interdependency, contracting, and relational 906–925.
behavior in marketing channels. J. Mark. 60, 19–38. Sha, K., 2009. “Re-seeking of the puzzle of scale-performance” — why
Macneil, I.R., 1978. Contracts: adjustment of long-term economic relations construction is big not strong? Constr. Econ. 9–11.
under classical, neoclassical, and relational contract law. Northwest. Univ. Tangpong, C., Hung, K., Ro, Y.K., 2010. The interaction effect of relational
Law Rev. 72, 854–905. norms and agent cooperativeness on opportunism in buyer–supplier
Macneil, I.R., 1980. The New Social Contract: An Inquiry into Modern relationships. J. Oper. Manag. 28, 398–414.
Contractual Relations. Yale University Press, New Haven. Turner, J.R., Keegan, A., 1999. The versatile project-based organization:
McKnight, D.H., Cummings, L.L., Chervany, N.L., 1998. Initial trust formation governance and operational control. Eur. Manag. J. 17, 296–309.
in new organizational relationships. Acad. Manag. Rev. 23, 473–490. Turner, J.R., Keegan, A., 2000. The management of operations in the project-
Meng, X., 2012. The effect of relationship management on project performance based organisation. J. Chang. Manag. 1, 131–148.
in construction. Int. J. Proj. Manag. 30, 188–198. Turner, J.R., Keegan, A., 2001. Mechanisms of governance in the project-based
Miller, R., Hobbs, B., 2005. Governance regimes for large complex projects. organization: roles of the broker and steward. Eur. Manag. J. 19, 254–267.
Proj. Manag. J. 36, 42. Villena, V.H., Revilla, E., Choi, T.Y., 2011. The dark side of buyer–supplier
Morgan, N.A., Kaleka, A., Gooner, R.A., 2007. Focal supplier opportunism in relationships: a social capital perspective. J. Oper. Manag. 29, 561–576.
supermarket retailer category management. J. Oper. Manag. 25, 512–527. Vrijhoef, R., Koskela, L., 2000. The four roles of supply chain management in
National Bureau of Statistics of China, 2012. China Statistical Yearbook construction. Eur. J. of Purchasing and Supply Manag. 6, 169–178.
(2006–2012). China Statistics Press, Beijing. Walker, D.H.T., 2003. In: Walker, D., Hampson, K. (Eds.), Implications of
Nickerson, J.A., Hamilton, B.H., Wada, T., 2001. Market position, resource Human Capital Issues. Blackwell Science, Malden, MA, pp. 258–296.
profile, and governance: linking Porter and Williamson in the context of Wang, X., Yang, Z., 2013. Inter-firm opportunism: a meta-analytic review and
international courier and small package services in Japan. Strateg. Manag. J. assessment of its antecedents and effect on performance. J. Bus. Ind. Mark.
22, 251–273. 28, 137–146.
Nixon, P., Harrington, M., Parker, D., 2012. Leadership performance is Wathne, K.H., Heide, J.B., 2000. Opportunism in interfirm relationships: forms,
significant to project success or failure: a critical analysis. Int. J. Product. outcomes, and solutions. J. Mark. 64, 36–51.
Perform. Manag. 61, 204–216. Williamson, O.E., 1981. The economics of organization: the transaction cost
Ouchi, W.G., 1979. A conceptual framework for the design of organizational approach. Am. J. of Sociol. 87, 548–577.
control mechanisms. Manag. Sci. 25, 833–848. Willaimson, O.E., 1985. The Economic Institutions of Capitalism. Free Press,
Phelps, A.F., Reddy, M., 2009. The influence of boundary objects on group New York.
collaboration in construction project teams. In Proceedings of the ACM Winch, G.M., 1989. The construction firm and the construction project: a
2009 International Conference on Supporting Group Work, pp. 125–128. transaction cost approach. Constr. Manag. Econ. 7, 331–345.
ACM. Winch, G.M., 2001. Governing the project process: a conceptual framework.
Pinto, J.K., Slevin, D.P., English, B., 2009. Trust in projects: an empirical Constr. Manag. Econ. 19, 799–808.
assessment of owner/contractor relationships. Int. J. Proj. Manag. 27, Yu, C.M.J., Liao, T.J., Lin, Z.D., 2006. Formal governance mechanisms,
638–648. relational governance mechanisms, and transaction-specific investments in
Poppo, L., Zenger, T., 2002. Do formal contracts and relational governance supplier–manufacturer relationships. Ind. Mark. Manag. 35, 128–139.
function as substitutes or complements? Strateg. Manag. J. 23, 707–725.
Project Management Research Committee of China, 2009. Chinese Project
Management Body of Knowledge (Revision). Publishing House of
Electronics Industry, Beijing.

Please cite this article as: P. Lu, et al., 2014. The effectiveness of contractual and relational governances in construction projects in China, Int. J. Proj. Manag. http://
dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ijproman.2014.03.004

You might also like