Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 8

Marine Policy 68 (2016) 187–194

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Marine Policy
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/marpol

Can environment management integrate into supply chain


management? Information sharing via shrimp aquaculture
cooperatives in northwestern Sri Lanka
Eranga K. Galappaththi a,n,1,2, Sarath S. Kodithuwakku b,1, Iroshani M. Galappaththi c,1
a
Department of Geography, McGill University, 805 Sherbrooke Street West, Montreal, QC, Canada H3A 0B9
b
Sultan Qaboos University, PO Box 34, Al-Khod 123, Sultanate of Oman
c
Manitoba Health, 300 Carlton Street, Winnipeg, Manitoba, Canada R3B 3M9

art ic l e i nf o a b s t r a c t

Article history: This paper examines the effects of information sharing via community cooperatives on supply chain
Received 30 November 2015 management (SCM) in community-based shrimp aquaculture in northwestern Sri Lanka. Further, it
Received in revised form identifies how environment management integrates into SCM. The paper examined shrimp aquaculture
7 March 2016
operations in northwestern Sri Lanka using the case study approach. Main actors of the shrimp aqua-
Accepted 7 March 2016
culture supply chain (SC) are: brood-stock suppliers; hatcheries; farmers; collectors; and processing
Available online 24 March 2016
companies. Information shared is: post-larvae prices; feed brands; harvest prices; production quotas;
Keywords: disease spread; farming techniques; and management practices. This paper explores the existing in-
Information formation sharing network. Its findings reveal that community cooperatives play crucial roles within this
Cooperatives
network while functioning under a mixed governance regime (private; communal; government).
Supply chain management
Membership gives farmers a mechanism for networking and accessing information. This article discusses
Information commons
Shrimp aquaculture how such information can act as commons. An efficient network of information sharing is vital for the
Sri Lanka community's socio-economic wellbeing, as well as social-ecological sustainability. Sri Lankan shrimp
aquaculture exemplifies SCM that integrates environment and commons management.
Crown Copyright & 2016 Published by Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

1. Introduction integrate into shrimp aquaculture SCM? Can effective information


sharing on SC be attained through community cooperatives? Such
Aquaculture performs an emergent role in global food supply questions have theoretical significance for SCM as well as com-
chains. Wild fish stock depletion and a growing demand for sea- mons management, and practical importance for sustainable
food are major reasons for reliance on aquaculture [1]. Supply aquaculture. This paper examines the effects of information shar-
chain management (SCM) plays a significant role in getting sea- ing through community cooperatives on SCM in community-based
food from pond to place at a reasonable price, with the best shrimp aquaculture in northwestern Sri Lanka.
quality, and without interruptions. Shrimp aquaculture is a unique SC is “a network of organizations that are involved, through
sector for SCM because of its high value, production-related un- upstream and downstream linkages, in the different processes and
certainty, and shrimp supply chain (SC) perishability [2,3]. Con- activities that produce value in the form of products and services
trarily, global shrimp aquaculture has a bad reputation in terms of delivered to the ultimate consumer” [11: 3]. An SC consists of
environment and social sustainability [4–7]. Sri Lankan shrimp multiple firms, both upstream (i.e., supply) and downstream (i.e.,
aquaculture is governed by community cooperatives with minimal distribution), and the ultimate consumer. SCM highlights the long-
adverse environmental impacts [8–10]. This paper examining term benefit of the chain's actors [12]. SCM's concern is “how to
small-scale shrimp aquaculture communities on the Indian Ocean coordinate the independent players, so that they work together as
in northwestern Sri Lanka. Can environment management a unit, in the pursuit of the common goal of changing market
conditions” [13: 344]. Collaboration among SC's actors uses limited
resources and attempts to coordinate production through the en-
n
Corresponding author. tire SC [14,15]. The “bullwhip effect”—originally applied to in-
E-mail address: erangakokila@yahoo.com (E.K. Galappaththi). formation distortion in SC—explains the aggregated impact along
1
Postgraduate Institute of Agriculture, University of Peradeniya, Old Galaha
Road, Peradeniya 20400, Sri Lanka.
the SC [16].
2
Natural Resources Institute, University of Manitoba, 70 Dysart Road, Winni- In literature, debates exist about information and knowledge
peg, Manitoba, Canada R3T 2N2. sharing in SC. Knowledge in the SCM context is valuable and

http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.marpol.2016.03.013
0308-597X/Crown Copyright & 2016 Published by Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
188 E.K. Galappaththi et al. / Marine Policy 68 (2016) 187–194

actionable information [12,17]. Knowledge enables predictions or northwestern and eastern coastal belts, covering more than 5000
predictive decisions. Information simply gives us facts. Knowl- hectares [41].
edge's primary elements are data—unrelated facts that have their Operations depend on the environment. A particular soil is
own values. Data combined and placed in a context create in- required to establish a shrimp pond. The soil's rich nutrient con-
formation. When information goes through a critical and creative tent facilitates better algae growth [42], resulting in a healthy
thought process, it becomes knowledge [12,18]. In a business aquatic system. Water is an equally important resource. The area's
context, both information and knowledge sharing are combinable primary water source is the “Dutch canal,” which contains brack-
and interchangeable. Therefore, this paper used the term “in- ish water (a mix of salt and fresh water). It runs from south to
formation sharing.” Information sharing is a collaborative effort, as north and connects several salt water lagoons and fresh water
communication involves the information provider and seeker rivers, forming a common water body. Galappaththi and Berkes
[19,20]. Benkler [21] identified information as a public good in a [9,10] explain how shrimp farmers manage this common water
strict economic sense; information is also input into its own pro- body as commons. Farmers who have no access to this water use
duction process. Further, Benkler [21] recognized the possibility of pumped salt water from the sea and/or a lagoon and groundwater
communication systems managed as commons. from tube wells.
This article focus on information sharing through community
cooperatives for shrimp aquaculture resource management activ-
ities affecting SCM. Collectively managed resources can work 2. Methods and study area
better than privately or government-managed resources [22,23],
and “collective action” can solve commons problems better than The study adopted a qualitative design with a case study ap-
individual solutions [23]. Cooperatives are locally/member-owned, proach [43,44] and was conducted in the Muthupanthiya, Koth-
collectively managed entities that affect community wellbeing thanthive, and Karamba communities of northwestern Sri Lanka
[24,25]. Sri Lankan shrimp aquaculture management relies on (Fig. 1). Participants were selected using the snowball sampling
community cooperatives and a multi-level institutional structure technique due to the absence of a proper sampling frame. Primary
that serves as the governance system's backbone [8]. Cooperatives data were collected through: a) questionnaire-based interviews
are significant components of the community-based management with shrimp farmers and other stakeholders (e.g., feed suppliers,
system in northwestern shrimp aquaculture [9], adopting com- hatchery managers, government aquaculture extension officers);
mons and collaborative management approaches for challenges b) key informant interviews; and c) participant observations. The
like shrimp disease [9,10]. sample contained 53 stakeholders, including 35 shrimp farmers
In theory, commons institutions like community cooperatives (Muthupanthiya, 11; Koththanthive, 14; Karamba, 10). Five key
can solve the commons problem [8,26]. Such institutions address informant interviews were undertaken for data verification pur-
basic issues, i.e., the “tragedy of commons” [9,26-28], which de- poses. Primary data collection took place from September 2008
scribes how individual freedom to access the commons causes the through December 2009. From April to August 2012, the com-
system to fail [28]. The tragedy starts in an aquaculture context munities were re-visited to gather supplementary data.
due to excessive use and/or misuse of environmental resources as
inputs and waste discharge (mainly used pond water) to the sur-
rounding environment [9,10,29]. However, the commons’ scope is 3. Results
broad [30]. Charlotte Hess [31] identified evolving commons types
as “new commons”—cultural; medical and health; neighbourhood; 3.1. Supply chain overview of shrimp aquaculture
knowledge; markets; and global. Some literature even compares
information commons to library commons and/or digital com- Fig. 2 provides an overview of the Sri Lankan shrimp aqua-
mons [32,33]. culture SC. Several stages and players are involved. Parent shrimp
SCM integrates environment management into SC, and re- (i.e., brood stock) of sizes appropriate for breeding are caught from
searchers recognize the best practice called green supply chain
integration (GSCI) [34]. Literature acknowledges the significance of
combined environment management into SC [34,35]. Community
green supply chain integration stems from studies of community
stakeholder pressures [34,36,37]. Community GSCI is a strategic
collaboration with stakeholders in an SC to manage the SC's op-
erational/environmental impact by orchestrating resources across
community stakeholders [34]. Wong et al. [34] highlighted the
significance of feedback information of community stakeholders.
Further, feedback information is the key resource for community
GSCI practices. So far there is no or little evidence available on
community GSCI in shrimp aquaculture SC; the Sri Lankan case
study could be one to look at.
The dominant aquaculture operation in Sri Lanka involves
coastal shrimp [38]. The most common species cultured is black
tiger shrimp (Penaeus monodon). The industry produces more than
2000 tons annually, with a farm gate value of about $70 million
[38]. It provides more than 1000 direct jobs and about 1800 in-
direct jobs [39]. Export markets are Japan, the U.K., and the U.S.
However, local markets are also part of shrimp aquaculture SC.
Compared to the global shrimp industry, Sri Lanka leads the world
in productivity, with an average yield of more than 4500 kg per
hectare [40]. The industry contains medium and small companies
[8]. As of 2012, shrimp farming is found mainly in the Fig. 1. Study area in northwestern Sri Lanka.
E.K. Galappaththi et al. / Marine Policy 68 (2016) 187–194 189

Fig. 2. Overview of Sri Lankan shrimp aquaculture SC.

the sea. They are sold to breeding stock suppliers who take them sea) is quantity-wise significant. The wild catch goes through the
to shrimp hatcheries. The parents are kept under controlled con- same SC pathway and competes against farm-produced crops for
ditions (temperature, salinity, pH value, lighting) until the eggs are better prices. Shrimp sold at local markets do not undergo value
extracted. The eggs are kept in a separation tank until they spawn addition or processing. However, before being sold at foreign
into a post-larvae (PL) stage. PLs are considered raw material in markets, the yield must be processed to increase its shelf life and
shrimp farming and are sold by quantity to farmers. The farmers add value. Value addition is also done based on buyers’ guidelines
culture PLs in grow-out ponds until they reach a stage appropriate (e.g., head on, shell on; headless, shell on; peeled and deveined;
for processing (harvest). The harvest is then sold either to seafood tail on). Shrimp farmers are the primary actors in the shrimp
processing plants (for export) or village-level shrimp collectors/ aquaculture supply chain. Their role is to maintain timely, con-
middlemen (for the local market). As of 2012, shrimp farmers sold sistent shrimp production to SC.
over 50% of the harvest to the local market. If the harvest is good Shrimp farm characteristics varied based on farm size (number
for export, its quality is graded and prices are set. If the harvest is of shrimp ponds) as well as ownership type. Shrimp farm ponds
sold in the local market, it is given a single bulk price. The famer varied in size from 0.2 hectares to 0.8 hectares. Forty-six percent
decides which market to sell to based on price levels and the (46%) of the farmers operated one to three ponds; 27% operated
harvest's quality. The number of actors involved in each stage, lead four or five ponds; and the rest operated six or seven ponds. Se-
times (i.e., the time taken to complete a particular stage), and venty-two percent (72%) of the shrimp farms in the sampled area
approximate unit values are given in Fig. 2. were family businesses (in which one or more family members
Secondary businesses evolved around the shrimp industry: were full-time shrimp farmers); the rest are owner-managed
supplying feed for PLs in hatcheries and growing adults in farms; farming operations. Shrimp farmers’ family members (mostly,
antibiotics to prevent disease; processing plants to produce value- wives and adult children) were involved in bookkeeping, labour,
added products; machinery rentals (paddle wheels, generators, sales, managing and investing. Furthermore, family members at-
water pumps); money lending arrangements (banks and informal tended monthly meetings of the shrimp farmers' community co-
money lenders); middlemen and collectors who buy harvests from operative. Communities engaged in two farming cycles (i.e., har-
farmers and sell them to processing plants; laboratory services to vests) per year. Shrimp farmers worked through community co-
test the quality/diseases of PLs (e.g., the Polymerized Chain Reac- operatives to manage their activities.
tion [PCR] test); and advisory services to provide extension ser-
vices/guidance/information on culturing, management practices, 3.2. The community cooperative
and disease prevention.
Nevertheless, while the shrimp industry attracts businessmen The institution that facilitates networking among farmers is the
due to its high profit margins and relatively short crop lifecycle, it community cooperative (called “samithiya” in the local language).
has high risk due to price fluctuations and shrimp's susceptibility Community cooperatives are farmer-initiated entities established
to disease. Further, wild catch (i.e., shrimp caught directly from the in the mid-1990s. Though the cooperatives serve the same
190 E.K. Galappaththi et al. / Marine Policy 68 (2016) 187–194

purpose, they gained legal status through various sources–the buy, which brand, and at what price. Availability of feed-related
Cooperatives Act or registration under the acts of government information depends on the marketing approaches taken by the
institutions such as divisional secretariat offices and the National feed sales and distribution companies. However, in Muthu-
Aquaculture Development Authority (NAqDA). A cooperative's panthiya, feed supplying is accomplished by a single agent based
membership is between 20 and 60 farmers (Muthupanthiya, 23; on a trust relationship that includes the complimentary facilities of
Koththanthive, 60; Karamba, 30). To engage in a community's informal credit arrangements and consultancy/extension services
shrimp aquaculture, farmers must become members of the com- provided with the feed. Both Koththanthive and Karamba access
munity cooperative. The elected officers include president, vice multiple feed suppliers and constantly make changes to achieve
president, secretary, treasurer, and assistant treasurer. These co- better-quality harvests.
operatives have constitutions to govern activities such as decision Farm gate price (the price at which a farmer sells produce to
making; finance management; and the election process. Monthly the buyer or processing company) is based on market price levels.
and special meetings are held as needed. Collective decision Farm gate price details are crucial to farmers as they determine
making is a significant characteristic [10,22]. profit margins. A listing of prices is available based on the average
These cooperatives collectively form the Sri Lanka Aquaculture weight of a shrimp ready to harvest. These prices fluctuate daily
Development Association (SLADA), the national entity represent- based on the international market's supply and demand; the local
ing shrimp farmers. The cooperatives also represent an overriding supply; and the currency exchange rate. Processing company re-
group which makes decisions related to shrimp farming. From a presentatives are in contact with shrimp farmers to communicate
resource management perspective, the cooperative is the lowest- their daily farm gate prices.
level self-organized community entity within the hierarchy of the Production quantities (quotas) for each season are determined
shrimp aquaculture governance structure. Government aqua- by a committee consisting of representatives from the government
culture extension officers (NAqDA) attend meetings and work line institution (NAqDA) and the national shrimp farmers’ industry
closely with the cooperatives to ensure that farming practices association (SLADA). Multiple factors are considered: farming ca-
comply with national regulations. However, the extension officers pacity of a community; prevailing shrimp disease conditions;
do not influence the cooperatives’ decisions; instead, they provide availability of shrimp post-larvae; and availability of parent stocks
information and guidance. to produce post-larvae. A crop calendar is designed for the
northwestern area, and production quotas (i.e., the maximum al-
3.3. Types of information shared lowed harvest quantity in kilograms) are announced along with
the stocking periods (i.e., when the post-larvae should be added to
Table 1 provides details about the types of information shared/ the ponds) for each area. NAqDA, SLADA, and cooperatives si-
used; information origins; users; the purpose of use; and the multaneously disseminate this information among all the co-
mechanism(s) of information sharing by the cooperative. Accord- operatives before the stocking periods. Farmers hear about this
ingly, shrimp post-larvae-related information (availability, quality, and decide how much to stock and by when. This information is
and prices) are generated by shrimp hatchery owners according to also available in national newspapers. The development of the
the quality of the post-larvae produced in each hatchery. Direct crop calendar is a collective decision-making process [10]. Even
users of this information are shrimp farmers who must decide though production quotas and stocking dates are publicized by
where to buy, at what price, and of which quality. Post-larvae price NAqDA and SLADA, shrimp farmers and cooperatives play a major
information is shared through cooperatives and personal contacts role in the annual crop calendar's development as farmers escalate
and is based on previous buying experiences. Some shrimp their input/feedback to national levels via farmer representatives
farmers prefer to buy post-larvae from different hatcheries for (i.e., community cooperative leaders).
individual ponds to minimize the risk of low-quality or disease- Disease-related information is also crucial. White spot disease
infected materials. Cooperatives do not formally recommend can destroy a harvest within 24 hours. Moreover, the shrimp
hatcheries, but share information related to post-larvae price and production cycle's success depends on the harvest being disease-
availability with their members. free. Disease-related information can be generated by different
Information related to feed brands and prices is crucial, as a groups: SLADA; NAqDA; cooperatives; and other individuals or
substantive portion of the production cost relates to feed. Feed groups of farmers. The information flows to shrimp farmers
cost-related details are generated and managed collectively by through the cooperatives. However, in rare instances, disease-re-
feed importers; selling companies; and/or sales agents. Direct lated information becomes limited if the individual/groups of
users of this information are farmers who must decide where to farmers do not disclose the information—considered unlawful—so

Table 1
Information sharing in the community.

Type of information Origin (who generates the Direct users and purpose of use Mechanism(s) of sharing
information)

Post-larvae availability, quality, and Hatchery owners Farmers to decide where to buy, at what Via cooperatives and personal contacts (within the
prices price, of which quality, when (date) the PLs cooperatives’ membership in an informal manner)
become available
Feed brands/prices Feed suppliers (importers, Farmers to decide where to buy, which Via cooperatives and personal contacts (within the
sales agents) brand, and at what price cooperatives’ membership in an informal manner)
Farm gate shrimp (harvest) prices Processing companies Farmers to decide to whom to sell and at Via personal contacts, processing factory re-
what price presentatives, the cooperatives
Production quota/stocking dates NAqDA, SLADA Farmers to decide how much and when to Via cooperatives and published in national
based on national crop calendar stock newspapers
Disease prevalence/spread SLADA, NAqDA, cooperatives, Farmers to take disease prevention and Via cooperatives
individual farmers control measures
Shrimp farming techniques/better NAqDA, cooperatives, in- Farmers to improve shrimp growth/quality Via cooperatives and workshops organized by
management practices dividual farmers and to minimize disease risk NAqDA and SLADA
E.K. Galappaththi et al. / Marine Policy 68 (2016) 187–194 191

that the harvest's marketability is not affected. Non-disclosure of (cooperatives, SLADA), government (NAqDA), and private sector
information may further intensify the spread of the disease. The (feed suppliers, processing companies, shrimp hatcheries) stake-
information becomes publicly available if known by SLADA, NAq- holders. The interaction between shrimp farmers and the co-
DA, or the cooperatives. The community cooperative takes the operative is a two-way process and shows a strong information
following actions against those who do not disclose this in- relationship. A similar interaction exists between the cooperative
formation: it refuses to issue permits for the crop season and/or and feed suppliers. The information flow between shrimp hatch-
inflicts penalties. eries and community cooperatives occurs both ways and shows a
Shrimp farming techniques and better management practices strong relationship. NAqDA and SLADA collaboratively provide
provide two benefits. Farmers can: (1) improve performance by information to the cooperatives (two-way strong interaction) and
enhancing shrimp growth and harvest quality; and (2) minimize shrimp hatcheries (strong one-way interaction). NAqDA also
disease risk by adopting preventive measures. Better management maintains a direct communication channel with the cooperatives
practices are designed by NAqDA and are to be implemented by through field extension officers. NAqDA and SLADA frequently
shrimp farmers under the purview of community cooperatives [9]. communicate between themselves, especially to inform officials
Specifications for disinfecting ponds and pumping water from the who represent the parties in the collaborative decision-making
canals are examples of better management practices. Shrimp body. SLADA, by its mandate, keeps the cooperative informed.
farming techniques are developed by NAqDA, SLADA, cooperatives, NAqDA, SLADA, and the cooperatives maintain multiple commu-
and/or individual farmers. Workshops are held by NAqDA and nication channels to meet information needs. Further, shrimp
SLADA to share new technologies. Furthermore, community-level farmers share information both ways with shrimp hatcheries, feed
sharing of experiences occurs through the cooperatives as well as suppliers, and processing companies.
informally among farmers. The “collaborative decision-making body” is a joint committee
consisting of SLADA and NAqDA officials, mandated to respond to
all shrimp-industry-related matters [8]. Strong interactions/lin-
3.4. Role of community cooperatives in information sharing
kages can be observed between the SLADA and NAqDA collective
decision-making body and the cooperatives. However, the co-
To investigate the role of community cooperatives in the in-
operative does not show strong interaction with processing com-
formation-sharing structure, a network of interactions was de-
panies, resulting in a moderate link with one of the most influ-
veloped (Fig. 3). The network is based on: (1) the direction of in-
ential stakeholders. The processing companies can act relatively
formation flow among stakeholders; and (2) the strength of the independently, as they do not completely rely on aquacultured
information shared. If an interaction/relationship is strong, the shrimp harvests as raw material. (Shrimps caught directly from
information is likely shared broadly and the ability to trust and act the sea, i.e., wild capture, is another raw material option.) Cultured
upon it is high. The inverse it also true. This diagram represents versus captured shrimp harvest quantities vary seasonally based
overall information flow, not for individual types of information on factors like local market demand; time of the year; quality of
discussed above (such as feed, PL, or farm gate price). cultured shrimps; and disease conditions.
The strength of information shared among stakeholders was Much communication happens during regular meetings, but
determined as follows. Respondents were asked to choose one of cellular phones are used extensively to communicate with farmers
three options (strong, moderate, or low) to describe information and other stakeholders. By constitution, the secretary is re-
sharing based on the information each stakeholder provided. The sponsible for sharing information, messages, and other corre-
level of satisfaction was determined based on average values (part spondences. Meeting minutes keep track of the records. Mem-
of the original study). For example, 88% (31 out of 35) of shrimp bership provides farmers with a means of networking and in-
farmers said that the information from their cooperatives was formation exchange. The types of information shared through the
“strong”; thus, on average, they experienced a strong information cooperative are important to daily farming operations and the
relationship. long-term management of community-level aquaculture business.
The information sharing network is a mix of communal Such information relates to: markets and prices; resource gov-
ernance; and disease spread. Shrimp farmers deal daily with new
and emerging problems (such as diseases and the quality of lagoon
waters) and argue among themselves in community cooperatives
over ways to overcome these challenges. As new challenges ap-
pear, they debate new approaches.

3.5. Information sharing effects on SC

Historical examples from northwestern shrimp aquaculture


explain how changes in the information sharing mechanism in
small-scale shrimp aquaculture affect its SC.
First, from 1999 to 2006 shrimp farming cooperatives did not
function well in some communities [8]. Lack of regular meetings,
low membership, and de-motivation due to uncontrollable disease
were some of the recorded reasons for this dysfunctionality. The
situation continued until SLADA and NAqDA strengthened the
cooperatives to implement the zonal crop calendar system [10].
The zonal crop calendar system is a new management approach
that minimizes the spread of the shrimp disease by controlling the
access to common lagoon water bodies through establishing
commonly agreed temporal and spatial boundaries [10]. Disabled
cooperatives could not share timely, accurate, and complete in-
Fig. 3. Present network of interactions among stakeholders. formation among the information sharing network (Fig. 3). As a
192 E.K. Galappaththi et al. / Marine Policy 68 (2016) 187–194

result, PL price, farm gate price, and shrimp production quantities processing companies. Second, community cooperatives are re-
fluctuated unexpectedly. National annual shrimp aquaculture cognized by shrimp aquaculture sector stakeholders. The govern-
production records showed a prominent inconsistency [45]. A ment institution NAqDA has identified community cooperatives as
number of actors, including hatcheries (about 20), framers (about formal entities for shrimp aquaculture management purposes [10].
100), and processing companies (e.g., Agro Marine) left the in- Third, all shrimp farmers must be members of community co-
dustry due to unfavorable conditions. operatives. Shrimp farmers’ dependence on community co-
Second, in 2006 shrimp farmers, with government support, operatives makes overriding systems (SCM and aquaculture
implemented the zonal crop calendar to manage shrimp diseases management) run efficiently.
using a collaborative approach [10]. The multi-level institution Sri Lankan shrimp aquaculture SC consists of small-scale actors.
structure was introduced and set up by shrimp farmers, SLADA, The main actors are: brood-stock suppliers (10); shrimp hatcheries
and NAqDA to support the zonal crop calendar system [8]. Sharing (40); shrimp farmers (600); shrimp collectors (10); and shrimp
of updates and accurate information was the key aspect of this processing companies (4) (Fig. 2). Though processing companies
new system. As a result, community cooperatives were strength- get seasonal captured shrimp from fishermen, shrimp aquaculture
ened and started functioning smoothly. Government monitored SC is dominated by shrimp farmers and is a primary producer of
these community cooperatives through extension officers. The aquacultured shrimp. Compared to other culture crops, shorter
information sharing network also began running smoothly. PL and crop lifecycles and a disease-sensitive nature are embedded fea-
shrimp farm gate prices, and national shrimp aquaculture pro- tures of shrimp aquaculture SC, bringing uncertainty and risk to all
duction, became consistent and relatively stable. This situation actors. A consistent supply of shrimp production and healthy price
brought some hatchery owners, farmers, and new processors (e.g., variations are key factors in the overall SCM; they also ensure
the Srimic seafood processing company) to the SC. actors’ income generation activities. Hence, disease control
Accordingly, the relationship between the cooperative's func- through a good environment and natural resource management
tionality, effective information sharing, and SC performance were are significant features of this SC and affect the performance of
identified (Fig. 4). Better functioning of community cooperatives shrimp aquaculture SC and SCM.
affords effective and timely information sharing among shrimp Environmental and commons management aspects of north-
farmers, which helps them make better decisions. Outcomes are western shrimp aquaculture affect SCM. Sri Lankan shrimp aqua-
reflected in the SC. The SC's better performance is reflected in the culture is managed by a mixed regime of communal (community
fact that consistent production reached consumers at a reasonable cooperatives)/state (NAQDA)/private (family/farmer-owned
price. shrimp farms and SLADA) entities [8–10,46,47]. The existence of
community-based management [8] and management of natural
resources are unique features [9]. There is a multi-level and bot-
tom-up institutional structure with a collaborative decision-mak-
4. Discussion
ing body composed of the government institution NAqDA and
sector association SLADA [8]. The strategy for shrimp disease
The Sri Lankan shrimp aquaculture SC shows the effectiveness
control involves a crop calendar system with the support of a
of information sharing via cooperatives in SCM. A positive re-
multi-level institution structure and collaborative management
lationship exists among community cooperative functionality, ef-
[8,10,48]. The community cooperative is the key commons in-
fectiveness of information sharing via cooperatives, and SC per-
stitution widely recognized by state authorities. Effective sharing
formance. How does information sharing via cooperatives work in
of information via cooperatives is another equally important
the context of Sri Lankan shrimp aquaculture? First, a well-es-
characteristic.
tablished community-based management system is represented
The types of information shared through community co-
by the cooperatives in farming communities. Cooperatives and
operatives are: post-larvae prices; feed brands/prices; farm gate
associations exist for hatcheries, brood-stock collectors, and
shrimp (harvest) prices; production quota and stocking dates
based on the national crop calendar; disease prevalence/spread;
and shrimp farming techniques and management practices. The
community cooperative is the main communication system (or
mechanism), sharing a substantial portion of information. Further,
the cooperative acts as an information hub and shows strong in-
teractions/linkages between most other SC actors. Being a member
of a community cooperative gives farmers access to market-,
production-, and environment-related information for shrimp
farming operations. Such information can influence the opera-
tional success of farming at both the individual farmer level and
the community level. It also determines the performance of SC and
is an important aspect for SCM.
In an economic sense, information is a resource for carrying out
income-generating/business activities [21]. If information is
shared widely and available readily, Sri Lankan shrimp farmers
learn about prices; product quality; new technologies; and com-
petition, and can adjust their actions (e.g., price comparisons;
bargaining for prices) accordingly. Such conditions allow farmers
to operate at an optimum level (i.e., zero discrimination based on
information) while maximizing overall economic returns. Simi-
larly, if the information is not readily accessible, it could become a
barrier, resulting in the absence of a competitive market and
Fig. 4. Relationship of effective information sharing via community cooperatives to leading to a “market failure”, which results from market dis-
small-scale shrimp aquaculture SC. equilibrium [49,50]. Moreover, information generates “signals”
E.K. Galappaththi et al. / Marine Policy 68 (2016) 187–194 193

[51] that have significant social, economic, and ecological benefits. [5] J.H. Primavera, Socio-economic impacts of shrimp culture, Aquac. Res. 28
As such, information can behave as commons (or ‘information (1997) 815–827.
[6] R. Bhatta, M. Bhat, Impacts of aquaculture on the management of estuaries in
commons’ as named by authors), affecting the overall wellbeing India, Environ. Conserv. 25 (2) (1998) 109–121.
(welfare) of shrimp farmers and social-ecological systems [4,8–10]. [7] M. Huitric, C. Folke, N. Kautsky, Development and government policies of the
Consequently, shrimp farmers’ actions (e.g., used pond water dis- shrimp farming industry in Thailand in relation to mangrove ecosystems, Ecol.
Econ. 40 (3) (2002) 441–455.
posal) determine how the natural ecological system is utilized [8] E.K. Galappaththi, F. Berkes, Institutions for managing common-pool re-
and/or affected. sources: the case of community-based shrimp aquaculture in northwestern Sri
These findings are consistent with the concept of GSCI [34]. Sri Lanka, Marit. Stud. 13 (2014) 13.
[9] E.K. Galappaththi, F. Berkes, Drama of the commons in small-scale shrimp
Lankan shrimp aquaculture SCM exemplifies multiple environ-
aquaculture in northwestern, Sri Lanka, Int. J. Commons 9 (1) (2015) 347–368.
mental management aspects integrated into SC. First, the co- [10] E.K. Galappaththi, F. Berkes, Can co-management emerge spontaneously?
operative's role in disseminating information related to production Collaborative management in Sri Lankan shrimp aquaculture, Mar. Policy 60
quotas based on the national crop calendar system allows for (2015) 1–8.
[11] J.T. Mentzer, W. DeWitt, J.S. Keebler, S. Min, N.W. Nix, C.D. Smith, Z.G. Zacharia,
management of the lagoon by optimizing shrimp farmers’ water Defining supply chain management, J. Bus. Logist. 22 (2) (2001) 25.
usage [10]. Second, cooperatives are sharing information to control [12] C.A.A. Rashed, A. Azeem, Z. Halim, Effects of information and knowledge
diseases throughout the lagoon. Shrimp farming cooperatives in sharing on supply chain performance: a survey based approach, J. Oper.
Supply Chains Manag. 3 (2) (2010) 61–77.
Sri Lanka show a high level of compliance with collective action [13] J.R. Montoya-Torres, D.A. Ortiz-Vargas, Collaboration and information sharing
design principles, indicating good governance [9,22]. Third, Sri in supply chains: a literature review over the period 2000–2012, Estud. Ger-
Lankan shrimp aquaculture can rely on cooperatives and their enc. 30 (2014) 343–354.
[14] M. Caridi, R. Cigolini, D. De Marco, Improving supply-chain collaboration by
simplicity because of the operations’ small-scale nature. This scale linking CPFR, Int. J. Prod. Res. 43 (20) (2005) 4191–4218.
and simplicity allow shrimp farmers to rely on fewer environ- [15] E. Verwaal, M. Hesselmans, Drivers of supply network governance: an ex-
mental resources. On the other hand, farmers minimize environ- plorative study of the Dutch chemical industry, Eur. Manag. J. 22 (4) (2004)
442–451.
mental impacts by managing water intake and pond water dis-
[16] H.L. Lee, V. Padmanabhan, S. Whang, The bullwhip effect in supply chains,
charge [9]. Sloan Manag. Rev. 38 (3) (1997) 93–102.
[17] S. Wadhwa, A. Saxena, Knowledge management based supply chain: an evo-
lution perspective, Glob. J. e-Bus. Knowl. Manag. 2 (2) (2005) 13–29.
[18] D. Hart, The wise supply chain: Knowledge as its component of success. in:
5. Conclusion Proceedings of the 13th Biannual Conference of Australian Rangeland Society,
Alice Springs, NT 2004, pp. 154–160.
Community cooperatives play a vital role in sharing specific [19] G.M. Wittenbaum, A.B. Hollingshead, I.C. Botero, From cooperative to moti-
vated information sharing in groups: moving beyond the hidden profile
information among farmers within the shrimp aquaculture SC in paradigm, Commun. Monogr. 71 (3) (2004) 286–310.
northwestern Sri Lanka and act as a platform for information [20] M.J. Shaw, Information based manufacturing with the web, Int. J. Flex. Manuf.
sharing. This paper explored the positive relationship among the 12 (2/3) (2000) 115–129.
[21] Y. Benkler, The political economy of commons, Upgrade 4 (3) (2003) 7.
functionality of community cooperatives, effective information [22] E. Ostrom, Governing the Commons: the Evolution of Institutions for Collec-
sharing, and the performance of shrimp aquaculture SC. The tive Action, Cambridge University Press, New York, 1990.
findings highlight the importance of community cooperatives for [23] E. Ostrom, Collective action and evolution of social norms, J. Econ. Perspect. 14
(3) (2000) 137–158.
SCM in community-based shrimp aquaculture. An efficient net-
[24] ICA. International Cooperative Alliance; 2014. 〈http://ica.coop/en/whats-co-
work of information sharing is vital for the community's socio- op/co-operative-identity-values-principles〉. Accessed 22.11.14.
economic wellbeing, as well as social-ecological sustainability. [25] O. Amarasinghe, M. Bavinck, Building resilience: fisheries cooperatives in
When shared broadly and available readily, information can be- southern Sri Lanka, in: S. Jentof, A. Eide (Eds.), Poverty mosaics: Realities and
Prospects in small-scale Fisheries, 383–406, Springer, Dordrecht, 2011.
have as commons. Sri Lankan shrimp aquaculture serves as evi- [26] E. Ostrom, J. Burger, C.B. Field, R.B. Norgaard, D. Policansky, Revisiting the
dence for community GSCI practices [34] by integrating the com- commons: local lessons, global challenges, Science 284 (1999) 278–282.
mons management approach into SCM. [27] G. Hardin, The tragedy of the commons, Sci., New Ser. 162 (3859) (1968)
1243–1248.
[28] D. Feeny, F. Berkes, B.J. McCay, J.M. Acheson, The tragedy of the commons:
twenty-two years later, Human. Ecol. 18 (1) (1990) 1–19.
Acknowledgement [29] F. Pa´ez-Osuna, The environmental impact of shrimp aquaculture: causes, ef-
fects, and mitigating alternatives, Environ. Manag. 28 (1) (2001) 131–140.
[30] C. Hess, E. Ostrom, Understanding Knowledge as a Commons, from Theory to
We sincerely appreciate the support of shrimp farmers and Practice, The MIT Press, Cambridge, 2007.
community members of northwestern Sri Lanka. I gratefully ac- [31] C. Hess, Mapping the new commons. Presented at the 12th Biennial Con-
ference of the IASC, Cheltenham, UK, 14–18 July; 2008.
knowledge Rohan Paaris from SLADA and all the staff of NAQDA [32] D. Beagle, Conceptualization an information commons, J. Acad. Librariansh. 25
Battulu-Oya shrimp farming monitoring and extension unit, for (2) (1999) 82–89.
their invaluable support and guidance. All authors owe a debt of [33] R. Bailey, B. Tierney, Information commons redux: concepts, evolution, and
transcending the tragedy of commons, J. Acad. Librariansh. 28 (5) (2002)
gratitude to Dr. Fikret Berkes, Canada Research Chair in Commu- 277–286.
nity-Based Resource Management, for his financial (The Canada [34] C.Y. Wong, C.W.Y. Wong, S. Boon-itt, Integrating environment management
Research Chairs Program: http://www.chairs-chaires.gc.ca) and into supply chains: a systematic literature review and theoretical framework,
Int. J. Phys. Distrib. Logist. Manag. 45 (1–2) (2015) 43–68.
intellectual support and advice regarding early drafts of this paper.
[35] R.D. Klassen, The integration of environmental Issues into manufacturing:
toward an interactive open-systems model, Prod. Oper. Manag. 4 (1) (1993)
82–88.
References [36] G. Kassinis, N. Vafeas, Stakeholder pressures and environmental performance,
Acad. Manag. J. 49 (1) (2006) 145–159.
[37] M.R. Hill, Sustainability, greenhouse gas emissions and international opera-
[1] R.L. Naylor, R.J. Goldburg, J.H. Primavera, N. Kautsky, M.C.M. Beveridge, J. Clay, tional management, Int. J. Oper. Prod. Manag. 21 (12) (2001) 1503–1520.
C. Folke, J. Lubchenco, H. Mooney, M. Troell, Effect of aquaculture on world fish [38] Anon, Ten year development policy framework of the fisheries and aquatic
supplies, Nature 405 (2000) 1017–1024. resources sector (2007–2016), Ministry of Fisheries and Aquatic Resources;
[2] J. Barnaby, A. Vincent, An assessment of the sustainability of shrimp pur- 2007: 4. 〈http://www.fisheries.gov.lk/English_link/10%20year%20plan.pdf/〉.
chasing at UBC, The University of British Colombia Sustainable Seafood Pro- Accessed 22.02.12.
ject-Phase II 2007, p. 27. [39] FAO, World review of fisheries and aquaculture (part 1), Food and Agriculture
[3] A. Cascorbi, Farm-raised shrimp worldwide overview. Seafood Watch Seafood Organization of the United Nations; 2010: 18. 〈http://www.fao.org/docrep/
Report: Farmed Shrimp, Final report 2004: 26. 013/i1820e/i1820e01.pdf〉. Accessed 23.11.15.
[4] P.K. Nayak, F. Berkes, Whose marginalization? Politics around environmental [40] Anon, Fisheries and Aquatic Resources Act No. 2 of 1996 of Sri Lanka, Section
justice in Indian's Chilika lagoon, Local Environ. 15 (6) (2010) 553–567. 66, 2011: 21. 〈http://www.customs.gov.lk/docs/25295.pdf〉. Accessed 03.03.12.
194 E.K. Galappaththi et al. / Marine Policy 68 (2016) 187–194

[41] J.M.P.K. Jayasinghe, Shrimp Culture in Sri Lanka: Key Issues in Sustainability 132–145.
and Research 1998, pp. 48–51. 〈http://aciar.gov.au/files/node/2196/pr90chap [47] T.T.T. Huong, F. Berkes, Diversity of resource use and property rights in Tam
ter07.pdf〉. Accessed 19.03.12. Giang lagoon, Vietnam, Int. J. Commons 5 (1) (2011) 130–149.
[42] A.W. Fast, L.J. Lester, Marine Shrimp Culture: Principles and Practices, Devel- [48] R.S. Pomeroy, R. Rivera-Guieb, Fishery Co-management: a PHhandbook, In-
opments in Aquaculture and Fisheries Science, Elsevier 1992, pp. 345–398. ternational Development Research Centre, Ottawa 2006, pp. 16–17.
[43] J.W. Creswell, Research Design: Qualitative, Quantitative, and Mixed Methods [49] E. Ostrom, C. Chang, M. Pennington, V. Tarko, The Future of the Commons:
Approaches, Third edition, Sage Publications, Lincoln, 2009. Beyond Market Failure and Government Regulation. Institute of Economic
[44] R.K. Yin, Case Study Research, Design and Methods, Volume 5. Applied Social Affairs Monographs, Indiana University, Bloomington School of Public & En-
Research Method Series, Sage, Thousand Oaks, CA, 2009. vironmental Affairs Research, 2012, Paper no. 2012-12-02: 57.
[45] FAO, National Aquaculture Sector Overview, Food and Agriculture Organiza- [50] B.D. Ottum, W.L. Moore, The role of market information in new product suc-
tion of the United Nations; 2015: 4. 〈http://www.fao.org/fishery/coun cess/failure, J. Product. Innov. Manag. 14 (4) (1997) 258–273.
trysector/naso_sri-lanka/en〉. Accessed 22.11.15. [51] H.R. Varian, Microeconomic Analysis, Third edition, W.W. Norton and Com-
[46] P.K. Nayak, F. Berkes, Commonisation and Decommonisation: understanding
pany Inc, New York 1992, p. 469.
the processes of change in the Chilika lagoon, India, Conserv. Soc. 9 (2) (2011)

You might also like