Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 10

See discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.

net/publication/288670066

Economy, Roman

Chapter · January 2014


DOI: 10.1007/978-1-4419-0465-2_1471

CITATIONS READS

0 275

1 author:

Miko Flohr
Leiden University
64 PUBLICATIONS   59 CITATIONS   

SEE PROFILE

Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects:

Building Tabernae - how commercial investment changed the cities of Roman Italy (200BCE-300CE) View project

Inequality and Society in the Roman World View project

All content following this page was uploaded by Miko Flohr on 01 November 2017.

The user has requested enhancement of the downloaded file.


 
E 2338 Economy, Roman
 
and related disciplines, with the aim to enhance GSELL, S. 1893. Recherches archéologiques en Algérie.
over the long term (from prehistory to the end of Paris: E. Leroux.
VALLET, G., F. VILLARD & P. AUBERSON. (ed.) 1983-.
the Middle Ages) an understanding of ancient Megara Hyblaea. Rome: École française de Rome.
societies of the Mediterranean basin, while con- VILLEDIEU, F. 1997-2007. La Vigna Barberini (Roma
tributing to the research training of young archae- antica 3, 6). 2 v. Rome: École française de Rome.
ologists and widely disseminating its findings in  
publications or on its website (www.efrome.it). Further Reading
  FERNIQUE, E. 1880. De Regione Marsorum, thesim
proponebat Facultati litterarum Parisiensi ad gradum
  doctoris promovendus Emmanuel Fernique. Paris: E.
Cross-References Thorin.
 
▶ American Academy in Rome  
▶ Archaeology and Anthropology  
▶ Architecture, Roman Economy, Roman
▶ Archival Research and Historical Archaeology  
▶ Central Italy: Pre-Roman and Archaic Miko Flohr
Ceramics Leiden University, Leiden, The Netherlands
▶ Ceramics, Ancient Greek  
▶ Ceramics, Roman Imperial  
▶ Ceramics: Roman Republican and Early Introduction and Definition
Principate  
▶ Deutsches Archäologisches Institut (DAI), The Roman economy was the economic system
Rome Department created by the geographical expansion of the
▶ Economy, Roman political power of Rome over the Mediterranean
▶ Epigraphy, Imperial Latin and Europe between the third-century BCE and
▶ Epigraphy, Latin: Early Through Late the first-century CE and maintained during the
Republican first centuries of our era until its gradual decline
▶ Italy: Medieval Archaeology in late antiquity. The Roman economy can be
▶ Latium Vetus, Latium Adjectum seen as the acme of a long period of technological
▶ North Africa, Roman development and economic growth in the
▶ North Africa: Historical Archaeology Mediterranean, which began in the early first
▶ Numismatics, Roman Imperial millennium BCE and led to population increase,
▶ Numismatics, Roman Republican intensification of land use, economic and political
▶ Religion, Italo-Roman, Archaeology of integration, and urbanization. Its decline in late
▶ Survey Archaeology in the Roman World antiquity marks the beginning of a long period of
 
transformation and urban regression in Europe as
 
  well as in large parts of the Mediterranean.
References  
   
BEN ABED BEN KHADER, A. & M. GRIESHEIMER. 2004. La Historical Background
nécropole de Pupput, I. Rome: Ecole française de  
Rome.
Academic History
BEN ABED-BEN KHADER, A., M. FIXOT, M. BONIFAY &
S. ROUCOLE. 2004. Sidi Jdidi I. La basilique sud. The history, structure, and performance of the
Rome: Ecole française de Rome. Roman economy have been hotly debated issues
BLOCH, R. 1972. Recherches archéologiques en territoire since the late nineteenth century. Debate about
volsinien de la protohistoire à la civilisation étrusque.
the Roman economy has long been characterized
Paris: De Boccard.
FIXOT, M. 2011. Sidi Jdidi. II. Le groupe episcopal. Rome: by a strong emphasis on the differences or simi-
Ecole française de Rome. larities between the Roman economy and the
 
Economy, Roman 2339 E
 
economy of the industrializing world and by an the economic role of cities, the existence of
opposition between optimists, who are inclined to long-distance trade, and the presence or absence
emphasize Roman achievement, and pessimists, of technological development.
who are inclined to emphasize Roman After the turn of the millennium, the debate
shortcomings. moved beyond the Finleyan paradigm and has
The debate originated in late nineteenth- begun to explore the relative position of the
century Europe, with a big controversy between Roman economy compared to other preindustrial
Karl Bücher and Eduard Meyer being a first economies, particularly Medieval and Early
major milestone. Bü cher argued that the ancient Modern Europe. In the debate, there is an
economy was a household economy character- increasing emphasis on historical change and,
ized by self-sufficiency. Meyer attacked this particularly, economic growth, issues that had
view and maintained that the Roman Empire traditionally been absent from both primitivist
saw the growth of “big business” and a full and modernist accounts of the Roman economy.
development of capitalism.  
In the core decades of the twentieth century, Evidence
a “modernist” paradigm dominated the field. Debates about the Roman economy are based on
It was most forcefully articulated by Mikhael a variety of datasets that can be divided into two
Rostovtzeff, who argued that the Roman groups: texts and material remains. There are
economy was structurally similar to the modern three groups of textual sources: literary texts,
economy but only differed in that it operated inscriptions, and documentary texts. Roman
on a much smaller scale. Romans had literary texts (including the law codes) provide
well-developed entrepreneurial mentalities, snippets of information about economic practice,
there was considerable long-distance trade, and though they are strongly biased towards the
the economic fate of cities depended on elite point of view and are not necessarily reliable
the degree to which they were able to develop when it comes to understanding the details of
large-scale, export-oriented production. everyday economic processes – particularly if
The 1970s saw a true paradigm shift, basically these took place beyond the world of the literary
caused by the work of Moses Finley, who was and political elites. Secondly, inscriptions
strongly influenced by both the work of Max incidentally reveal information about urban
Weber and Karl Polanyi and who argued that economic life, particularly in Italy and Asia
the ancient economy was, in general, a primitive Minor, and particularly about the social dynamics
affair. Long-distance trade was restricted to that surrounded urban manufacturing and
luxury goods, while bulk demand was satisfied commerce. Epigraphically preserved government
through locally produced wares. Moreover, decrees incidentally shed light on the impact of
cultural and societal structures impeded large- local and supra-local governments on economic
scale elite investment in manufacturing and held life. Thirdly, documentary texts, including papyri
back economic growth. Cities were centers of and writing tablets, provide detailed information
consumption (Weberian “consumer cities”) and about all kinds of transactions, including loans,
display whose economic fate depended on the tax payments, sales, and orders, though they are
presence of a landowning elite, and not on only available for a limited number of areas and
market-oriented export production. sites (e.g., Egypt, Pompeii, Vindolanda).
Finley’s work proved highly provocative and Archaeological evidence used in the Roman
was subsequently refined, adapted, and contested. economy debate includes remains of infra-
Especially in the 1980s and 1990s, Finley’s ideas structure and buildings, transport containers,
were at the center of a fierce academic debate products, coins, and iconographic representations
between “modernists” and “primitivists” – with of economic processes. Remains of port and
archaeologists generally opting for the modernist road infrastructure give clear indications about
side of the debate. Key issues in the debate were not only the geography of trade routes but also
 
E 2340 Economy, Roman
 
the investment involved in constructing and to its proximity to the major crossing of the Tiber
and, thus, to the flow of people and goods
maintaining the trade network. Similar informa-
between Etruria and southern Latium and
tion can be derived from the remains of commer-
Campania. As a consequence, trade and transport
cial facilities and manufacturing establishments.
were at the heart of the Roman economy right
Transport containers, particularly amphorae, can
generally be provenanced and tend to give an from the start, and the subsequent expansion of
indication of the products they contained. Rome, from early on, was characterized not
only by the spread of political power but also by
Finished products themselves reveal information
about provenance and production technology, the emergence of a tightly knit network of
economic connections – partially created by gov-
and through the emerging practice of “stamping”,
they inform scholars about their makers as ernment policy and partially emerging through
well. Coins and coin hoards allow scholars to market interaction. Politics and the economy
discuss monetization and coin circulation, were closely related: economic integration in
which is fundamental to understanding the many cases preceded and/or fostered political
integration, which would then further enhance
dynamics of trade and transactions. Iconography
economic integration. Where this was not the
plays key roles in debates about the technology of
production processes, showing depictions of case, Romans sometimes appear to have had
work equipment that has not been preserved clear economic motives for expansion, such as
archaeologically. However, archaeological datathe presence of metal ores that could be mined
are biased and unequally divided over the (e.g., Spain, Dacia).
Roman world, both in time and space, and their The city of Rome emerged as the center of
interpretation is often complicated by their inac-
gravity of this economic network early on, and
cessibility and by varying standards of the volume of demand generated by the city
publication. would become a defining feature of the Roman
While the Roman economy debate until the late
economy as it developed from a regional center
1970s was characterized by an overwhelm- into a metropolis of hitherto unknown propor-
tions. From the middle republic to late antiquity,
ing emphasis on textual evidence, and particularly
on literature, the 1980s and 1990s saw a clearmetropolitan demand was a key driving force
increase in the use of material remains in behind the Roman economy and, to a certain
discussing economic issues. extent, behind the Roman political system.
Quantitative
analyses of dated Mediterranean shipwrecks andThe Roman metropolis is a feature that sets
the Roman economy clearly apart from all its
of the geographical spread of terra sigillata pottery
Mediterranean predecessors and separates it
from the imperial period had a deep impact on the
debate, as had the results of field survey projects.
from most of the preindustrial economies of
An increased focus on urban production facilities
Medieval and Early Modern Europe.
in the late 1990s changed the dynamics of the The historical development of the Roman
debate about urban economies. After the turn of
economy was closely related to and to
the millennium, archaeologists increasingly a considerable extent conditioned by develop-
started to explore the possibilities of scientific
ments in the Mediterranean of the first millen-
analysis, including isotopic and DNA analysis on
nium BCE. These include, firstly, the
organic remains, which is now enabling to include
colonization of the western Mediterranean by
material categories into the debate that hitherto
the Greeks and the Phoenicians from the early
had little to offer, such as animal bones and eighth-century BCE onwards and the subsequent
human remains. increase in contacts between Etruscans, Italians,
  and Greeks, which transformed the economic
Historical Context landscape of central Italy and the Tyrrhenian
The emergence of Rome as a local power in Sea and created long-distance trade routes
the seventh and sixth centuries BCE was related between Latium and the Eastern Mediterranean.
 
Economy, Roman 2341 E
 
Secondly, an intensification of Aegean and area. Together, they brought about a dramatic
Eastern Mediterranean trade in the second halfdecrease in transaction costs which made long-
distance transport and trade more feasible than
of the first millennium BCE, and the Helleniza-
tion of the East and Egypt after Alexander, ever before.
created an intensive trade network that the Fundamental to the integration of the Roman
Romans could easily tap into. A similar network
economy was the large network of roads, which
was created by Carthaginian expansion in Northwas created and maintained by the state and
which connected inland regions with each other
Africa and Spain, though this was initially less
readily accessible to the Romans. These develop-
and with the sea. There is debate as to whether
ments were basic requirements for the much more
these roads were specifically created to foster
far-reaching economic integration of the land transport, but there is no debate about the
Mediterranean which took place under Roman fact that they dramatically lowered its costs.
leadership from the last centuries BCE onwards.
Though land transport still was much more
Yet besides economically integrating the expensive than river or sea transport, the vast
road network allowed traders to penetrate areas
Mediterranean to an extent hitherto unseen, the
Roman economy also integrated, unlike Greek that hitherto had been inaccessible at a relatively
and Hellenistic economies had done, the low cost. Comparable investment is visible in
European continent into Mediterranean networksport facilities in the Mediterranean, which
of trade and exchange and saw the development became more numerous and also larger.
of intensive trade and exchange with regions The establishment of colonies and the settle-
beyond the political boundaries of the Roman ment of Romans throughout the Roman world,
world, including Europe and Scandinavia, the but particularly in Roman Europe, also contrib-
Near East, and, particularly, India, which uted to the integration of the Roman economy, as
developed a trade connection with Roman Roman communities retained close contact with
Egypt through the desert, the Red Sea, and theItaly and the Mediterranean. As a result, much
Indian Ocean. Further, there were indirect trading
more accurate information about faraway
connections with China, probably both over markets would have been available throughout
land, via the Silk Route, and by sea, via India.
the empire. The spread of Mediterranean culture
  and consumptive patterns over Roman Europe
  created considerable markets for Mediterranean
Key Issues/Current Debates products, including wine, olive oil, and fish
  sauce, that were not available locally. Integration
Integration of taste also fostered standardization. Especially
A key aspect of the Roman economy was the in the imperial period, certain products (e.g.,
integration of an enormous area into what was, shoes) were standardized to an extent that
essentially, one economic system – even though empire-wide trends in design can be perceived.
the extent of regional fragmentation is not to  
be underestimated. Economic integration was Agriculture
based on the political unity of the Roman Agriculture was the basis of the Roman economy
world, which brought advanced, often state- and occupied, probably, over 80 % of the popu-
sponsored, transport infrastructure; unity in lation. Key crops included the traditional
laws and currency; and the spread, throughout Mediterranean triad of olives, grapes, and
the empire, of large groups of people with good cereals. While evidence for agricultural practice
long-distance connections and of two languages is extremely scarce, it is usually assumed that
that together sufficed to conduct business there was relative technological stability in farm-
throughout large parts of the Roman world. All ing methods. Yet Mediterranean farming
these phenomena were unique, and had not been methods and plant species did disseminate over
seen before on this scale and over such a large a large area, including Europe, and there were
 
E 2342 Economy, Roman
 
major developments in the organization of rural Roman Africa and Spain, particularly around
space, particularly around colonies. The rational- the Straits of Gibraltar, was similarly aimed at
ized organization of the countryside resulting a vast imperial market.
from centuriation lowered overhead costs by  
improving the accessibility of land and making Raw Materials
the organization and planning of agriculture As far as the non-food economy is concerned, it is
easier. In general, there is a clear increase in important to distinguish extraction from
the total area used for intensive agriculture, manufacturing. Raw materials for which there
with intensification being particularly remark- was large-scale and empire-wide demand include
able in the Latin-speaking west. In Roman a wide range of metals (gold, silver, tin, lead,
Africa, field survey has shown an increased use copper, iron, zinc), stone and marbles, wood,
of even rather marginal lands for oleiculture. clay, wool, and flax. The availability of these
While in many parts of the Roman world materials differed – some, such as wool, iron,
the small- to medium-sized farmstead was the clay, and wood, were widely available, but
standard unit in agriculture, there is a clear others, particularly coin metals and marbles,
emergence of farms operating on a much larger were only found in specific regions or places.
scale, including large villae rusticae owned by In the case of coin metals, high-quality
the elite, which came to control significant parts marbles, and colored stone, there seems to be
of the countryside (e.g., Settefinestre). There also a direct involvement of the government in extrac-
appears to be an accumulation of estates tion: large mines and quarries were generally
(latifundia) in the hand of increasingly wealthy owned and run by the state, and especially in the
landowners, some of whom would own a rich case of the important mining regions of Dacia and
portfolio of estates in various parts of the Spain, the presence of mineable gold and silver
Roman world. It is assumed that this large-scale seems to have played an important role in
landowning also fostered new agricultural conquest. In mining, Romans used advanced
strategies, including monoculture, and large- hydraulic technologies to get out the metal ores
scale clusters for processing. Nevertheless, in large quantities, which also involved large-
mixed agriculture remained the norm on most scale investment in aqueducts. They also used
farmsteads and villae. Archimedes’ screws and water wheels to drain
The Roman world also saw a clear increase in underground mines, so that they were able reach
the amounts of agricultural yields that were a much greater depth than in earlier periods. Ores
consumed at long distances from the place of were smelted on or near the mining site and then
production. Metropolitan and army demand fos- turned into bars or ingots, which were stamped
tered agriculture throughout the empire, as is and transported throughout the Roman world.
attested by literary sources and by the amphora When the imperial government was not directly
remains from the Monte Testaccio, which show involved, the evidence suggests more locally
that, especially in the Imperial period, an over- oriented extraction through traditional methods
whelming amount of the olive oil consumed in and on a much smaller scale. This goes for mining
Rome came from Southern Spain. A defining as well as quarrying.
element of the Roman cereal economy was the There is clear evidence that materials were
annona, through which the emperor divided grain transported and traded in more or less raw form
among the population of the Roman metropolis. over long distances. This included wood, raw
Most of this grain came from Egypt and Africa. wool, flax fibers, stone, and all metals, though
Other large cities in the empire seem to have had trade was much less intensive when materials
similar vast areas from which they drew were widely available. The only real exception
their basic foodstuffs, though their economic hin- is clay, which was generally turned into its final
terland is less well studied. Large-scale fish product in a location close to the pit.
processing and garum production on the coast of Glass, dependent on the availability of natron,
 
Economy, Roman 2343 E
 
was produced in a limited number of scale, such as at La Graufesenque or Scoppietto.
locations – particularly in the Near East – and Fulling factories at Ostia and Rome employed up
then transported in raw form to the place where it to 100 people and stood at the end of long-
was turned into a final product, as is indicated distance clothing trade catering for the metropol-
by the discovery of raw glass in several itan market. Large-scale workshops could be
shipwrecks. Trade in raw wool and linen was highly rationalized and use a strict division of
probably limited to the finer qualities from cer- labor and rudimentary materials handling. Liter-
tain regions and to some bulk trade for the ary texts further suggest the existence of cities
metropolitan market of large cities, including producing large amounts of textiles, though here,
Rome itself. Nevertheless, the general picture individual production units may have remained
suggests intensification and integration compared small.
to earlier periods.  
  Commerce
Processing and Manufacturing Roman cities were centers of consumption-
In processing materials and foodstuffs, and in oriented commerce, and commercial facilities
manufacturing consumer goods, small-scale played a highly visible role in the urban land-
establishments remained the norm. The typical scape. Streets, especially in and around city
workshop was situated in one or two small centers, tended to be lined with shops. These
rooms and operated by a small work group had wide openings on the street that fostered
organized around a (male) skilled artisan. interaction between retailers and passersby.
Investment in production facilities in such work- This is a big development from the Greek and
shops was low, and while the workspace was Hellenistic world, in which shops were much less
well-organized, the success of the workshop common and had less wide openings. Here,
mainly depended on the artisanal and organiza- commerce was more focused on the agora and
tional skills of the work group and, particularly, private houses. There is a clear change in the
its leader. In an urban context, workshops would commercial articulation of cities in the Roman
be situated in or attached to a house, and world, particularly, but not exclusively, in
members of the (family) household would Roman Italy.
form the core of the work group. Most of this Most shops were related to houses. Medium-
production also seems to have been directly sized atrium houses in Italy would have one or
oriented towards private customers rather than two shops next to their main entrance; larger
traders and thus towards local consumption: houses could have up to ten. The strip buildings
many workshops had a shop or were situated dominating the cities of Roman Europe also often
in one, and iconographic representations of would have a shop in front. Besides these
craftsmen show their interaction with customers privately managed commercial facilities, there
as well as their work on the products. also is a spectacular proliferation of market
Yet alongside this traditional, small-scale facilities, such as macella and fora, and other
manufacturing world, there also is an emergence buildings with a (partially) commercial function,
of manufacturing or processing establishments such as basilicae. Most of this was the result
operating on a much larger scale. More often of either state-sponsored initiatives or, more
than not, these also were related to long-distance frequently, euergetism or investment by mem-
trade. Imperial period fish-salting establishments bers of local elites. In cities with larger consumer
in North Africa and Southern Spain could reach markets, purpose-built shop complexes emerge,
vast dimensions, and their products were as happened in Pompeii from the second c. BCE
consumed throughout the empire. High-quality onwards; the exceptional consumer market of
tableware pottery (terra sigillata) was produced Rome saw the construction of true shopping
in a limited number of production sites where malls, such as, most dramatically, Trajan’s
kilns and workshops would operate on a large Markets.
 
E 2344 Economy, Roman
 
This formalization of commercial space technologies that found their first widespread
occurred, however, against a background in application in the Roman world. Important is
which informal commerce also played a key the material revolution caused by the spread of
role. There is considerable evidence for street glassblowing in the first-century AD: glass ves-
sellers and itinerant merchants, who operated on sels quickly began to compete with their
the street rather than in shops or visited their terracotta and metal equivalents, transforming
customers in their homes. Epigraphic evidence the dynamics of the tableware and storage ware
points to the existence, in many cities, of periodic economies. The invention of the screw press,
markets taking place on fixed days and presumably in the late first-century BCE, had an
following a fixed schedule within a certain impact on olive and wine production as well as on
region. This also emphasizes the economic role the textile economy.
of cities as central places where people from the Yet the technological development that is
surrounding countryside could go to get goods most radical and most hotly debated is the appli-
and products that were not available in or around cation of water power in several manufacturing
their villa or village. processes in the imperial period. While few
  scholars doubt that the principles of mechanical
Technology water power were understood in elite circles, it
Technological innovation is a hotly debated was long disputed to which extent these princi-
issue among scholars. It is uncontroversial that ples actually were applied in everyday economic
the spread of the Roman economic network over life; however, archaeological work has now
Europe brought a spread of established, more confirmed that water power was not only much
advanced Mediterranean technology over more common than was assumed in the past but
a large area that technologically had been less also was a clear development of the Roman
well developed and that this had some economic imperial period. Attested are water-powered
effect. Yet, beyond that basic tenet, opinions installations for milling flour (e.g., at Barbegal
diverge sharply: some argue in favor of signifi- and in Rome) but also to saw stone (e.g., at
cant technological advance, while others argue in Ephesos).
favor of technological stagnation. There is, in  
fact, something to say for both sides. Growth
In general, stability was the norm, and produc- Since the turn of the millennium, the Roman
tion processes technologically tend not to differ economy debate has developed a strong focus
radically from earlier periods. A key example is on understanding the scale and nature of eco-
textile production: spinning and weaving were nomic growth. Most scholars now believe that
done with traditional instruments like the spindle there was at least some form of aggregate growth
and the warp-weighted loom. While there is evi- in the Roman economy in the late republic and
dence for the emergence of the more advanced the early empire. It is believed that maritime
horizontal loom in late antiquity, it does not seem transport reached a high peak in this period and
to have become widespread very quickly. that this is somehow reflected in the chronologi-
A similar picture emerges from blacksmithing cal spread of Mediterranean shipwrecks, which
and bronze working. While pottery production shows a clear peak between 100 BCE and 100
saw a clear increase in the use of molds for CE. Several other datasets have been thought to
high-quality tableware, this must be seen as show similar peaks, including air pollution levels
a change of strategy rather than as technological as recorded in the Greenland ice cap. All these
innovation: the technology had been around as data are, however, controversial, so while the
early as the Bronze Age and was widely used general picture of growth is not in doubt, it has
already before the Roman period. not yet been possible to map its precise chrono-
This is not however the whole story of Roman logical development or its geographical
technological progress: there are several key dimensions.
 
Economy, Roman 2345 E
 
However, the issue at stake is not so much Roman economic system. Current views are
the occurrence of economic growth in itself but more nuanced and emphasize the dynamic and
rather the relation between growth and demo- unpredictable nature of developments and the
graphic expansion: if the economy grew faster different fates of different regions, with the East-
than the population, GDP per capita would rise, ern Mediterranean enjoying sustained stability
and living standards would increase. If this was not for much longer than the rest of the Empire and
the case, GDP per capita would be stable or decline economic changes in the Latin-speaking part of
and so would living standards. The question thus is the Roman world not only starting earlier but also
to what degree the Roman economy was able to being more drastic. While for the Eastern Medi-
improve average living standards. The way to do terranean it is, in certain ways, possible to speak
this would be through technological innovation of a “transition,” for the western half of the
and lower transaction costs, which would enhance empire and specifically Europe, “decline” seems
productivity. While it is acknowledged that Roman a more appropriate term.
economic integration lowered transaction costs and The symptoms of decline become first visible
that there was innovation in some sectors of the towards the end of the second century. The large-
economy, it is controversial as to whether these scale imperial mines and quarries are deserted in
developments really led to sustained per capita the last quarter of the second century, which is
growth. Some scholars have embraced the Malthu- followed by a strong debasement of fine metal in
sian model of economic growth, which predicts coinage. Investment in large-scale processing
that, in preindustrial economies, the improved liv- and manufacturing plants is severely reduced,
ing standards generated by per capita growth with few new constructions, and some going out
directly lead to population increase, which eats of use or continuing on a smaller scale. There also
away the positive effect, so that living standards seem to be maintenance difficulties in the road
will have remained approximately at the same network; silting problems in harbors are less rig-
low level. Other scholars point to the boom in orously tackled than had been done before, with
investment in public monuments and urban some notable exceptions. This points to a decline
leisure facilities such as baths, theaters, and amphi- in long-distance trade, which also may be
theaters and to the increasingly wide diffusion of reflected in the decrease in shipwrecks from this
luxury goods and domestic decoration throughout period (though this also may be related to
the Roman world, both of which suggest that aver- a partial replacement of amphorae by barrels).
age living standards were raised to considerably Monumental construction – both imperial and
above subsistence level in the early empire. How- euergetic – declines strongly, especially after
ever, this was not necessarily reflected in health the Severan period, taking away one of the
and life expectancy, both of which, as analyses of motors of early imperial Roman urban econo-
skeletal remains and epigraphy suggest, seem to mies. Price inflation and state attempts to control
have remained at levels that are roughly typical for the market under Diocletian point to
the preindustrial world. a perception of serious economic turmoil by the
  imperial elite.
Decline As to what caused the changes after the sec-
The strong focus on late republican and early ond century, there is a range of possible causes.
imperial growth in the scholarly debate has not They can, roughly, be divided into external
yet been matched by an equally strong focus on causes and internal ones. External causes con-
the economic history of the Roman world after tributing to economic turmoil include several
the second century, when growth evidently came epidemics that hit the empire in the late second
to a halt, and the empire and its economy ran into and third centuries, including the devastating
trouble. Traditional accounts saw the late second Antonine Plague, which raged for 20 years and
century as the beginning of a sharp decline that in caused a significant decrease in population.
the end inevitably led to the collapse of the Moreover, the third century brought intensive
 
E 2346 Economy, Roman
E 2346 El Miron Cave: Geography and Culture
 
warfare at the frontier and several massive inva- HARRIS, W. 2000. Trade, in A. Bowman, P. Garnsey &
sions from non-Roman Europe. Some scholars D. Rathbone (ed.) Cambridge ancient history XI. The
High Empire: A.D. 70-192: 710-40. Cambridge: Cam-
have also suggested that the early imperial econ- bridge University Press.
omy was brought into trouble by climate change. - 2011. Rome’s imperial economy. Twelve essays.
Internal factors contributing to decline may Oxford: Oxford University Press.
include political unrest and the long political HOPKINS, K. 1980. Taxes and trade in the Roman Empire.
Journal of Roman Studies 70: 101-25.
crisis of the mid-third century. Further, HORDEN, P. & N. PURCELL. 2000. The corrupting sea.
a fallout in investment may have led to consumer Oxford: Blackwell.
economies coming to a standstill, while increas- KEHOE, D. 2007. The early Roman Empire: production, in
ing economic inequality caused more and more W. Scheidel, I. Morris & R. Saller (ed.) The Cambridge
economic history of the Greco-Roman world: 543-69.
wealth to be concentrated in the hands of Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
the elite, which has been thought to affect the MORLEY, N.1996. Metropolis and hinterland. Cambridge:
buying power of the rest of the population. Some Cambridge University Press.
have argued that early imperial economic pros- - 2007. The early Roman Empire: distribution, in
W. Scheidel, I. Morris & R. Saller (ed.) The Cambridge
perity simply was not sustainable, so that part of economic history of the Greco-Roman world: 570-91.
the process taking place in the third century Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
would be a natural correction. Yet, it is some- ROSTOVTZEFF, M. 1957. The social and economic history of
times hard to distinguish causes from effects, the Roman Empire. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
SCHEIDEL,W. 2009. In search of Roman economic growth.
and in reality, many of the abovementioned Journal of Roman Archaeology 22: 46-70.
factors may have contributed to decline and SCHEIDEL, W & S. FRIESEN. 2009. The size of the economy
transformation; the debate on this issue has not and the distribution of income in the Roman Empire.
yet produced a dominant theory. Journal of Roman Studies 99: 61-91.
  WILSON, A. 2002. Machines, power and the ancient
economy. Journal of Roman Studies 92: 1-32.
  - 2008. Large-scale manufacturing, standardization, and
Cross-References trade, in J.P. Oleson (ed.) Oxford handbook of engi-
neering and technology in the classical world:
393-417. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
▶ Infrastructure in the Roman World: Roads and - 2009. Indicators for Roman economic growth:
Aqueducts a response to Walter Scheidel. Journal of Roman
▶ Trade and Transport in the Ancient Archaeology 22: 71-82.
 
Mediterranean  
▶ Villas and Farms in the Mediterranean World  
 
 
 
  El Miron Cave: Geography and
Further Reading Culture
   
BANG, P. 2008. The Roman bazaar. Cambridge: Lawrence Guy Straus1 and
Cambridge University Press. Manuel R. González Morales2
BOWMAN, A. & A. WILSON. (ed.) 2009. Quantifying the 1
Roman economy. Methods and problems. Oxford:
Department of Anthropology, University of
Oxford University Press. New Mexico, Albuquerque, NM, USA
2
FINLEY, M.I. 1973. The ancient economy. London: Chatto Instituto Internacional de Investigaciones
and Windus. Prehistóricas, Universidad de Cantabria,
GREENE, K. 1986. The archaeology of the roman economy.
Berkeley: University of California Press.
Santander, Spain
- 2000a. ‘Technological innovation and economic pro-  
gress in the ancient world: M.I. Finley re-considered’.  
The Economic History Review 53(1): 29-59. Introduction
- 2000b. Industry and technology, in A. Bowman,
P. Garnsey & D. Rathbone (ed.) Cambridge ancient
 
history XI. The High Empire: A.D. 70-192: 741-68. El Mirón is a large cave that dominates a stretch
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. of the upper Asón River valley at the eastern end

View publication stats

You might also like