Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 8

Land Use Policy 57 (2016) 694–701

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Land Use Policy


journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/landusepol

Classification of farmland ownership fragmentation as a cause of land


degradation: A review on typology, consequences, and remedies
Petr Sklenicka ∗
Czech University of Life Sciences Prague, Faculty of Environmental Sciences, Prague 165 21, Czech Republic

a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t

Article history: Farmland ownership fragmentation is one of the important drivers of land-use changes. It is a process
Received 22 January 2016 that in its extreme form can essentially limit land management sustainability. Based on a typology of
Received in revised form 19 June 2016 land degradation and its causes, this process is here classified for the first time as an underlying cause
Accepted 24 June 2016
which through tenure insecurity causes land degradation in five types (water erosion, wind erosion, soil
Available online 6 July 2016
compaction, reduction of organic matter, and nutrient depletion). A review of relevant literature enables
the further presentation of a list of 21 types of land degradation and another extensive list of the 37 most
Keywords:
common causes of land degradation. This work further presents an overview of harmful consequences of
Land tenure
Sustainable land use
high farmland ownership fragmentation, and possibilities for remedying the effects. These possibilities
Land degradation typology consist of eliminating or mitigating those causes accelerating the fragmentation process, defragmenting
Land market current land ownership, and remedying the effects brought by this process.
Land consolidation © 2016 The Author. Published by Elsevier Ltd. This is an open access article under the CC BY-NC-ND
license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/).

1. Introduction fication of LD types (Section 2.1) and causes (Section 2.2). Section
3 outlines the farmland ownership fragmentation issue, classifying
There is no definitive list of land degradation (LD) types or this phenomenon as an underlying cause of LD (Section 3.1) and
causes, and it is very possible that there never will be. To date, the describing its possible remedies (Section 3.2). The conclusions of
list of types is dominated by processes reflecting the degradation of this review are presented in Section 4.
all physical, chemical, and biological properties of ecosystem sub-
components. Similarly incomplete is the list of the causes of LD,
which is, in contrast, dominated by, in addition to natural causes, 2. Land degradation
items of a socioeconomic character that have the end result of
reducing the primary production services of ecosystems. In this Lists of various LD types differ depending on the author, the fur-
regard, this work offers the most detailed overview to date of LD ther use for the typology, and primarily the definition of this term. It
types and causes. can generally be said that there is presently no universal agreement
This study focuses on a process with the end result of LD that has on a single definition. The term itself was coined quite recently,
not yet been described in sufficient detail, namely farmland owner- and as of 1994 did not even exist as an independent category in the
ship fragmentation. A review of the literature enables a description U.S. Library of Congress Classification (Johnson and Lewis, 2007).
of the negative effects of this phenomenon on agricultural land use Differences in currently used definitions consist primarily in two
as well as arguments supporting the conclusion that high farm- main issues. The first is broad interpretations of the term “land”
land ownership fragmentation is a cause of LD. The work goes on from the all-encompassing (umbrella) term embracing degrada-
to describe methods for mitigating the causes and negative conse- tion of all elements of the environment, including their interactions
quences of this process. (Stocking and Murnaghan, 2001), through the single-purpose or
The paper is organized as follows: Section 2 introduces various absolute limitation of the topic within “soil degradation” (Oldeman,
definitions of LD and discusses their consequences for the classi- 1994), to the entirely inappropriate simplification of the problem in
the interest of popularization, such as when Lomborg (2001) used
the term LD exclusively for soil erosion. The second essential differ-
∗ Corresponding author. Permanent address: Czech University of Life Sciences
ence arises from whether the definition covers natural processes as
Prague, Faculty of Environmental Sciences Kamycka 129, Prague, 165 21, Czech
causes of LD. In this area, authors are divided into two groups, with
Republic. one considering LD as a phenomenon or process that arises only as
E-mail address: sklenicka@fzp.czu.cz a result of human activities (e.g., Norbu et al., 2003; Johnson and

http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.landusepol.2016.06.032
0264-8377/© 2016 The Author. Published by Elsevier Ltd. This is an open access article under the CC BY-NC-ND license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/).
P. Sklenicka / Land Use Policy 57 (2016) 694–701 695

Lewis, 2007), while the other, larger group expands the definition of the land and/or ecosystem. Socioeconomic characteristics are
to include among causes such natural processes as rainfall, wind, not presented as types of LD but exclusively as factors influencing
temperature, and earthquakes under conditions without human LD. Table 1 presents an overview of the LD types used in relevant
influence (e.g., Blaikie and Brookfield, 1987; Sarukhán et al., 2005; typological and case studies. Individual types are divided into LD
Nachtergaele et al., 2011; Nkonya et al., 2011). In addition to these subcomponents, with the commonly used term soil degradation
two main areas within which the definition of LD diverges, there are also split into soil physics and soil chemistry. The list of types is not
a number of other differences affecting the form of the definition definitive. The list can be expected to expand in the area of biodi-
and therefore the typology of LD. These include such differences as versity, just as the tendency has recently been strengthening for the
whether the effects of degradation are understood exclusively in definition of LD to be expanded further from its previous narrow
relation to humans or at a general level, and also whether degrada- meaning of soil degradation to include other land components.
tion is expressed only as reductions in primary production or in a Compiling a general typology is no easy task in as much as LD
much broader sense to include such measures as biodiversity indi- must be judged in its spatial, temporal, economic, and cultural con-
cators. Moreover, Blaikie and Brookfield (1987) had emphasized the text (Warren, 2002). It generally holds that changes at the local level
socioeconomic dimension in stating that LD decreases the yields of affect global processes just as they are affected by these processes
labor and capital inputs into production. However, these authors (Wilbanks and Kates, 1999), and vice versa. Some types are mea-
did not offer any corresponding socioeconomic LD type. surable only at the finest scales, while others are regional or global.
This review will employ a concise but substantively broad def- Most of the types are, however, identifiable across scales.
inition thoughtfully compiled from several sources (Blaikie and
Brookfield, 1987; Sarukhán et al., 2005; Nkonya et al., 2011): “land 2.2. Causes of land degradation
degradation is the reduction or loss of natural beneficial goods and
services, notably primary production services, derived from terres- The causes of LD have not been comprehensively deliberated in
trial ecosystems”. This results in a definition embracing both human terms of their typology, interrelationships, or possible effects. Not
and natural causes and emphasizing primary production services even the terminology is unified, as in addition to the frequently used
but considering them within the context of all components of the term “cause” (e.g., Stocking and Murnaghan, 2001; Nachtergaele
land (soil, water, vegetation, and other components of the ecosys- et al., 2011; Nkonya et al., 2011), some authors (e.g., Barbier,
tem). The consequences of the process are not limited exclusively 1997) have used the term “determinant”, and others (e.g., Meadows
to human needs, although these are emphasized. Degradation thus and Hoffman, 2002) have used “factor.” Tefera et al. (2002) used
includes more types and affects soils, biomass, water, and socioeco- the two terms cause and factor, while Nachtergaele et al. (2011)
nomic services derived from ecosystems. I personally added to the used both cause and driver, without detailing any differences in
definition the word “natural,” which thus incorporates within LD their interpretation. It is necessary, however, to acknowledge one
cases wherein all beneficial goods and services may remain at the essential difference between the term cause and the terms fac-
previous level but at the cost of a higher input of additional energy tor, determinant, and driver. The term “causes” carries with it a
(fertilizer, irrigation, human work, etc.). Even such cases in which negative connotation of agency, while “factors”, “determinants”,
the natural potential of ecosystems is decreased should properly and “drivers” simply indicate the occurrence of the phenomenon,
be considered as LD. without raising the issue of an agent responsible for the negative
effects of what has happened. For this reason, it is not appropriate
2.1. Types of land degradation to denote as causes of LD such aspects as tenure security, abil-
ity to defend rights, and enforcement of rules, but rather tenure
This broad definition is suitable for the subsequent consider- insecurity, inability to defend rights, and weak enforcement of
ation of LD typology. However, it leads to several complications rules, respectively. As many authors do not take these nuances into
for further use. Above all, there is no consensus on how to assess account, Table 2 presents an overview of causes as well as factors,
ecosystem goods and services. All authors who discuss LD in gen- determinants, and drivers.
eral and who offer their own definitions or apply a certain point of To date, causes of LD have been mentioned only in an incomplete
view to specific cases fail to present a comprehensive accounting form or in the context of a specific LD type or research location.
of LD types. Similarly as with most other typologies, accounting for Nkonya et al. (2011) distinguished immediate (proximate) and
individual LD types is influenced primarily by the way in which the underlying causes, which helps to clarify complicated causal rela-
problem is defined and the purpose of its further use, which affects tionships for further study. These authors expressed the complexity
in particular the need for detail. The required level at which to of the relationship between these two levels in which some under-
assess these processes is derived from the purpose of the typology lying causes appear in other cases as immediate causes and vice
(global, regional, or local; Wiebe, 2003), which helps substantially versa. An example can be seen in tenure insecurity, which most
in deciding the suitability and measurability of individual types. often appears as an immediate cause of LD but in some cases may
Another important factor determining the form of LD types relates be classified as an underlying cause of poverty (Clerc, 2012). Spe-
to the local characteristics of the study area, particularly in endeav- cific causes may in certain cases even be consequences of Nkonya
oring to reflect the causes and processes which are dominant or et al. (2011) gave as an example those causes of poverty that lead
decisive in the given region or, in contrast, to suppress or exclude to insufficient investment in land management practices and to
from the assessment those types which are less important or are loss of natural fertility. Similarly, degradation of land fertility can
not present. also conversely establish or accelerate poverty. Cases where one LD
In terms of the distribution of individual LD types, water and type causes another LD type are also possible, as for example loss of
wind erosion together with loss of biodiversity most frequently vegetation cover (e.g., deforestation) may be a cause of water ero-
occur in less populated areas, while in agricultural areas the dom- sion. These are further reasons why a general relationship scheme
inated types are water shortages, soil depletion, and soil pollution at the level of individual LD causes has not yet been exhaustively
(Nachtergaele et al., 2011). Bai et al. (2008) stated that almost described and seemingly never can be.
one-fifth of degraded land comprised cropland, while 23% was Authors who include natural processes among causes of LD (see
deciduous forest, 19% coniferous forest, and 20–25% rangeland. Section 2) essentially agree on the basic division of causes into nat-
Currently used typologies emphasize physical, chemical, or bio- ural (biophysical) and human-induced causes (Nachtergaele et al.,
logical processes caused by both natural factors and human use 2011; Nkonya et al., 2011). A number of causes may seem to be
696 P. Sklenicka / Land Use Policy 57 (2016) 694–701

Table 1
Overviewof land degradation types mentioned in relevant typological and case studies.

Components Land Used in study


degradation
types

Oldeman (1994) Scherr and Yadav Stocking and Zuquette et al. Al-Awadhi et al. Bai et al. (2008) Omuto et al.
(1996) Murnaghan (2004) (2005) (2014)
(2001)

Soil physics Water erosion X X X X X X X


Wind erosion X X X X X X X
Compaction X X X X X
Crusting X X X X X
Sealing X X X X
Sedimentation/ X
silting
Increased X
temperature

Soil chemistry Acidification X X


Alkalinization X
Reduction of X X X X
organic matter
Nutrient leach- X X X X X
ing/depletion
Soil X X X X X
contamination

Water regime Water table X X


drawdown
Waterlogging X X
Salinization X X X X X X X
Water X
pollution

Vegetation Loss of X X X X X
vegetation
cover
Decline in X X X
species
diversity
Alien plant X
invasion

Air/climate Air pollution X X


Desertification X X

natural, but are in fact entirely, partially, or indirectly affected by individual farming (Sklenicka et al., 2009). Unlike in developing
humans and their activities (e.g. air quality, climate characteristics, countries, in Europe this considerable ownership fragmentation
soil vulnerability, water shortage, vegetation characteristics). contrasts sharply with predominantly modern farming methods
requiring large production blocks. The owners of small parcels are
essentially forced to rent these parcels to users farming nearby. In
3. Description of farmland ownership fragmentation the Czech Republic, for example, there are currently more than 3.5
million land owners, but only 30,000 farming entities (Sklenicka
In recent decades, a considerable number of European coun- et al., 2014). Together with Slovakia, this country holds the Euro-
tries as well as China, India, and others (Anantha Ram et al., pean record for alienating land owners from their land, as only
1999; Van Dijk, 2003; Tan et al., 2006) have been dealing with approximately 20% of land is farmed by its owners while the
the process of farmland ownership fragmentation and its effects. remaining 80% is rented. According to Eurostat (2015), such coun-
In developed countries, this process also comes into conflict with tries as Poland, Ireland, and Romania have the opposite proportions,
increasingly concentrated land use, modernization of farm machin- while the EU average ranges around 45% of farmland being rented.
ery, and increasing need for economically efficient management. The main cause of ownership fragmentation is partible inheri-
Land parcels are frequently so small that they cannot be individu- tance, whereby land is divided among all heirs and is not passed,
ally farmed and their owners are forced to rent the land to become for example, only to the oldest child. Partible inheritance occurs
part of the larger wholes of large agricultural holdings. This process in two ways. Either the land is physically divided among heirs or
can be seen as gradually alienating owners from their land, result- the new heirs increase the number of land co-owners (Noev et al.,
ing in clear negative impacts on most aspects of sustainable land 2003). Both cases result in fragmentation of land ownership rights.
use (Sklenicka et al., 2014). In addition to inheritance rights, the fragmentation process is influ-
Prime examples of extremely fragmented land ownership pat- enced by such other factors as the production potential of the land
terns are Central and Eastern European countries such as Slovakia, (more fertile land is less fragmented) and various historic events
Romania, the Czech Republic, Slovenia, Macedonia, and Bulgaria, that caused sudden jumps in the fragmentation rate (e.g., expelling
where mean farmland parcel sizes range between 0.3 and 0.5 ha the original inhabitants and dividing the land among new owners,
(Kopeva and Noev, 2001; Noev et al., 2003; Sabates-Wheeler, 2005; land reforms, and land consolidation; Sklenicka et al., 2009). The
Ciaian, 2008; Sklenicka et al., 2014). The fragmented, scattered, second most important cause of fragmentation is the physical divi-
and frequently inaccessible parcels are not economically viable for
P. Sklenicka / Land Use Policy 57 (2016) 694–701 697

Table 2
Overview of identified causes, factors, determinants, and drivers of land degradation based on relevant studies.

Character Causes/Factors/ Used in study


Determinants/Drivers

Barrow Stocking and Huber- Lu et al. Nachtergaele Nkonya et al. Other studiesa
(1991) Murnaghan Sannwald et al. (2007) et al. (2011) (2011)
(2001) (2006)

Natural (biophysical) Rainfall X X X X X


Wind X X X X
Temperature X X X X
Topography X X X
Geology X X
Soil vulnerability X X
Vegetation characteristics X X
Water characteristics X
Water shortage X X
Air quality X
Earthquake X X
Wild fires X X
Volcanic activity X X

Human-induced Overgrazing X X
(anthropogenic)
Overcultivation X X
Inappropriate management X X X X X X
Nutrient mining X
Water overdrawing X X
Deforestation X X
Marginalization X X
Mining X
Pollution and industrial causes X X
Climate change X
Inappropriate law and/or X X X
policy
Underdevelopment X X
Poverty X X X X X X
Population pressure/migration X X X X X X
Urban expansion X X
Tenure security X X X X
Access to markets X X
Availability of infrastructure X X
Economic incentives X X
Bioenergy subsidies X X
Labor availability X X
Inappropriate technology X X X
Health problems X X
Inadequate education X X
a
Other studies addressing specific cases of land degradation mention from one to three causes that frequently are specific to the given case.

sion of parcels during their sale, or change of use, most frequently between individual small parcels. That this is no minor issue can be
as a result of land conversion induced by development pressure seen in the fact that more than 40% of farmland in the Czech Repub-
(Irwin and Bockstael, 2007). lic is distributed across parcels smaller than the economic viability
threshold (Sklenicka et al., 2014). Another large problem of such
highly fragmented ownership patterns lies in the fact that many
3.1. Classifying ownership fragmentation as a cause of land
parcels are not accessible by road due to increasing fragmentation
degradation
that has not been accompanied by the construction of a denser
road network (Sklenicka, 2006). In most of the Central European
The justification for terming high to extreme levels of farm-
countries inaccessible parcels cannot be farmed by travelling across
land ownership fragmentation as a new type of LD is derived from
neighboring parcels. For the owner of an inaccessible parcel, this
the following arguments that reflect the main negative effects of
limits the possible tenants as the owner is forced to rent to the user
extreme fragmentation.
of a neighboring parcel. The lack of competition thus considerably
affects the rent to the owner’s disadvantage (Vranken and Swinnen,
3.1.1. Small parcels are not economically viable for individual 2006). Overall, the freedom of owners to farm their own land is thus
farming substantially limited, as are their options when they rent their land.
In the conditions of Central Europe, the mean size of a parcel eco- This form of land ownership insecurity, which is economic rather
nomically viable for individual farming is given as 1 ha (Sklenicka than legal, further manifests itself in the entirely dominant role
et al., 2014). Of course, this threshold is lower in more fertile areas played by the land rental market, which often brings with it neg-
and higher in less productive regions. Viable parcel size also differs ative effects (which are discussed within a third argument – see
according to economic level and other specifics of the given country below).
or region. Farming overly small parcels is excessively expensive for
farmers due to the increased proportion of unproductive passages
over the parcel (Gonzalez et al., 2004) and the effect of travelling
698 P. Sklenicka / Land Use Policy 57 (2016) 694–701

3.1.2. Land divided into overly small parcels has considerably poorer care of it than do owners, goes straight to the heart of the
lower value definition of LD. Insufficient tenure security results in diminished
Due to high ownership fragmentation, larger parcels are more motivation to invest in holdings, to increase the fertility of the soil,
sought after and have a price advantage. In 2008, buyers in the and also probably leads diminished motivation to invest in bio-
Czech Republic paid 44% more for 1 ha parcels than for average-size diversity protection, landscape renewal, and any potential water
parcels (0.4 ha), 2.2 times more for 2 ha parcels, and paid the most resource protection. As a result, this management type, which we
for 8 ha parcels (2.8 times more; Sklenicka et al., 2013). Still larger can characterize by a low degree of land tenure security, can be
parcels had slightly lower prices. Maddison (2000) confirmed a sim- considered unsustainable. Particularly in countries where a sub-
ilar trend in England and Wales except among the smallest parcels, stantial part of farmland is divided in this manner, a substantial
where higher prices led to relatively higher transaction costs. In proportion of land is threated by degradation. This is confirmed,
contrast to these results, Huang et al. (2006) found in Illinois that among other things, by the results of long-term farmland monitor-
farmland value decreases with parcel size. It is highly likely that the ing in the Czech Republic mentioned above, where about 80% of
difference among trends comes from the fact that in the conditions farmland is farmed by tenant-farmers (Research Institute for Soil
of Illinois very small parcels of the size in European conditions, such and Water Conservation, 2015; Eurostat, 2015).
as those of the Czech Republic, mostly did not exist and so were not A study in Czech conditions (Sklenicka et al., 2014) has demon-
on the market. The observed decrease in prices with parcel size is strated that very small parcels also display the phenomenon known
then consistent with the trend for larger parcels (i.e., those over as the “Farmland Rental Paradox.” This describes the tendency of
8 ha) determined by Sklenicka et al. (2013). Moreover, the contin- ever smaller parcels (under 1 ha) to create increasingly larger pro-
uing division of parcels frequently leads to a loss of direct access duction blocks due to more frequent renting. Large production
to land, which results in further decreases in the market price of blocks farmed by a single tenant and frequently comprising as many
the land. Sklenicka et al. (2013) determined for conditions of the as hundreds of parcels belonging to many owners often cover large
Czech Republic that prices of parcels with access to roads are on areas. Up to a level of several tens of hectares, such larger blocks
average 2.1 times higher than the prices for land without direct can bring economic benefits through lower expenses per unit area
access. These examples demonstrate that farmland is devalued sim- (Gonzalez et al., 2004). This scenario is typical for intensive rural
ply through the physical division of parcels, even when fertility and areas, while in marginal environments fragmentation usually leads
other relevant attributes influencing land value are held constant. to abandonment and related consequences.
Despite these benefits, however, overly large blocks hundreds
3.1.3. Land divided into overly small parcels is more frequently of hectares in area bring a number of problems by contribut-
rented and tenants take poorer care of it than do owners (Fraser, ing considerably to water and wind erosion (Jenny, 2012) and by
2004; Carolan, 2005) homogenizing the farmland, which leads to numerous problems of
Economically nonviable small parcels are essentially “sen- landscape and ecology (decreased spatial heterogeneity and land-
tenced” to be farmed through renting. A number of studies scape connectivity; Turner et al., 2001), water management (lower
presented below show this way to be far less sustainable, as ten- resistance to hydrological extremes – drought and torrential rain;
ants care less well for the land entrusted to them than do farming Qiu and Turner, 2015), and agronomy (consolidating land with var-
owners, in the same spirit as one does not wash a rented car. ious agronomic characteristics into a single block and unifying its
This fact depends strongly on the given country’s level of land farming; Sklenicka and Salek, 2008) with negative impacts also on
tenure security. According to land monitoring in the Czech Repub- the visual value of the landscape and on its potential for recreational
lic over more than 30 years, for example, parcels farmed by tenants uses (de Val et al., 2006).
considerably more frequently have diminished organic matter con- The scheme proposed in Fig. 1 depicts on one side high land
tent, increased compaction, evidence of effects from erosion, and ownership fragmentation as one of the underlying causes of tenure
overall decreased natural fertility (Research Institute for Soil and insecurity, and on the other side the LD types most frequently
Water Conservation, 2014). Regarding erosion control measures, affected by tenure insecurity. Other underlying causes depicted
Sklenicka et al. (2015) determined that over the previous 5 years include eight socioeconomic or demographic causes describing pri-
owners used wide-row crops in crop rotation Schemes 45% as fre- marily legal, administrative, cultural and ethical, community, and
quently as did tenants, while they used soil-improving crops 1.9 economic barriers to achieving tenure security. Of interest is the
times more frequently and contour farming 1.8 times more fre- inclusion of overall LD as one of the underlying causes of tenure
quently. In addition, the slope length in production blocks farmed insecurity. In principle, any LD type or combination of types may
by owners was on average 41% of the slope length in blocks farmed cause tenure insecurity. Degraded land discourages land owners
by tenants. A large number of other studies have confirmed that and tenants from making large investments in land/farms, partic-
insecure land tenure, caused mainly by short-term lease contracts, ularly on long- and medium-term scales.
does not contribute to soil conservation (e.g., Nowak and Korsching, Tenure insecurity as an intermediate cause most frequently
1983; Soule et al., 2000; Fraser, 2004). In cases of tenure insecu- leads to five LD types (Fig. 1): water erosion, wind erosion
rity, Jacoby et al. (2002) found substantially lower use of organic (Sklenicka et al., 2015), reduction of organic matter (Jacoby et al.,
fertilizers, which have long-lasting benefits for soil fertility. Other 2002), soil compaction, and nutrient leaching/depletion (Scherr,
studies from across the globe and various political, economic, and 2000). At the same time, all of these types relate to soil degra-
cultural systems have also confirmed the substantial positive effect dation. It is nevertheless highly likely that tenure insecurity can
of tenure security on farm and land improvements (e.g., Feder and also cause other LD types, in particular loss of vegetation cover,
Onchan, 1987; Gebremedhin and Swinton, 2003; Fenske, 2011), as decline in species diversity, alien plant invasion, and water table
well as on farm productivity (Feder, 1987; Abdulai et al., 2011). In drawdown, and others. Such speculations, however, are not yet
addition to this effect, Scherr (2000) also found an effect of tenure supported by sufficient high-quality research confirming them, nor
insecurity on soil compaction and nutrient depletion. are they customarily associated through tenure insecurity to the
While the first two arguments, Small parcels are not economi- farmland fragmentation classified here.
cally viable for individual farming, and Land divided into overly small
parcels has considerably lower value, create conditions for LD or are
accompanying negative effects, the third argument, Land divided
into overly small parcels is more frequently rented and tenants take
P. Sklenicka / Land Use Policy 57 (2016) 694–701 699

Fig. 1. High land ownership fragmentation as an underlying cause of tenure insecurity and the most frequently affected land degradation types.

3.2. Possible remedies concentrated through individual contracts based on the free will of
the seller and purchaser. High ownership fragmentation rates are
Ownership fragmentation is a dynamic process, the speed of very frequently caused by nonfunctional or weak selling markets.
which depends mainly on the factors mentioned above, in a given The end result is a feedback loop. National policy can also be help-
country. Corrective policies in countries with high fragmentation ful, for example by supporting land acquisition loans to farming
should focus on three different levels: identifying the causes of frag- entities (not speculators). This considerably strengthens the land
mentation (slowing the process), decreasing current fragmentation sale market. The second instrument is land consolidation, which
(defragmenting ownership), and remedying the effects. enables ownership to be concentrated through individual plans
and resultant changes in the land registry. The principle of land
3.2.1. Eliminating or mitigating the main causes of fragmentation consolidation is most frequently based on a change in the spatial
In this area, consideration is given primarily to legislative inter- distribution of individual dispersed parcels in order to join individ-
ventions into inheritance rights and interventions limiting the ual owners’ parcels into larger wholes. However, implementation
freedom of land transactions. However, both of these options are of land consolidation is problematic in heterogeneous areas where
very unpopular in liberal market economies. In most European each parcel has distinct features for topographic and microclimatic
countries, a complete change of inheritance rights from part- reasons. The amount of defragmentation achieved in this manner
ible inheritance to non-partible inheritance (e.g., primogeniture) varies across different countries and regions. In the Czech Repub-
is highly unlikely. Nevertheless, it is realistic to introduce cer- lic, the initial number of parcels (6.3 parcels per owner; mean size
tain features of a majority inheritance system into current law. 0.4 ha) could in this manner be decreased on average by one half
Consideration can be given to such interventions as establishing (Sklenicka et al., 2009). The most radical instrument for ownership
the minimum viable size of a single owner’s land holdings (farm) defragmentation is land reform. This method of changing owner-
and limiting the physical division of individual parcels. A possible ship rights is generally used, or enforced, only in exceptional cases
method would be to define a certain minimum sustainable parcel accompanying a change in the country’s political system and other
size for the natural and economic conditions of a country or region, politically or economically exceptional situations. The use of this
and to endeavor to protect the land by law from further fragmenta- instrument in countries with a liberal market system is unlikely.
tion. Similar partial limitations on inheritances and land sales can Its defragmenting effect can be very “aggressive” depending on the
already be found in the legal systems of some European countries. purpose and design of the rules of the reform itself.

3.2.2. Active defragmentation of land ownership 3.2.3. Remedying the effects of extreme fragmentation
There are essentially three strong instruments for defragmenta- The land rental market is a natural instrument in market
tion. The first is a land sale market that enables land holdings to be economies capable of reacting very quickly to problems with farm-
700 P. Sklenicka / Land Use Policy 57 (2016) 694–701

ing mall, economically nonviable parcels. The land rental market is Al-Awadhi, J.M., Omar, S.A., Misak, R.F., 2005. Land degradation indicators in
usually most highly developed in countries with poorly functioning Kuwait. Land Degrad. Dev. 16, 163–176.
Anantha Ram, K., Tsunekawa, A., Saha, D.K., Miyazaki, T., 1999. Subdivision and
land sale markets. The smaller the parcels are, the more intensive fragmentation of land holdings and their implication in desertification in the
and the easier is their rental. In Central and Eastern European coun- Thar Desert. India J. Arid Environ. 41, 463–477.
tries, the rental market began to work relatively well following the Bai, Z.G., Dent, D.L., Olsson, L., Schaepman, M.E., 2008. Proxy global assessment of
land degradation. Soil Use Manage. 24, 223–234.
transformation of planned economies into market economies after Barbier, E.B., 1997. The economic determinants of land degradation in developing
1990. In contrast, the land sale market has grown only gradually countries. Philos. Trans. R. Soc. B 352, 891–899.
in these countries and in some it is not sufficiently developed even Barrow, C.J., 1991. Land Degradation: Development and Breakdown of Terrestrial
Environments. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.
after a quarter of a century. The second effective instrument for
Blaikie, P., Brookfield, H., 1987. Land Degradation and Society. Methuen, London.
remedying effects consists in farm subsidies. If designed properly, Carolan, M.S., 2005. Barriers to the adoption of sustainable agriculture on rented
these subsidies can encourage responsible and sustainable land use land: an examination of contesting social fields. Rural Sociol. 70, 387–413.
Ciaian, P., 2008. Land, EU Accession and Market Imperfections. PhD Thesis.
among owners and tenants. An example can be seen in direct Euro-
Katholieke Universiteit Leuven.
pean subsidies to farming entities with payment conditioned on Clerc, J., 2012. Unpacking Tenure Security: Development of a Conceptual
meeting standards for good agricultural and environmental con- Framework and Application to the Case of Oil Palm Expansion on Customary
ditions which focus in particular on erosion control, groundwater Land in Kapuas Hulu District, West Kalimantan, Indonesia. Working Paper No.
102. Center for International Forestry Research (CIFOR), Bogor, Indonesia.
management, and increasing soil organic matter (Sklenicka et al., Eurostat, 2015. http://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/web/agriculture/data/.
2015). A supportive policy option for reducing fragmentation is Feder, G., Onchan, T., 1987. Land ownership security and farm investment in
when priority for renting and buying is accorded to neighbours Thailand. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 69, 311–320.
Feder, G., 1987. Land ownership security and farm productivity: evidence from
(option). This type of policy exists in some European countries. Thailand. J. Dev. Stud. 24, 16–30.
All three remedial approaches may include the very useful addi- Fenske, J., 2011. Land tenure and investment incentives: evidence from West
tional instrument of raising awareness and educating land owners Africa. J. Dev. Econ. 95, 137–156.
Fraser, E.D., 2004. Land tenure and agricultural management: soil conservation on
and tenants. Information on soil degradation by fragmentation, rented and owned fields in southwest British Columbia. Agric. Hum. Values
and on possible remedies, may lead to higher voluntary engage- 211, 73–79.
ment in slowing fragmentation, defragmentation, and remedying Gebremedhin, B., Swinton, S.M., 2003. Investment in soil conservation in northern
Ethiopia: the role of land tenure security and public programs. Agric. Econ. 29,
the effects of fragmentation.
69–84.
Gonzalez, X.P., Alvarez, C.J., Crecente, R., 2004. Evaluation of land distributions
with joint regard to plot size and shape. Agric. Syst. 82, 31–43.
4. Conclusions
Huang, H., Miller, G.Y., Sherrick, B.J., Gomez, M.I., 2006. Factors influencing Illinois
farmland values. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 88, 458–470.
Despite the relatively complicated causal relationship affect- Huber-Sannwald, E., Maestre, F.T., Herrick, J.E., Reynolds, J.F., 2006.
ing LD processes, this study has substantiated the argument that Ecohydrological feedbacks and linkages associated with land degradation: a
case study from Mexico. Hydrol. Process. 20, 3395–3411.
high farmland ownership fragmentation is an underlying cause Irwin, E.G., Bockstael, N.E., 2007. The evolution of urban sprawl: evidence of spatial
affecting tenure insecurity as an immediate cause for various types heterogeneity and increasing land fragmentation. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. U. S. A.
of LD. It is therefore necessary to focus attention and necessary 104, 20672–20677.
Jacoby, H.G., Li, G., Rozelle, S., 2002. Hazards of expropriation: tenure insecurity
resources on prevention and against existing fragmentation. To this and investment in rural China. Am. Econ. Rev. 92, 1420–1447.
end, countries and regions with currently high rates of land owner- Jenny, H., 2012. The Soil Resource: Origin and Behavior. Springer, New York.
ship fragmentation should act immediately on several levels. They Johnson, D.L., Lewis, L.A., 2007. Land Degradation: Creation and Destruction.
Rowman & Littlefield, Lanham.
must eliminate or at least mitigate causes the accelerate the frag- Kopeva, D., Noev, N., 2001. Aspects of land consolidation after the Bulgarian land
mentation process, defragment current land ownership, and also reform. In: Proceedings of International Workshop the New Structure of the
remedy the consequences of this process. Even countries that have Rural Economy of Post-Communist Countries, October 26–30th, Lomnice nad
Luznici, Czech Republic, pp. 123–159.
not until now had high rates of fragmentation are threatened, as Lomborg, B., 2001. The Sceptical Environmentalist: Measuring the Real State of the
the trend of the fragmentation process indicates that a problem- World. Cambridge University, Cambridge.
atic level may be reached in the foreseeable future. In such cases, Lu, D., Batistella, M., Mausel, P., Moran, E., 2007. Mapping and monitoring land
degradation risks in the Western Brazilian Amazon using multitemporal
efforts must be directed primarily at slowing the process.
Landsat TM/ETM+ images. Land Degrad. Dev. 18, 41–54.
Land ownership fragmentation also leads to loss of the sense of Maddison, D., 2000. A hedonic analysis of agricultural land prices in England and
responsibility for the condition of the land and landscape. Extreme Wales. Eur. Rev. Agric. Econ. 27, 519–532.
farmland ownership fragmentation can be identified as a major Meadows, M.E., Hoffman, M.T., 2002. The nature, extent and causes of land
degradation in South Africa: legacy of the past, lessons for the future? Area 34,
cause of unsustainable land use. In addition, land ownership frag- 428–437.
mentation in combination with excessive concentration of land use Nachtergaele, F., Biancalani, R., Petri, M., 2011. Land Degradation: SOLAW
into a small number of large agricultural holdings can lead to the Background Thematic Report 3. Food and Agriculture Organization of the
United Nations, Rome.
disruption and even total destruction of traditional social structures Nkonya, E., Gerber, N., von Braun, J., De Pinto, A., 2011. Economics of Land
and relationships in the countryside. Degradation, 68. IFPRI Issue Brief, Washington, DC.
Noev, N., Swinnen, J., Vranken, L., 2003. The Development of Land Rental Markets in
Bulgaria and the Former Yugoslav Republic of Macedonia. FAO, Working Paper.
Acknowledgements Norbu, C., Baillie, I., Dema, K., Jamyang, Y., Dema, Y., Tshering, K., Tamang, H.,
Turkelboom, F., 2003. Types of land degradation in Bhutan. J. Bhutan Stud. 8,
88–114.
This contribution was written on the basis of than 15 years Nowak, P.J., Korsching, P.F., 1983. Social and institutional factors affecting the
of research into the causes and effects of farmland ownership adoption and maintenance of agricultural BMPs. In: Schaller, F.W., Bailey, G.W.
fragmentation, which has been supported in phases by National (Eds.), Agricultural Management and Water Quality. Iowa State University
Press, Ames Iowa, pp. 349–373.
Agency for Agricultural Research grant No. QH8D, by Czech Sci-
Oldeman, L.R., 1994. The Global Extent of Soil Degradation. ISRIC Bi-Annual Report
ence Foundation grant No. GA14-09212S, and by EEA grant No. 1991–1992. ISRIC, Wageningen.
EHP-CZ02-OV-1-027-2015. Omuto, C.T., Balint, Z., Alim, M.S., 2014. A framework for national assessment of
land degradation in the drylands: a case study of Somalia. Land Degrad. Dev.
25, 105–119.
References Qiu, J., Turner, M.G., 2015. Importance of landscape heterogeneity in sustaining
hydrologic ecosystem services in an agricultural watershed. Ecosphere 6, 1–19.
Abdulai, A., Owusu, V., Goetz, R., 2011. Land tenure differences and investment in Research Institute for Soil and Water Conservation, 2014. Monitoring of Soil
land improvement measures: theoretical and empirical analyses. J. Dev. Econ. Quality in the Czech Republic Between 1984 and 2014. Project Report. VUMOP,
96, 66–78. Prague.
P. Sklenicka / Land Use Policy 57 (2016) 694–701 701

Sabates-Wheeler, R., 2005. Cooperation in the Romanian Countryside: an Insight Stocking, M., Murnaghan, N., 2001. Handbook for the Field Assessment of Land
into Post-Soviet Agriculture. Lexington Books, USA. Degradation. Earthscan, London.
Sarukhán, J., Whyte, A., Hassan, R., Scholes, R., Ash, N., Carpenter, S.T., Leemans, R., Tan, S., Heerink, N., Qu, F., 2006. Land fragmentation and its driving forces in China.
2005. Millenium Ecosystem Assessment: Ecosystems and Human Well-Being. Land Use Policy 23, 272–285.
Island Press, Washington, D.C. Tefera, B., Ayele, G., Atnafe, Y., Jabbar, M.A., Dubale, P., 2002. Nature and Causes of
Scherr, S.J., Yadav, S., 1996. Land Degradation in the Developing World: Land Degradation in the Oromiya Region: A Review. Socio-economic and
Implications for Food, Agriculture, and the Environment to 2020. Food, Policy Research. Working Paper No. 36. International Livestock Research
Agriculture, and the Environment Discussion Paper 14. International Food Institute (ILRI), Nairobi, Kenya, pp. 18–35.
Policy Research Institute, Washington, DC, USA. Turner, M., Gardner, R., O’Neill, R., 2001. Landscape Ecology in Theory and Practice.
Scherr, S.J., 2000. A downward spiral? Research evidence on the relationship Springer-Verlag, New York, New York, USA.
between poverty and natural resource degradation. Food Policy 25, 479–498. Van Dijk, T., 2003. Scenarios of Central European land fragmentation. Land Use
Sklenicka, P., Salek, M., 2008. Ownership and soil quality as sources of agricultural Policy 20, 149–158.
land fragmentation in highly fragmented ownership patterns. Landscape Ecol. Vranken, L., Swinnen, J., 2006. Land rental markets in transition: theory and
23, 299–311. evidence from Hungary. World Dev. 34, 481–500.
Sklenicka, P., Hladik, J., Strelecek, F., Kottova, B., Lososova, J., Cihal, L., Salek, M., Warren, A., 2002. Land degradation is contextual. Land Degrad. Dev. 13, 449–459.
2009. Historical, environmental and socio-economic driving forces on land Wiebe, K.D., 2003. Land Quality, Agricultural Productivity, and Food Security:
ownership fragmentation, the land consolidation effect and project costs. Biophysical Processes and Economic Choices at Local, Regional, and Global
Agric. Econ. Czech 55, 571–582. Levels. Edward Elgar Publishing, Northampton.
Sklenicka, P., Molnarova, K., Pixova, K.C., Salek, M.E., 2013. Factors affecting Wilbanks, T.J., Kates, R.W., 1999. Global change in local places: how scale matters.
farmland prices in the Czech Republic. Land Use Policy 30, 130–136. Clim. Change 43, 601–628.
Sklenicka, P., Janovska, V., Salek, M., Vlasak, J., Molnarova, K., 2014. The Farmland Zuquette, L.V., Pejon, O.J., dos Santos Collares, J.Q., 2004. Land degradation
Rental Paradox: extreme land ownership fragmentation as a new form of land assessment based on environmental geoindicators in the Fortaleza
degradation. Land Use Policy 38, 587–593. metropolitan region, state of Ceará, Brazil. Environ. Geol. 45, 408–425.
Sklenicka, P., Molnarova, K.J., Salek, M., Simova, P., Vlasak, J., Sekac, P., Janovska, V., de Val, G.D.L.F., Atauri, J.A., de Lucio, J.V., 2006. Relationship between landscape
2015. Owner or tenant: who adopts better soil conservation practices? Land visual attributes and spatial pattern indices: a test study in
Use Policy 47, 253–261. Mediterranean-climate landscapes. Landscape Urban Plan 77, 393–407.
Sklenicka, P., 2006. Applying evaluation criteria for the land consolidation effect to
three contrasting study areas in the Czech Republic. Land Use Policy 23,
502–510.
Soule, M.J., Tegene, A., Wiebe, K.D., 2000. Land tenure and the adoption of
conservation practices. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 82, 993–1005.

You might also like