Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 11

International Journal of Hospitality Management 31 (2012) 218–228

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

International Journal of Hospitality Management


journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/ijhosman

Effect of diversification on firm performance: Application of the entropy measure


Kwangmin Park a,1 , SooCheong (Shawn) Jang b,∗
a
Department of Foodservice Management, College of Hospitality and Tourism Management, Sejong University, Seoul, South Korea
b
School of Hospitality and Tourism Management, Purdue University, West Lafayette, IN 47907-0327, United States

a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t

Keywords: This study investigated the effects of diversification on firm performance in the restaurant industry. In
Diversification strategy prior studies, the theoretical rationales and empirical results appeared to contradict each other. These
Profitability contradictory results may be due to factors such as industry-specific characteristics or a linear under-
Volatility
standing of the relationship between diversification strategies and firm performance. Thus, this study
Entropy measure
suggested a non-linear hypothesis based on the costs and benefits of diversification strategies with busi-
Restaurant firms
nesses categorized based on their level of diversification. The results of this study showed that restaurant
firms do not benefit from a low level of related diversification. This study also found that when restaurant
firms are involved in both related and unrelated businesses, the optimal mixed ratio of diversification
is approximately half and half. More detailed results, as well as academic and practical implications, are
discussed in this paper.
© 2011 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

1. Introduction pointed out that prior researchers have overlooked industry struc-
ture (e.g., industry competition, concentration, growth rate, and
Corporate diversification strategies establish the scope of a profitability). This suggests that the performance of diversifica-
firm’s business activities and contribute to a firm’s performance tion strategies depends on the performance of the target industry.
(Hofer and Schendel, 1978; Porter, 1987). Since Rumelt (1974, Thus, when the primary and diversifying target industry character-
1982), the relationship between diversification and performance istics are neglected, the projected performance of a diversification
(hereafter, DP) has frequently been investigated by strategic man- strategy could be misleading. Further, although there are benefits
agement researchers. Despite improvements in various aspects of to diversification there are also costs associated with diversifica-
DP studies, the theoretical rationales and empirical results remain tion, such as transaction costs (Jones and Hill, 1988) and a loss of
contradictory and the actual effects of diversification strategies efficiency and control (Markides, 1992; Rajan et al., 2000; Meyer
remain ambiguous at best. In the realm of hospitality academia et al., 1992). Thus, a non-linear relationship may exist between
several researchers have initialized diversification studies (Lee and diversification and firm performance. Finally, few studies have
Jang, 2007; Jang and Tang, 2009; Tang and Jang, 2010). However, investigated the optimal mixed ratio of related and unrelated diver-
they focused on either within-industry diversification or geograph- sification when firms are involved in both related and unrelated
ical diversification. Little research has been done within hospitality businesses.
academia on the effects of market diversification. Thus, this study Consequently, the purpose of this study is to examine the
examined the relationship between diversification and firm per- non-linear relationship between diversification strategy and firm
formance from the perspective of market diversification in the performance in the restaurant industry. Specifically, the objec-
restaurant industry. tives of this study are: (1) to examine the effects of diversification
Rumelt’s (1974, 1982) proposition that related diversification on accounting profitability and risk (volatility) of profitability
produces greater profits than unrelated diversification has gener- according to related and unrelated diversification in the restaurant
ally been accepted. It is also generally accepted that both related industry and (2) to investigate the optimal mixed ratio of related
and unrelated diversifications reduce profit volatility, with a larger and unrelated diversification.
risk reduction effect accompanying unrelated diversification. How-
ever, empirical studies have failed to validate these traditional 2. Literature review
conceptions of profitability and risk (volatility). Datta et al. (1991)
2.1. The definition of diversification and DP studies in hospitality
academia
∗ Corresponding author. Tel.: +1 765 496 3610.
E-mail addresses: kmpark@sejong.ac.kr (K. Park), jang12@purdue.edu (S. Jang). Corporate diversification can be defined as businesses a corpo-
1
Tel.: +82 02 3408 3186. ration should be involved in (Pils, 2009) and describes the scope

0278-4319/$ – see front matter © 2011 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.ijhm.2011.03.011
K. Park, S. Jang / International Journal of Hospitality Management 31 (2012) 218–228 219

of business activities (Hofer and Schendel, 1978; Porter, 1987). that are difficult for single business firms to achieve. Thus, prof-
However, various definitions of diversification have been used in itability can be enhanced by unrelated diversification strategies
previous studies. For instance, Ansoff (1957) first used the term (Scharfstein and Stein, 2000). Defenders of unrelated diversification
‘diversification’ to illustrate corporate growth strategies involving contend that firms utilizing related diversification have investment
entering new markets with a new product. On the other hand, options that are very similar to their current situation, but firms
Berry (1971) defined diversification as an increase in the number of utilizing unrelated diversification have a variety of investment
industries a business participates in. The term ‘market diversifica- options. Thus, unrelated diversification could be more profitable
tion’ is more specific because diversification could also be carried than related diversification because unrelated diversified firms are
out by entering new markets with present products or services in a better position to reduce the cost of capital and optimally invest
(Ansoff, 1957; Berry, 1971). Thus, diversification implies a firm (Hill and Snell, 1988).
moving into a number of markets (sectors, industries, or segments) Since Rumelt (1974, 1982), however, many empirical studies
it was not previously engaged in. Hereafter in this study the term have claimed that related diversification enhances profits more
diversification indicates market diversification. than unrelated diversification (Bettis, 1981; Lecraw, 1984; Lubatkin
The DP relationship has been frequently investigated in strate- and Rogers, 1989; Palepu, 1985). Bettis (1981) found that related
gic management but there has been little effort within hospitality diversification outperforms unrelated diversification by approxi-
academia to explore it. Singh and Gu (1994) failed to find any mately one to three points of return on assets. Along the same
differences in the operational performance of diversified hotel line, Palepu (1985) reported that profitability growth is signifi-
firms and undiversified firms. However, Lee and Jang (2007) cantly larger with related diversification as opposed to unrelated
found that within-industry diversification by hotel firms (diver- diversification. Lubatkin and Rogers (1989) also stated that related
sification into luxury, upscale, mid-priced, economy, or budget diversification has a tendency to produce better market returns
segments) improved the stability of their financial performance but than unrelated diversification. Nevertheless, Bass et al. (1977),
not accounting profits. Jang and Tang (2009) found that interna- Chatterjee (1986), Grinyer et al. (1980), and Ravenscraft (1983)
tional diversification has a moderating effect on the relationship could not find any evidence that related diversification offers more
between financial leverage and profitability in the hotel industry advantages than unrelated diversification. Consequently, the profit
and Tang and Jang (2010) stated that firm value discounts exist in superiority of related diversification is contradictory in terms of
association with international diversification. However, they also both its theoretical rationale and the empirical findings.
indicated that the relationship between international diversifica-
tion and excess value is curvilinear (U-shaped), suggesting that 2.3. Related diversification vs. unrelated diversification and risk
highly diversified hotel firms could still benefit from international (volatility) of profitability
diversification. However, the focus of Jang and Tang’s (2009) and
Tang and Jang’s (2010) studies was on geographic diversification, The impact of diversification strategies on risk is also contra-
not on market diversification. Thus far, prior hospitality research dictory. Researchers have generally accepted that diversification
has focused on only geographic diversification or within-industry reduces risk based on the portfolio theory (Markowitz, 1952).
(operation) diversification. Similarly, there are only a few studies Montgomery (1985) argued that managers consider diversifica-
that have investigated the diversification strategies of tourism- tion strategies in order to avoid unfavorable uncertainties within
related companies. Liu and Wang (2007) and Wang and Xu (2008) a single market. Regarding the DP relationship, Rumelt (1974)
found that diversification strategies recently enhanced in Chinese claimed that diversification could be understood as an aggregation
tourism companies. Based on this review of past diversification of two or more income streams. Thus, negatively correlated income
studies, there is still a need to examine the relationship between streams could produce a smaller variance as compared to a single
market diversification and firm performance in the hospitality and income stream. Of course a perfect negative correlation is rare in
tourism industry. the real world, but if two income streams are weakly correlated
the volatility of the combined income stream can be reduced. Thus,
2.2. Related diversification vs. unrelated diversification and in comparison to related diversification, unrelated diversification
profitability reduces volatility because the aggregated income stream of unre-
lated diversification tends to be more weakly related to the primary
Theoretical arguments on the profitability of related and unre- market.
lated diversification are contradictory. On the one hand, Rumelt However, as West (1967) argued, corporate diversification can-
(1974, 1982) argued that related diversification produces superior not produce the same outcomes as financial diversification. In
profits as opposed to unrelated diversification, which suggests that financial diversification, an asset portfolio is composed of various
related diversification allows for a larger transfer of core tangible investment options: securities in the stock market, real estate, and
and intangible capabilities (i.e., product lines, knowledge, skills, and other financial options. These assets can be bought and sold by port-
experience) into the diversifying target business (Penrose, 1959; folio owners and adding or substituting an asset does not affect
Rumelt, 1974). This rationale is based on economies of scope and the return and risk of the remaining individual assets. Thus, the
scale and the synergy hypothesis. From this perspective, unre- volatility of a portfolio can constantly be reduced by adding new
lated diversification requires certain substantial costs derived from investment options. However, in corporate diversification any busi-
new and unfamiliar business environments, which could adversely ness in the business portfolio influences the remaining individual
reduce profits. business segments as well as the overall corporate structure and
On the other hand, the internal market efficiency hypothe- efficiency (Bettis and Hall, 1982; Lubatkin and O’Neill, 1987). This
sis favors unrelated diversification. The internal market efficiency means that risk reduction based on the portfolio theory could dif-
hypothesis (Higgins and Schall, 1975; Lewellen, 1971; Scherer, fer between financial diversification and corporate diversification.
1980) argues that diversified firms can allocate their capital This implies that the consequences of corporate diversification per-
resources more efficiently than undiversified firms by optimally formance may not be a linear function (Lubatkin and Chatterjee,
using internal capital. Accordingly, these internal market efficien- 1994).
cies allow diversified firms to access relatively inexpensive external A number of studies have investigated the relationship between
funds and transfer capital between businesses within its portfolio diversification and risk. Amit and Livnat (1988) found that unre-
(Meyer et al., 1992). Diversification is a source of varied efficiencies lated diversification lowers risk. However, Barton (1988), Bettis
220 K. Park, S. Jang / International Journal of Hospitality Management 31 (2012) 218–228

(1981), Bettis and Hall (1982), and Montgomery and Singh each separate related and unrelated diversification. Likewise, Palich
(1984) found that unrelated diversification increases risk. Fur- et al.’s (2000) limited studies investigated the non-linear DP rela-
ther, Lubatkin and O’Neill (1987) found that related diversification tionship at the level of total diversification. Grant et al. (1988),
reduces risk while unrelated diversification increases risk. Conse- Tallman and Li (1996), Nachum (2004) and Narasimhan and Kim
quently, the actual risk reduction effect of various diversification (2002) found that profits increase up to a certain point of total diver-
strategies is theoretically and practically ambiguous. sification but decrease beyond that point. Moreover, Palich et al.’s
(2000) hypothesis assumed that firms first diversify into related
2.4. Industry-specific effects on performance businesses and then later move into unrelated businesses. How-
ever, this assumption does not always hold for diversified firms.
Christensen and Montgomery (1981) argued that differences in Another limitation of Palich et al. (2000) is the ambiguous con-
diversification performance are due to market structure. Datta et al. ceptual separation of the diversification level into moderate and
(1991) also pointed out that diversification studies have shown high levels of diversification. To clarify performance differences
little interest in industry-specific factors, such as industry concen- according to the level of diversification, businesses must be clearly
tration, growth, and profitability. Schmalensee (1985) suggested separated into low and high levels of diversification. Thus, when
that industry-specific effects could be even more important than we hypothesized diversification performance we separated diver-
firm-specific effects in terms of the performance of diversification sification into low and high levels for both related and unrelated
strategies. For example, Bass et al. (1977) found that diversification diversification in order to examine the costs and benefits of diver-
strategies had a positive effect in slow-growth industries but a neg- sification according to the level (low or high) and type (related or
ative effect in high-growth industries. Bettis and Hall (1982) also unrelated) of diversification.
concluded that in terms of profits and risk there are no differences At a low level of related diversification, profitability might
between related and unrelated diversification once industry factors decrease because the costs of related diversification (i.e., low prof-
are incorporated. Thus, when the primary industry-specific effects itability of the related businesses) can dominate the benefits of
are neglected, as well as the diversifying target industry-specific related diversification (i.e., economies of scale and scope and syn-
effects, the predicted performance of a diversification strategy ergy between businesses). On the other hand, profits might increase
could be misleading. with a high level of related diversification because the benefits of
It is well known that the restaurant industry has low profitability related diversification could dominate due to economies of scale
and high risk (Kim and Gu, 2003; Skalpe, 2003). In terms of related and scope and synergy. Thus, profitability decreases up to a cer-
businesses, restaurant firms frequently diversify into the franchis- tain level of related diversification but increases beyond that level,
ing segment. The performance of this segment would be the same which might be described as a U-shaped curve. In the relationship
as the primary business. Further, the food-production industry, between unrelated diversification and profitability, lower levels of
another frequently diversified segment, is a big challenge because unrelated diversification could increase profitability because unre-
it relies on high volume, low profits, and slow growth in sales lated businesses might create more profits, relatively, than the
(MacGregor and Sever, 1996). The situation of related segments primary business. However, at a high level of unrelated diversi-
in the restaurant industry is not very different from that of the fication profitability might decrease as firms stray further away
primary industry. Consequently, if restaurant firms diversify into from the primary business. In other words, high levels of unrelated
related segments it is unlikely they will achieve profit enhancement diversification can lead to a loss of control and lack of managerial
due to the low profitability of the related businesses. In addition, capacity. Markides (1992) and Nachum (2004) argued that man-
in terms of risk of profitability the income streams of related busi- agers have a limited capacity to cope with increased complexity,
nesses might be highly correlated with the primary business. Even loss of control, and increased inflexibility. It can also be difficult to
though the portfolio theory (Markowitz, 1952) predicts moderate transfer a firm’s competitive advantages across markets and prod-
risk reduction from related diversification, the risk could actually ucts. Further, inefficiencies may arise if there are problems adapting
increase because the aggregated income streams should behave to environmental differences.
similarly.
In contrast, unrelated diversification of restaurant firms could Hypothesis 1. Profitability decreases up to a certain level of
enhance profitability if the unrelated businesses are relatively related diversification, but beyond that level it increases as related
profitable compared to the primary business. This means that diversification increases.
diversification into a relatively profitable target industry could con- Hypothesis 2. Profitability increases up to a certain level of unre-
tribute to profit enhancement. Further, unrelated diversification lated diversification, but beyond that level it decreases as unrelated
of restaurant firms could reduce risk considerably if the income diversification increases.
streams of the primary business and the unrelated business are
weakly (or perhaps even negatively) correlated. Consequently, the In spite of encouragement by Palich et al. (2000), scholars have
overall expectations for restaurant diversification could differ from presently made no attempt to investigate the non-linear relation-
the traditional rationale when restaurant industry-specific charac- ship between diversification and the risk (volatility) of profitability.
teristics are incorporated. The conventional hypothesis follows portfolio theory (Markowitz,
1952) and expects consistent risk reduction with both related and
2.5. Non-linear hypothesis regarding the DP relationship unrelated diversification. However, low levels of related diversifi-
cation could increase risk because the similar risk characteristics
Palich et al. (2000) proposed a non-linear hypothesis that related of the highly correlated income streams would likely overpower
diversification (i.e., a moderate level of diversification) increases the effects of risk reduction. On the other hand, at high levels of
firm performance but unrelated diversification (i.e., a high level of related diversification profit volatility would decrease because the
diversification) decreases it. However, Palich et al. (2000) proposed risk reduction effects of portfolio theory (Markowitz, 1952) might
a simple synthesis of Rumelt’s (1974, 1982) propositions regarding dominate the synthetic related business risk. Consequently, profit
the total level of diversification: (1) related diversification posi- volatility increases up to a certain level of related diversification but
tively effects firm performance and (2) unrelated diversification decreases beyond that level. Risk decreases up to a certain level of
negatively effects firm performance. Thus, in Palich et al. (2000) unrelated diversification due to the weak (or even negative) cor-
there is no consideration of the non-linear relationship between relation of income streams as stated in the portfolio theory, but it
K. Park, S. Jang / International Journal of Hospitality Management 31 (2012) 218–228 221

increases beyond that level due to business risk and a loss of control firms were diversified. The Compustat Segment Database provides
and flexibility. annual sales of each business segment based on the four-digit SIC
(Standard Industrial Classification). Performance data, such as prof-
Hypothesis 3. Profitability risk increases up to a certain level of
itability and risk (volatility) of profitability, were collected from
related diversification, but beyond that level it decreases as related
Compustat Fundamental Annual Database and merged with the
diversification increases.
Compustat Segment data. If the sales generated from the primary
Hypothesis 4. Profitability risk decreases up to a certain level segment (SICs 5812) were less than 50% the observation was elim-
of unrelated diversification, but beyond that level it increases as inated.
unrelated diversification increases.

Finally, when considering diversification strategies it is impor- 3.2. Dependent variables


tant to note that firms can utilize related and unrelated
diversification simultaneously. Thus, finding the optimal mixed The major interest of this study was to investigate the effects of
level of related and unrelated diversification is crucial. Nev- diversification strategy on firm performance using profitability and
ertheless, no prior studies have examined the optimal mixed risk (volatility) of profitability as major performance variables. For
level of related and unrelated diversification. Based on our prior robust results we incorporated two variables for profitability and
hypotheses, the influence of related and unrelated diversification risk respectively. As profitability measurements, we used adjusted
is completely opposite. In order to counterbalance the positive and return on assets (ROA) and return on sales (ROS). These variables
negative effects of related and unrelated diversification, the optimal (ROA and ROS) are ratios that include positive and negative values.
mixed level would be approximately half and half between related To examine risk (volatility) of profitability, we used the three-year
and unrelated diversification. Consequently, it is expected that variance of adjusted ROA and ROS. The adjusted ROA was calculated
profitability might be maximized and profitability risk (volatility) as the ratio of net income plus total interest paid on the total assets
minimized when related and unrelated diversification are mixed in at the beginning of the year. Likewise, adjusted ROS was measured
the same proportions. as the ratio of the sum of net income and total interest paid on net
sales for the year.
Hypothesis 5. Profitability is maximized when related and Prior studies used the conventional variance calculation method
unrelated diversifications are mixed in approximately the same to measure the variance of profitability. The conventional mea-
proportions. sure uses the average of the previous three years to calculate
variance. However, this assumes that profitability is stationary,
Hypothesis 6. Profitability risk is minimized when related and
which implies that profitability remains approximately the same
unrelated diversifications are mixed in approximately the same
for several years. However, Mueller (1977, 1986) found that
proportions.
profit increases up to a certain level, which means that profit is
non-stationary. To overcome this limitation, we incorporated the
2.6. Endogenous relationship between diversification and
predicted value from a simple AR(3) regression using a series of
performance
adjusted ROA and ROS. For example, profitability at time t is the
dependent variable, while profitability at times t-3 to t-1 were used
A handful of prior studies have examined the endogenous
as independent variables. Then, we used the predicted value from
relationship between diversification and firm performance. This
the AR(3) model as the expected value, instead of the prior three-
means that diversification could affect firm performance, but firm
year average, to calculate the variance. However, the variance had a
performance might also influence diversification. Lang and Stulz
unique distribution characteristic, which was censored because the
(1994), Hyland and Diltz (2002), and Graham et al. (2002) inves-
variance did not allow for negative values. Consequently, we ulti-
tigated the endogenous relationship between diversification and
mately used the logarithmically transformed three-year variance
firm performance. Those studies investigated whether low perfor-
as the risk (volatility) of profitability (adjusted ROA and ROS).
mance motivates corporate diversification. Rijamampianina et al.
(2003) listed a firm’s motivations to diversify as follows: (1) stock
value enhancement, (2) firm (or sales) growth, (3) internal mar- 3.3. Independent variables
ket efficiency, (4) stability of income stream, and (5) profitability
enhancement. This suggests that low performance could influ- The independent variable in this study is the diversification
ence diversification decisions, as well as the level of diversification. measure. Thus, this study incorporated the entropy measurement.
Because diversification could also be perceived as an investment Initially, Boltzmann (1896) invented entropy to measure disor-
behavior, firms with enough managerial and financial capacity der, chaos, and uncertainty of a state in physics. The entropy
could easily diversify into other industries. Consequently, firm per- measure spread into science and engineering, but usage and def-
formance could be a determinant of the decision to diversify and at initions differ slightly in each research field. Jacquemin and Berry
what level to do so. Thus, this study expects an endogenous rela- (1979) introduced the entropy measure into diversification studies
tionship between diversification and firm performance. Due to the because it has several benefits. In comparison with prior measures
biased results from OLS (Ordinary Least Square) regression, we con- (e.g., Wrigley/Rumelt measurement), the entropy measure is objec-
trolled the endogeneity issue in this study using the instrumental tive, continuous, and decomposable. Decomposability means that
variable regression method. total diversification entropy could be broken down into related and
unrelated diversification entropy. The calculation method for the
3. Methodology entropy measure is as follows:


n 1
3.1. Data DT = Pi × ln
Pi
i=1
This study used diversification data on the U.S. restaurant indus-
try from 1980 to 2008 retrieved from the Compustat Segment where Pi = the ratio of the firm’s total sales within the ith industry
Database (Primary SIC is 5812). The sample included a total of 308 segment; n = the number of industry segments in which the firm
companies and 2829 observations. Of the 308 restaurant firms, 77 participates.
222 K. Park, S. Jang / International Journal of Hospitality Management 31 (2012) 218–228

DT represents total diversification entropy; Pi is the share of 3.5. Control and instrumental variables
the ith business within the firm; and n is the number of business
segments identified by the four-digit SIC code. Thus, a larger DT Following prior studies, we included a number of control vari-
means a higher degree of overall diversification at the firm level. ables in the model. Firm size is critical to our analysis because the
dependent variables are divided by firm size. Thus, to control for

M
the size effect on the dependent variables we used logarithmically
DR = DRj × Pj
transformed total assets and sales and their squared logarithmically
j=1 transformed variables. We also incorporated financial and oper-
where DRj = diversification within industry groups; M = number of ating leverage. In prior studies, debt leverage positively affected
industry groups (n ≥ M); and Pj = the ratio of the firm’s total sales profitability in Hurdle (1974), but negatively affected it in Hall and
within the jth industry group. Weiss (1967) and Gale (1972). However, highly leveraged firms
DR represents related diversification entropy; DRj is the related can reduce wasteful investments and increase firm performance
diversification arising from operating in several businesses within through managerial discipline (Jensen, 1986; Stulz, 1990). To con-
an industry group j; and Pj is the share of the segment jth group’s trol for the financial leverage effect, we used the logarithmically
sales out of the total sales of the firm. Thus, a lager DR means that transformed ratio of total debt to total assets. Ito (1997) found that
a firm is highly diversified into related businesses. a fixed-asset ratio had a positive effect on profitability. A higher
fixed-asset ratio means that more physical assets are needed to

M  
1 produce products and services, which implies that firms with a
DU = Pj × ln higher fixed-asset ratio have a larger market share. Most diversi-
Pj
j=1 fied restaurant firms had food manufacturing and equipment lines.
Many had even invested in real estate in order to diversify into
where M = the number of industry groups; Pj = the ratio of the firm’s
hotel/motel industries. Considering the purpose of this study, it
total sales within the jth industry group.
is necessary to examine this factor in the relationship between
DU implies unrelated diversification entropy; Pj is the share of
diversification and firm performance. Thus, to control for operating
the jth industry group’s sales out of the total sales of the firm; and M
leverage the logarithmically transformed ratio of property, plant
is the number of industry groups (Palepu, 1985). Likewise, a larger
and equipment to total assets and the ratio of depreciation to total
DU means that a firm is highly diversified into unrelated businesses.
assets were included.
According to the free cash flow hypothesis (Jensen, 1986), exces-
DT = DR + DU sive free cash flows allow managers to pursue personal goals
regardless of firm value. Although cash flow has a positive effect on
Finally, total diversification entropy is the sum of related and firm performance because it can be used for profitable investment,
unrelated diversification entropy. This is the decomposability of Brush et al. (2000) found that free cash flow can have a negative
the entropy measurement. As indicated earlier, to examine the influence on firm performance due to unprofitable investments.
non-linear relationship between diversification and performance Thus, we incorporated cash flow, a dummy of Tobin’s Q, and free
we incorporated the square terms of the entropy measures: DR2 cash flow in the model. Also, we followed Himmelberg et al. (1999)
(square term of DR) and DU2 (square term of DU). method to calculate Tobin’s Q. Similar to Brush et al. (2000), if
Finally, the last diversification measurement is the ratio of Tobin’s Q is less than one the firm has free cash flows, but if Tobin’s Q
unrelated entropy to total entropy (RUTE). When firms are simul- is larger than one there are no free cash flows. Additionally, because
taneously considering both related and unrelated diversification mergers and acquisitions might change firm size, we incorporated
strategies, it is difficult to decide how firms should mix them. an M&A dummy. We also controlled for size change using total asset
Thus, this study incorporated the ratio of unrelated entropy to total growth and net sales growth. Finally, to control for changes in the
entropy in order to identify the optimal mixed ratio of related and primary market size we incorporated the average prior three-year
unrelated diversification. In this measure, a value of “one” implies sales growth, which is the average of the primary market (SIC 5812)
that the firm is wholly diversified into unrelated businesses, and a sales growth at times t-1, t-2 and t-3. Detailed descriptions of all
value of “zero” indicates that the firm is diversified fully into related variables are provided in Table 1.
businesses. Similar to prior entropy measures, we incorporated the Methodologically, the instrumental variable (IV) regression
squared term (RUTE2 ) in our analysis. needs reliable and valid instruments for first stage estimation. The
appropriate instrumental variables for this study are determinants
3.4. Classification of related and unrelated diversification of corporate diversification, as we addressed in the discussion of
the endogenous relationship between corporate diversification and
When measuring related and unrelated entropy, whether a firm performance. For instance, many firm-level factors are related
business (industry or sector) is classified as either related or to diversification decisions: firm size, fixed assets, overall firm
unrelated is important. Prior studies tend to favor Rumelt’s classi- growth advertising expenditures, and capital structures such as
fication. However, it has limitations due to categorizing businesses total and long-term debt leverage or debt/equity ratio. Simply put,
as related or unrelated based on the SIC classification system. large firms can diversify more easily since they have more resources
Conventional Rumelt’s classification identifies the relatedness of and low growth firms are more likely to diversify than high growth
businesses based on whether the first two-digit SIC codes are the firms. Also, firms with higher advertising expenditures are better
same or not. If they are same, the two businesses are categorized situated to exploit their market reputation when diversifying. Since
as related businesses. Otherwise, they are categorized as unre- diversification is a kind of investment behavior, capital structure
lated businesses. However, the SIC classification system does not is also associated with diversification (Jang and Tang, 2009). All
represent the relatedness of businesses. Thus, this study modi- instrumental variables (IV) in the analysis used the average prior
fied the classification method based on the basic characteristics of three-year variable. In other words, the average value from time t-1
each diversifying target industry. Because restaurant firms provide to time t-3 was used. Theoretically, the diversification decision is
food-related products and services, we categorized food-related determined by long-term performance rather than short-term per-
businesses, such as food retail and food production, as related to formance. Thus, using the prior three-year average value is more
the primary business. logical. Another advantage of the prior three-year average is that it
K. Park, S. Jang / International Journal of Hospitality Management 31 (2012) 218–228 223

Table 1
Variable description. 2
Volatilityi,t = ˇ1 × (DR)i,t + ˇ2 × (DR)i,t + ˇ3 × ln (TDL)i,t
+ ˇ4 × ln (Firm Size)i,t
Variable Description 2
+ ˇ5 × ln (Firm Size)i,t + ˇ6 × (Firm Size Growth)i,t
ROAi,t Adjusted return on assets [(net income + interests +ˇ7 × Avg Pri NSGRi,t
paid) ÷ total assets at the beginning of time t] + DYt
ROSi,t Adjusted return on sales [(net income + interests Model 3-a & Model 3-b
paid) ÷ net sales at time t]
ln(Var ROA)i,t Logarithmic transformed modified 3-year variance of
2
adjusted ROA Volatilityi,t = ˇ1 × (DU)i,t + ˇ2 × (DU)i,t + ˇ3 × ln (TDL)i,t
ln(Var ROS)i,t Logarithmic transformed modified 3-year variance of + ˇ4 × ln (Firm Size)i,t
2
adjusted ROS + ˇ5 × ln (Firm Size)i,t + ˇ6 × (Firm Size Growth)i,t
DRi,t Related diversification entropy +ˇ7 × Avg Pri NSGRi,t
DR2i,t Squared term of related diversification entropy + DYt
DUi,t Unrelated diversification entropy Model 4-a & Model 4-b
DU2i,t Squared term of unrelated diversification entropy
RUTEi,t Ratio of unrelated entropy to total entropy DR represents related diversification entropy and DU repre-
[DU ÷ (DR + DU)] sents unrelated diversification entropy. Models 1-a and 1-b apply
RUTE2i,t Squared term of RUTEi,t to Hypothesis 1, which concerns the relationship between related
ln(TDL)i,t Logarithmic transformed total debt leverage [ln(total
diversification and profitability. It was expected that coefficient ˇ1
debt ÷ total assets)]
ln(NS)i,t Logarithmic transformed net sales would be negative and ˇ2 would be positive. Models 2-a and 2-b
2
ln (NS)i,t Squared logarithmic transformed net sales were proposed to examine Hypothesis 2. It was expected that coef-
ln(TA)i,t Logarithmic transformed total assets ficient ˇ1 would be positive and ˇ2 would be negative. Models 3-a
2
ln (TA)i,t Squared logarithmic transformed total assets and 3-b were suggested to investigate Hypothesis 3. It was expected
ln(PP&E)i,t Logarithmic transformed fixed asset ratio [ln(PP&E ÷ total that coefficient ˇ1 would be positive and ˇ2 would be negative and
assets)]
DEPi,t Depreciation of firm i at time t
significant. Models 4-a and 4-b were suggested for Hypothesis 4. It
CFi,t Cash flow of firm i at time t [(operating income before was expected that coefficient ˇ1 would be negative but coefficient
depreciation − total income taxes − change in deferred ˇ2 would be positive.
taxes from the previous year to the current year − gross
2
interest expense − preferred dividend requirements on Profitabilityi,t = ˇ1 × (RUTE)i,t + ˇ2 × (RUTE)i,t + ˇ3 × ln (TDL)i,t
cumulative preferred stocks and dividends paid on + ˇ4 × ln (Firm Size)i,t
2
non-cumulative preferred stock − total dollar amount of + ˇ5 × ln (Firm Size)i,t + ˇ6 × ln (PP&E)i,t + ˇ7 × DEPi,t
dividends declared on common stocks) ÷ total assets] + ˇ8 × CFi,t + ˇ9 × DQi,t 
DQi,t Dummy Tobin’s Q = 1 if Tobin’s Q is larger than 1/ = 0 if + ˇ10 × FCFi,t + ˇ11 × DM&Ai,t + DYt
Tobin’s Q is less than 1 Model 5-a & Model 5-b
FCFi,t Free cash flow of firm i at time t = CFi,t if Tobin’s Q is less
than 1/=0 if Tobin’s Q is larger than 1
2
DM&Ai,t Dummy M&A = 1 if firm i executed M&A at time t/ = 0 Volatilityi,t = ˇ1 × (RUTE)i,t + ˇ2 × (RUTE)i,t + ˇ3 × ln (TDL)i,t
otherwise + ˇ4 × ln (Firm Size)i,t
2
NSGRi,t Net sales growth [(net salesi,t − net salesi,t-1 ) ÷ net salesi,t-1 ] + ˇ5 × ln (Firm Size)i,t + ˇ6 × (Firm Size Growth)i,t
TAGRi,t Total assets growth [(total assetsi,t − total assetsi,t-1 ) ÷ total +ˇ7 × Avg Pri NSGRi,t
assetsi,t-1 ] + DYt
Avg Pri NSGRi,t Average sales growth of the primary business (SIC 5812) Model 6-a & Model 6-b
 from t-1 to t-3
DYt Year dummies Finally, RUTEi,t represents the ratio of unrelated entropy to total
entropy for firm i at time t. Models 5-a and 5-b apply to Hypothesis
5, which represents the relationship between the ratio of unrelated
reduces redundancy and helps avoid over-identification. Multiple entropy to total entropy and profitability. It was expected that coef-
usages of the same IV tend to make the model over-identified. (For ficient ˇ1 would be positively significant but coefficient ˇ2 would
example, using average prior three-year total debt leverage rather be negatively significant because the positive and negative effects
than the three total debt leverages from time t-1 to time t-3). Fol- of the two types of diversification were mitigated when they were
lowing these theoretical rationale and prior studies, instrumental equally mixed. Models 6-a and 6-b were suggested for Hypothesis
variables were also used in the analysis. 6. We expected that coefficient ˇ1 would be negative and ˇ2 would
be positive.
3.6. Proposed models
3.7. Estimation method
To examine the hypotheses regarding the relationship between
diversification and firm performance, this study proposed the fol- There were two estimation issues in this study. The first is the
lowing models: firm-specific effect, which refers to an unobservable heterogene-
ity in each firm’s behavior. To overcome heterogeneity problems
2
Profitabilityi,t = ˇ1 × (DR)i,t + ˇ2 × (DR)i,t + ˇ3 × ln (TDL)i,t panel estimation is frequently used to account for fixed-effects in
+ ˇ4 × ln (Firm Size)i,t
2 the model. The fixed-effect estimation could control the variation in
+ ˇ5 × ln (Firm Size)i,t + ˇ6 × ln (PP&E)i,t + ˇ7 × DEPi,t
error terms between heterogeneous firms. Thus, the current study
+ ˇ8 × CFi,t + ˇ9 × DQi,t  applied the fixed-effect estimation in our analysis. Additionally, this
+ ˇ10 × FCFi,t + ˇ11 × DM&Ai,t + DYt
Model 1-a & Model 1-b study included year dummies to control for time variation because
performance differences could be affected by time variations. Con-
2 sequently, this study applied the panel estimation model on the
Profitabilityi,t = ˇ1 × (DU)i,t + ˇ2 × (DU)i,t + ˇ3 × ln (TDL)i,t
+ ˇ4 × ln (Firm Size)i,t firm-specific effect and applied the time variation to the analysis.
2
+ ˇ5 × ln (Firm Size)i,t + ˇ6 × ln (PP&E)i,t + ˇ7 × DEPi,t The second estimation issue relates to the appropriateness
+ ˇ8 × CFi,t + ˇ9 × DQi,t  of instrumental variables since we used instrumental variable
+ ˇ10 × FCFi,t + ˇ11 × DM&Ai,t + DYt regression. First, if an instrument cannot appropriately predict
Model 2-a & Model 2-b the endogenous variable (diversification variable) the second stage
224 K. Park, S. Jang / International Journal of Hospitality Management 31 (2012) 218–228

Table 2
Mean values of diversified and undiversified firms.

Total sample Undiversified Diversified

Obs. 2829 2432 397


Total entropy 0.0697 – 0.4966
Related entropy 0.0365 – 0.2602
Unrelated entropy 0.0332 – 0.2364
RUTE 0.4546 – 0.4546
Adjusted ROA (%) 4.56% 4.23% 6.61%
Adjusted ROS (%) 3.55% 3.53% 3.62%
Variance of adjusted ROA 0.0115 0.0118 0.0091
Variance of adjusted ROS 0.0049 0.0050 0.0045
Tobin’s Q 1.7805 1.8527 1.3404
Total assets (US million $) 376.226 362.366 461.132
Net sales (US million $) 490.477 434.655 832.438

Note: RUTE is the ratio of unrelated entropy to total entropy.

Fig. 1. Prediction of ROA for related and unrelated diversification entropy.


estimation is biased. Thus, the appropriateness of the instrumen-
tal variables should be put to an under-identification test. We used
the Kleibergen-Paap LM rk statistics to test for under-identification.
The null hypothesis of the under-identification test was that the 4.2. Related and unrelated diversification entropy and firm
equation is weakly (or under) identified. Second, if an instru- performance
ment is significantly correlated with the endogenous dependent
variable (here profitability and risk of profitability) the equation Hypotheses 1 and 2 address the relationship between
could be over-identified. If the equation is over-identified the esti- related/unrelated diversification entropy and profitability. Table 3
mates are also biased. Thus, this study tested for over-identification presents the results of Models 1-a and 1-b testing Hypothesis 1
using Hansen J-statistics. The null hypothesis of this test was that and Models 2-a and 2-b testing Hypothesis 2. The coefficient of
the instruments are exogenous (or not over-identified). Finally, to related diversification entropy was negatively significant, whereas
check the endogenous DP relationship, we included an endogeneity the coefficient of the squared term was positively significant (see
test based on the Husman test statistics (Wu-Hausman F-statistics). Table 3). Thus, Hypothesis 1 was accepted. This means that prof-
The null hypothesis of this test was that the variables are exoge- itability decreases up to a certain level of related diversification, but
nous. Additionally, to avoid heteroskedasticity this study applied beyond that level profitability increases. In other words, at lower
the heteroskedastic-robust standard errors. levels of related diversification the costs are larger than the benefits
due to the relatively lower profitability of related businesses. How-
ever, at higher levels of related diversification the positive effects of
4. Results related diversification (i.e., scale and scope economies and synergy)
dominate the negative effects.
4.1. Descriptive statistics Further, the coefficient of unrelated diversification entropy was
positive and the squared term was negative (see Table 3). Thus,
Our data included 308 restaurant firms with 2829 observations. Hypothesis 2 was accepted. This implies that profitability increases
In our sample, 77 firms were identified as diversified. As indicated in up to a certain level of unrelated diversification, but beyond that
Table 2, the total diversification entropy of the diversified firms was level profitability decreases. As we expected, at low levels the pos-
approximately 0.5, related diversification entropy was 0.26, and itive effects of unrelated diversification are larger than the costs.
unrelated diversification entropy was 0.23. This means that restau- Within this range, the influence of relatively profitable unrelated
rant firms tended slightly more toward related diversification. The businesses is dominant. However, beyond that level the positive
ratio of unrelated entropy to total entropy was approximately 0.45, effects are dominated by the costs of unrelated diversification, such
which also confirms that restaurant firms were moderately more as internal transaction costs, loss of control and effort, and lack
inclined toward related diversification. of flexibility. Excessive unrelated diversification signals a greater
In terms of firm performance, the adjusted return on assets distance between the primary industry and its diversifying indus-
(ROA) in the restaurant industry was 4.56% and the adjusted return tries. Consequently, this can lead to a dilution of business focus and,
on sales (ROS) was 3.55%. Both profitability measures were higher ultimately, deteriorating profits. Figs. 1 and 2 present predictions
for diversified firms than undiversified firms. Thus, it seems that regarding the effects of related/unrelated diversification entropy
diversification might increase profitability. In terms of risk (volatil- on profitability. The overall patterns were very similar between
ity) of profitability, the variance of adjusted return on assets (ROA) ROA and ROS. The overall effect of various diversification entropy
and return on sales (ROS) was lower for diversified restaurant firms. measures on profitability was very similar, regardless of the type
Thus, the overall risk of diversified firms appears to be lower than of profitability, which implies robust results.
the overall risk of undiversified firms. Hypotheses 3 and 4 apply to the relationship between
As we mentioned earlier, we re-categorized related and unre- related/unrelated diversification entropy and risk (volatility) of
lated segments based on industry characteristics. Because the profitability. Table 4 presents the results of Models 3-a, 3-b, 4-a,
restaurant business deals with products and services related and 4-b. As seen in Table 4, the coefficient of related diversifica-
to food, we re-categorized food-related businesses to include tion entropy was positively significant and the squared term was
categories such as food retail and production. Typically, these busi- negatively significant. This means that volatility increases up to a
nesses would be classified as unrelated diversification. Finally, we certain level of related diversification, but beyond that level risk
identified that restaurant firms were diversified into 55 industries: decreases as related diversification increases. Thus, Hypothesis 3
21 industries related to the primary business and 34 industries was accepted. The results indicate that at lower levels of related
unrelated to the primary business. diversification the synthetic business risk of related businesses
K. Park, S. Jang / International Journal of Hospitality Management 31 (2012) 218–228 225

Table 3
The related/unrelated diversification entropy effect on profitability.

Model 1-a (D.V.: ROA) Model 1-b (D.V.: ROS) Model 2-a (D.V.: ROA) Model 2-b (D.V.: ROS)

DRi,t −5.2171** −1.8969**


DR2i,t 5.5475*** 2.1273**
DUi,t 12.5228*** 7.0048**
DU2i,t −14.9808** −9.3911**
ln(TDL)i,t −0.0735** −0.0435*** 0.0033 −0.0308
ln(NS)i,t 0.1441** −0.0292
2
ln (NS)i,t −0.0101** −0.0080
ln(TA)i,t −0.0026 −0.0788
2
ln (TA)i,t −0.0005 0.0028
ln(PP&E)i,t −0.0060 −0.0072 0.1172*** 0.0716
DEPi,t −1.7156*** −1.3156*** −3.1443*** −1.7777***
CFi,t 0.1878** 0.1022 0.0721 −0.1800
DQi,t 0.0146 0.0015 −0.0014 −0.0158
FCFi,t −0.0857 −0.1834 −0.7743 −0.4507
DM&Ai,t 0.0388 0.0067 0.0048 −0.0061

Number of Obs. 1401 1221 956 832


Under-identification test (Kleibergen-Paap LM statistics) 8.008** 18.489*** 13.521** 14.155**
Over-identification test (Hansen J statistics) 0.112 4.020 3.526 4.852
Endogeneity test 18.651*** 13.742*** 28.936*** 7.446**

Note: Results of year dummies are not presented.


*p < 0.1.
**
p < 0.05.
***
p < 0.001.

dominates the risk-reduction effect. However, at higher levels of between related/unrelated diversification entropy and profitability
related diversification the risk-reduction effect dominates the syn- volatility.
thetic business risk from related businesses.
As seen in Table 4, the coefficient of unrelated diversifica- 4.3. RUTE (ratio of unrelated entropy to total entropy) and firm
tion entropy was negatively significant and the squared term performance
was positive, but only significant for the volatility of ROA.
This means that the volatility of ROA decreases up to a cer- The final hypotheses examine the optimal mixed levels of
tain level of unrelated diversification, but beyond that level related and unrelated diversification that maximize profitability
the risk of ROA increases as unrelated diversification entropy and minimize profitability volatility (Hypotheses 5 and 6). To test
increases. However, the risk of ROS linearly decreased as unre- these hypotheses, we incorporated the ratio of unrelated entropy
lated diversification increased. This suggests that asset efficiency to total entropy. Table 5 shows the results of Models 5-a and 5-b,
decreases at an extreme level of unrelated diversification. How- which relate to Hypothesis 5. The linear term of the ratio of entropy
ever, squared unrelated diversification entropy remained positive to total entropy (RUTE) was positively significant, and the squared
on the volatility of ROS. Thus, Hypothesis 4 was partially term (RUTE2 ) was negatively significant. If we took derivatives of
accepted. Figs. 3 and 4 show the predictions of the relationship ROA and ROS with respect to RUTE for the results of both Models 5-a

Table 4
The related/unrelated diversification entropy effect on risk (volatility) of profitability.

Model 3-a D.V.: ln(VAR ROA) Model 3-b D.V.: ln(VAR ROS) Model 4-a D.V.: ln(VAR ROA) Model 4-b D.V.: ln(VAR ROS)

DRi,t 28.6970** 21.8741**


DR2i,t −48.2268** −47.3671**
DUi,t −88.6641*** −43.0451**
DU2i,t 155.2150** 79.3548**
Ln(TDL)i,t 0.3460 0.6997*** 0.5073*** 0.7922***
Ln(NS)i,t −2.9070*** −3.1580***
2
ln (NS)i,t 0.1911*** 0.1968***
TAGRi,t 0.1237 0.2187
Ln(TA)i,t −1.3738* −1.2696**
2
ln (TA)i,t 0.0731 0.0544
NSGRi,t −0.3313 −0.2741
Avg Pri NSGRi,t −1.0351 0.1383 0.4092 −0.3424

Number of Obs. 635 522 1,039 894


Under-identification test 15.018** 20.325*** 9.026** 10.215**
(Kleibergen-Paap LM
statistics)
Over-identification test 7.079 8.467 1.472 4.479
(Hansen J statistics)
Endogeneity test 10.557*** 12.268*** 20.165*** 8.553**

Note: Results of year dummies are not presented.


*p < 0.1.
**
p < 0.05.
***
p < 0.001.
226 K. Park, S. Jang / International Journal of Hospitality Management 31 (2012) 218–228

Table 5
The effect of ratio of unrelated entropy to total entropy on profitability and volatility.

Model 5-a D.V.: ROA Model 5-b D.V.: ROS Model 6-a D.V.: ln(VAR ROA) Model 6-b D.V.: ln(VAR ROS)

(RUTE)i,t 6.0578** 3.0727** −11.1632*** −9.9220**


2
(RUTE)i,t −5.7968** −3.0817** 9.1265** 9.0778**
ln(TDL)i,t −0.0435 −0.0164 1.6539* 1.5296*
ln(TA)i,t 0.1098 1.2810
2
ln(TA)i,t −0.0136 −0.0287
ln(NS)i,t −0.0202 −5.0657**
2
ln (NS)i,t −0.0060 0.3259**
ln(PP&E)i,t 0.3418*** 0.0994
DEPi,t −1.3643 −1.4712
CFi,t 0.2202 0.2967**
DQi,t 0.0143 0.0380
FCFi,t −0.1668 0.3426
DM&Ai,t 0.0370 0.0118
TAGRi,t −0.3089
NSGRi,t −1.2732
Avg Pri NSGRi,t −2.2733* −2.1894

Number of Obs. 119 108 72 65


Under-identification test 13.860** 11.043** 21.929** 11.062**
(Kleibergen-Paap LM
statistics)
Over-identification Test 8.630 1.577 9.249 5.026
(Hansen J statistics)
Endogeneity test 18.775*** 14.239*** 26.737*** 7.443**

Note: Results of year dummies are not presented.


*
p < 0.1.
**
p < 0.05.
***
p < 0.001.

Table 6
Summary of hypotheses and results.

Dependent variable Independent variables Hypo. Result Hypothesis accept/reject

ROA ROS

DR − − −
Hypothesis 1 is accepted
DR2 + + +
Profitability
DU + + +
Hypothesis 2 is accepted
DU2 − − −

DR + + +
Hypothesis 3 is accepted
DR2 − − −
Profitability risk (volatility)
DU − − −
Hypothesis 4 is accepted
DU2 + + +

RUTE + + +
Profitability Hypothesis 5 is accepted
RUTE2 − − −

RUTE − − −
Profitability risk (volatility) Hypothesis 6 is accepted
RUTE2 + + +

Note: NS means “Not Significant”.

Fig. 2. Prediction of ROS for related and unrelated diversification entropy. Fig. 3. Prediction on the variance of ROA for related and unrelated diversification
entropy.
K. Park, S. Jang / International Journal of Hospitality Management 31 (2012) 218–228 227

high levels of related diversification the positive effect from scale


and scope economies and synergy overrules the negative effect.
On the other hand, unrelated diversification increases profitability
up to a certain level, which implies that at a low level of unre-
lated diversification the positive effects of the relatively profitable
unrelated business segments dominate. However, beyond that level
unrelated diversification decreases profitability, which implies that
at high levels of unrelated diversification internal transaction costs
increase and there is a loss of control and effort due to the distance
from the primary business.
In terms of the volatility of accounting profitability, related
diversification increases volatility up to a certain level. This means
that at low levels of related diversification the synthetic related
business risk is larger than the risk reduction effect. However,
beyond that level of diversification volatility decreases because at
high levels of related diversification the risk reduction effect domi-
Fig. 4. Prediction on the variance of ROS for related and unrelated diversification nates. Conversely, unrelated diversification decreases volatility up
entropy. to a certain level because the income streams of unrelated busi-
nesses are weakly correlated. However, at high levels of unrelated
and 5-b and set the equation at zero, the maximized ratio appears diversification volatility increases because the firm faces various
as follows: business risks and loses managerial control.
∂ROA A number of managerial implications could be derived from
= 6.0578 − 2 × 5.7968 × RUTE = 0 the results of this study. First, restaurant managers should be cau-
∂RUTE
RUTE ≈ 0.523 tious when they consider diversifying into related businesses as
a first diversification strategy because it will inevitably be situ-
ated at a low level of related diversification. Within this range
∂ROS
= 3.0727 − 2 × 3.0817 × RUTE = 0 of related diversification, profitability decreases and volatility
∂RUTE
RUTE ≈ 0.499 increases. Thus, it is recommended that restaurant managers just
beginning to diversify should move into unrelated businesses.
Consequently, when we mixed related and unrelated entropy Second, even though diversification into unrelated businesses pro-
at approximately half and half profitability was maximized. Thus, duces positive outcomes, at high levels of unrelated diversification
Hypothesis 5 was accepted. profitability decreases and volatility increases. Accordingly, when
Finally, Table 5 shows the results of Models 6-a and 6-b. The managers decide to increase the unrelated businesses in their
coefficient of RUTE was negatively significant, while RUTE2 was business portfolio they should be cautious. Finally, well balanced
positively significant. Likewise, if we took derivatives with respect diversification into both related and unrelated businesses is the
to RUTE for the results of both Models 6-a and 6-b and set the best strategy for restaurant firms. The negative and positive effects
equation at zero, the maximized ratio appears as follows: of both types of diversification can be counterbalanced, and prof-
∂ ln(Var ROA) itability is maximized while volatility is minimized.
= −11.1632 + 2 × 9.1265 × RUTE = 0 This study is not free from limitations. Other factors may influ-
∂RUTE
RUTE ≈ 0.612 ence the DP relationship, such as organizational efficiency and
structure, managerial capability and experience, and ways to diver-
sify. Further, the results of this study cannot be generalized to
∂ ln(Var ROS)
= −9.9220 + 2 × 9.0778 × RUTE = 0 other industries due to the sample’s uniqueness. Because of limita-
∂RUTE
RUTE ≈ 0.546 tions in the public data this study could not reveal each segment’s
profitability at the firm level. Thus, future studies might improve
The calculation results show that when related and unrelated our understanding of the DP relationship by incorporating pri-
entropy are mixed in approximately the same proportions, the vate information about firm level segment profitability. Further,
volatility of profitability is minimized. Thus, Hypothesis 6 was also investors could benefit from corporate diversification even if they
accepted. Finally, Table 6 shows a summary of all the hypotheses are not diversifying their investment assets portfolio. However,
and results of this study. such benefits for investors have not been examined in the hos-
pitality industry. Thus, the investor’s perspective on corporate
5. Conclusion diversification strategies could be an interesting subject for future
research.
The DP relationship deserves the attention it has garnered in
the field of strategic management. However, few efforts have been
made to understand the DP relationship in the hospitality field. References
This study investigated the relationship between diversification
Amit, R., Livnat, J., 1988. Diversification strategies, business cycles and economic
strategies and accounting performance in the restaurant industry
performance. Strategic Management Journal 9 (2), 99–110.
using an entropy measure. In particular, the current study exam- Ansoff, H., 1957. Strategies for diversification. Harvard Business Review 35 (5),
ined the non-linear effect of diversification on firm performance by 113–124.
Barton, S., 1988. Diversification strategy and systematic risk: another look. Academy
controlling for endogeneity and firm-specific effects.
of Management Journal 31 (1), 166–175.
This study found that related diversification decreases prof- Bass, F., Cattin, P., Wittink, D., 1977. Market Structure and Industry Influence on
itability up to a certain level, which means that at a low level of Profitability. Indiana University Press, Bloomington.
related diversification the negative effect from relatively unprof- Berry, C., 1971. Corporate growth and diversification. Journal of Law and Economics
14, 371–383.
itable related business segments dominates. However, beyond that Bettis, R., 1981. Performance differences in related and unrelated diversified firms.
level profitability increases as related diversification increases. At Strategic Management Journal 2 (4), 379–393.
228 K. Park, S. Jang / International Journal of Hospitality Management 31 (2012) 218–228

Bettis, R., Hall, W., 1982. Diversification strategy, accounting determined risk, Lubatkin, M., O’Neill, H., 1987. Merger strategies and capital market risk. Academy
and accounting determined return. Academy of Management Journal 25 (2), of Management Journal 30 (4), 665–684.
254–264. Lubatkin, M., Rogers, R., 1989. Diversification, systematic risk, and shareholder
Boltzmann, L., 1896. Entgegnung auf die warmetheoretischen Betrachtungen des return: a capital market extension of Rumelt’s 1974 study. Academy of Man-
Hrn. E. Zermelo. Annalen der Physik 293, 773–784. agement Journal 32 (2), 454–465.
Brush, T., Bromiley, P., Hendrickx, M., 2000. The free cash flow hypothesis for MacGregor, G., Sever, P., 1996. Salt-overwhelming evidence but still no action: can
sales growth and firm performance. Strategic Management Journal 21 (4), a consensus be reached with the food industry? British Medical Journal 312
455–472. (7041), 1287.
Chatterjee, S., 1986. Types of synergy and economic value: the impact of acquisitions Markides, C., 1992. Consequences of corporate refocusing: ex ante evidence.
on merging and rival firms. Strategic Management Journal, 119–139. Academy of Management Journal, 398–412.
Christensen, H., Montgomery, C., 1981. Corporate economic performance: diversi- Markowitz, H., 1952. Portfolio selection. Journal of Finance 7 (1), 77–91.
fication strategy versus market structure. Strategic Management Journal 2 (4), Meyer, M., Milgrom, P., Roberts, J., 1992. Organizational prospects, influence costs
327–343. and ownership changes. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy 1 (1),
Datta, D., Rajagopalan, N., Rasheed, A., 1991. Diversification and performance: criti- 9–35.
cal review and future directions. Journal of Management Studies 28 (5), 529–558. Montgomery, C., 1985. Product-market diversification and market power. Academy
Gale, B., 1972. Market share and rate of return. The Review of Economics and Statis- of Management Journal 28 (4), 789–798.
tics 54 (4), 412–423. Montgomery, C., Singh, H., 1984. Diversification strategy and systematic risk. Strate-
Graham, J., Lemmon, M., Wolf, J., 2002. Does corporate diversification destroy value? gic Management Journal 5 (2), 181–191.
Journal of Finance 57 (2), 695–720. Mueller, D., 1977. The persistence of profits above the norm. Economica 44 (176),
Grant, R., Jammine, A., Thomas, H., 1988. Diversity, diversification, and profitability 369–380.
among British manufacturing companies, 1972–84. Academy of Management Mueller, D., 1986. Profits in the Long Run. Cambridge Univ Press.
Journal 31 (4), 771–801. Nachum, L., 2004. Geographic and industrial diversification of developing country
Grinyer, P., Yasai-Ardekani, M., Al-Bazzaz, S., 1980. Strategy, structure, the environ- firms. Journal of Management Studies 41 (2), 273–294.
ment, and financial performance in 48 United Kingdom companies. Academy of Narasimhan, R., Kim, S.W., 2002. Effects of supply chain integration on the rela-
Management Journal 23 (2), 193–220. tionship between diversification and performance: evidence from Japanese and
Hall, M., Weiss, L., 1967. Firm size and profitability. The Review of Economics and Korean firms. Journal of Operations Management 20, 303–323.
Statistics 49 (3), 319–331. Palepu, K., 1985. Diversification strategy, profit performance and the entropy mea-
Higgins, R., Schall, L., 1975. Corporate bankruptcy and conglomerate merger. Journal sure. Strategic Management Journal, 239–255.
of Finance 30 (1), 93–113. Palich, L., Carini, G., Seaman, S., 2000. Curvilinearity in the diversification-
Hill, C., Snell, S., 1988. External control, corporate strategy, and firm performance in performance linkage: an examination of over three decades of research.
research-intensive industries. Strategic Management Journal 9 (6), 577–590. Strategic Management Journal 21 (2), 155–174.
Himmelberg, C., Hubbard, R., Palia, D., 1999. Understanding the determinants of Penrose, E., 1959. The Theory of the Growth of the Firm. John Wiley & Sons, New
managerial ownership and the link between ownership and performance. Jour- York, NY.
nal of Financial Economics 53 (3), 353–384. Pils, F., 2009. Diversification, Relatedness, and Performance. Gabler Verlag.
Hofer, C., Schendel, D., 1978. Strategy Formulation: Analytical Concepts. West, St. Porter, M., 1987. From competitive advantage to corporate strategy. Harvard Busi-
Paul, MN. ness Review 65 (3), 43–59.
Hurdle, G., 1974. Leverage, risk, market structure and profitability. The Review of Rajan, R., Servaes, H., Zingales, L., 2000. The cost of diversity: the diversification
Economics and Statistics 56 (4), 478–485. discount and inefficient investment. Journal of Finance 55 (1), 35–80.
Hyland, D., Diltz, J., 2002. Why firms diversify: an empirical examination. Financial Ravenscraft, D., 1983. Structure–profit relationship at the line of business and indus-
Management 31 (1), 51–81. try level. The Review of Economics and Statistics 65 (1), 22–31.
Ito, K., 1997. Domestic competitive position and export strategy of Japanese manu- Rijamampianina, R., Abartt, R., February, Y., 2003. A framework for concentric diver-
facturing firms: 1971–1985. Management Science 43 (5), 610–622. sification through sustainable competitive advantage. Management Decision 41
Jacquemin, A., Berry, C., 1979. Entropy measure of diversification and corporate (4), 362–371.
growth. The Journal of Industrial Economics 27 (4), 359–369. Rumelt, R., 1974. Strategy, Structure, and Economic Performance. Harvard University
Jang, S., Tang, C., 2009. Simultaneous impacts of internationalization and financial Press, Cambridge, MA.
leverage on profitability. Journal of Hospitality and Tourism Research 33 (3), Rumelt, R., 1982. Diversification strategy and profitability. Strategic Management
347–368. Journal 3 (4), 359–369.
Jensen, M., 1986. Agency costs of free cash flow, corporate finance, and takeovers. Scharfstein, D.S., Stein, J.C., 2000. The dark side of internal capital markets: divisional
The American Economic Review 76 (2), 323–329. rent-seeking and inefficient investment. Journal of Finance 55, 2537–2564.
Jones, G., Hill, C., 1988. Transaction cost analysis of strategy-structure choice. Strate- Scherer, F., 1980. Industrial Market Structure and Economic Performance. Rand
gic Management Journal 9 (2), 159–172. McNally, Chicago, IL.
Kim, H., Gu, Z., 2003. Risk-adjusted performance: a sector analysis of restaurant Schmalensee, R., 1985. Do markets differ much? The American Economic Review 75
firms. Journal of Hospitality & Tourism Research 27 (2), 200. (3), 341–351.
Lang, L., Stulz, R., 1994. Tobin’s q, corporate diversification, and firm performance. Singh, A., Gu, Z., 1994. Diversification, financial performance, and stability of food
Journal of Political Economy 102 (6), 1248–1280. service firms. Hospitality Research Journal 18 (2), 3–18.
Lecraw, D, 1984. Diversification strategy and performance. The Journal of Industrial Skalpe, O., 2003. Hotels and restaurants—are the risks rewarded? Evidence from
Economics 33 (2), 179–198. Norway. Tourism Management 24 (6), 623–634.
Lee, M.J., Jang, S., 2007. Market diversification and financial performance and stabil- Stulz, R., 1990. Managerial discretion and optimal financing policies. Journal of
ity: a study of hotel companies. International Journal of Hospitality Management Financial Economics 26 (1), 3–27.
26 (2), 362–375. Tallman, S., Li, J., 1996. Effects of international diversity and product diversity on the
Lewellen, W., 1971. A pure financial rationale for the conglomerate merger. Journal performance of multinational firms. Academy of Management Journal 39 (1),
of Finance, 521–537. 179–196.
Liu, H.Y., Wang, S.J., 2007. An analysis on the relationship between diversification Tang, C., Jang, S., 2010. Does international diversification discount exist in the hotel
strategies and firm value: empirical evidence from China’s listed tourism com- industry? Journal of Hospitality & Tourism Research 34 (2), 225–246.
panies. Journal of Beijing International Studies University 5, 57–61. Wang, C.P., Xu, H.G., 2008. The economic results of tourism companies’ diversifica-
Lubatkin, M., Chatterjee, S., 1994. Extending modern portfolio theory into the tion. Tourism Tribune 7, 18–22.
domain of corporate diversification: does it apply? Academy of Management West, R., 1967. Homemade diversification vs. corporate diversification. Journal of
Journal, 109–136. Financial and Quantitative Analysis 2 (4), 417–420.

You might also like