Commodification of Natural Resources and PDF

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 10

Environmental Conservation: page 1 of 10 

C Foundation for Environmental Conservation 2016 doi:10.1017/S0376892916000436

Commodification of natural resources and forest THEMED ISSUE


Forest Ecosystem Services
ecosystem services: examining implications for forest
protection
H E L E N K O P N I N A 1, 2 ∗
1
Leiden University, Anthropology Department, Wassenaarseweg 52 2333 AK Leiden, The Netherlands and 2 The
Hague University of Applied Science, International Business Management Studies, Johanna Westerdijkplein 75,
2521 EN Den Haag, The Netherlands
Date submitted: 18 August 2015; Date accepted: 24 September 2016

SUMMARY environmental governance, supported by financial institutions


such as the Word Bank (e.g. Caine 2013). In this
Through the commodification of nature, the framing
framing, forest protection and community rights are seen
of the environment as a ‘natural resource’ or
as externalities that can be mitigated through economic
‘ecosystem service’ has become increasingly prom-
measures (e.g. Shoreman-Ouimet & Kopnina 2016). These
inent in international environmental governance.
measures stimulate a convergence of capitalist expansion
The economic capture approach is promoted by
and environmental protection within so-called neoliberal
international organizations such as the United Nations
conservation through top-down environmental governance
Environmental Program (UNEP) through Reducing
(e.g. Brosius 1999; Brockington 2002; Büscher & Fletcher
Emissions from Deforestation and Forest Degradation
2014; Duffy et al. 2015). Igoe and Brockington (2007) discuss
(REDD), Payments for Ecosystem Services (PES)
‘hybrid environmental governance’, in which governments,
and The Economics of Ecosystems and Biodiversity
the private sector, non-governmental organizations (NGOs)
(TEEB). This paper will inquire as to how forest
and communities share responsibility for and profits from
protection is related to issues of social and ecological
conservation, and institute new types of territorialisation: the
justice, exploring whether forest exploitation based
partitioning of resources and landscapes in ways that control
on the top-down managerial model fosters an
local people through regulation by national and transnational
unequitable distribution of resources. Both top-down
elites.
and community-based approaches to forest protection
The economic cost–benefit worldview is promoted by
will be critically examined and a more inclusive
international organizations such as the United Nations
ethical framework to forest protection will be offered.
Environmental Program (UNEP) through Payments for
The findings of this examination indicate the need
Ecosystem Services (PES), Reducing Emissions from
for a renewed focus on existing examples of good
Deforestation and Forest Degradation (REDD) and The
practice in addressing both social and ecological
Economics of Ecosystems and Biodiversity (TEEB).
need, as well as the necessity to address the less
According to Neef (2015), ecosystem services refers
comfortable problem of where compromise appears
to functions such as carbon sequestration, ecotourism,
less possible. The conclusion argues for the need to
promotion of sustainable agriculture and forestry, erosion
consider ecological justice as an important aspect
and flood control, clean drinking water or nature recreation.
of more socially orientated environmental justice for
PES is built upon two premises: that ecosystem services have
forest protection.
quantifiable economic value and that this value can be used to
Keywords: agroforestry, commodification, community-based entice investment in restoration and maintenance, combined
conservation, ecological justice, ecosystem services, PES, with managing environmental externalities (e.g. UNEP 2008;
REDD, TEEB Hiedanpaa & Bromley 2014). REDD seeks to create financial
value for the carbon stored in forests, offering incentives for
developing countries to reduce emissions from forested lands.
INTRODUCTION REDD includes the roles of conservation, the sustainable
The framing of the environment as a ‘common good’ management of forests and the enhancement of forest carbon
regulating of nature-based industries and environmental stocks (UN-REDD 2015). TEEB is a global initiative focused
services has become increasingly common in international on mainstreaming the values of biodiversity and ecosystem
services into decision-making at all levels (TEEB 2010).
Commodification, or putting a price on nature in the form
∗ of species banking and conservation finance, is supported as a
Correspondence: Dr. Helen Kopnina e-mail h.kopnina@hhs.nl;
h.n.kopnina@fsw.leidenuniv.nl core strategy for solving a range of environmental problems,

Downloaded from http:/www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 145.101.26.2, on 18 Nov 2016 at 11:42:31, subject to the Cambridge Core terms of use, available at http:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S0376892916000436
2 H. Kopnina

from climate change to deforestation (e.g. Poiani et al. 2011; traditional agriculture and perceptions of it as environmentally
Engel et al. 2013; Harvey et al. 2013). Commodification benign (e.g. Lansing 1991; Schroth & Harvey 2007).
is believed to avoid the tragedy of the commons by A widespread shift from the top-down models of
privatizing certain resources, and is viewed as strategic tool for forest management towards more participatory forms of
communicating the value of biodiversity using a language that co-management has coincided with calls to return to
reflects dominant political and economic views (Daily et al. traditional agroforestry, including small-scale slash-and-burn
2009), thus making environmental protection both legitimate and swidden agriculture, and to turn away from authoritative
and efficient, as it is centrally enforced. governance (e.g. Henley 2011). In the context of the discussion
Despite this assessment, commodification is often seen as of protected areas and traditional activities, it was argued
disadvantageous to local communities, as they rarely derive that small-scale farming is ecologically benign, in some cases
profits from natural commodities (e.g. German et al. 2010; actually contributing to local-level conservation (Lansing
Klooster 2010; Büscher & Fletcher 2014; Duffy et al. 2015). 1991), for example when cocoa farmers leave substantial
This critique emerged partially in response to the failure of amounts of original trees and plants (Schroth & Harvey 2007).
structural adjustment programmes in developing countries, However, CBC has also been criticized, as its
leading to financial dependency (e.g. Easterly 2006), and implementation has not always yielded successful policies.
partially in response to the general mistrust of top-down CBC was noted to be short sighted and marred by elite
institutions that profit from the neoliberal conservation of capture, corruption and mismanagement (Temudo 2012).
forests (e.g. Escobar 1996; Escobar 2006; Li 2007). The For example, due to corruption, CBC programmes in Africa
overarching criticism of neoliberal conservation is linked often benefit local authorities or elites, but not individuals in
to suspicion regarding open market neoliberalism and its the community (Sinclair 2015:77). As the number of people
advocacy of privatization, deregulation and scaling down of increases in the region, a demand to increase the harvest also
state government in an attempt to control and profit from increases, but the wildlife in a set area does not tend to increase.
resources at the expense of vulnerable communities (e.g. Thus, a steady harvest means that each person now receives a
Milne & Adams 2012; Quan et al. 2014). Generally, the critics declining income, but as people expect an increasing income,
are concerned with social justice or environmental justice demand for an increasing harvest is therefore exacerbated.
in regards to the equitable distribution of environmental Typically, the areas set aside for CBC decline over time due
risks (such as pollution) and benefits (such as natural to expanding populations, increasing development and loss
resources) between nations and across generations (e.g. Guha of soil, so wildlife populations decrease (Sponsel 2014). For
& Alier 2013). Anthropologists, political ecologists, human these reasons, CBC areas often become unsustainable in the
ecologists and historical ecologists have argued that human– long term.
environment interactions are characterized by changing, While the critique of commodification as disadvantaging
fluctuating relationships in which humans have always shaped local communities is well established, forest protection is
natural systems (e.g. Balee 1994; Igoe & Brockington 2007; rarely discussed in terms of ecological justice or justice
Milne & Adams 2012). Thus, the exclusion of its human between species (Baxter 2005). Scholars concerned with
inhabitants through a ‘fortress conservation’ model of strict ecological justice have pointed out that rendering an
protection based on top-down policies is neither practical nor environment solely as an entity that is instrumental to human
ethically justifiable (e.g. Brockington 2002). well-being ignores its non-utilitarian value (e.g. Crist 2012;
To counteract this tendency, community-based conserva- Cafaro & Primack 2014; Miller et al. 2014; Terborgh 2015).
tion (CBC) was proposed. Advocated for by a number of Sinclair (2015:77) emphasizes that CBC favours only those
international NGOs and human rights advocacy groups such species that are useful to humans, while other species, such
as Just Conservation or Survival International, there has been as large carnivores, are often excluded and even persecuted.
a widespread shift from the more top-down models of forest In addressing the areas of tension between supporters and
management towards more participatory co-management. opponents of social and/or ecological justice in relation to
Greater community participation in the management of forest protection, this paper will reflect on the market-based
natural resources is believed to achieve multiple aims, from instruments examining both top-down and CBC approaches,
reducing opportunities for corruption and thus guaranteeing and offer a reconciliatory vision of the sustainable use of
greater profitability of forest resources to satisfying social forests.
equality aims and empowering local communities, as well as This paper is structured as follows. It first examines
reducing poverty (e.g. Milne & Adams 2012). CBC has been neoliberal forest conservation and existing schemes to
proven in some cases to increase broad support for policy protect forests, reflecting on both the opportunities and
outcomes (Ban et al. 2013), ensure compliance with rules pitfalls of market-based instruments. A broader discussion
and regulations (Sutton & Tobin 2009), foster greater trust of the advantages and disadvantages of resource management
in scientific expertise (Brown 2009) and provide income for follows. A section on CBC and farming then reflects on the
local peoples in developing countries in the hope that they trade-offs involved in traditional forest exploitation systems.
come to value the areas and the native species that lie within It concludes by analysing top-down and community-based
them (Sinclair 2015). CBC has also been linked to small-scale initiatives from the social and ecological justice points of view.

Downloaded from http:/www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 145.101.26.2, on 18 Nov 2016 at 11:42:31, subject to the Cambridge Core terms of use, available at http:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S0376892916000436
Commodification of natural resources and forest ecosystem services 3

NEOLIBERAL FOREST PROTECTION agriculture and use systems that provide food security and
resilience, all linked to ‘climate-smart agriculture’ (Harvey
A number of international initiatives linking forest et al. 2013).
certification with PES have emerged. By the early 1990s, Despite the rhetoric of sustainable development that tends
the Rainforest Alliance began their ‘SmartWood’ certification, to underlie the congruity of social, economic and ecological
and later the Forest Stewardship Council (FSC) certification objectives (WCED 1987), the impacts of top-down forest
emerged (e.g. Klooster 2010). Shortly after the turn of the management have not always been harmonious or balanced.
millennium, Forest Law Enforcement and Governance and According to critics, certification agencies, for example, have
Trade (FLEGT) aimed to mobilize international commitment normalized the idea of ‘sustainable forestry’, and these critics
from governments that profit from forest conservation to question whether any commercially used plantations can be
increase efforts to combat illegal logging and corruption (The environmentally benign because they are normally planted
World Bank 2013). FLEGT included voluntary partnership where original forest stood (Brosius 1999). Gómez-Baggethun
agreements between countries in order to ensure that only legal and Ruiz-Pérez (2011) have argued that economic valuation
timber could be traded as part of the larger effort to provide is potentially counterproductive for biodiversity conservation
timber certification (Brown et al. 2008). One such initiative and equity of access to ecosystem services benefits.
is Forest Certification for Ecosystem Services (ForCES) in Additionally, timber verification schemes are difficult to
Indonesia, where PES was extended in FSC certification, implement and have had limited success (Brown et al. 2008).
with more than 1 million hectares of forest attaining FSC Hiedanpaa and Bromley (2014) argue that PES schemes face
certification (FSC 2015). a daunting challenge if they are to bring about sustainable
Similar PES deals have emerged wherever corporate part- practices and that such schemes have yet to empirically
ners, public sector agencies and not-for-profit organizations demonstrate their efficacy and financial sustainability. Until
have taken an active interest in a new source of income for land now, critics described conservation as a (global) subsidy
management, restoration, conservation and sustainable use system that redistributes resources under the assurance that
activities, purportedly aimed at simultaneously contributing this is ‘short-term support for the effort to generate self-
to economic development and reducing the rate of biodiversity sustaining markets’ (Büscher & Fletcher 2014:20).
loss (UNEP 2008). PES allows users who benefit from a certain Particularly in anthropology, the critique of ‘neo-colonial’
ecosystem service to pay those who have to sacrifice their or ‘elitist’ approaches to conservation in general and to
own resources to maintain such services. One of the central forest management in particular has become prominent
ideas is that ‘resource management’, both in the original (old- (Brockington 2002; Igoe & Brockington 2007; Bose et al. 2012;
growth) forests and land cleared for agricultural development, West & Brockington 2012). Some of these critics argue against
is contingent on profitable exploitation of ecological services, climate change mitigation through REDD, referring to it as
for which providers (i.e. farmers and other land owners) are a ‘menace’ imposed by the corporate or political elites on
compensated (Neef 2015). disadvantaged communities (Beymer-Farris & Bassett 2012).
Gómez-Baggethun and Ruiz-Pérez (2011) have argued Critique of forest conservation as a commodity also draws
that ecosystems services can be classified into two main attention to power relations and the politics of resistance as
approaches. The first approach involves interventions through one of the key practices in contemporary community forestry
state taxes and subsidies. The second approach is through (Li 2007). Escobar’s (1996) exploration of the link between
private transactions, often in markets where ecosystem neo-colonialism and the contemporary institutionalization of
services can be freely sold and bought. These approaches conservation includes the role of economic inequality and
have been implemented via two main mechanisms: ‘markets trade policy, as well as the conflicts over natural resources in
for ecosystem services’ and PES. ‘Thus the ‘polluter pays response to neoliberal globalization. There is a broader process
principle’ which underlies the former is complemented by the of making populations and landscapes in the developing
‘steward earns principle’ which underlies the latter’ (Gómez- world continuously subordinated to neoliberalism, allowing
Baggethun & Ruiz-Pérez 2011:6). According to Jax et al. localities and populations to be operationalized, managed
(2013), a major strength of the ecosystem services concept and exploited more effectively (Escobar 1996). Through the
is that it enables a succinct description of how human well- three inter-related rubrics of economic, ecological and cultural
being depends on nature, showing that the neglect of this factors, including global trade networks, many post-colonial
dependency has negative consequences for human well-being nature reserves have been said to retain the top-down status of
and the economy. a protected area with the rights of community access heavily
Similarly to PES, identifying and managing optimal curtailed (e.g. Escobar 2006; Igoe & Brockington 2007).
areas and strategies of forest conservation has been integral
to REDD. REDD supports those strategies that prevent
DEBATING CORRUPTION AND ILLEGALITY
deforestation by putting a price on the carbon produced by
the forest – one of the key strategies for addressing global Top-down governance was criticized for reinforcing unequal
greenhouse emissions that cause climate change (UN-REDD power relations between those that own the resources (large
2015). REDD attempts to financially motivate sustainable international organizations and local government officials)

Downloaded from http:/www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 145.101.26.2, on 18 Nov 2016 at 11:42:31, subject to the Cambridge Core terms of use, available at http:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S0376892916000436
4 H. Kopnina

and marginal communities (local people, small farmers, livelihoods depend on that biodiversity (e.g. Miller et al. 2014;
etc.), rendering certain traditional practices corrupt or illegal Sinclair 2014; Doak et al. 2015). In this way, it is not so much
(Brockington 2002; Büscher & Fletcher 2014). Some have the anthropocentrism but the ‘industrocentrism’ or capitalist
even argued that criminalizing practices like poaching is development that disadvantages both human and non-human
counterproductive (e.g. Duffy et al. 2015) or exaggerated by interests (Kidner 2014).
‘hysterical’ environmentalists (Büscher 2015). While resource management brings much-needed funding
It has been argued that the real ‘crime’ is not committed into the realm of conservation, PES is criticized for subsuming
by local communities, but by large agricultural projects set up biological diversity under a homogenous category of carbon
by international organizations that result in industrial logging, credits, reducing complex natural and social phenomena to
causing far greater devastation than small-scale farming driven tradable commodities and ignoring the inherent value of non-
by poverty and despair, as well as corruption (e.g. German human species (e.g. Vucetich et al. 2015). The underlying
et al. 2010; Klooster 2010; Milne & Adams 2012). In the critique of commodification is that it is ‘time to recognize
case of forest conservation, one concern is what is meant by that nature is the largest company on Earth working for the
corruption. benefit of 100 percent of humankind – and it’s doing it for
In Nigeria, many cocoa and plantain farms are indeed free’ (Sullivan 2009:2).
‘illegal’, with the plantain farms (largely unknown by higher- At present, however, as Vira (2015:763) has noted, for many,
up forest officers) transporting thousands of tons of plantain to the industrial development logic demands for maintaining
Lagos every week (von Hellermann 2016). The fact that these stable economic growth and redistributing the benefits to
plantations provide livelihoods for small-scale farmers and ensure wider prosperity appear to have the highest priority
traders is seen as a moderating factor, since illegal plantations and are unconnected to sustainability concerns, especially in
enable marginal communities to reap some benefits from much cases related to the protection of rare and endangered species.
larger profit-seeking activities (von Hellermann 2016). Thus, the position of ecological justice (Baxter 2005) and
the intrinsic value of nature become secondary to social and
economic distribution issues.
COMMUNITIES AND FORESTS: ETHICAL
DISPUTES
THE QUESTION OF THE EFFICACY OF FOREST
For REDD in Mozambique, the difficulties of linking
PROTECTION
mitigation objectives through tree planting, conservation and
carbon trading with the promotion of sustainable livelihoods The evidence for the efficacy of top-down management
and climate adaptation highlight the problems of there being approaches as well as CBC in achieving both social
different coalitions with conflicting agendas (Quan et al. 2014). justice and forest protection has been mixed (e.g. Temudo
These agendas range from private control of forests linked to 2012; Hiedanpaa & Bromley 2014; Sinclair 2015). Some
external carbon markets to national NGOs that reject REDD anthropologists have argued that indigenous populations
as a means of alleviating poverty. employ their traditional ecological knowledge and often
This is where the critique of both top-down (neoliberal manage their environments well, as exemplified by case studies
governance) and bottom-up (CBC) forest conservation bi- of agroecology (e.g. Anderson 2012). Agroecology, which
furcates. One group of scholars, who include anthropologists, studies the entire human food system from production and
political ecologists, human ecologists and those supporting processing to nutrition, has recently emphasized traditional
economic development, human and indigenous rights and production systems as inherently sustainable and able to
social justice, criticizes commodification as a process that provide nutrition to the most vulnerable social groups,
dispossesses local communities. Another group, mostly made guaranteeing food security and other indirect benefits
up of conservationists, ecologists, biologists and ecologically of income generation, nutrition and ecosystem services
inclined social scientists, point out that commodification (Hoffman 2013).
essentially serves anthropocentric interests. This division However, historically, agroforestry was created and
becomes particularly salient in the context of protected maintained by institutions that were radically different from
areas, where proponents of social justice argue that local today’s global capitalist system. Attention to today’s global
communities are disadvantaged by their creation (Brockington institutions, including REDD, PES and TEEB, makes it
2002; Igoe & Brockington 2007; Bose et al. 2012; West & difficult to imagine the alternative forms of production that
Brockington 2012; Duffy et al. 2015). Favouring conservation would have to accompany post-industrial agro-ecosystems
that was not intended to be for the benefit of the people has (Fraser et al. 2015). Forest protection combined with
even gained the label of misanthropy (Kareiva & Marvier 2007; supposedly benign types of traditional swidden farming has
Marvier 2014; Büscher 2015). been criticized as a romantic ideal, obscuring the fundamental
In contrast, supporters of strict conservation measures incompatibility of agriculture with nature conservation
have argued that even partial human use of fragile forest (Henley 2011). Local participation and traditional activities,
habitats is likely to exacerbate biodiversity crises and including small-scale farming, have proven to be less clearly
thus further disadvantage vulnerable communities whose ecologically harmless or socially equitable than previously

Downloaded from http:/www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 145.101.26.2, on 18 Nov 2016 at 11:42:31, subject to the Cambridge Core terms of use, available at http:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S0376892916000436
Commodification of natural resources and forest ecosystem services 5

thought (Henley 2011). The idealized community (Mehta private sector (von Hellermann 2016). Because forests are
et al. 2001) is similar to the much-criticized idea of the ‘noble treated as property, marginalized communities are officially
savage’ (e.g. Sivaramakrishnan 1999). Indigenous people are ‘allowed’ to reap its benefits by paternalistic and neo-colonial
not necessarily the best custodians of their land, as exemplified land owners who continue to profit from it (von Hellermann
by the ‘myth of indigenous stewardship’ (Fennell 2008). Even 2016).
at the small scale, when used too often and too intensely by an In the ethnography of the Gimi-speaking peoples in
increasing number of people, soil tends to degrade (Sinclair Papua New Guinea, the congruity of market valuation with
2014). Indigenous societies may have once lived in a state of indigenous notions has been questioned (West 2006). The
ecological equilibrium with the environment, but such a state integrated conservation and development project attempting
may now be disrupted (Sponsel 2014). According to Balee to tie a local valuation of nature to economic markets through
(1994:116), disequilibrium with the environment typically the creation of ‘eco-enterprises’ failed to consider the Gimi
manifests itself in high population densities, dependence worldview and practice (West 2006). Based on ethnographic
on global market economies, fossil fuel-based technologies, material, the Gimi understand their forests to be part of a
reduction in exposure to the natural environment and a huge series of dialectical relationships rather than commodities,
negative effect on biological diversity. Even if the ecological complicating neoliberal conservation efforts (West 2006).
impact of indigenous cultures was often low, this was not Another complication in relationships between local
necessarily because of their inherent natural wisdom, but governments, communities and conservation organizations
because of a low population density, the absence of a market exists in the context of the conservation of the Malaysian
and poor technology (Fennell 2008). rainforest, where a number of pitfalls have occurred in
Accommodation of the growing human population and alliances between NGOs and local people, as well as between
the expansion of often illegally appropriated agricultural grassroots and Western environmentalists (Brosius 1999). The
lands have resulted in further escalation of biodiversity crises indigenous protest movement in Malaysia teamed up with
(Sinclair 2015). Many formerly ‘traditional’ communities that environmentalists to fight for a common cause, but this alliance
live in proximity to protected areas have reached populations eventually fell apart because they had ultimately incompatible
exceeding the carrying capacity of their natural environment, agendas (Brosius 1999).
unintentionally depleting resources (Sponsel 2014). Today, There is a remarkable convergence between a diverse
agricultural development exists where indigenous laws would range of actors and voices supporting the principles of
previously have prohibited them; for example, close to rivers good governance in forest conservation, including those of
or on steep hillsides, all places that are prone to erosion and development economists, NGOs and human rights activists
less likely to be resilient (Shoreman-Ouimet & Kopnina 2016). (von Hellermann 2016). These historically adversarial groups
Tropical forest soil’s nutrient-holding capacity is limited, all largely agree that it is the underlying causes of deforestation
and when cleared, the thin layer of fertile topsoil washes that need to be tackled and that local people should have
away, causing the area to be more vulnerable to fires and more control over their own resources. In this sense, everyone
making it very difficult for native flora and fauna to become speaks more or less the same language of participation,
re-established afterwards (Henley 2011). Multiple instances accountability, transparency and sustainability and against
of over-hunting and habitat destruction in community- corruption, with the last allowing both illegal logging and
managed regions have demonstrated that, in some instances, poaching.
fortress conservation-type protection is more successful than
‘permissive’ conservation or CBC (e.g. Sinclair 2014; Doak
DISPUTING CORRUPTION
et al. 2015).
Both industrial agricultural projects and small-scale, While obstacles to forest protection and successful
top-down methods of management can have devastating conservation have been identified, and corruption has been
effects on the environment. In order to understand the singled out as one of the key areas of concern, a counter-
complex relationship between exploitation of the forest and reaction to combatting corruption came from the same ‘camp’
environmental degradation, a more nuanced understanding of human rights defenders. Far from considering this an
of the agencies and actors that harm forests and benefit from impediment to forest protection, some social scientists have
forest protection is required. As Crist (2012:145) has argued, argued that corruption and even illegal poaching should be
the planet-wide abuse of the environment is driven by the seen through a cultural interpretative lens. Instead of evoking
Faustian economic partnerships and the life-ways of both the a ‘culture of corruption’ (Smith 2007), they called for a more
world’s rich and poor. nuanced, differentiated and sector-specific understanding of
While traditional agroforestry seems to strike a compromise corruption (Fortmann 2005). In Benin, von Hellermann
between top-down and local-level control of resources, (2016) notes that logging allocations are strengthened by
agroforestry is not without its critics. Agroforestry is often the regular exchange of greeting cards and calendars, which
supported by regimes instituted by REDD, PES and TEEB, are prominently displayed in the offices of loggers and
which set a clear political agenda of protecting forests as forest staff alike, as well as the less overt but even more
property, promoting the participation of civil society and the important flow of ‘gifts’ from loggers to forest staff, and

Downloaded from http:/www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 145.101.26.2, on 18 Nov 2016 at 11:42:31, subject to the Cambridge Core terms of use, available at http:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S0376892916000436
6 H. Kopnina

the allocations are generally shaped by and an integral that restores depleted habitats can help break the vicious spiral
part of patrimonial relations. Fortmann (2005) argues that in which the poor are forced to overuse natural resources,
the assumptions that African officials are corrupt are often which in turn further impoverishes them (Elliott 2013).
informed by underlying dismissive attitudes that warn against In fact, biodiversity conservation and poverty alleviation
putting natural resources, especially wild animals, under have been demonstrated to go hand in hand. As an example,
village control. In fact, it was argued that categories such the prominent primatologist Jane Goodall (2015:23–24)
as illegality, corruption and poaching are constructed by reports on the activities of the Roots & Shoots programme
the ruling elites (Büscher 2015), and criminalizing poaching she helped to found over a decade ago in Tanzania. The
militarizes conservation (Duffy 2014). There are some ethical programme started by selecting a team of local villagers in
issues with this approach. order to discuss their needs and priorities, which included
There is a danger in excusing activities that lead to increased food production. This need was addressed through
environmental degradation on the grounds of social justice, the restoration of fertility to the overused farmland without
as well as in conflating neo-colonial practices, which are the use of chemical fertilizers. Roots & Shoots has encouraged
indeed ethically problematic, and any strict policies of the establishment of wood lots close to the villages, enabling
forest protection (Shoreman-Ouimet & Kopnina 2015). By villagers to acquire fuel-efficient stoves and build more
criticizing all types of forest policies designed for biodiversity hygienic toilets. Another expressed set of needs was for
conservation, those that oppose criminalizing poaching might improved financial security, health provision and better access
be overlooking the existential threat to forests’ non-human to education. In response, the programme initiated micro-
inhabitants. In equating wild animals with natural resources, credit programmes for environmentally sustainable projects
Fortmann (2005) and other critics of strict conservation in fact of the people’s own choice, which included tree nurseries. In
replicate the anthropocentric instrumental attitudes towards response to the need for better education, Roots & Shoots has
nature of the very neoliberal elites they profess to criticize. provided scholarships for girls to stay in school. Addressing
health concerns, with regards to population pressures, Roots
& Shoots has trained volunteers to provide family planning
REVISITING ECOLOGICAL JUSTICE
information. These types of actions have led to positive
While the criticism of top-down approaches to conservation as community responses and volunteer action, and the villagers
disadvantaging marginal communities is well placed in some agreed to set aside a buffer zone – a designated village forest
cases, the ethical judgement that condemns conservation is reserve – surrounding Gombe National Park. Within this
often hinged upon a robust anthropocentric bias (Kopnina forest regeneration zone, no hunting or tree felling is allowed,
2012; Kopnina 2016a; Kopnina 2016b). The insistence on the although limited access is granted for foraging for medicinal
moral primacy of social equality leaves open the question of the plants and mushrooms, beekeeping and dead wood collection.
non-instrumental value of biodiversity (Vucetich et al. 2015). Simultaneously, the forest reserve protects the clean water
Some points of the social justice critique are very pertinent supply to the villages. Over the past 10 years, the trees have
to the aim of successful biodiversity conservation, namely reached heights of over 20 feet, allowing chimpanzees and
the need to understand contemporary practices in a historical other animals considerable freedom of movement (Goodall
context. Yet other points can lead to ecological myopia and 2015:23). It is this type of programme that illustrates the
ethical double-standards. Vayda and Walters (1999) argue possibility of combining ecological and social objectives.
that human ecologists and political ecologists often refuse Yet such successful programmes are rarely discussed by
to privilege the ecological over the political or economic conservation critics.
forces, exposing a typical storyline of capitalist forces usurping Even less discussed is forest protection for the sake of non-
control of local resources. This storyline avoids the discussion humans, which is at present of low priority in policy agendas
of responsibility for interspecies genocide (Cafaro 2015). This (e.g. Miller et al. 2014; Sinclair 2014). The discussion of forest
requires a different moral sensitivity, without which the protection beyond the immediate social and economic agendas
‘cultural interpretation’ of poaching excuses severe violations has apparently erased consideration of the intrinsic value of
of nature in the name of social justice. The proponents of nature beyond its utility (Doak et al. 2015). A focus on prudent
exclusive social justice do not perceive the disappearance of forest use for people may serve to justify the destruction of
old-growth forests and the termination of multiple species as non-human forest inhabitants that hold little or no economic
problematic as long as the people themselves are not harmed or nutritional value to humans (Cafaro 2015).
(Cafaro & Primack 2014). Instead, strictly protected areas take
the fall for the purported moral aim of social equality, while
WAYS FORWARD: COMBINING CBC AND
exploitation of nature remains unchallenged (Crist 2015:93).
MARKET-BASED INSTRUMENTS
While the destructive reach of large landowners and
corporations is certainly globally profound, local people cause Where both ecological and environmental (i.e. social equality)
deforestation by clearing the forest for subsistence agriculture ‘camps’ coincide in their assessment is their critique of
and fuel or hunting for ‘bushmeat’ (wild animals), leading the commodification of nature. In attributing the causes of
to the ‘empty forest syndrome’ (Peterson 2013). Conservation ecological degradation to consumption and land acquisition

Downloaded from http:/www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 145.101.26.2, on 18 Nov 2016 at 11:42:31, subject to the Cambridge Core terms of use, available at http:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S0376892916000436
Commodification of natural resources and forest ecosystem services 7

practices associated with the consolidation of wealth and people; rather, people benefit from a nature that is conserved
growing inequity globally, its critics are observing that (Rolston 2016:279). Such synergies have the potential to
commodification is not only impermissible in terms of social engender a more helpful and ‘allied’ conversation regarding
and economic justice, but that it is also detrimental to issues that are critical for both social and ecological justice. It
environmental purposes (Sullivan 2009). is also crucial to recognize that such reconciliation should
Both social and ecological justice supporters have been not support the ‘business as usual’ scenario, which hides
at pains to work with and support conservation activities strong economic agendas behind the rhetoric of sustainable
and organizations, in part by highlighting the detrimental development and the need to find a necessary balance while
ecological outcomes of social injustices in conservation continuing exploitation.
contexts (Duffy et al. 2013; Shoreman-Ouimet & Kopnina Yet reconciliation will not always be easy. The problem
2015; S. Sullivan, personal communication 2015). Continuing is that, in some cases, synergies may either not be possible
dichotomization of social and ecological justice, both or will lead to bad compromises. We have yet to develop
intellectually and politically, may be the most pressing barrier an ethical framework for dealing with situations in which
to progressive change for multispecies flourishing (S. Sullivan, difficult decisions need to be made. We need to have an open
personal communication 2015). Critical social scientists who discussion – both at the public (involving local communities as
are highlighting the social and ecological inconsistencies key actors) and political (involving power-holders and policy-
associated with conservation alliances point out that policies makers) levels – about how to weigh social justice against
and practices that entrench economic inequality require ecological justice. Yet another stakeholder in this debate is
globally costly consumption practices (such as tourism and ourselves, academics, who could start by laying bare our own
trophy hunting in order to generate conservation revenue) biases and ideas of what justice entails.
and seem to amplify rather than shift this barrier (S. Sullivan, More points of conversion need to be developed between
personal communication 2015). the proponents of ecological and social justice (e.g. Shoreman-
Yet ecological justice should not simply be considered Ouimet & Kopnina 2015) for the use of landscapes that is truly
after social and economic justice are fully addressed (as sustainable in the long term. Practically, this requires the
they might never be), nor considered as subordinate to creation of more wildlife refuge areas and wildlife corridors,
anthropocentric interests (Kopnina 2012a). The instrumental ensuring ecological connectivity (e.g. Poiani et al. 2011;
view of the environment is akin to the dominant rhetoric of Sinclair 2015) as well as rewilding (e.g. Crist 2015; Shoreman-
sustainable development (Kopnina 2012b), which centres on Ouimet & Kopnina 2016). The more ecocentric framework of
social equality and economic equity across human generations forest protection promises to provide long-term benefits to
(WCED 1987). This anthropocentric view in relation to both both the human and non-human inhabitants of the forest,
top-down and CBC approaches renders the loss of biodiversity necessitating further exploration of what forms of governance
inconsequential as long as the ‘ecosystem services’ that benefit or food production systems are more effective at preserving
humanity remain intact (Cafaro & Primak 2014). Many species natural resources for future generations of both humans and
are unlikely to have an economic value, and their extinction is non-humans.
unlikely to affect ecosystem services (Vucetich et al. 2015).
Instead, many contend that ecological justice needs to be
CONCLUSION
served simultaneously and in equal measure to social justice
(Crist 2012; Crist & Kopnina 2014; Shoreman-Ouimet & Forest protection is currently premised on the process of
Kopnina 2015; Shoreman-Ouimet & Kopnina 2016; Strang commodification, which is dependent on top-down control
2016). This requires change in regarding human groups as and contingent with the profitable exploitation of ecological
the only beneficiaries of the exploitation of nature, as well as services, such as carbon sequestration and erosion and flood
a recognition of the value of the forest, in which extinction is control. Good governance, which is needed to protect forests
a great moral wrong (Cafaro & Primack 2014). Otherwise, the as food resources, necessarily requires the types of regimes
prevailing assumption of human entitlement to the benefits instituted by REDD, PES and TEEB, but scrutiny of
of nature will facilitate the conversion of the last remaining these is necessitated by concerns about social justice as well
wildernesses and traditional ways of living into ‘resources’, as ecological justice, which sees exploitation of the forest
masked by the high moral grounds of serving justice (Crist exclusively as a resource for human benefit as anthropocentric.
2015:93). Scholars that support social or ecological justice, or both,
In this context, research in which forests and agroforestry object to the economic capture approach because it promotes
systems can be managed as food provisioning systems presents social injustice or imbalances of power and demotes nature
forest as nothing more than exclusive feeding lots for one and non-human species to commodities.
species only. The ways forward include reconciliation of social This paper critically examined both top-down and CBC
and ecological objectives that emphasize – and hopefully fairly approaches to forest protection and offered alternative ways
weigh – the costs and benefits of forest conservation and the forward. Further research is needed of PES, REDD and
synergies between humanity’s and nature’s interests (Strang TEEB, considering that the evidence is somewhat mixed and
2016). Ideally, one does not need to sacrifice nature to benefit contradictory. Ethical tensions also need to be addressed, on

Downloaded from http:/www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 145.101.26.2, on 18 Nov 2016 at 11:42:31, subject to the Cambridge Core terms of use, available at http:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S0376892916000436
8 H. Kopnina

the one hand, regarding the question of the control and benefits presentation at British International Studies Association. 16–19
of forest exploitation by socially and economically powerful June, London, UK.
and marginal groups and, on the other hand, between human Büscher, B. & Fletcher, R. (2014) Conservation by accumulation.
and ecological interests. Forests can also be providers of food New Political Economy 19(1): 1–26.
for the most vulnerable groups, yet this should not be the Cafaro, P. (2015) Three ways to think about the sixth mass extinction.
Biological Conservation 192: 387–393.
only reason for protecting the forests. The forests themselves,
Cafaro, P. & Primack, R. (2014) Species Extinction is a Great Moral
the food security of all species within the forests, macro-level
Wrong: Sharing the Earth with other species is an important
drivers of unsustainability, namely local demographic change, human responsibility. Biological Conservation 170: 1–2.
and the potential subordination of forest protection by profit- Caine, K. J. (2013) Bourdieu in the north: practical understanding
driven exploitation also need to be taken into consideration. in natural resource governance. Canadian Journal of Soci-
The possibility that a global subsidy system for forest ology/Cahiers Canadiens de Sociologie 38(3): 333.
protection or the creation of self-sustaining local markets Crist, E. (2012) Abundant earth and population. In: Life on the
initiated by powerful mechanisms such as REDD, TEEB and Brink: Environmentalists confront Overpopulation, eds. P. Cafaro &
PES might in fact lead to systems that can more efficiently E. Crist, pp. 141–153. Athens, GA: University of Georgia Press.
protect biodiversity, both for human benefit and increasing a Crist, E. (2015) I walk in the world to love it. In: Protecting the
forest’s intrinsic value (Shoreman-Ouimet & Kopnina 2016). Wild: Parks and Wilderness, The Foundation for Conservation, eds.
G. Wuerthner, E. Crist & T. Butler, pp. 82–95. Washington, DC,
Such a system could provide livelihoods for both human and
and London, UK: The Island Press.
non-human species in the long term.
Crist, E. & Kopnina, H. (2014) Unsettling anthropocentrism.
Dialectical Anthropology 38: 387–396.
Daily, G. C., Polasky, S., Goldstein, J., Kareiva, P. M., Mooney,
FINANCIAL SUPPORT H. A., Pejchar, L, et al. (2009) Ecosystem services in decision
This research has not received any specific grant from any making: time to deliver. Frontiers in Ecology and the Environment
funding agency or commercial or not-for-profit sectors. 7: 21–28.
Doak, D. F., Bakker, V. J., Goldstein, B. E. & Hale, B. (2015) What
is the future of conservation? In: Protecting the Wild: Parks and
References Wilderness, The Foundation for Conservation eds., G. Wuerthner,
E. Crist & T. Butler, pp. 27–35. Washington, DC, and London,
Anderson, E. N. (2012) Tales best told out of school: traditional life- UK: The Island Press.
skills education meets modern science education. In: Anthropology Duffy, R. (2014) Waging a war to save biodiversity: the rise of
of Environmental Education, ed. H. Kopnina, pp. 12–24. New York, militarised conservation. International Affairs 90(4): 819–834.
NY: Nova Science Publishers. Duffy, R., Emslie, R. H. & Knight, M. H. (2013) Rhino poaching:
Balee, W. (1994) Footprints in the Forest: Ka’apor Ethnobotany – the how do we respond? Evidence on Demand, UK [www document].
Historical Ecology of Plant Utilization by an Amazonian People. URL http://www.evidenceondemand.info/rhino-poaching-
New York, NY: Columbia University Press. how-do-we-respond
Ban, N. C., Mills, M., Tam, J., Hicks, C. C., Klain, S., Stoeckl, Duffy, R., St John, F. A. V., Büscher, B. & Brockington, D. (2015)
N. et al. (2013) A social–ecological approach to conservation The militarization of anti-poaching: undermining long term goals?
planning: embedding social considerations. Frontiers in Ecology Environmental Conservation 42(4): 345–348.
and the Environment 11(4): 194–202. Easterly, W. (2006) The White Man’s Burden: Why the West’s Efforts
Baxter, B. (2005) A Theory of Ecological Justice. New York, NY: to Aid the Rest Have Done So Much Ill and So Little Good. New
Routledge. York, NY: The Penguin Group, Inc.
Beymer-Farris, B. A. & Bassett, T. J. (2012) The REDD menace: Elliott, J. (2013) An Introduction to Sustainable Development, London,
resurgent protectionism in Tanzania’s mangrove forests. Global UK: Routledge.
Environmental Change – Human and Policy Dimensions 22(2): 332– Engel, S., Pagiola, S. & Wunder, S. (2008) Designing payments for
341. environmental services in theory and practice: an overview of the
Bose, P., Arts, B. & van Dijk, H. (2012) ‘Forest governmentality’: issues. Ecological Economics 65: 663–674.
a genealogy of subject-making of forest-dependent ‘scheduled Escobar, A. (1996) Constructing nature: elements for a post-
tribes’ in India. Land Use Policy 29(3): 664–673. structuralist political ecology. In: Liberation Ecologies, eds. R. Peet
Brockington, D. (2002) Fortress Conservation. The Preservation of & M. Watts, pp. 46–68. London, UK: Routledge.
the Mkomazi Game Reserve. Bloomington, IN: Indiana University Escobar, A. (2006) Difference and conflict in the struggle over natural
Press. resources: a political ecology framework. Development 49(3): 6–13.
Brosius, P. (1999) Green dots, pink hearts: displacing politics from Fennell, D. A. (2008) Ecotourism and the myth of indigenous
the Malaysian rain forest. American Anthropologist 101(1): 36–57. stewardship. Journal of Sustainable Tourism 16(2): 129–149.
Brown, D., Schreckenberg, K., Bird, N., Cerutti, P., Del Gatto, F., Fortmann, L. (2005) What we need is a community Bambi: the
Diaw, C., et al. (2008) Legal Timber. Verification and Governance in perils and possibilities of powerful symbols. In: Communities and
the Forestry Sector. London, UK: Overseas Development Institute. Conservation: Histories and Politics of Community-Based Natural
Brown, M. (2009) Science in Democracy: Expertise, Institutions, and Resource Management, eds., P. J. Brosius, A. L. Tsing & C. Zerner,
Representation. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. pp. 195–205. Walnut Creek, CA: Alta Mira Press.
Büscher, B. (2015) “Rhino poaching is out of control!” Violence, Fraser, J., Frausin, V. & Jarvis, A. (2015) An intergenerational
heroes and the politics of hysteria in online conservation. Paper transmission of sustainability? Ancestral habitus and food

Downloaded from http:/www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 145.101.26.2, on 18 Nov 2016 at 11:42:31, subject to the Cambridge Core terms of use, available at http:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S0376892916000436
Commodification of natural resources and forest ecosystem services 9

production in a traditional agro-ecosystem of the Upper Guinea Marvier, M. (2014) A call for ecumenical conservation. Animal
Forest, West Africa. Global Environmental Change 31: 226–238. Conservation 17(6): 518–519.
FSC (2015) ForCES (Forest Certification for Ecosystem Services). Mehta, L., Leach, M. & Scoones, I. (2001) Editorial: environmental
Indonesia [www document]. URL http://forces.fsc.org/ governance in an uncertain world. IDS Bulletin 32(4): 1–9.
indonesia.26.htm Miller, B., Soulé, M. E. & Terborgh, J. (2014) ‘New conservation’
German, L., Karsenty, A. & Tiani, A.-M. (eds.) (2010) Governing or surrender to development? Animal Conservation 17(6): 509–
Africa’s Forests in a Globalized World. London, UK: Earthscan. 515.
Gómez-Baggethun, E. & Ruiz-Pérez, M. (2011) Economic valuation Milne, S. & Adams, W. (2012) Market masquerades: uncovering
and the commodification of ecosystem services. Progress in Physical the politics of community-level Payments for Environmental
Geography 35: 617–632. Services in Cambodia. Development and Change 43(1):
Goodall, J. (2015) Caring for people and valuing forests in Africa. 133–158.
In: Protecting the Wild: Parks and Wilderness, The Foundation for Neef, A. (2015) Sustainable rural development and livelihoods.
Conservation, eds. G. Wuerthner, E. Crist & T. Butler, pp. 21–26. In: Sustainability: Key Issues, eds. H. Kopnina & E. Shoreman-
Washington, DC, and London, UK: The Island Press. Ouimet, pp. 315–322. London, UK: Routledge.
Guha, R. & Alier, J. M. (2013) Varieties of Environmentalism: Essays Peterson, D. (2013) Talking about bushmeat. In: Ignoring Nature No
North and South. London, UK: Routledge. More: The Case for Compassionate Conservation, ed. M. Bekoff, pp.
Harvey, C. A., Chacón, M., Donatti, C. I., Garen, E., Hannah, L., 64–76. Chicago, IL: Chicago University Press.
Andrade, A. et al. (2013) Climate-smart landscapes: opportunities Poiani, K. A., Goldman, R. L., Hobson, J., Hoekstra, J. M. & Nelson,
and challenges for integrating adaptation and mitigation in tropical K. S. (2011) Redesigning biodiversity conservation projects
agriculture. Conservation Letters 7(2): 77–90. for climate change: examples from the field. Biodiversity and
Henley, D. (2011) Swidden farming as an agent of environmental Conservation 20(1): 185–201.
change: ecological myth and historical reality in Indonesia. Quan, J., Naess, L. O., Newsham, A., Sitoe, A., & Fernandez,
Environment and History 17: 525–554. M. C. (2014) Carbon forestry and climate compatible
Hiedanpaa, J. & Bromley, D. W. (2014) Payments for ecosystem development in Mozambique: a political economy analysis
services: durable habits, dubious nudges, and doubtful efficacy. [www document]. URL http://www.ids.ac.uk/publication/
Journal of Institutional Economics 10(2): 175–195. carbon-forestry-and-climate-compatible-development-in-
Hoffman, U. (ed.) (2013) Trade and environment review 2013: wake mozambique-a-political-economy-analysis
up before its too late – make agriculture truly sustainable now Rolston, H. (2016) Environmental ethics and environmental
for food security in a changing climate [www document]. URL anthropology. In: Handbook of Environmental Anthropology, pp.
http://unctad.org/en/PublicationsLibrary/ditcted2012d3_en. 276–287. New York, NY: Routledge.
pdf Schroth, G. & Harvey, C. A. (2007) Biodiversity conservation
Igoe, J. & Brockington, D. (2007) Neoliberal conservation: a brief in cocoa production landscapes: an overview. Biodiversity and
introduction. Conservation and Society 5(4): 432–449. Conservation 16(8): 2237–2244.
Jax, K., Barton, D. N., Chan, K. M., de Groot, R., Doyle, U., Eser, Shoreman-Ouimet, E. & Kopnina, H. (2015) Reconciling ecological
U. et al. (2013) Ecosystem services and ethics. Ecological Economics and social justice to promote biodiversity conservation. Biological
93: 260–268. Conservation 184: 320–326.
Kareiva, P. & Marvier, M. (2007) Conservation for the people. Shoreman-Ouimet, E. & Kopnina, H. (2016) Conservation and
Scientific American 297: 50–57. Culture: Beyond Anthropocentrism. New York, NY: Routledge
Kidner, D. (2014) Why ‘anthropocentrism’ is not anthropocentric. Earthscan.
Dialectical Anthropology 38: 465–480. Sinclair, A. R. E. (2014) Serengeti Story: Life and Science in the
Klooster, D. (2010) Standardizing sustainable development?: the World’s Greatest Wildlife Region. Oxford, UK: Oxford University
Forest Stewardship Council’s plantation policy review process as Press.
neoliberal environmental governance. Geoforum 41: 117–129. Sinclair, A. R. E. (2015) Protected areas are necessary for
Kopnina, H. (2012a) Towards conservational anthropology: conservation. In: Protecting the Wild: Parks and Wilderness,
addressing anthropocentric bias in anthropology. Dialectical The Foundation for Conservation, eds. G. Wuerthner, E. Crist
Anthropology 36(1): 127–146. & T. Butler, pp. 72–81. Washington, DC: The Island
Kopnina, H. (2012b) Education for sustainable development (ESD): Press.
the turn away from ‘environment’ in environmental education? Sivaramakrishnan, K. (1999) Modern Forests. Statemaking and
Environmental Education Research 18: 699–717. Environmental Change in Colonial Eastern India. Stanford, CA:
Kopnina, H. (2016a) Half the earth for people (or more)? Addressing Stanford University Press.
ethical questions in conservation. Biological Conservation 203: 176– Smith, D. J. (2007) A Culture of Corruption: Everyday Deception and
185. Popular Discontent in Nigeria. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University
Kopnina, H. (2016b) Wild animals and justice: the case of the dead Press.
elephant in the room. Journal of International Wildlife Law & Sponsel, L. (2014) Human impact on biodiversity: overview. In:
Policy 19(3): 219–235. Encyclopedia of Biodiversity, ed. S. A. Levin, pp. 137–152.
Lansing, S. (1991) Priests and Programmers: Technologies of Power Waltham, MA: Academic Press.
in the Engineered Landscape of Bali. Princeton, NJ: Princeton Strang, V. (2016) Justice for all: inconvenient truths – and
University Press. reconciliation – in human–non-human relations. In: Handbook
Li, T. M. (2007) Practices of assemblage and community forest of Environmental Anthropology, eds. H. Kopnina & E. Shoreman-
management. Economy and Society 36(2): 263–293. Ouimet, pp. 259–279. New York, NY: Routledge.

Downloaded from http:/www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 145.101.26.2, on 18 Nov 2016 at 11:42:31, subject to the Cambridge Core terms of use, available at http:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S0376892916000436
10 H. Kopnina

Sullivan, S. (2009) Green capitalism and the cultural poverty of Vayda, A. P. & Walters, B. (1999) Against political ecology. Human
constructing nature as service provider. Radical Anthropology 3: Ecology 27(1): 167–179.
18–27. Vira, B. (2015) Taking natural limits seriously: implications for
Sutton, S. G. & Tobin, R. C. (2009) Recreational fishers’ development studies and the environment. Development and
attitudes towards the 2004 rezoning of the Great Barrier Change 46: 762–776.
Reef Marine Park. Environmental Conservation 36, 245– von Hellermann, P. (2007) Things fall apart? Management,
252. environment and Taungya Farming in Edo State, Southern
TEEB (2010) The Economics of Ecosystems and Biodiversity: Ecological Nigeria. Africa 77(3): 371–392.
and Economic Foundations, ed. P. Kumar. London, UK: Earthscan. von Hellermann, P. (2016) ‘Good governance’, corruption, and forest
Temudo, M. P. (2012) “The white men bought the forests”: protection: critical insights from environmental anthropology.
conservation and contestation in Guinea-Bissau, Western Africa. In: The Routledge Handbook of Environmental Anthropology, eds.
Conservation Society 10: 354–366. H. Kopnina & E. Shoreman-Ouimet, pp. 302–315. London, UK:
Terborgh, J. (2015) Foreword. In: Protecting the Wild: Parks and Routledge.
Wilderness, The Foundation for Conservation, eds. G. Wuerthner, Vucetich, J., Bruskotter, J. & Nelson, M. (2015) Evaluating whether
E. Crist & T. Butler, pp. xi–viii. Washington, DC, and London, nature’s intrinsic value is an axiom of or anathema to conservation.
UK: The Island Press. Conservation Biology 29: 321–332.
The World Bank (2013) Regional Forest Law Enforcement WCED (1987) Brundtland Report. Our Common Future. World
and Governance (FLEG) initiatives [www document]. Commission on Environment and Development. Oxford: Oxford
URL http://www.worldbank.org/en/topic/forests/brief/fleg- University Press.
regional-forest-law-enforcement-governance West, P. (2006) Translation, value, and space: theorizing an
UNEP (2008) Payments for Ecosystem Services: Getting ethnographic and engaged environmental anthropology. American
started [www document]. URL http://www.unep.org/pdf/ Anthropologist 107(4): 632–642.
PaymentsForEcosystemServices_en.pdf West, P. & Brockington, D. (2012) Introduction: capitalism and the
UN-REDD (2015) UN-REDD programme [www document]. URL environment. Environment and Society: Advances in Research, 3(1):
http://www.un-redd.org/Home/tabid/565/Default.aspx 1–3.

Downloaded from http:/www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 145.101.26.2, on 18 Nov 2016 at 11:42:31, subject to the Cambridge Core terms of use, available at http:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S0376892916000436

You might also like