Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 16

Sharing the Shared Value: A Transaction

Cost Perspective on Strategic CSR Policies


in Global Value Chains

Aurélien Acquier, Bertrand Valiorgue &


Thibault Daudigeos

Journal of Business Ethics

ISSN 0167-4544

J Bus Ethics
DOI 10.1007/s10551-015-2820-0

1 23
Your article is protected by copyright and all
rights are held exclusively by Springer Science
+Business Media Dordrecht. This e-offprint
is for personal use only and shall not be self-
archived in electronic repositories. If you wish
to self-archive your article, please use the
accepted manuscript version for posting on
your own website. You may further deposit
the accepted manuscript version in any
repository, provided it is only made publicly
available 12 months after official publication
or later and provided acknowledgement is
given to the original source of publication
and a link is inserted to the published article
on Springer's website. The link must be
accompanied by the following text: "The final
publication is available at link.springer.com”.

1 23
Author's personal copy
J Bus Ethics
DOI 10.1007/s10551-015-2820-0

Sharing the Shared Value: A Transaction Cost Perspective


on Strategic CSR Policies in Global Value Chains
Aurélien Acquier1 • Bertrand Valiorgue2 • Thibault Daudigeos3

Received: 4 February 2015 / Accepted: 12 August 2015


 Springer Science+Business Media Dordrecht 2015

Abstract This paper explores the conditions favouring or to bypass the numerous difficulties involved in the imple-
inhibiting the implementation of strategic corporate social mentation of strategic CSR policies.
responsibility (CSR) policies in the context of global value
chains (GVCs). Using transaction cost theory (TCT), we
Keywords Global value chains  Strategic corporate
specify the economic and behavioural issues raised by
social responsibility  Transaction cost theory  Asset
strategic CSR policies. We show that the existence of
specificity  Governance structure
market rewards for such policies does not constitute a
solution per se, but tends to increase the difficulties that
Abbreviations
value chain members face. Bringing TCT into the analysis
CSR Corporate social responsibility
of the diffusion of strategic CSR policies in GVCs helps us
GVC Global value chain
to make different contributions. We first theoretically
MSI Multi-stakeholder initiative
identify some limiting conditions of strategic CSR policies
NGO Non-governmental Organisation
in GVCs. We also contribute to developing a more robust
TCT Transaction cost theory
theoretical perspective for CSR in GVC research, which
remains underdeveloped and mostly driven by empirical
case studies. Finally, we shed light on new research
questions and topics that could guide major theoretical and
empirical investigations in the capacity of GVCs members Introduction

A major issue for multinational corporations adopting


corporate social responsibility (CSR) policies is to find a
We sincerely thank the Editor Adam Lindgreen and the two balance between responsible practices and competitive
anonymous reviewers for their insightful reviews and comments initiatives to maintain a robust position in challenging
which have helped us to improve the paper. business environments (Lund-Thomsen and Lindgreen
2013). This topic has received special attention within the
& Bertrand Valiorgue
bertrand.valiorgue@udamail.fr strategic CSR corpus (McWilliams and Siegel 2001;
McWilliams et al. 2006; Porter and Kramer 2006, 2011),
Aurélien Acquier
aacquier@escpeurope.eu exhorting firms to balance offer and demand in the field of
CSR (Orlitzky et al. 2011; Crane et al. 2014). From this
Thibault Daudigeos
thibault.daudigeos@grenoble-em.com research perspective, firms adopt CSR policies to the extent
that they find customers or shareholders ready to offer a
1
ESCP Europe, Paris, France market premium for such policies (Burke and Logsdon
2
CRCGM, Ecole Universitaire de Management, 1996; McWilliams et al. 2006; Vogel 2006). These policies
Clermont-Ferrand, France are considered as strategic issues for creating ‘shared
3
Grenoble Ecole de Management, Grenoble, France value’ between firms and society, by setting up

123
Author's personal copy
A. Acquier et al.

policies and operating practices that enhance the assumptions of strategic CSR and the shared-value con-
competitiveness of a company while simultaneously cept, which rest on natural cooperation among stakeholders
advancing the economic and social conditions in the and the firm, are theoretically inconsistent with the other
communities in which it operates (Porter and Kramer dominant approach to strategy, which views the relation-
2011, p. 6). ship between the firm and its stakeholders as opportunistic
and conflictual (Levy 2008; Bair and Palpacuer 2012;
Despite its fast academic growth, the strategic CSR
Soundararajan and Brown 2014).
corpus tends to ignore a key dimension in the emergence of
In this article, we wish to contribute to this theoretical
a balance between a CSR offer and demand: it does not
debate. We agree with Crane et al. (2014) that the strategic
take into account the managerial specificity of situations
CSR corpus needs theoretical elaboration and coherence in the
where introducing CSR policies involves not a single
way it approaches the implementation of CSR policies in the
company but a larger collection of firms involved in global
context of GVCs. To achieve this, we rely on the analytical
value chains (GVCs) (Maloni and Brown 2006; Scherer
apparatus developed by transaction cost theory (TCT), which
and Palazzo 2007, 2008, 2011; Andersen and Skjoett-
explores the conditions for the emergence of new markets and
Larsen 2009). This shortcoming is problematic as a rising
intra- and inter-firm systems of cooperation (Williamson
number of CSR issues and policies unfold in such organ-
1991; King 2007; Williamson 2008). By bringing TCT into
isational contexts. In the 1990s, Nike faced a public
the analysis of the diffusion of CSR policies in GVCs, we
backlash over the working conditions in foreign contractor
make various contributions. First, we increase the theoretical
companies in Indonesia, Vietnam and Pakistan. It had to
coherence of the strategic CSR stream and thus address one of
manage the implementation of CSR policies involving
its main shortcomings. Second, we contribute to developing a
legally independent firms located in foreign countries
robust theoretical perspective for CSR in GVC research,
(Arnold and Bowie 2003; Locke et al. 2007; Boje and Khan
which remains underdeveloped and so far dominated by
2009). Likewise, the Rana Plaza disaster in Bangladesh,
empirical case studies (Wahl and Bull 2013). Third, we pro-
which killed over 1200 employees in 2013, occurred in the
vide a better explanation of the specific organisational chal-
context of a complex organisational arrangement involving
lenges raised by the implementation of CSR policies in GVCs,
multinational brands from the fashion industry working
and we propose an assessment of the regulatory potential (and
with local contractors and subcontractors (Lund-Thomsen
limits) of strategic CSR. In particular, the existence of trans-
and Lindgreen 2013; Perry et al. 2014). In this context,
action and cooperation costs explains the difficulties in
implementing CSR policies implies various forms of
implementing CSR initiatives, and shows that strategic CSR
cooperation and coordination with a large collection of
does not constitute a magic answer to the private and auton-
participants, suppliers, contractors, distributors, clients,
omous regulation of GVCs (King 2007; Lund-Thomsen and
strategic allies and stakeholders (Gereffi et al. 2005; Mal-
Lindgreen 2013).
oni and Brown 2006; Soundararajan and Brown 2014). In
The rest of the paper is structured as follows. ‘‘Theo-
such organisational and institutional contexts, the central
retical background’’ section reviews the literature on
issue is no longer to know how a vertically integrated
strategic CSR, GVCs and TCT. ‘‘Implementing strategic
corporation can gain a competitive advantage via strategic
CSR policies in GVCs: economic and behavioural issues’’
CSR policies, but to know how a collection of legally
section explores the economic and behavioural issues
independent business organisations located in different
underlying the implementation of CSR policies in GVCs.
parts of the world can collectively implement and give
Section ‘‘Asset specificity and GVCs governance structures
value to a series of scattered socially responsible practices
as moderating variables’’ identifies two mediating variables
(Spence and Rinaldi 2012; Soundararajan and Brown
that affect these issues and increase the difficulties of
2014).
implementing CSR policies in GVCs. In ‘‘Contributions
Among critics of strategic CSR, several authors recently
and research perspectives’’ section, we develop the main
contested the theoretical value of the strategic CSR
implications of this work and present research perspectives,
research stream for being overly optimistic about the
before drawing conclusions in ‘‘Conclusion’’ section.
ability of GVCs to self-regulate via the implementation of
CSR policies (Palpacuer 2008; Lund-Thomsen and Lind-
green 2013; Crane et al. 2014; Soundararajan and Brown Theoretical Background
2014). They argue that strategic CSR policies are not
naturally endorsed by companies along a GVC, because Strategic CSR
political complexities, conflicts and contradictions among
chain members and numerous stakeholders are not easily The field of strategic CSR encompasses various perspec-
bypassed (Vogel 2006). For these authors, the behavioural tives exploring the economic and strategic—rather than

123
Author's personal copy
Sharing the Shared Value: A Transaction Cost Perspective on Strategic CSR Policies in Global…

ethical—drivers for CSR. As such, it keeps its distance and economic perspectives and TCT (McWilliams and
both from normative perspectives, which focus on the Siegel 2001; McWilliams et al. 2006; King 2007).
ethical dimension of CSR (Donaldson and Preston 1995), These perspectives have implicitly taken the large and
and from institutional perspectives, which consider how vertically integrated firm as their object of analysis, and
political, cultural and economic institutions frame firms’ thus have either ignored or bypassed a major transfor-
CSR initiatives and policies (Campbell 2007; Matten and mation in contemporary business landscapes: the out-
Moon 2008). Strategic CSR investigates how market and sourcing and fragmentation of production processes
competitive logics shape CSR behaviours, and how firms (Kaplinsky 2004; Acquier et al. 2011). This fragmenta-
can gain competitive advantage by combining economic tion of production processes and dispersion at a global
and social value creation (Grayson and Hodges 2004; scale of independent business partners increases the
Vogel 2006). From this perspective, complexity of CSR policies (Freeman and Liedtka 1997).
Indeed, implementing a strategic CSR policy does not
managers conduct a cost/benefit analysis to determine
constitute a simple trade-off between the costs and
the level of resources to devote to CSR activities/
benefits of such policy; it engages many different actors
attributes. […] They assess the market demand for
and stakeholders located in different institutional contexts
CSR and also evaluate the cost of satisfying this
who must find and implement new coordination patterns.
demand. […] CSR can be an integral element of a
GVCs increase the complexity of setting-up global and
firm’s business and corporate-level differentiation
efficient CSR policies, as CSR issues expand beyond the
strategies (McWilliams et al. 2006, p. 6).
traditional limits of ownership and control (Vurro et al.
Translated into the language of business, this means 2009).
While the inclination of strategic CSR to find arguments
transforming social problems into business opportu-
in favour of CSR is understandable, we contend that the
nities, thereby contributing to the solving of critical
omission of outsourcing and GVCs as a central contem-
societal challenges while simultaneously driving
porary organisational reality constitutes a major limitation
greater profitability (Crane et al. 2014, p. 130).
of the present literature, which severely limits its
Research related to strategic CSR has explored the explanatory power. Accordingly, strategic CSR needs to
relationship between CSR and financial performance better integrate the main difficulties that actors engaged in
(Margolis and Walsh 2003; Arouri and Pijourlet 2015) and a GVC may encounter when they want to implement and
opened the black box of this relationship by exploring the give value to CSR policies (Tsutsui and Lim 2015).
business case of CSR (Daudigeos and Valiorgue 2011).
Authors try to specify which kind of competitive gains (in GVCs and CSR
terms of reputational gains, market innovations, cost
reductions, increased employee motivation. etc.) can be In contrast to the literature on strategic CSR, that on GVCs
obtained from CSR initiatives (Burke and Logsdon 1996; has explored how international trade and the global divi-
Husted and Allen 2007). The vision that CSR should be sion of labour have led to an increased complexification
better articulated with competitive strategy has also led to and interconnectedness of production processes. The con-
various conceptual and empirical developments. Concepts cept of GVCs refers to the integration of internationally
such as the ‘triple bottom line’ (Elkington 1994) or ‘cre- fragmented activities, where value creation is organised
ating shared value’ (Porter and Kramer 2006, 2011) have among legally independent businesses, based in different
been put forth not only to raise managerial awareness of countries and linked to one another by more or less
social and environmental issues, but also to practically recurrent supply, production or distributed commercial
explore business models that simultaneously drive eco- transactions (Gereffi et al. 2005). Some authors prefer the
nomic, social and environmental value creation (Daudigeos term ‘Global Production Network’, believing it better
and Valiorgue 2010). Following this call, research on describes the complex relational networks (not simply
social business (Yunus et al. 2010) or markets at the bottom linear chain) composed of business partners and secondary
of the pyramid (Prahalad 2009) explores business models stakeholders (Ernst and Ravenhill 1999; Dicken et al.
that combine social and economic value creation in 2001). From this perspective, GVCs are seen as politically
developing economies (Nidumolu et al. 2009). Other works contested organisational fields, driven by major power
have explored strategic CSR initiatives under the lens of asymmetries. Using sociological and critical perspectives,
‘mainstream’ strategy theories, such as the Resource-Based this research perspective shows how dominant actors in
View (Aragon-Correa and Sharma 2003), dynamic capa- GVCs produce and reproduce their dominance through
bilities (Russo and Fouts 1997; Marcus and Anderson market, political and ideological influences (Levy 2008;
2006), stakeholder theory (Harrison and Freeman 1999) Bair and Palpacuer 2012).

123
Author's personal copy
A. Acquier et al.

Instead of focusing on a single organisation, research on generates transaction costs and coordination problems
GVCs takes industry and international value chains (in- between business partners (Williamson 1996). Governance
stead of single companies) as the primary units of analysis. schemes are thus required to mitigate the risks of fraud and
Within this stream, a significant amount of work has deception among partners (Williamson 1991).
focused on the economic structure and governance mech- Three main categories of transaction costs are generally
anisms of GVCs. Based on TCT, Gereffi and colleagues proposed by TCT: the cost of finding business partners, the
have identified five main types of GVCs and governance cost of negotiating agreements and the cost of monitoring
mechanisms, depending on the presence, location and role and enforcing compliance with agreements (Shelanski and
of lead firms among the different business partners (Gereffi Klein 1995). In some cases, transaction costs are too high
1999; Gereffi et al. 2005). and the use of market mechanisms is prohibited. This sit-
A central macro-economic debate within the literature uation can be observed in situations where there are fre-
concerns ‘economic and social upgrading processes’, i.e. quent transactions and there is greater asset specificity.
the ways in which local corporations and developing Specific assets are non-redeployable physical and human
countries capture economic value, and stimulate economic investments that are specialised and unique to a task. Four
and social development, through their engagement in categories are generally identified: site specificity, physical
GVCs (Gereffi 2005; Gereffi and Lee 2014). While the asset specificity, human asset specificity and dedicated
traditional literature on GVCs has often implicitly assumed assets. These assets have a value only within the relation-
that economic involvement in GVCs would naturally lead ship between contracting parties, and prove hard to rede-
to economic and social upgrading, there is a growing ploy and value for other purposes or with other commercial
recognition that the rights of workers and the quality of parties. Asset specificity involves an increased dependence
their employment are not natural by-products of belonging among business partners and increases the risk of ‘hold-up’
to GVCs (Barrientos et al. 2011; Barrientos 2013). As a (Holmström and Roberts 1998; Masten and Saussier 2000).
result, researchers have begun to pay attention to CSR as Hold-up is a situation in which the parties obtain mutual
one potential factor in such upgrading processes (Tsutsui benefits from cooperating, but all have an interest in min-
and Lim 2015). This sub-field is dominated by practice- imising their contribution and in maximising their own
oriented research (Wahl and Bull 2013), revealing the profit to their partners’ detriment—or in taking advantage
limits of CSR initiatives on GVCs by pointing out the of an investment so as to maximise their bargaining power
inherent tensions between lead firms and the other eco- over that of their partners. The phenomenon is due to the
nomic actors of the chain, from both compliance and fact that the parties undertaking to collaborate remain
cooperation perspectives (Lund-Thomsen and Lindgreen legally independent—i.e. owners of their assets—and
2013). According to GVC scholars, there is a need to better constitute autonomous decision-making centres, the beha-
characterise such difficulties and to analyse how chain viour of which can change over time according to each
members bypass them (Knudsen 2013). GVCs scholars actor’s interest. In this context, transaction costs dramati-
must achieve a greater theoretical integration in order to cally rise with asset specificity, because partners must
better assess the potential of CSR initiatives as a regulatory engage ‘‘special efforts to design an exchange that has
tool (Wahl and Bull 2013). good continuity properties’’ (Williamson 1981, p. 555).
Asset specificity, opportunism and transaction costs can
TCT be softened with specific governance structures such as
joint ventures, long-term contractual relationships, etc.
TCT has played a central role in understanding the delin- (Ménard 1996; Menard 2000). From this perspective,
eation of firm and market boundaries. If we view markets GVCs can be described as examples of hybrid governance
and hierarchies as alternative coordination modes, one of structures, between ‘pure’ market and ‘pure’ hierarchy
the main focuses of TCT is to understand on what basis (Williamson 1991; Ménard 1996). Using TCT, Gereffi
managers decide to internalise some business operations et al. (2005) have identified five main governance mecha-
and to outsource others to subcontractors and business nisms to treat asset specificity, opportunism and transaction
partners (Coase 1937, 1992; Williamson and Winter 1993). costs in the context of global inter-connected production
In explaining this, TCT throws light on why business processes. These governance structures permit GVC
partners rely on arm’s-length market relationships to pro- members to develop mutually beneficial exchanges and
duce a product or service in some cases, and on adminis- efficient inter-firm systems of coordination on a global
trative and hierarchical mechanisms in others. Based on scale.
assumptions of imperfect information, and the limited Recently, some authors have extended the scope of TCT
rationality, uncertainty and opportunistic behaviours of beyond economic transactions, to explore the specific
economic actors, TCT argues that any economic activity cooperation and transactional problems raised by business

123
Author's personal copy
Sharing the Shared Value: A Transaction Cost Perspective on Strategic CSR Policies in Global…

and society issues. For example, King (2007) analyses abandonment of certain functions (increasing the skills and
cooperation between firms and their non-commercial competences of chain members) and chain upgrading
stakeholders (i.e. Non-Governmental Organisations (changing the overall pattern of activities and institutions
(NGOs), International Organisations, local environmental of the industry). All these changes involved in the imple-
associations, etc.) through the lens of transaction costs. mentation of a CSR policy inevitably incur costs that GVC
King considers that firms and stakeholders encounter dif- members have to take on board.
ficulties in cooperating because there are ‘cooperation
Proposition 1 Implementing CSR policies in GVCs gen-
costs’ that have to be overcome. These costs are composed
erates organisational costs for chain members.
of three parts: the cost of identifying relevant social and
environmental issues and related stakeholders; the cost of
negotiating agreement with these stakeholders and the cost Transaction Costs: Redesigning Contractual Arrangements
of monitoring and enforcing compliance with agreements. with Business Partners
In this way, King follows the position of Coase, who argues
that firms and stakeholders can obtain mutually beneficial Developing and implementing CSR policies generates
exchange through direct and private negotiations between transaction costs. Indeed, implementing CSR policies leads
these actors, but that costs get in the way and actors have to to an evolution and transformation of existing contractual
deal with them. arrangements between parties. GVC members need to
redefine the division of labour and responsibilities among
existing chain members. For a global brand in the clothing
Implementing Strategic CSR Policies in GVCs: industry, introducing criteria for workplace safety in third-
Economic and Behavioural Issues world countries implies rewriting existing contracts to
allocate responsibility to clients and suppliers, and
In this section, we integrate the inputs from the TCT and designing monitoring mechanisms accordingly. In other
the GVC literature to identify the difficulties associated cases, implementing CSR policies will also require existing
with implementing strategic CSR policies in GVCs. We contracts to be severed, switching to new suppliers and
classify these difficulties into two distinct categories: eco- introducing new actors along the GVC—external certifi-
nomic (‘‘Economic issues’’ section) and behavioural issues cation bodies, auditors, partners for developing new tech-
(‘‘Behavioural threats’’ section). Figure 1 offers a graphic nologies, new suppliers or distributors, etc. (Reinecke et al.
representation of the argument. 2012). Incorporating these new actors generates transaction
costs, as GVC members have to identify trustworthy and
Economic Issues competent partners, negotiate contracts and enforce com-
pliance mechanisms. Recent work has shed some light on
Implementing CSR policies in GVCs involves many this phenomenon in the specific case of coffee GVCs. They
changes and transformations, which inevitably generate show how the requirements of Western firms in terms of
costs. Three types of costs can be pinpointed: (i) organisa- technical transfer, certification and product upgrading
tional costs; (ii) transaction costs with business partners increase the transaction costs in the value chain, and how
and (iii) cooperation costs with secondary stakeholders. multinational coffee traders tend to pass such costs onto the
farmers further along the chain (Neilson 2008, Wahl and
Organisational Costs: Transformations of Productive Bull 2013). Implementing a CSR policy requires new
Processes contracts to be drafted and/or old contracts made more
complicated, with the modifications generating many
When firms involved in a GVC want to implement CSR ‘transaction costs’ that actors along the value chain have to
policies, the first costs originate in the investments that take on board.
these firms must make in order to conceive and realise Proposition 2 Implementing CSR policies in GVCs gen-
operational changes. In a recent study, Gereffi and Lee erates transaction costs among existing and new chain
documented the different changes that chain members must members.
make in order to integrate local stakeholder needs and
implement CSR policies along a GVC (Gereffi 2005; Cooperation Costs: Identifying and Reaching Agreement
Gereffi and Lee 2014). They identified four major areas: with Secondary Stakeholders
product transformations (moving into more sophisticated
and responsible product lines); productive process The implementation of strategic CSR policies in GVCs
improvements (reorganising the production system and requires not only the development of new sets of contracts
introducing more responsible technologies); creation or and relationships with economic partners, but also

123
Author's personal copy
A. Acquier et al.

Fig. 1 Impact of asset Asset


specificity and GVC structure specificity
on economic and behavioural
issues
P5
P1 – Organisational costs

Economic costs
P2 – Transaction costs

Strategic CSR P3 – Cooperation costs


in GVC

Behavioural threats P4 – investment


sharing and profit
appropriation

P6

GVC structure

coordination with secondary and non-business stakeholders As for the transactions established between firms in a
(Clarkson 1995). These stakeholders may include diverse GVC, cooperation with secondary stakeholders is far from
actors operating at various levels (e.g. international being a cost-free and spontaneous process (King 2007).
organisations, national governments, NGOs, trade unions, Using TCT phraseology, cooperation costs with secondary
advocacy groups, local business associations, community stakeholders refer to the costs of identifying relevant and
organisations and religious groups (Lund-Thomsen and legitimate social issues, and the associated stakeholders.
Lindgreen 2013). They do not entertain formal contractual Subsequent to this identification, it is necessary to define a
links with the company; interacting and coordinating with response designed to meet the stakeholders’ expectations—
them is distinctively complex, as the relationships between which correspond to the costs of negotiating agreement. A
the firm and secondary stakeholders cannot be mediated by conclusion needs eventually to be reached, implemented
either commercial contracts or administrative mechanisms and monitored; this is the cost of monitoring and enforcing
(Eesley and Lenox 2006). Chain members must develop compliance with agreements (King 2007). Working and
horizontal forms of collaboration with such stakeholders. cooperating with secondary stakeholders inevitably gener-
Controlling and predicting behaviours is also made difficult ates cooperation costs, and this category of costs is gen-
by the plurality and heterogeneity of the stakeholders, and erally obscured, but turns out to be central in the
the fact that the parties do not directly derive profit from implementation of any CSR policies in GVCs.
the social issue, which makes their behaviour atypical
Proposition 3 Implementing CSR policies in GVCs gen-
(Lund-Thomsen and Nadvi 2010; Rivera-Santos and Rufı́n
erates cooperation costs between chain members and
2010). Beyond the inherent political complexity of navi-
secondary stakeholders.
gating through such heterogeneous networks of stake-
holders, GVC members may be faced with contradictory
values and expectations on social issues, such as child Behavioural Threats
labour (Ruwanpura and Roncolato 2006; Khan et al. 2007;
Neilson and Pritchard 2011). Establishing cooperation with For strategic CSR scholars, market premiums can cover the
secondary stakeholders presupposes selecting a relevant organisational, transaction and cooperation costs of
social issue from among all the possible problems, recog- strategic CSR, and push firms to implement CSR policies.
nising the stakeholders concerned, understanding what they In the specific context of GVCs, these market premiums for
expect and appraising their power as well as the urgency CSR policies do not constitute a sufficient condition, due to
and legitimacy of the claims expressed (Mitchell et al. opportunistic behaviours. These behavioural issues arise
1997; de Bakker and den Hond 2008). from the threats of conflicts related to how investments and

123
Author's personal copy
Sharing the Shared Value: A Transaction Cost Perspective on Strategic CSR Policies in Global…

profits generated by the CSR policy are shared among Asset Specificity and GVCs Governance Structures
chain members. The GVC literature provides empirical as Moderating Variables
evidence of situations where specific actors are expected to
cover a disproportionate amount of the additional costs Implementing CSR policies in GVCs can be called into
incurred in implementing CSR initiatives without receiving question by the existence of costs generated by such ini-
a similar share of the profit generated. For example, Barri- tiatives, as well as by the threats of conflicts of interests
entos (2013) describes situations where international buyers and opportunistic behaviours between chain members.
from Western countries impose labour codes on their sup- Mobilising the TCT theoretical apparatus, we show in the
pliers without providing any support for compliance costs, following paragraphs that economic costs and behavioural
while squeezing their prices. Likewise, Ruwampara and threats are moderated by two elements: the specificity of
Wrigley (2011) have shown that Sri Lankan clothing man- assets that chain members may have to develop (‘‘Impact
ufacturers that display high commitment to social and of asset specificity on economic issues’’ section) and GVC
environmental policies do not enjoy any economic rewards governance structures (‘‘Impact of GVC structures on
or clear economic incentives from their clients. In such sit- behavioural threats’’ section).
uations, how should the sharing of investments and the
market premiums for CSR policies be organised, when dif- Impact of Asset Specificity on Economic Issues
ferent and independent business organisations are involved?
Members of GVCs come up against the classic issue of Implementing CSR policies entails initiatives and invest-
‘hold-up’ (Holmström and Roberts 1998; Masten and ments by chain members to adapt their production pro-
Saussier 2000), where certain firms along the value chain cesses, re-coordinate themselves and reach agreements
benefit more than others from the economic value created with secondary stakeholders. Formulated in TCT vocabu-
by the strategic CSR policy. The initiative may collectively lary, investments needed for implementing CSR policies
generate economic value, but chain members have to share result in the creation of more or less specific assets (Wil-
this economic value fairly. If one actor captures a dispro- liamson 1991). Such CSR-specific assets may be physical
portionate amount of the value collectively created, the (as in the case of material for evaluating pollution), human
cooperation among partners will be broken, and other chain (via, for instance, hiring sustainable-development man-
members are likely to give up on the CSR initiative or to agers) or organisational and intangible (through creating
engage in cheating, fraud or deception. Such a situation is certificates, processes and behavioural standards). They
empirically met in GVCs (Lund-Thomsen and Lindgreen may be particular to a single firm or to several firms in the
2013), with empirical studies uncovering auditing fraud by value chain, with the firms involved sharing their know-
local Chinese suppliers (Wilshaw et al. 2013; Egels-Zan- how and resources so as to produce and coordinate them-
dén 2014) and within client organisations themselves selves in a socially responsible way.
(Lund-Thomsen et al. 2012). When the efforts of GVC members to implement a CSR
Sharing the investments required to implement a policy necessitate the involvement of specific assets, the
strategic CSR policy and the value collectively created by transaction and cooperation costs associated with the pol-
the enforcement of such a policy are two central issues in icy will dramatically increase. Indeed, specific investments
GVCs. If GVC members fail to tackle these behavioural must be protected and chain members must have contrac-
issues, no strategic CSR initiatives will emerge. tual guarantees that those investments will lead to eco-
nomic compensation. Chain members need to be confident
Proposition 4 Implementing CSR policies in GVCs tends
that their business partners along the chain will provide
to generate behavioural threats related to a dispropor-
them with an ongoing stream of payments for the specific
tionate distribution of investment and profit among chain
investments made. However, once a GVC member has
members.
made investments, other business partners will have little
Implementing CSR policies in the context of GVCs incentive to provide any such payments. In this case, chain
generates many costs that chain members have to take on members have to protect the specific investments for which
board. The existence of a premium paid by customers and/ they are responsible, through contractual arrangements that
or shareholders for CSR policies does not constitute a will guarantee they will receive payments. This tends to
solution per se; on the contrary, it is the source of beha- increase transaction costs—especially ex-post transaction
vioural threats that can slow down or even block the costs between chain members, who are often located in
implementation of CSR policies. Table 1 synthesises the different institutional and legal contexts (Young 2006;
various issues involved in the implementation of CSR Scherer and Palazzo 2011). In such contexts, the costs of
policies in GVCs. monitoring and eventually contesting contractual

123
Author's personal copy
A. Acquier et al.

Table 1 Nature and range of issues associated with the implementation of CSR policies in GVCs
Nature of the issues Range of issues Definition

Economic costs Organisational costs Costs and investments associated with designing and implementing CSR policies
Transaction costs Costs of identifying new business partners, (re)negotiating contracts and monitoring performance
Cooperation costs Costs of identifying stakeholders, negotiating compromises and monitoring performance
Behavioural threats Investment sharing Threats owing to a disproportionate distribution of investments among chain members
Profit appropriation Threats owing to a disproportionate distribution of profits among chain members

agreements are high, as business partners belong to dif- policies (Russo and Perrini 2010; Lund-Thomsen and
ferent systems of law. Lindgreen 2013; Soundararajan and Brown 2014). By
The same phenomenon can be observed for cooperation GVCs governance structures, we refer to the configuration
costs with secondary stakeholders. GVCs members can of GVCs in terms of coordination and division of labour.
negotiate and reach agreement on responsible behaviours One particular aspect is the existence of a focal, pivot or
with their stakeholders through developing specific assets dominant firm within the value chain, enjoying high bar-
dedicated to the treatment of a specific environmental or gaining power and able to impose certain standards of
social issue. Nothing guarantees that after this agreement, behaviour or pricing conditions on the other firms, and to
stakeholders and their representatives will not ask for new govern their relations (Kaplinsky and Morris 2001; Gereffi
engagements and investments, and push chain members to et al. 2005; Crook and Combs 2007). This type of con-
invest in other assets. GVCs members must secure their figuration can be found in, for instance, the textile or the
relationships with secondary stakeholders through agree- agro-food industry, with large international buyers inter-
ments and joint projects that lead to an increase in coop- acting with a wide network of dispersed suppliers (Elms
eration costs. and Low 2013). Such ‘captive value chains’ (Gereffi et al.
2005) constitute a paradoxical configuration for the
Proposition 5 The more specific the assets involved in
implementation of strategic CSR policies.
the implementation of strategic CSR policies are, the more
On one hand, the presence of a highly visible lead firm
they will increase transaction and cooperation costs.
makes it easier for secondary stakeholders—such as NGOs
Reducing asset specificity is thus key to reducing transac- and advocacy movements—to target the lead firm and
tion costs and securing behaviours with secondary stake- blame it for irresponsible practices within the supply chain
holders. Standards, norms and labels are highly relevant in this (Bair and Palpacuer 2012). Likewise, through its power,
regard, as they allow the ‘despecification’ of the investments the lead firm can more easily organise and control trans-
that GVC members have to undertake, or the securement of a actions, and put pressure on suppliers to comply with rules,
fair return for the investments—as in fair trade. For example, it responsibility standards and CSR policies (Gereffi et al.
would be very risky for farmers to switch to growing organic 2005; Vurro et al. 2009).
food without the existence of any label or standard: they would On the other hand, such a configuration limits the scope
have to make significant investments in the form of organi- and implementation of CSR policies, because it increases
sation and transaction costs (such as removing chemicals from behavioural threats. As the dominant firm has the power
their processes, and finding new clients and retail stores). They and capacity to impose pricing conditions and behavioural
would also have to bear the risk that such investments were not standards, it is in a position to derive most benefits from
seen as appropriate responses by environmentally aware strategic CSR policies (Crook and Combs 2007; Stigzelius
customers and stakeholders. In such situations, labels are and Mark-Herbert 2009; Kaplinsky 2013). Weak firms in
likely to reduce transaction and cooperation costs by provid- the value chain both depend on this central actor and resist
ing a predefined list of investments, and a guarantee that such being fully committed, since the CSR programme tends to
investments can be re-deployed and will have a value for other make them more dependent on—and held captive by—a
business partners and stakeholders who adhere to the same firm that may grab all the benefits of the initiative for itself
standards. (Baden et al. 2009; Locke et al. 2009; Lund-Thomsen and
Lindgreen 2013). For instance, some leading firms ask their
Impact of GVC Structures on Behavioural Threats suppliers to change their employment policies, and force
them to be more socially responsible by hiring permanent,
GVC governance structures constitute a second variable full-time employees and paying compensation after lay-
that has an important impact on the implementation of CSR offs, but they do not guarantee sufficient work throughout

123
Author's personal copy
Sharing the Shared Value: A Transaction Cost Perspective on Strategic CSR Policies in Global…

the year. For these suppliers, it becomes financially extend the scope of strategic CSR to the context of GVCs,
unsustainable to continue with such responsible employ- and specify the limiting conditions of strategic CSR
ment policies in their factories (Lund-Thomsen 2008; initiatives.
Lund-Thomsen and Lindgreen 2013). In this case, the lead Strategic CSR scholars have clearly demonstrated that
firm enjoys the value of the strategic CSR initiative, but the implementing a CSR policy involves costs (McWilliams
cost and the burden are outsourced to suppliers (Kaplinsky et al. 2006; Vogel 2006; Porter and Kramer 2011), but they
2013). do not give explanations for the nature and origins of these
Owing to their power, lead firms in the GVC can thus costs, and tend to focus on one type of costs: organisational
seek to transfer the burden of most of the CSR investments costs. We contribute to this debate by providing a theo-
onto other chain members, and take the premium that retical specification of the costs associated with CSR in
customers or shareholders are willing to pay in order to see GVC, which take the form of organisational costs, trans-
the implementation of a CSR policy (Kaplinsky 2013; action costs and cooperation costs. Doing so, we integrate
Lund-Thomsen and Lindgreen 2013). Such phenomena are into strategic CSR theory the fact that we live in a world of
major threats in the implementation of CSR policies in positive transaction/cooperation costs (Coase 1992; King
GVCs—as, for some firms, it means implementing socially 2007) and that these costs must be taken into consideration
responsible practices and making disproportionate efforts when members of value chains implement a strategic CSR
without benefiting from guarantees on the returns on their policy. We have also shown that organisational costs can
investments. The literature on supply chain management be considered as ‘the tip of the iceberg’, and strategic CSR
has documented these aspects and has shown that scholars have to investigate transaction and cooperation
depending on the dependency between chain members, costs in the implementation of CSR policies.
lead firms tend to take a disproportionate amount of profit Another contribution to the strategic CSR literature is
(Crook and Combs 2007). Because of the power of the lead related to market premiums and their capacity to cover the
firm, weak actors in the chain may be forced to adopt the costs of CSR initiatives. Such premiums appear as a nec-
CSR policy, but are likely to try to resist or adopt deceptive essary but not sufficient condition for strategic CSR poli-
behaviours such as fraud, decoupling and ceremonial cies to be implemented in GVCs. Market rewards for CSR
adoption (Meyer and Rowan 1977) in order to limit the policies certainly push some value chain members to make
amount of specific investment required to satisfy client changes in their ways of thinking and acting, but they also
requirements. create problems as the value collectively created by the
implementation of the CSR policy must be fairly shared
Proposition 6 Lead firms push GVCs members to
(Ponte and Gibbon 2005; Kaplinsky 2013; Soundararajan
implement strategic CSR initiatives and tend to increase
and Brown 2014). Any attempt to capture a dispropor-
behavioural threats.
tionate amount of value or to minimise investments is
likely to break cooperation among actors (Kaplinsky 2013).
Market premiums for CSR policies open up alternatives,
Contributions and Research Perspectives but can lead to behavioural threats between chain members
and prevent the emergence of such policies. They have an
In this section, we develop our contributions to strategic ambiguous nature and do not constitute a magic answer to
CSR and the GVC literature (‘‘Theoretical contributions’’ the regulation of GVCs.
section) and an agenda for future research (‘‘Avenues for Overall, our work contributes to theoretically identify-
future research’’ section). ing the limiting conditions for the emergence of strategic
CSR initiatives in the specific context of GVCs (Vogel
Theoretical Contributions 2006). Indeed, TCT provides both a warning about and
guidance on the regulatory potential of strategic CSR
While the literature on strategic CSR suggests that CSR policies in the context of GVCs. According to TCT,
initiatives can be a source of economic and social progress, cooperation among chain members is not guaranteed, even
the GVC literature provides empirical evidence that effi- if there are business opportunities. Because of the presence
cient implementation of strategic CSR policies is difficult of various categories of costs and behavioural threats
and complex in the context of GVCs (Lund-Thomsen and among chain members related to the issue of sharing the
Lindgreen 2013; Gereffi and Lee 2014; Tsutsui and Lim shared value, cooperation in implementing a CSR policy is
2015). By using TCT, we contribute to bridging this gap, something to be achieved rather than assumed as a starting
and we develop theoretical explanations of the difficulties point. The conditions for the genuine diffusion of CSR
that chain members and their stakeholders face when they policies along GVCs appear considerably more complex
want to implement strategic CSR policies. By so doing, we than often suggested by strategic CSR scholars.

123
Author's personal copy
A. Acquier et al.

We also make various contributions to the GVC litera- (Ciliberti et al. 2009). By implementing such a standard,
ture. While academic research has largely debated the chain members can reduce the specificity of investments
positive and negative social and economic impacts of related to CSR policies, and can share the value of
GVCs on developing countries, more limited attention has investments with other business partners seeking to pro-
been paid to the factors favouring or inhibiting the emer- mote CSR in GVCs (Schleper and Busse 2013).
gence of CSR policies (Lund-Thomsen and Lindgreen In practice, however, the picture appears significantly
2013; Wahl and Bull 2013; Tsutsui and Lim 2015). The more complex. Empirical studies show an uncoordinated
theoretical apparatus of TCT can be useful for organising boom in—and an enduring multiplicity of—standards in
research in the field of GVCs, which has been described as GVCs (Reinecke et al. 2012). This proliferation of stan-
mostly case-based and lacking theoretical elaboration/in- dards seems to severely limit the ability of GVCs to sim-
tegration. Two notions are central in this regard: asset plify transactions and to reduce transaction/cooperation
specificity and GVC structure. When the implementation of costs (Chatterji and Levine 2005; Fransen 2011). They also
the CSR policy entails the development of specific assets, seem to indicate the existence of competition and oppor-
the cost of the policy is directly impacted and chain tunistic behaviours in the process of designing and dif-
members will have to internalise transaction and/or coop- fusing such standards. Last, standardisation processes seem
eration costs. These costs inevitably mitigate the economic to follow new logics on GVCs that can be depicted as a
gains that the policy offers. The structure of the GVC has process of ‘meta-standardisation’. This refers to a situation
also a direct impact on the implementation of the strategic where a multiplicity of standards may coexist, supporting
CSR policy. The presence of a dominant actor along the diversity in concrete attributes while convergence occurs
value chain can affect cooperation between chain members on overarching principles (Reinecke et al. 2012). Much
if this actor captures an important part of the value created research is needed to understand and assess the impacts of
by the policy. such standardisation processes on costs (organisational,
transaction and cooperation) and behavioural threats, in
Avenues for Future Research order to understand to what extent such codes and stan-
dards constitute a viable solution to the problem of asset
We explore three research avenues that, we believe, specificity.
deserve increased attention in the future to refine our
understanding of implementing strategic CSR policies in Multi-stakeholder Platforms and Efficient Cooperation
GVCs: the role of standards in taming asset specificity with Stakeholders
issues; the capacity of multi-stakeholder initiatives (MSIs)
to develop cooperation with stakeholders and the impact of From a similar perspective, and as a second research ave-
GVCs structures on the dynamic of implementing strategic nue, researchers should investigate the impacts of multi-
CSR policies. stakeholder platforms and collaborative devices on coop-
eration costs with secondary stakeholders. At the level of a
Standards and Asset Specificity GVC, stakeholders are numerous, divided and located in
remote areas—and suffer from a lack of democratic rep-
The first research avenue deals with the role of standards as resentation (Young 2006; Banerjee 2008; de Bakker et al.
a potential solution to the problem of asset specificity. As 2013). We need more knowledge to understand how chain
we have shown, asset specificity has a negative impact on members deal with these issues and construct legitimate
the likelihood of implementing a strategic CSR policy, political platforms capable of effectively and efficiently
because it requires actors to engage in investments that are linking chain members and their stakeholders. A first focus
both specific to the CSR project and hard to recover/re- for GVC scholars could be to study the contributions of
deploy once they are made. A major issue is thus to explore MSIs—defined as institutions and political platforms
ways to reduce asset specificity within GVCs. A potential involving corporations, stakeholders, civil society organi-
solution to the problem can be found through standards, sations, governments, academia and unions—in coping
labels and norms (Scherer et al. 2006). They allow—in with social and environmental challenges across industries
theory—the ‘de-specification’ of the investments that GVC on a global stage (Rasche and Gilbert 2012). By focusing
members must undertake, and facilitate efficient institu- on MSIs related to a single GVC (such as the sustainable
tional regulation (Liebowitz and Margolis 1995; Manning soy bean or coffee value chain), researchers could explore
et al. 2012). Ciliberti and colleagues show how the adop- how MSIs contribute to the construction of idiosyncratic
tion of global standards—in this case, SA8000, the social political platforms involving chain members, stakeholders,
accountability standard—can reduce information asym- unions and local representatives, to affect and facilitate the
metry and transaction costs between chain members cooperation between firms and their stakeholders. MSIs

123
Author's personal copy
Sharing the Shared Value: A Transaction Cost Perspective on Strategic CSR Policies in Global…

provide learning and legitimising platforms, enable issues Research should also explore how CSR initiatives may
to be selected, develop and enforce behavioural standards, contribute to the reconfiguration of GVC structures, and the
support auditing and compliance, and issue labels and potential power-redistribution mechanisms involved. This
certifications (Mena and Palazzo 2012). Research should would imply understanding which CSR solutions lead to
explore how these various objectives, which are all related making GVCs more modular (through, for example, the use
to cooperation costs with secondary stakeholders, are of standards), and which other solutions lead to more
tackled by MSIs. captive or relational GVCs. Complementary research may
Another issue directly related to the development of focus on the relationships and the degree of dependence
political platforms would be the role of states and public that GVC members will entertain. Depending on the nature
authorities in facilitating dialogue and discussions between of these relationships, Crook and Combs have shown that
chain members and their related stakeholders. In their lead firms express their bargaining power in different ways,
analysis of the role of public authorities in promoting and take more or less economic value (Crook and Combs
shared value and solving social issues, Porter and Kramer 2007).
articulate a clear role for state actors in enforcing regula- The role of lead firms deserves more consideration. The
tions ‘‘that enhance shared value, set goals, and stimulate literature on innovation and business ecosystems has shown
innovation’’. This includes setting ‘‘performance stan- how, in some cases, lead firms may take the role of techno-
dards’’, defining ‘‘phase-in periods for meeting standards’’ logical and industrial platform leaders, such as Intel in the
and ‘‘putting in place universal performance reporting computer industry (Gawer and Phillips 2013). Such platform
systems.’’ (Porter and Kramer 2011, p. 14). leaders organise technological innovation at the level of the
While this may be possible in Western countries, the ecosystem and the value chain. More research is needed to
situation is completely different in developing countries, understand whether such platform leadership can be trans-
where political institutions and nation states may be weak posed to CSR issues, and to describe and understand its
(Young 2006; Scherer and Palazzo 2011). Before imple- practical forms. The presence of leading firms in GVCs is an
menting strategic CSR, chain members—especially leading opportunity to engage in an efficient dialogue with stake-
firms located in Western countries—must be engaged in holders, and push chain members to think and act differently in
political CSR, and must develop local institutions and terms of CSR. But these leading firms have the responsibility
practices that will favour and facilitate dialogue between of constructing trustworthy relationships with their business
numerous stakeholders and chain members (Scherer et al. partners and stakeholders; otherwise, they will not cooperate
2006; Scherer and Palazzo 2011; Scherer et al. 2014). and strategic CSR initiatives will not emerge. Research must
be developed in order to understand how leading firms can
GVC Structures and Strategic CSR Implementation construct such relationships. We need to develop our knowl-
edge on governance mechanisms that favour cooperation
We have argued that GVC structures have a direct impact between actors. In this regard, economic incentives, control
on the implementation of strategic CSR policies. This is and enforcement mechanisms may appear as counter-pro-
especially so when the GVC encompasses a lead firm ductive to building cooperation and trust (Ghoshal and Moran
capable of exerting pressure and controlling a captive value 1996). Ethical-trade labels, initiatives to relocate agriculture
chain. In practice, GVCs scholars have theorised on and closer to consumers, and movements such as social businesses
documented different configurations of GVCs, each of and the sharing economy may provide interesting insights to
which relies on different coordination and control mecha- understanding whether such initiatives are based on trusting
nisms, and exhibits different types of power relationships relationships and shared purposes, or on more classic forms of
among actors (Gereffi et al. 2005; Elms and Low 2013). controls and incentives for CSR policies. Scholars need to set
Some configurations (market and modular) enable high aside, in their analysis, controls and incentives for CSR poli-
degrees of independence among actors, but others (rela- cies, and focus on the different practices and options that allow
tional and captive) are characterised by strong interde- chain members to bypass opportunistic behaviours and
pendencies, one-to-one interactions and power develop in practice trust-based relationships and shared
asymmetries. While some works have begun to consider purposes.
the influence of GVC structures on CSR implementation
(Vurro et al. 2009), important research questions remain
unanswered. For example, it is still unclear which types of Conclusion
GVC structure will enable or inhibit technological inno-
vation related to sustainability issues. Further work is With the support of TCT, we have shown in this research
needed to understand how each GVC configuration affects that GVCs members face many difficulties that slow down
economic costs, asset specificity and behavioural threats. and even prevent the implementation of strategic CSR

123
Author's personal copy
A. Acquier et al.

policies. By so doing, we offer robust theoretical tools for Arouri, M., & Pijourlet, G. (2015). CSR Performance and the value of
envisaging the numerous limitations observed and descri- cash holdings: International evidence. Journal of Business
Ethics. doi:10.1007/s10551-015-2658-5.
bed by many scholars in implementing CSR policies in the Baden, D. A., Harwood, I. A., & Woodward, D. G. (2009). The effect
context of GVCs (Lund-Thomsen and Lindgreen 2013; of buyer pressure on suppliers in SMEs to demonstrate CSR
Wahl and Bull 2013; Soundararajan and Brown 2014). We practices: an added incentive or counter productive? European
also propose research perspectives to shed light on the Management Journal, 27(6), 429–441.
Bair, J., & Palpacuer, F. (2012). From varieties of capitalism to
difficulties that actors face—and the pragmatic solutions varieties of activism: The antisweatshop movement in compar-
that they develop to bypass these—in implementing valu- ative perspective. Social Problems, 59(4), 522–543.
able CSR policies. Banerjee, S. B. (2008). Corporate social responsibility: The good, the
Mobilising TCT for analysing the implementation of bad and the ugly. Critical Sociology, 34(1), 51–79.
Barrientos, S. (2013). Corporate purchasing practices in global
CSR policies in GVCs also has a counterintuitive effect, as production networks: a socially contested terrain. Geoforum,
it reveals the paradoxical nature of policies that go against 44, 44–51.
the outsourcing logic at the heart of GVCs. Ultimately, it Barrientos, S., Gereffi, G., & Rossi, A. (2011). Economic and social
appears that GVCs are simultaneously a cause of CSR upgrading in global production networks: A new paradigm for a
changing world. International Labour Review, 150(3–4),
issues and an obstacle to their resolution. In GVCs, the 319–340.
commitment by a firm to increase its social responsibilities Boje, D. M., & Khan, F. R. (2009). Story-branding by empire
goes against the very logic underlying the fragmentation entrepreneurs: Nike, child labour, and Pakistan’s soccer ball
and dispersion of value chains. Indeed, the aim of frag- industry. Journal of Small Business and Entrepreneurship, 22(1),
9–24.
menting a hierarchically organised structure of production Burke, L., & Logsdon, J. M. (1996). How corporate social respon-
and dividing work between various legally and hierarchi- sibility pays off. Long Range Planning, 29(4), 495–502.
cally independent parties is to optimise the use of each of Campbell, J. L. (2007). Why would corporations behave in socially
the firm’s assets by setting up a system of market gover- responsible ways? An institutional theory of corporate social
responsibility. Academy of Management Review, 32(3),
nance, and systematically making the parties compete 946–967.
against one another. In contrast, implementing CSR poli- Chatterji, A., & Levine, D. (2005). Breaking down the wall of codes:
cies is diametrically opposed to this logic, since the parties Evaluating non-financial performance measurement. California
must come closer to each other, improve their coordination Management Review, 48(2), 29–51.
Ciliberti, F., de Groot, G., de Haan, J., & Pontrandolfo, P. (2009).
and agree on specific investments that will be profitable Codes to coordinate supply chains: SMEs’ experiences with
only through maintaining contractual relations over a long SA8000. Supply Chain Management: An International Journal,
period. As we have shown, this coming together makes 14(2), 117–127.
maintaining a strictly commercial framework of relations Clarkson, M. E. (1995). A stakeholder framework for analyzing and
evaluating corporate social performance. Academy of Manage-
especially problematic. Short of integrating the parties into ment Review, 20(1), 92–117.
a single legal and hierarchical structure, developing CSR Coase, R. H. (1937). The nature of the firm. Economica, 4(16),
policies apparently implies the setting-up of specific gov- 386–405.
ernance systems that will enable the parties to coordinate Coase, R. H. (1992). The institutional structure of production. The
American Economic Review, 82(4), 713–719.
themselves and handle the economic and behavioural Crane, A., Palazzo, G., Spence, L. J., & Matten, D. (2014). Contesting
threats. Thus, CSR policies in GVCs seem to be less a the value of ‘‘creating shared value’’. California Management
remedy for—and more a symptom of—the crises con- Review, 56, 2.
nected with the dispersion of responsibilities in GVCs. Crook, T. R., & Combs, J. G. (2007). Sources and consequences of
bargaining power in supply chains. Journal of Operations
Management, 25(2), 546–555.
Daudigeos, T., & Valiorgue, B. (2010). Les limites du traitement
marchand de la responsabilité sociale de l’enteprises, Revue
Française de Socio-Economie, (6), 65–86.
References Daudigeos, T., & Valiorgue, B. (2011). Conditions for value creation
in the marketplace through the management of CSR issues: A
Acquier, A., Daudigeos, T., & Valiorgue, B. (2011). Corporate social negative external effects framework. Business and Society,
responsibility as an organizational and managerial challenge: the 50(1), 28–49.
forgotten legacy of the Corporate Social Responsiveness move- de Bakker, F. G., & den Hond, F. (2008). Introducing the politics of
ment. Management, 14(4), 222–250. stakeholder influence a review essay. Business and Society,
Andersen, M., & Skjoett-Larsen, T. (2009). Corporate social respon- 47(1), 8–20.
sibility in global supply chains. Supply Chain Management: An de Bakker, F. G., den Hond, F., King, B., & Weber, K. (2013). Social
International Journal, 14(2), 75–86. movements, civil society and corporations: Taking stock and
Aragon-Correa, J. A., & Sharma, S. (2003). A contingent resource- looking ahead. Organization Studies, 34(5–6), 573–593.
based view of proactive corporate environmental strategy. The Dicken, P., Kelly, P. F., Olds, K., & Wai-Chung Yeung, H. (2001).
Academy of Management Review, 28(1), 71–88. Chains and networks, territories and scales: towards a relational
Arnold, D. G., & Bowie, N. E. (2003). Sweatshops and respect for framework for analysing the global economy. Global Networks,
persons. Business Ethics Quarterly, 13(2), 221–242. 1(2), 89–112.

123
Author's personal copy
Sharing the Shared Value: A Transaction Cost Perspective on Strategic CSR Policies in Global…

Donaldson, T., & Preston, L. E. (1995). The stakeholder theory of the King, A. (2007). Cooperation between corporations and environmen-
corporation: Concepts, evidence, and implications. Academy of tal groups: A transaction cost perspective. Academy of Manage-
Management Review, 20(1), 65–91. ment Review, 32(3), 889–900.
Eesley, C., & Lenox, M. J. (2006). Firm responses to secondary Knudsen, J. S. (2013). The growth of private regulation of labor
stakeholder action. Strategic Management Journal, 27(8), standards in global supply chains: mission impossible for
765–781. western small-and medium-sized firms? Journal of Business
Egels-Zandén, N. (2014). Revisiting supplier compliance with MNC Ethics, 117(2), 387–398.
codes of conduct: Recoupling policy and practice at Chinese toy Levy, D. L. (2008). Political contestation in global production
suppliers. Journal of Business Ethics, 119(1), 59–75. networks. Academy of Management Review, 33(4), 943–963.
Elkington, J. (1994). Towards the suitable corporation: win-win-win Liebowitz, S. J., & Margolis, S. E. (1995). Path dependence, lock-in,
business strategies for sustainable development. California and history. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 11,
Management Review, 36(2), 90–100. 205.
Elms, D. K. & Low, P. 2013. Global value chains in a changing Locke, R., Amengual, M., & Mangla, A. (2009). Virtue out of
world. World Trade Organization Geneva. necessity? Compliance, commitment, and the improvement of
Ernst, D., & Ravenhill, J. (1999). Globalization, convergence, and the labor conditions in global supply chains. Politics and Society,
transformation of international production networks in electron- 37(3), 319–351.
ics in East Asia. Business and Politics, 1(1), 35–62. Locke, R., Kochan, T., Romis, M., & Qin, F. (2007). Beyond
Fransen, L. (2011). Why do private governance organizations not corporate codes of conduct: Work organization and labour
converge? A political–institutional analysis of transnational standards at Nike’s suppliers. International Labour Review,
labor standards regulation. Governance, 24(2), 359–387. 146(1–2), 21–40.
Freeman, E., & Liedtka, J. (1997). Stakeholder capitalism and the Lund-Thomsen, P. (2008). The global sourcing and codes of conduct
value chain. European Management Journal, 15(3), 286–296. debate: five myths and five recommendations. Development and
Gawer, A., & Phillips, N. (2013). Institutional work as logics shift: Change, 39(6), 1005–1018.
The case of Intel’s transformation to platform leader. Organi- Lund-Thomsen, P., & Lindgreen, A. (2013). Corporate social
zation Studies, 34(8), 1035–1071. responsibility in global value chains: where are we now and
Gereffi, G. (1999). International trade and industrial upgrading in the where are we going?’. Journal of Business Ethics, 123(1), 1–12.
apparel commodity chain. Journal of International Economics, Lund-Thomsen, P., & Nadvi, K. (2010). Global value chains, local
48(1), 37–70. collective action and corporate social responsibility: a review of
Gereffi, G. (2005). The global economy: organization, governance, empirical evidence. Business Strategy and the Environment,
and development. The handbook of economic sociology, 2, 19(1), 1–13.
160–182. Lund-Thomsen, P., Nadvi, K., Chan, A., Khara, N., & Xue, H. (2012).
Gereffi, G., Humphrey, J., & Sturgeon, T. (2005). The governance of Labour in global value chains: Work conditions in football
global value chains. Review of International Political Economy, manufacturing in China, India and Pakistan. Development and
12(1), 78–104. Change, 43(6), 1211–1237.
Gereffi, G., & Lee, J. (2014). Economic and social upgrading in Maloni, M. J., & Brown, M. E. (2006). Corporate social responsibility
global value chains and industrial clusters: Why governance in the supply chain: an application in the food industry. Journal
matters. Journal of Business Ethics. doi:10.1007/s10551-014- of Business Ethics, 68(1), 35–52.
2373-7. Manning, S., Boons, F., Von Hagen, O., & Reinecke, J. (2012).
Ghoshal, S., & Moran, P. (1996). Bad for practice: A critique of the National contexts matter: The co-evolution of sustainability
transaction cost theory. Academy of Management Review, 21(1), standards in global value chains. Ecological Economics, 83,
13–47. 197–209.
Grayson, D., & Hodges, A. (2004). Corporate social opportunity!: 7 Marcus, A. A., & Anderson, M. H. (2006). A general dynamic
steps to make corporate social responsibility work for your capability: Does it propagate business and social competencies
business. Sheffield: Greenleaf Publishing. in the retail food industry?*. Journal of Management Studies,
Harrison, J. S., & Freeman, R. E. (1999). Stakeholders, social 43(1), 19–46.
responsibility, and performance: empirical evidence and theo- Margolis, J. D., & Walsh, J. P. (2003). Misery loves companies:
retical perspectives. Academy of Management Journal, 42(5), Rethinking social initiatives by business. Administrative Science
479–485. Quarterly, 48(2), 268–305.
Holmström, B., & Roberts, J. (1998). The boundaries of the firm Masten, S. E., & Saussier, S. (2000). Econometrics of contracts: an
revisited. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 12(4), 73–94. assessment of developments in the empirical literature on
Husted, B. W., & Allen, D. B. (2007). Strategic corporate social contracting. Revue d’économie industrielle, 92(1), 215–236.
responsibility and value creation among large firms: lessons from Matten, D., & Moon, J. (2008). ‘‘Implicit’’ and ‘‘explicit’’ CSR: a
the Spanish experience. Long Range Planning, 40(6), 594–610. conceptual framework for a comparative understanding of
Kaplinsky, R. (2004). Spreading the gains from globalization: what corporate social responsibility. Academy of Management Review,
can be learned from value-chain analysis? Problems of Eco- 33(2), 404–424.
nomic Transition, 47(2), 74–115. McWilliams, A., & Siegel, D. (2001). Corporate social responsibility:
Kaplinsky, R. (2013). Globalization, poverty and inequality: between A theory of the firm perspective. Academy of Management
a rock and a hard place. New York: Wiley. Review, 26(1), 117–127.
Kaplinsky, R., & Morris, M. (2001). A handbook for value chain McWilliams, A., Siegel, D. S., & Wright, P. M. (2006). Corporate
research. Ottawa: IDRC. social responsibility: Strategic implications. Journal of Manage-
Khan, F. R., Munir, K. A., & Willmott, H. (2007). A dark side of ment Studies, 43(1), 1–18.
institutional entrepreneurship: Soccer balls, child labour and Mena, S., & Palazzo, G. (2012). Input and output legitimacy of multi-
postcolonial impoverishment. Organization Studies, 28(7), stakeholder initiatives. Business Ethics Quarterly, 22(3),
1055–1077. 527–556.

123
Author's personal copy
A. Acquier et al.

Menard, C. (2000). Institutions, contracts and organizations. Per- habermasian perspective. Academy of Management Review,
spectives from New Institutional Economics. Cheltenham: 32(4), 1096–1120.
Edward Elgar. Scherer, A., & Palazzo, G. (2011). The new political role of business
Ménard, C. (1996). The economics of hybrid organizations. Journal in a globalized world: A review of a new perspective on CSR
of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 160(3), 1–32. and its implications for the firm, governance, and democracy.
Meyer, J. W., & Rowan, B. (1977). Institutionalized organizations: Journal of Management Studies, 48(4), 899–931.
Formal structure as myth and ceremony. American Journal of Scherer, A., Palazzo, G., & Baumann, D. (2006). Global rules and
Sociology, 83(2), 340–363. private actors-towards a new role of the transnational corpora-
Mitchell, R. K., Agle, B. R., & Wood, D. J. (1997). Toward a theory tion in global governance. Business Ethics Quarterly, 16,
of stakeholder identification and salience: Defining the principle 505–532.
of who and what really counts. Academy of Management Review, Scherer, A. G., Palazzo, G., & Matten, D. (2014). The business firm as
22(4), 853–886. a political actor a new theory of the firm for a globalized world.
Neilson, J. (2008). Global private regulation and value-chain Business and Society, 53(2), 143–156.
restructuring in Indonesian smallholder coffee systems. World Schleper, M. C., & Busse, C. (2013). Toward a standardized supplier
Development, 36(9), 1607–1622. code of ethics: development of a design concept based on
Neilson, J., & Pritchard, B. (2011). Value chain struggles: institutions diffusion of innovation theory. Logistics Research, 6(4),
and governance in the plantation districts of South India. 187–216.
Chichester: Wiley. Shelanski, H. A., & Klein, P. G. (1995). Empirical research in
Nidumolu, R., Prahalad, C. K., & Rangaswami, M. (2009). Why transaction cost economics: A review and assessment. Journal of
sustainability is now the key driver of innovation. Harvard Law, Economics, and Organization, 11(2), 335–361.
Business Review, 87(9), 56–64. Soundararajan, V., & Brown, J. A. (2014). Voluntary governance
Orlitzky, M., Siegel, D. S., & Waldman, D. A. (2011). Strategic mechanisms in global supply chains: Beyond CSR to a
corporate social responsibility and environmental sustainability. stakeholder utility perspective. Journal of Business Ethics.
Business and Society, 50(1), 6–27. doi:10.1007/s10551-014-2418-y.
Palazzo, G., & Scherer, A. G. (2008). Corporate social responsibility, Spence, L. J., & Rinaldi, L. (2014). Governmentality in accounting
democracy, and the politicization of the corporation. Academy of and accountability: A case study of embedding sustainability in a
Management Review, 33(3), 773–775. supply chain. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 39(6),
Palpacuer, F. (2008). Bringing the social context back in: governance 433–452.
and wealth distribution in global commodity chains. Economy Stigzelius, I., & Mark-Herbert, C. (2009). Tailoring corporate
and Society, 37(3), 393–419. responsibility to suppliers: Managing SA8000 in Indian garment
Perry, P., Wood, S., & Fernie, J. (2014). Corporate social responsi- manufacturing. Scandinavian Journal of Management, 25(1),
bility in garment sourcing networks: Factory management 46–56.
perspectives on ethical trade in Sri Lanka. Journal of Business Tsutsui, K., & Lim, A. (2015). Corporate Social Responsibility in a
Ethics. doi:10.1007/s10551-014-2252-2. Globalizing World. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Ponte, S., & Gibbon, P. (2005). Quality standards, conventions and Vogel, D. (2006). The market for virtue: The potential and limits of
the governance of global value chains. Economy and society, corporate social responsibility. Washington, DC: Brookings Inst
34(1), 1–31. Press.
Porter, M. E., & Kramer, M. R. (2006). The link between competitive Vurro, C., Russo, A., & Perrini, F. (2009). Shaping sustainable value
advantage and corporate social responsibility. Harvard Business chains: Network determinants of supply chain governance
Review, 84(12), 78–92. models. Journal of Business Ethics, 90(4), 607–621.
Porter, M., & Kramer, M. R. (2011). Creating shared value. Harvard Wahl, A., & Bull, G. Q. (2013). Mapping research topics and theories
Business Review, 89(1/2), 62–77. in private regulation for sustainability in global value chains.
Prahalad, C. K. (2009). The fortune at the bottom of the pyramid, Journal of Business Ethics, 124(4), 585–608.
revised and updated 5th anniversary. Eradicating poverty Williamson, O. E. (1991). Comparative economic organization: The
through profits. New Jersey: FT Press. analysis of discrete structural alternatives. Administrative
Rasche, A., & Gilbert, D. U. (2012). Institutionalizing global Science Quarterly, 36(2), 269–296.
governance: the role of the United Nations Global Compact. Williamson, O. E. (1996). The mechanisms of governance. Oxford:
Business Ethics: A European Review, 21(1), 100–114. Oxford University Press.
Reinecke, J., Manning, S., & Von Hagen, O. (2012). The emergence Williamson, O. E. (2008). Outsourcing: Transaction cost economics
of a standards market: Multiplicity of sustainability standards in and supply chain management. Journal of supply chain
the global coffee industry. Organization Studies, 33(5–6), management, 44(2), 5–16.
791–814. Williamson, O. E., & Winter, S. G. (1993). The nature of the firm:
Rivera-Santos, M., & Rufı́n, C. (2010). Odd couples: understanding origins, evolution, and development. Oxford: Oxford University
the governance of firm–NGO alliances. Journal of Business Press.
Ethics, 94(1), 55–70. Wilshaw, R., Unger, L., Quynh, C. D., & Thu, T. P. (2013). Labour
Russo, M. V., & Fouts, P. A. (1997). A resource-based perspective on Rights in Unilever’s Supply Chain: From compliance to good
corporate environmental performance and profitability. Academy practice. An Oxfam study of labour issues in Unilever’s Viet
of Management Journal, 40(3), 534–559. Nam operations and supply chain. Oxfam Policy and Practice:
Russo, A., & Perrini, F. (2010). Investigating stakeholder theory and Private Sector, 10(1), 1–108.
social capital: CSR in large firms and SMEs. Journal of Business Young, I. M. (2006). Responsibility and global justice: a social
Ethics, 91(2), 207–221. connection model. Social Philosophy and Policy, 23(01),
Ruwanpura, K. N., & Roncolato, L. (2006). Child rights: An enabling 102–130.
or disabling right? The nexus between child labor and poverty in Yunus, M., Moingeon, B., & Lehmann-Ortega, L. (2010). Building
Bangladesh. Journal of Developing Societies, 22(4), 359–378. social business models: lessons from the Grameen experience.
Scherer, A. G., & Palazzo, G. (2007). Toward a political conception Long Range Planning, 43(2), 308–325.
of corporate responsibility: business and society seen from a

123

You might also like